Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
February 7, 2022
The recent proliferation of private digital currencies or cryptocurrencies, such as Bitcoin, has led
to questions of whether the Federal Reserve (Fed) should create a central bank digital currency
Marc Labonte
(CBDC)—a digital dollar that would share some of the features of these private digital
Specialist in
currencies.
Macroeconomic Policy
In addition, several countries are moving forward with plans to create CBDCs, and this has
Rebecca M. Nelson
increased calls for the Fed to act. According to a survey from the Bank for International
Specialist in International
Settlements, more than 85% of central banks worldwide are researching, piloting, or in advanced
Trade and Finance
stages of development of CBDCs. For example, China has completed several digital currency
trials in major cities across the country, as well as cross-border trials with Hong Kong; the
European Central Bank hopes to launch a digital euro by 2025; the Eastern Caribbean is piloting
its digital currency (DCash) in four countries; and the Bank of Japan has announced a “phase
one” of testing a digital yen. The proliferation of CBDCs around the world has raised questions about whether the United
States is falling behind in the future of the financial system, and whether that could affect its “reserve currency” status.
Digital payments and account access are already widespread in the United States. A key question from an end user (e.g.,
consumer or merchant) perspective is: would a CBDC be faster and less expensive than the current system? A CBDC would
presumably allow for real-time settlement of payments—a feature that is not currently ubiquitous in the U.S. payments
system, but may become so after the Fed rolls out FedNow, its planned real-time settlement system. Creating a CBDC could
take several years, whereas FedNow is expected to be operational in 2023. Whether payments using a CBDC would be less
expensive than the status quo remains unknowable until detailed proposals have been made. (Cross-border payments have
been identified as offering greater potential gains in cost and speed.)
From an end-user perspective, CBDC proposals range from a system similar to the current status quo to one that is
fundamentally different. The Fed and private sector already operate bank-to-bank digital wholesale payments systems, some
of which are settled in real time, so a CBDC only accessible to banks may differ slightly from the current system. In contrast,
proposals for consumers to be able to hold CBDCs in accounts at the Fed would fundamentally change the role of the Fed
and its relationship with consumers and banks. Thus, depending on its attributes, a domestic CBDC could potentially
compete with private digital currencies, foreign CBDCs, private payment platforms, or banks. CBDC proponents differ as to
which of these they would like a domestic CBDC to compete with. CBDCs are more likely to compete with private digital
currencies as a payment means for legal commerce than to function in their other current uses (e.g., as speculative
investments or as payment means for illicit activities).
Depending on its features and how much it differed from the status quo, a U.S. CBDC would have an ambiguous but
potentially significant effect on financial inclusion, financial stability, cybersecurity, Federal Reserve independence,
seigniorage, and the effectiveness of monetary policy. If the CBDC mainly crowded out cash and cryptocurrency use, it could
make illicit activity more difficult, possibly at some expense of individual privacy. If used to deliver government payments,
the CBDCs’ ability to improve their speed and efficiency would depend on the extent of its adoption by those not already
receiving payments by direct deposit, which might be low unless mandatory.
To date, the Fed has not taken a position on whether creating a CBDC would be desirable. It has stated that it “does not
intend to proceed with issuance of a CBDC without clear support from the executive branch and from Congress, ideally in
the form of a specific authorizing law.” Regardless, Congress might choose to legislate in order to either explicitly authorize
or mandate the Fed create a CBDC and shape its features and uses, or to prevent one from being introduced.
Congressional Research Service
link to page 4 link to page 5 link to page 7 link to page 7 link to page 9 link to page 9 link to page 12 link to page 13 link to page 16 link to page 18 link to page 18 link to page 18 link to page 19 link to page 20 link to page 20 link to page 21 link to page 22 link to page 22 link to page 23 link to page 25 link to page 26 link to page 26 link to page 27 link to page 27 link to page 28 link to page 30 link to page 31 link to page 32 link to page 33 link to page 14 link to page 16 link to page 33
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
Contents
Introduction ..................................................................................................................................... 1
Digital Payments and Private Digital Currencies Today ................................................................. 2
What Is a CBDC? ............................................................................................................................ 4
Federal Reserve Views on a U.S. CBDC .................................................................................. 4
U.S. CBDC Design Options ...................................................................................................... 6
How Would a CBDC Differ from the Current System? ............................................................ 6
Approaches to CBDCs Around the World ....................................................................................... 9
Variation in CBDC Initiatives Across Countries ..................................................................... 10
International Organizations and Digital Currencies .......................................................... 13
Policy Issues .................................................................................................................................. 15
What Would a CBDC Compete With? Would a CBDC Crowd Out Private Financial
Services? .............................................................................................................................. 15
Cryptocurrencies ............................................................................................................... 16
Private Payment Systems .................................................................................................. 17
Commercial Banks ............................................................................................................ 17
Would CBDCs Be Less Costly and More Efficient Than the Current System? ...................... 18
Would International Coordination on CBDC Improve the Efficiency of Cross-Border
Transactions?........................................................................................................................ 19
Would CBDC Promote Financial Inclusion? .......................................................................... 20
Would a CBDC Enable Faster and More Efficient Government Payments? .......................... 22
How Would a CBDC Affect Privacy and Illicit Activity? ....................................................... 23
What Effect Would a CBDC Have on Systemic Stability? ..................................................... 23
Would a CBDC Increase or Decrease Cybersecurity Risk? .................................................... 24
What Other Risks Does a CBDC Pose to the Fed? ................................................................. 24
Would New Regulation Be Needed? ....................................................................................... 25
Would CBDCs Make Monetary Policy More Effective? ........................................................ 27
Would CBDCs Generate More Government Seigniorage Than the Current System? ............ 28
How Could the U.S. Dollar be Affected by Other Countries’ CBDCs? .................................. 29
The Role of Congress .................................................................................................................... 30
Tables
Table 1. CBDC Initiatives Worldwide: Selected Examples ........................................................... 11
Table 2. International Institutions and Regulatory Bodies: Central Bank Digital Currency ......... 13
Contacts
Author Information ........................................................................................................................ 30
Congressional Research Service
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
Introduction
Over the country’s history, the U.S. monetary system has undergone several fundamental
transformations, resulting in significant changes in how the financial system operates. Both
commercial banks and the U.S. Treasury issued their own paper currency until the 20th century,
and until 1864, there was no federal regulation of private bank-issued currency.1 The Federal
Reserve (Fed), currently the exclusive issuer of currency, was not established until 1914.2 For
most periods until 1933, the value of the dollar was fixed to precious metals; it has not been
convertible to gold or silver since. These changes were controversial at the time, creating winners
and losers, but are now taken for granted.
In recent years, digital currencies, such as Bitcoin, have been privately issued, and many
countries have begun developing central bank digital currencies (CBDCs). This has led to a
debate in the United States about whether the Fed should also issue a CBDC. It is an open
question whether the introduction of a CBDC would also lead to fundamental changes in the
financial system, or whether it would be more comparable to the introduction of electronic
clearing of paper checks—a technological change in back office operation that is largely
unnoticeable to consumers.
Congress has held several hearings on whether the United States should have a CBDC and, if so,
the features it should have and whether legislation is needed to enable or expedite that process.3
The current chairs of the Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs (S. 3571,
sponsored by Senator Brown) and House Financial Services Committee (Section 101 of H.R.
6321, sponsored by Representative Waters) both introduced legislation in the 116th Congress that
would have created CBDC and digital wallets at the Fed that any individual could hold CBDC in.
In addition, both bills would have allowed federal COVID-19 stimulus payments to be delivered
through those wallets. In the 117th Congress, legislation related to CBDCs includes H.R. 1030
(sponsored by Representative Talib), H.R. 2211 (sponsored by Representative Foster), H.R. 3506
(sponsored by Representative Hill), and H.R. 6415 (sponsored by Representative Emmer).
This report explains what CBDCs are and how they would alter the current financial landscape,
what steps the rest of the world is taking to develop CBDCs, the range of potential design features
for a CBDC, and what policy issues are raised by CBDCs. It starts with a brief description of
current payments systems and digital currencies.
1 For more information, see CRS Report R41887,
Brief History of the Gold Standard in the United States, by Craig K.
Elwell; and Franklin Noll, “A Brief History of U.S. Government Currency, 1861-Present: Part 1,”
Treasury Notes,
8/25/2014, at https://www.treasury.gov/connect/blog/Pages/US-Currency-Brief-History-Part-1.aspx.
2 Currency (“Federal Reserve notes”) is a liability of the Federal Reserve, but physically created at the Fed’s behest by
the Bureau of Engraving. Coins are issued by the U.S. Mint and are a liability of the Treasury Department.
3 U.S. Congress, Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, Subcommittee on Economic Policy,
Building A Stronger Financial System: Opportunities of a Central Bank Digital Currency, 117th Cong., 1st sess., June 9,
2021; U.S. Congress, House Committee on Financial Services, Task Force on Financial Technology,
Digitizing the
Dollar: Investigating the Technological Infrastructure, Privacy, and Financial Inclusion Implications of Central Bank
Digital Currencies, 117th Cong., 1st sess., June 15, 2021; U.S. Congress, House Committee on Financial Services,
Subcommittee on National Security, International Development, and Monetary Policy,
The Promises and Perils of
Central Bank Digital Currencies, 117th Cong., 1st sess., July 27, 2021.
Congressional Research Service
1
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
Digital Payments and Private Digital
Currencies Today
The U.S. financial system includes private digital currencies that currently have only a niche role
in payments. It also features widely available private digital retail payment systems based on the
dollar and underpinned by digital interbank wholesale payment systems run by the Fed and the
private sector. Currently, the Federal Reserve issues two liabilities that facilitate payments, paper
currency for retail payments and reserves that banks hold in accounts at the Fed for wholesale
payments. The latter are accessed digitally, as are balances held by consumers in bank accounts.
In traditional electronic payment systems, which predominate today, participants hold
fiat money
(i.e., serves as legal tender by government decree) in an account at a private commercial bank or
other financial intermediary that maintains accurate private ledgers of how much money each
customer has available. To make a payment, the payer instructs (using a physical check or an
electronic message) the intermediary to transfer money to the recipient’s account. If the recipient
holds an account at a different intermediary, those intermediaries will send messages to each other
via electronic messaging networks—even if the payment is made by paper check—instructing
each to make the necessary changes to their ledgers. The intermediaries validate the transaction,
ensure the payer has sufficient funds for the payment, deduct the appropriate amount from the
payer’s account, and add that amount to the payee’s account.4 When the intermediaries in these
payments systems are banks, they are closely regulated to ensure safety and soundness, consumer
protection, and financial stability. In addition, the value of the money is generally maintained by a
public central bank that aims to circulate a supply of money large enough to facilitate economic
activity, but not so large as to destabilize the value of money.
While these systems generally offer relatively fast, convenient, and safe payment options, they
involve significant costs and physical infrastructure to ensure the systems’ integrity, performance,
and availability. For example, payment system providers operate and maintain vast electronic
networks to connect retail locations with banks, and the Federal Reserve operates and maintains
networks to connect banks to itself and each other.5 In addition, although the traditional payment
system may be sufficiently fast and convenient for most transactions, some transactions can
involve brief delays. One such delay can be a lag time between when a payment (such as a
paycheck) is deposited at a bank and when the full amount of the funds can be used by the
individual.6
In recent years, thousands of privately issued
digital currencies have been developed and
captured public attention.7 Bitcoin, Ethereum, Dogecoin, and Litecoin are prominent examples.
4 Richard J. Sullivan, “The Federal Reserve’s Reduced Role in Retail Payments: Implications for Efficiency and Risk,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review (third quarter 2012), pp. 80-87.
5 Sullivan, “Federal Reserve’s Reduced Role.”
6 Regulation CC governs how long banks can take to make funds available to depositors. Aaron Klein,
How the Fed
Can Help Families Living Paycheck to Paycheck, The Brookings Institution, November 22, 2017, at
https://www.brookings.edu/research/how-the-fed-can-help-families-living-paycheck-to-paycheck/. Currently, the
Federal Reserve settles payments on a same-day or next-business day basis. Federal Reserve, “Potential Modifications
to the Federal Reserve Banks’ National Settlement Service and Fedwire® Funds Service To Support Enhancements to
the Same-Day ACH Service,” 84
Federal Register 221223, May 16, 2019, at https://www.federalregister.gov/
documents/2019/05/16/2019-09949/potential-modifications-to-the-federal-reserve-banks-national-settlement-service-
and-fedwire-funds.
7 For a more detailed analysis of these issues, see CRS Report R45427,
Cryptocurrency: The Economics of Money and
Selected Policy Issues, by David W. Perkins.
Congressional Research Service
2
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
Instead of transferring money by making changes to private, centralized ledgers of intermediaries
such as banks, these alternative systems generally make changes to public or
distributed,
decentralized ledgers. These ledgers are typically protected from manipulation or unauthorized
transfers with blockchain technology and cryptography (hence, many of them are referred to as
cryptocurrencies).8
Although portrayed as an alternative form of money, private digital currencies have not achieved
the defining characteristics of money—they are not a medium of exchange (i.e., widely accepted
for payment), a store of value (i.e., retains much of its value over time), and a unit of account
(i.e., an easily understood measure of the value of things). For example, because cryptocurrencies
are not legal tender—that is, there is no legal requirement for parties to use them to settle debts—
and they cannot be used to pay taxes, they may not function well as a medium of exchange. Thus
far, no cryptocurrency has succeeded in settling payments rapidly on a large scale. In addition, the
values of cryptocurrencies have been volatile, arguably making them poor stores of value and
ineffective units of account.9 Because the supply of cryptocurrency is typically determined by a
computer protocol and not a centralized authority like a central bank, it is not clear how or when
their values would stabilize.
Some developers have attempted to create cryptocurrencies with stable values, often called
stablecoins. Prominent examples are USD coin and Tether. Stablecoins may share some of the
technological features of cryptocurrency, but the issuer of the coin pegs the coin’s value to a
stable currency or basket of stable currencies (or to some other asset or commodity). In principle,
this could make stablecoins more attractive as a medium of exchange and store of value than the
cryptocurrencies that experience large and rapid changes in value. A Facebook (now Meta)-led
proposal to develop a stablecoin to be used for payments on the Facebook platform—initially to
be called
Libra and later rebranded as
Diem—generated much controversy before the initiative
was formally abandoned in January 2022.10
In most cases, private digital currencies’ decentralized nature and lack of centralized authority is
at the root of many of the challenges and risks they pose (discussed below). This has led some
observers to suggest that central banks could use the technologies underlying cryptocurrencies or
otherwise replicate certain features of the currencies to issue their own
central bank digital
currencies (CBDCs). The aim of CBDCs would be to realize the touted benefits of private digital
currencies in a way that would be “safe, robust, and convenient.”11 The rapid growth in
stablecoins and other cryptocurrencies has led to increased calls for central banks to consider
issuing CBDCs to maintain public money’s central economic role.12
8 For more information, see CRS Report R45116,
Blockchain: Background and Policy Issues, by Chris Jaikaran.
9 David Yemack,
Is Bitcoin a Real Currency? An Economic Appraisal, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Working Paper no. 19747, December 2013, pp. 2-3, at https://www.nber.org/papers/w19747.
10 For more information, see CRS Insight IN11183,
Libra: A Facebook-led Cryptocurrency Initiative, by Rebecca M.
Nelson and David W. Perkins.
11 Bank for International Settlements (BIS), Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures,
Central Bank Digital
Currencies, March 12, 2018, pp. 1-2, at https://www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d174.htm; hereinafter BIS,
Central Bank
Digital Currencies.
12 Markus K. Brunnermeier, Harold James, and Jean-Pierre Landau,
The Digitization of Money, Princeton University
working paper, August 2019, at https://scholar.princeton.edu/sites/default/files/markus/files/02c_digitalmoney.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
3
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
What Is a CBDC?
There is no consensus definition for what a CBDC would comprise—the term is used to refer to a
number of concepts.13 If defined simply as a central bank liability that is digital, the term could be
misleading in the sense that central banks already make their fiat money available digitally to
commercial banks for inter-bank payments and as a store of value through their central bank
reserve accounts.14 A broad, if imprecise, definition of CBDC provided by the Bank of
International Settlements (BIS) is a “digital form of central bank money that is different from
balances in traditional reserve or settlement accounts.”15 Rather than providing a definition, this
report will highlight where differences in definitions lead to differences in outcomes for users or
policy. However, there is no consensus on the exact form that a CBDC might take, since such
currencies could vary widely in their features and characteristics.16 As discussed below, the
mandates, authorities, and goals of different countries’ central banks vary, and so their motivation
and ability to issue a CBDC—and in what form—differ.17
Federal Reserve Views on a U.S. CBDC
In January 2022, the Fed released a report on CBDC, which it defined as “a digital liability of a
central bank that is widely available to the general public.”18 The report provides more detail on
the Fed’s vision for a CBDC:
CBDC transactions would need to be final and completed in real time, allowing users to
make payments to one another using a risk-free asset. Individuals, businesses, and
governments could potentially use a CBDC to make basic purchases of goods and services
or pay bills, and governments could use a CBDC to collect taxes or make benefit payments
directly to citizens.
The report identified four characteristics that it argued were necessary “to best serve the needs of
the United States”: It should be privacy-protected to the extent compatible with deterring criminal
use, intermediated (i.e., services would be offered through financial institutions), widely
transferable among holders, and identity-verified (i.e., not anonymous). The report took no
position on several design features, such as whether the CBDC would pay interest, whether it
could be used offline, and whether there would be size limits on transactions or holdings.
The report argued that a CBDC should be introduced only if it would
13 BIS,
Central Bank Digital Currencies, pp. 3-4.
14 Federal Reserve Governor Lael Brainard, “Digital Currencies, Stablecoins, and the Evolving Payments Landscape,”
speech at “The Future of Money in the Digital Age” conference, Washington, DC, February 5, 2020, at
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/brainard20191016a.htm. See also, Lael Brainard, “An Update on
Digital Currencies,” speech, August 13, 2020, at https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/
brainard20200813a.htm.
15 This definition rules out proposals for “synthetic CBDC” that is issued by private entities but fully backed by
reserves held in accounts at the Fed. The Bank for International Settlements (BIS) is an international financial
institution founded in 1930 and composed of 62 central banks, including the U.S. Federal Reserve; quotation from BIS,
Central Bank Digital Currencies, pp. 3-4. See also Agustín Carstens, “Digital Currencies And The Future Of The
Monetary System,” Bank for International Settlements, January 27, 2021, at https://www.bis.org/speeches/
sp210127.pdf.
16 BIS,
Central Bank Digital Currencies, pp. 3-7
. 17 Codruta Boar, Henry Holden, and Amber Wadsworth,
Impending Arrival – A Sequel to the Survey on Central Bank
Digital Currency, BIS, BIS Paper No. 107, January 2020, at https://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap107.pdf.
18 Federal Reserve,
Money and Payments: The U.S. Dollar in the Age of Digital Transformation, January 2022,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/publications/files/money-and-payments-20220120.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
4
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
provide benefits to households, businesses, and the overall economy that exceed any costs
and risks; yield such benefits more effectively than alternative methods; complement,
rather than replace, current forms of money and methods for providing financial services;
protect consumer privacy; protect against criminal activity; and have broad support from
key stakeholders.
The report acknowledges that existing payments are “generally effective and efficient” but
highlights financial inclusion and cross-border payments as areas for potential improvement and
notes that a CBDC could buttress the dollar’s international role as reserve currency. The report
also notes several areas where a CBDC could pose risks—including privacy, illicit activity,
financial stability, and cybersecurity—or impose costs on existing financial actors, such as banks.
The report stated that the Fed “does not intend to proceed with issuance of a CBDC without clear
support from the executive branch and from Congress, ideally in the form of a specific
authorizing law.” The report “is not intended to advance a specific policy outcome and takes no
position on the ultimate desirability of a U.S. CBDC” and was coupled with a request for public
comment. The public comment period is 120 days, and the Fed is soliciting comments on 20
different questions pertaining to CBDCs. The report also provides a summary of the research,
outreach, international collaboration, and technological experimentation that the Fed has
conducted in preparation for the potential introduction of a CBDC. The report did not address
what statutory changes, if any, would be required to introduce a CBDC.
In January 2021, Chair Jerome Powell reportedly stated that, if the Fed decided to move forward,
the introduction of a CBDC was years, not months, away.19 In March 2021, Powell was quoted as
saying, “We don’t need to rush this project, and we don’t need to be first to market…. The real
threshold question for us is does the public want or need a new digital form of central bank
money to complement what is already a highly efficient, reliable and innovative payments arena
and system.”20 Chair Powell was also quoted as saying that “we would need buy-in from
Congress, from the Administration, from broad elements of the public…. [W]e would not proceed
with this without support from Congress, and I think that would ideally come in the form of an
authorizing law, rather than us trying to interpret our law to enable this.”21
Other Fed statements on CBDC include various speeches, testimony, and a 2019 letter to
Representative French Hill. In this letter, the Fed highlighted legal uncertainty about whether all
of the actions that would be needed to successfully implement a CBDC could be taken under its
existing authority. These include whether a CBDC would be legal tender, whether the Fed can
offer accounts or digital wallets to the public, and what legal rights, obligations, and protections
CBDC users would have.22
19 “Fed’s Powell: CBDC Will Be Years, Not Months,” Away, PYMNTS, January 14, 2021, at
https://www.pymnts.com/news/payment-methods/2021/fed-powell-cbdc-years-not-months-away/.
20 CQ Transcripts,
House Financial Services Committee Holds Hearing on Monetary Policy and the State of the
Economy, February 24, 2021.
21 Michael S. Derby, “Powell Says Congressional Support Likely Needed to Adopt Fully Digital Dollar,”
WSJ Pro
Central Banking, March 22, 2021. See also Jess Cheng, Angela N Lawson, and Paul Wong, “Preconditions For A
General-Purpose Central Bank Digital Currency,” Federal Reserve,
FEDS Notes, February 24, 2021, at
https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/feds-notes/preconditions-for-a-general-purpose-central-bank-digital-
currency-20210224.htm.
22 Federal Reserve Chair Jerome Powell,
Letter to the Honorable French Hill, November 19, 2019. See also Paige
Paridon,
Legal Authority to Issue a U.S. Central Bank Digital Currency, Bank Policy Institute, June 9, 2021,
https://bpi.com/legal-authority-to-issue-a-u-s-central-bank-digital-currency/.
Congressional Research Service
5
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
U.S. CBDC Design Options
Any concrete proposal for introducing a CBDC in the United States needs to specify a number of
still-undecided design elements that would have implications for how it would work and be used,
and what advantages, disadvantages, and risks it would pose.23 These include the following:
How would the Fed regulate the supply of CBDC? The overall money supply
plays a role in determining inflation, and most central banks, including the Fed,
are tasked with maintaining low and stable inflation.
Should the Fed pay CBDC holders interest? Currently, most central banks pay
interest on bank reserves held at the central bank, but do not pay interest on
physical currency.
Who would be able to use CBDC—banks, financial firms, or the general public?
Who would be able to access and hold CBDC directly with the central bank? For
example, would any member of the U.S. public have direct access through
“
FedAccounts” or only approved intermediaries? If the latter, what types of
intermediaries should be allowed to exchange and store CBDC on behalf of the
public—banks, existing nonbank financial firms, or a new type of financial firm?
Should Treasury have any role in the issuance, production, or backing of CBDC?
Would CBDC be legal tender to pay debts? Would it be allowed to pay taxes and
receive government payments? Would banks and merchants be required to accept
them for payment? All of these considerations would affect how widely and
quickly the CBDC was adopted.
Should CBDC transactions be anonymous or traceable by the Fed?
Should CBDC payments and exchange flow through the Fed’s existing payment
and settlement systems, private systems, or should a new system be created?
Could CBDC be exchanged between users “offline”?
Should CBDC use the technology underpinning private cryptocurrencies (e.g.,
blockchain, distributed ledgers, cryptography)? Or would these technologies be
extraneous or counterproductive in the presence of a trusted central
administrator?
How would the Fed’s CBDC interface with other countries’ CBDCs in cross-
border payments? Should CBDC be available for use only in the United States or
globally?
How Would a CBDC Differ from the Current System?
Two key features of a CBDC is that it can be used digitally and can be transferred between parties
with negligible delay. Digital payments are already ubiquitous in the U.S. financial system for
those who choose to use them, however. Real-time payments (i.e., instantaneous settlement) at the
23 Federal Reserve Chair Jerome Powell,
Letter to the Honorable French Hill, November 19, 2019; BIS, “Central Bank
Digital Currencies: Foundational Principles And Core Features,” Report No. 1, 2020, at https://www.bis.org/publ/
othp33.pdf; Davis Polk,
Digital Dollars/Central Bank Digital Currencies, March 17, 2021, at
https://alerts.davispolk.com/10/5625/uploads/digital-dollars-central-bank-digital-currencies.pdf; Sarah Allen et al.,
“Design choices for Central Bank Digital Currency: Policy and technical considerations,” Brookings working paper
140, July 2020, at https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2020/07/Design-Choices-for-CBDC_Final-for-
web.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
6
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
retail level are currently available24 but not widespread. However, they may eventually become
ubiquitous after the Fed introduces
FedNow, its real-time clearing and settlement system, which
is currently planned for 2023.25 Since planning for a CBDC has not yet started, ubiquitous real-
time payments of dollars will likely already be the status quo if and when a CBDC were to
become available. Likewise, a CBDC could reduce counterparty risk currently involved in
settlement, but real-time settlement would also reduce that risk. This raises questions about how a
CBDC might differ from the current system or the system that will be in place once FedNow is
fully implemented, and has led some observers to wonder whether CBDC is a proverbial
“solution in search of a problem.”26
The technology underpinning many private digital currencies is structurally different from the
current payment system. Proposals vary as to the extent that a CBDC would or would not use
these technologies. Regardless of the technological underpinnings, a CBDC could differ very
little or very significantly from the current system from an end user’s (e.g., a consumer’s or retail
business’s) perspective, depending on its features. A CBDC that differed only on cost
effectiveness from an end user perspective would be justifiable enough to some. However, CBDC
plans are not detailed enough to speculate whether these differences would reduce costs to users.
Broadly, a CBDC could be compared to the current system under three scenarios based on types
of users—banks, financial firms (such as nonbank payment firms), or consumers/merchants
directly.27 A CBDC used only by banks would be the most similar to the current system from an
end user perspective. Banks (and a limited number of other financial institutions) already clear
and settle wholesale payments digitally through interest-earning digital accounts held at the Fed.28
Depending on the design, a CBDC could nevertheless have new features, such as a blockchain-
based ledger29 accessible to users or “tokenization” allowing it to be held or transferred outside of
the Fed’s payment network.30 Nevertheless, if access is limited to banks, it is possible a CBDC
would not lead to the availability of any new financial products or features for consumers.
24 The Clearing House Payments Company L.L.C. (PayCo) currently offers its members a private real-time payment
settlement service.
25 See CRS Report R45927,
U.S. Payment System Policy Issues: Faster Payments and Innovation, by Cheryl R.
Cooper, Marc Labonte, and David W. Perkins.
26 Marcelo M. Prates, “Central Banks Had to Up Their Money Game This Year – And They Did,”
Coindesk, December
21, 2020, at https://www.coindesk.com/money-game-central-banks-cbdc. Vice Chair for Supervision Randal K.
Quarles, “Parachute Pants and Central Bank Money,” Speech, June 28, 2021, at https://www.federalreserve.gov/
newsevents/speech/quarles20210628a.htm.
27 Federal Reserve Governor Christopher Waller, “CBDC: A Solution in Search of a Problem?,” speech, August 5,
2021, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/waller20210805a.htm; John Kiff et al,
A Survey of Research
on Retail Central Bank Digital Currency, International Monetary Fund working paper WP/20/104, June 2020, at
https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2020/06/26/A-Survey-of-Research-on-Retail-Central-Bank-Digital-
Currency-49517; Martin Chorzempa,
How Are Central Bank Digital Currencies Different from Other Payment
Methods? Peterson Institute for International Economics, April 21, 2021, at https://www.piie.com/research/piie-charts/
how-are-central-bank-digital-currencies-different-other-payment-methods.
28 These payments can be settled through settlement systems run by the Fed or private-sector settlement systems that
operate through accounts at the Fed.
29 For more information, see CRS Report R45116,
Blockchain: Background and Policy Issues, by Chris Jaikaran.
30 Note that there is disagreement over whether CBDC would be token-based or account-based, and over how those
terms are defined. Alexander Lee, Brendan Malone, and Paul Wong, “Tokens and Accounts in the Context of Digital
Currencies,” Federal Reserve,
FEDS Notes, December 23, 2020, at https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/feds-
notes/tokens-and-accounts-in-the-context-of-digital-currencies-122320.htm. Rod Garratt, Michael Lee, Brendan
Malone, and Antoine Martin, “Token- or Account-Based? A Digital Currency Can Be Both,”
Liberty Street Economics,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, August 12, 2020, at https://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2020/08/token-
Congressional Research Service
7
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
Allowing other types of financial firms to hold and exchange CBDC could potentially lead to
innovations in payments that are difficult to anticipate without any details about what the
CBDC’s features would be. A key difference could be that nonbank payment providers would no
longer need to route payments between different providers through banks.31 Still, the Fed’s role as
the central administrator and regulator of wholesale payment systems would not change, although
the underpinning technology would. Again, from an end user’s perspective, these innovations
may or may not be noticeable, depending on the CBDC’s other features. For example, nonbank
retail payment systems are already prevalent, but end users might no longer need to link retail
payment accounts to bank accounts.32
A CBDC that individuals hold and use directly could potentially differ more fundamentally from
the current system. In thinking about those differences, a key question is where individuals would
be permitted to store and access CBDC—at a bank, nonbank financial institution, or directly at
the Fed (popularly known as “FedAccounts”)? For end users, CBDC held in an account or wallet
at a bank might look similar to a bank account, perhaps with additional features and capabilities.33
But instead of being a liability of the bank, which is government insured up to the deposit limit,
the CBDC would be a risk-free liability of the Fed. FedAccounts would differ most
fundamentally from the current financial system, in which the Fed does not offer any retail
services to consumers. In this scenario, depending on design features, retail payments, direct
deposits, and government payments could potentially flow between individuals without involving
banks or any other existing payment intermediaries.
One characteristic of a CBDC that sets it apart from any private digital currency—and could
potentially justify its creation—is that “central bank money ... represents a safe settlement asset,
allowing users to exchange central bank liabilities with confidence in their acceptance and
reliability.”34 According to proponents, “[At present,] cash is also the only liquid asset for saving
outside of the private financial system.... We believe there is great demand for a virtual asset
issued by a trusted party [such as CBDCs] that can be used to save outside of the private financial
system.”35 If CBDC were held only by banks, this would not differ from reserve accounts banks
hold at the Fed in the current system. But if held by consumers, this would expose them to no
credit risk, unlike a private digital currency and uninsured balances held at a bank or in certain
payment systems—although it would arguably be as safe as federally insured balances held in a
bank account.36
or-account-based-a-digital-currency-can-be-both.html.
31 Instead of creating a CBDC, this could also be accomplished by giving nonbank payment providers reserve accounts
at the Fed. Policymakers have recently debated the merits of granting fintech payment firms a bank charter that could
result in them being granted reserve accounts at the Fed.
32 In the current financial system, if the two parties to a payment are not members of the same payment system, the
payment must flow through the banking system and the Fed.
33 A key feature that would determine comparability is whether the CBDC would pay interest. For purposes of this
report, whether CBDC were stored in accounts or wallets arguably does not raise meaningful policy differences.
34 Federal Reserve Governor Lael Brainard, “The Digitalization of Payments and Currency: Some Issues for
Consideration,” speech at Stanford, CA, February 5, 2020, at https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/
brainard20200205a.htm.
35 Aleksander Berentsen and Fabian Schar, “The Case for Central Bank Electronic Money and the Non-case for Central
Bank Cryptocurrencies,”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, vol. 100, no. 2 (Second Quarter 2018), at
https://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/2018/02/13/the-case-for-central-bank-electronic-money-and-the-
non-case-for-central-bank-cryptocurrencies/.
36 Technically, deposits are liabilities of the bank they are held in, unlike a CBDC, but they are federally guaranteed
under the deposit limit. Martin Chorzempa,
Testimony before the US-China Economic and Security Review
Congressional Research Service
8
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
Approaches to CBDCs Around the World
Since 2017, interest in CBDCs has evolved from a fringe policy initiative to an area of active
policy development for most countries around the world. In the mid- to late-2010s, only a handful
of countries expressed public interest in CBDCs. China’s central bank launched research on
CBDCs in 2014 as part of its broader efforts to internationalize the renminbi (RMB), maintain
control over its financial system as private cryptocurrencies proliferate, and gain greater
surveillance over individuals’ transactions. For other countries, notably Iran, Russia, and
Venezuela, early interest in CBDCs (around 2016-2018) was driven by a desire to evade U.S.
sanctions. Venezuela—in the midst of a severe economic crisis and subject to U.S. financial
sanctions—launched a blockchain-based CBDC, the
petro, in 2018, that was ultimately
unsuccessful.
Central bank officials in most advanced economies argued against the benefits of CBDCs and/or
announced that they did not intend to adopt a CBDC in the late 2010s.37 To varying degrees, they
questioned the need for CBDCs and cautioned that CBDCs could be prone to hacking and
undermine financial stability. Sweden was an outlier among advanced economies, launching a
CBDC (the e-krona) project in 2017 in response to the declining use of cash and increasing
reliance on private payment processors. Two international financial institutions, the Bank for
International Settlements (BIS) and the International Monetary Fund (IMF), published early
conceptual, exploratory research on CBDCs.38 Both institutions stressed the uncertainty
surrounding the benefits and risks of CBDCs.
The announcement that Facebook, along with a consortium of a couple dozen other companies,
intended to create a cryptocurrency for use on a global scale changed the assessments of the
potential importance of digital currencies at many central banks. Until then, cryptocurrencies
remained a small, niche, and volatile market that did not challenge the utility or prevalence of fiat
money in any meaningful way. Regulators around the world raised a number of concerns about
the project, including consumer protections and privacy, global financial stability, and monetary
Commission, April 15, 2021, https://www.uscc.gov/sites/default/files/2021-04/Martin_Chorzempa_Testimony.pdf.
37 For example, see Lael Brainard (U.S. Federal Reserve Board of Governors), “Cryptocurrencies, Digital Currencies,
and Distributed Ledger Technologies: What Are We Learning?,” speech, San Francisco, May 15, 2018,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/brainard20180515a.htm; Francesco Canepa, “ECB Has No Plan to
Issue Digital Currency: Draghi,” Reuters, September 14, 2018; Michael Kumhof and Clare Noone, “Central Bank
Digital Currencies: Design Principles and Balance Sheet Implications,” Bank of England Staff Working Paper No. 725,
May 2018, https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/-/media/boe/files/working-paper/2018/central-bank-digital-currencies-
design-principles-and-balance-sheet-implications; Tony Richards (Head of Payments Policy Department at the Reserve
Bank of Australia), “Cryptocurrencies and Distributed Ledger Technology,” speech at Australian Business Economists
Briefing, Sydney, June 26, 2018, https://www.rba.gov.au/speeches/2018/sp-so-2018-06-26.html; Bank of Israel, “The
Bank of Israel Published a Summary of the Work of the Team to Examine Central Bank Digital Currency (CBDC),”
press release, June 11, 2018, https://www.boi.org.il/en/NewsAndPublications/PressReleases/Pages/6-11-18.aspx; Geoff
Bascand (Governor of the Reserve Bank of New Zealand), “In Search of Gold: Exploring Central Bank Digital
Currency,” speech, June 26, 2018, Auckland, https://www.rbnz.govt.nz/research-and-
publications/speeches/2018/speech2018-06-25.
38 The BIS is an international financial institution owned by central banks (including the Fed) that fosters international
monetary and financial cooperation. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) is an international financial organization
that promotes international monetary stability. Morten Linnemann Bech and Rodney Garratt, “Central Bank
Cryptocurrencies,” BIS, Quarterly Review, September 17, 2017; “Central Bank Digital Currencies,” Committee on
Payments and Market Infrastructures, Bank for International Settlements, March 2018; and Tommaso Mancini-Griffoli,
Maria Soledad Martinez Peria, Itai Agur et al., “Casting Light on Central Bank Digital Currency,” IMF Staff
Discussion Note, November 2018.
Congressional Research Service
9
link to page 14
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
sovereignty. Many central banks accelerated their work on CBDCs in response to the project,
which Facebook formally abandoned in January 2022.39
Over the following years, CBDC policy initiatives have proliferated around the globe, with IMF
Managing Director Kristalina Georgieva arguing in April 2021, “the field is on the cusp of major
changes that have the potential to reshape cross-border payments and remittances.”40 According
to a BIS survey of 65 central banks, conducted in late 2020, with results published in 2021, the
vast majority of surveyed central banks—86%—are actively engaged in some sort of CBDC
work, although only 14% are in advanced stages of development (such as CBDC pilots).41 Central
banks not engaged in any CBDC work are generally from smaller jurisdictions. According to the
survey, central banks collectively representing a fifth of the world’s population are likely to issue
a CBDC in the next three years. An additional 21% of surveyed central banks consider it a
possibility.
Additionally, the BIS survey highlights the fact that many central banks are progressing from
research to conceptual development of CBDCs; most central banks are working on CBDCs that
would be directly available to consumers; and interest in CBDCs is stronger among emerging
market and developing economies than in advanced economies. Emerging markets are generally
viewed as having stronger motivations for launching CBDCs; increasing financial inclusion is
one of their top priorities for CBDC development. The survey also finds that most emerging
market and developing economies are mostly focused on CBDCs for domestic payments, but
some larger jurisdictions with ongoing pilots (likely a reference to China) also consider cross-
border payments efficiency as important. The survey highlights a major outstanding issue: the
compatibility of CBDCs with legal frameworks. About half of surveyed central banks are
uncertain as to whether they have the legal authority to issue a CBDC.
Variation in CBDC Initiatives Across Countries
Within these broad trends highlighted by the BIS survey, countries’ experiences with CBDCs to
date are quite v
aried (Table 1). Some central banks—including in Canada and the United
Kingdom—are researching CBDCs but have not yet made a final determination about whether
they will ultimately create a digital currency. Meanwhile, the Bahamas has already launched its
digital currency, the Sand Dollar, and some countries are in advanced stages of development. For
example, China has completed pilots in several major cities, and the Eastern Caribbean Central
Bank (ECCB) is piloting its digital currency—
DCash. At the same time, some CBDC initiatives
have faded or proved unsuccessful. A new government in the Marshall Islands is backing away
from the previous government’s efforts to launch a digital currency, called the
SOV, a policy
initiative about which the IMF expressed serious concerns.42 Venezuela’s petro currency is not in
circulation and is largely considered a scam.43
39 For example, see Stephen Perrenod, “Currency Wars: Libra Accelerates the Battle of the Central Banks,” Medium,
September 4, 2019; and U.S. Congress, House Committee on Financial Services,
Monetary Policy and the State of the
Economy, 116th Cong., 2nd sess., February 11, 2020.
40 Kristalina Georgieva (IMF Managing Director), “Leveraging Digital Money to Facilitate Remittances,” Opening
Remarks at iLab Spring Meetings Virtual Workshop, April 14, 2021.
41 For the most recent survey, see Codruta Boar and Andreas Wehrli,
Ready, Steady, Go? – Results of the Third BIS
Survey on Central Bank Digital Currency, BIS Paper No. 114, January 2021. Sixty-five central banks, representing
72% of the world’s population and 91% of the world’s economic output, responded to the most recent survey. The
respondents included 21 advanced economies and 44 emerging market and developing economies.
42 “Republic of the Marshall Islands: Selected Issues,” International Monetary Fund, August 10, 2018.
43 Brian Ellsworth, “Special Report: In Venezuela, New Cryptocurrency is Nowhere to Be Found,” Reuters, August 30,
Congressional Research Service
10
link to page 16
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
Central banks also have various time frames for testing, development, and launch, and these
timelines are frequently evolving. For example, in March 2021, the European Central Bank
(ECB) announced a four-year time frame for creating a digital euro and, in July 2021, announced
a 24-month investigation into the design and function of a potential digital euro. Similarly, Brazil
had been hoping to launch a digital currency by 2022, although it recently pushed back its time
frame by two to three years. Turkey’s central bank first announced its interest in a digital
currency in January 2021 and has signed contracts with domestic firms to develop and test a
prototype digital lira network. Sweden, in contrast, researched digital currencies for three years
before moving to testing.
China’s central bank—the People’s Bank of China (PBOC)—has been working on a CBDC for a
number of years and is widely seen as the most advanced in its development of a digital currency
among major economies. Since 2020, the PBOC has completed various trials and pilots for a
CBDC, including cross-border settlements with Hong Kong, Thailand, and the United Arab
Emirates. As of October 2021, about 140 million people had opened digital wallets for China’s
digital yuan and used it for transactions totaling about 62 billion yuan (nearly $10 billion),
according to a senior PBOC official.44 China’s two dominant payment systems—WeChat Pay and
AliPay—are partnering with the central bank on the digital yuan project.
Central banks are also looking at different design choices for their digital currencies. For
example, the Bahamas’ Sand Dollar and the ECCU’s DCash are only for domestic use, while
others, including France and Switzerland, are also testing cross-border CBDC transactions. While
most digital currencies under consideration would be or are directly available to consumers, Saudi
Arabia and the UAE are exploring a digital currency specifically for bank-to-bank transactions
(wholesale use).
Table 1. CBDC Initiatives Worldwide: Selected Examples
Jurisdiction
CBDC Initiatives
Advanced Economies
Canada
The Bank of Canada has undertaken various “proof-of-concept” experiments with
private-sector partners but would require more testing before settling on a model for a
CBDC. It is also still considering whether there is a compelling argument for a digital
version of the Canadian dollar.
European
In October 2021, the ECB began a two-year investigation into what a digital euro could
Central Bank
look like. The investigation is focused on how a digital euro could be designed and
(
ECB)a
distributed to retailers and the public, as well as the impact it would have on the market
and the changes to European legislation that might be needed. The decision to create a
digital euro will be based on the investigation.
Japan
In April 2021, the Bank of Japan launched experiments, to continue until March 2022, to
study the feasibility of issuing its own digital currency. The Bank of Japan has stressed that
it currently has no plan to issue a CBDC.
Norway
After four years of research, in April 2021 Norway’s central bank—Norges Bank—
announced that it plans to start testing technical solutions for a CBDC over the next two
years.
2018; Katia Moskvitch, “Inside the Bluster and Lies of Petro, Venezuela’s Cryptocurrency Scam,”
Wired, August 22,
2018.
44 Reuters, “$9.5 Billion Spent Using Chinese Central Bank’s Digital Currency – Official,” November 3, 2021.
Congressional Research Service
11
link to page 16
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
Jurisdiction
CBDC Initiatives
Sweden
Sweden’s central bank, the Riksbank, began researching the potential creation of an “e-
krona” in 2017. The Riksbank launched a pilot in 2020, focused on simulations within the
Riksbank. The second phase of the pilot, launched in 2021, also expands to include
transactions with parties outside the central bank, including commercial banks.
Switzerland
The central bank of Switzerland (the Swiss National Bank) has successfully tested a digital
version of the Swiss franc to perform instant transactions on the country’s main stock
exchange. In June 2021, the Swiss National Bank and the Bank of France launched a trial
for cross-border, wholesale central bank digital currency payments. In January 2022, the
bank successfully piloted transactions with commercial banks using a digital currency.
United Kingdom
In April 2021, the Bank of England and the HM Treasury announced the joint creation of a
Central Bank Digital Currency (CBDC) Taskforce to coordinate the exploration of a
potential UK CBDC. The UK government and the Bank of England have not yet made a
determination on whether to introduce a CBDC in the UK.
United States
The U.S. Federal Reserve (Fed) does not have a position on introducing a CBDC.
However, the Fed has been conducting research since 2020 with the Massachusetts
Institute of Technology to lay the technical groundwork for the potential creation of a
CBDC.
Emerging Market and Developing Economies
Bahamas
The Bahamas launched the “Sand Dollar” for its residents in October 2020. The Sand
Dollar is a digital version of the Bahamian dollar and is issued by the Central Bank of the
Bahamas through authorized financial institutions. Residents can use the digital currency
through mobile phone applications or using a physical payment card to access a digital
wallet. The Sand Dollar is backed by the central bank’s foreign reserves and restricted to
domestic use.
Brazil
In 2020, the Central Bank of Brazil announced plans to launch a digital currency by 2022.
In 2021, the central bank announced a two- to three-year delay in the launch.
China
China’s central bank—the People’s Bank of China (PBOC)—has been on the forefront of
CBDC development. In 2014, it created a dedicated research team on a digital version of
the yuan. The PBOC has since filed dozens of patents related to its digital currency, and
launched pilots in multiple cities and economic regions. China’s digital currency project is
to be initially domestically focused, but the PBOC is testing cross-border transactions.
Although a formal launch date has not been announced, about one-fifth of China’s
population has installed the central bank’s digital yuan wallet.
Eastern
The Eastern Caribbean Central Bank (EECB) launched a pilot of DCash in March 2021.
Caribbean
DCash is issued by the EECB and distributed by licensed bank and nonbank financial
Central Bank
institutions in four pilot countries (Saint Christopher [St. Kitts] and Nevis, Antigua and
(
ECCB)b
Barbuda, Grenada, and Saint Lucia). Consumers and businesses can use an application on
smart devices to make financial transactions. DCash cannot be used for transactions
outside the Eastern Caribbean Currency Union (ECCU).
Marshall Islands
The Marshall Islands’ legislature passed legislation in 2018 making a new blockchain-based
digital currency, called the Marshallese sovereign or SOV, legal tender. A new government
formed in January 2020 is taking a more cautious approach to the SOV, and the
Parliament is considering repealing the 2018 SOV Act. However, the SOV website is still
allowing interested investors to pre-register for the first public issuance of the SOV (no
date provided on planned issuance).
Turkey
The Central Bank of Turkey has not made a final decision regarding the issuance of a
digital currency but expects to report results from pilot studies in 2022. The central bank
has signed agreements with various domestic firms to form the Digital Turkish Lira
Collaboration Platform.
Russia
The Central Bank of Russia published a consultation paper on a digital ruble in October
2021 and in 2022 launched digital currency pilots with several domestic banks.
Congressional Research Service
12
link to page 16 link to page 17 link to page 17
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
Jurisdiction
CBDC Initiatives
Saudi Arabia and
The central banks of Saudi Arabia and the United Arab Emirates are collaborating on a
the United Arab
joint digital currency, Aber, for interbank money transfer. The central banks are
Emirates (UAE)
continuing to research and refine the currency, having completed a pilot in late 2020.
Ukraine
The National Bank of Ukraine piloted a digital currency—the e-Hryvnia—in December
2018, with about 5,500 tokens. The project included a test on distributed ledgers,
formulating a provisional framework and regulations, establishing a temporary accounting
model, and study of various impacts. The central bank is considering how to technically
advance a nationwide launch.
Venezuela
Venezuela launched a digital currency—the petro—in 2018, which is purportedly backed
by oil, natural gas, and mineral reserves and administered using blockchain technology.
The petro has not been adopted for general use, and there is little evidence that it is a
functional or operational digital currency.
Sources: CRS analysis of central bank press releases and news reporting.
a. The ECB is the monetary authority for the 19 European countries that use a common currency, the euro.
b. The ECCB is the monetary authority for the eight island Caribbean economies that use a common
currency, the Caribbean dollar.
International Organizations and Digital Currencies
Beyond a handful of cross-border trials, there has been relatively little coordination among
countries in their work on digital currencies. Several international organizations and regulatory
bodies, however, are seeking to increase international collaboration on digital currency issues, as
summarized i
n Table 2.
Table 2. International Institutions and Regulatory Bodies: Central Bank Digital
Currency
International Organization or Forum
Engagement with CBDC Policy Issues
Bank for International Settlements (BIS)
The BIS is owned by 60 central banks (including the U.S.
Starting in 2017, the BIS has surveyed central banks about their
Federal Reserve). Established in 1930 and currently
plans for CBDCs.
representing about 95% of world gross domestic
The BIS is working with a group of seven central banks (the Bank
product, its mission is to foster monetary and financial
of Canada, Bank of England, Bank of Japan, the European Central
stability, focusing on fostering discussion and facilitating
Bank, the U.S. Federal Reserve, Sveriges Riksbank [Sweden’s
collaboration among central banks.
central bank], and Swiss National Bank) on CBDC issues. In
October 2020, they laid out common foundational principles and
core features of
a CBDC.b In September 2021, the group
published more detailed reports on CBDC design and
interoperability, user needs and adoption, and financial stability
implication
s.c
The BIS Innovation Hub, established in 2019 to identify and
develop insights into critical trends in financial technology relevant
to central banks, is researching CBDCs as one of its six key
themes. BIS Innovation Hub Centers in Hong Kong, Singapore,
and Switzerland are particularly focused on CBDCs.
Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures (CPMI)
CPMI is an international standard setter that promotes,
CPMI—in collaboration with the BIS Innovation Hub, International
monitors, and makes recommendations about the safety
Monetary Fund (IMF), and World Bank—published in July 2021 an
and efficiency of payment, clearing, settlement, and
assessment of provisional domestic CBDC designs and central
related arrangements. Twenty-eight central banks,
including the Fed, are members of CPMI.
Congressional Research Service
13
link to page 18 link to page 18 link to page 18 link to page 18 link to page 18 link to page 18 link to page 18 link to page 18
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
International Organization or Forum
Engagement with CBDC Policy Issues
bank experimentation to determine to what extent they could be
used for cross-border paym
ents.f
Financial Action Task Force (FATF)
FATF sets standards and promotes effective
FATF has recommended that money laundering and terrorism
implementation of legal, regulatory, and operational
financing risks be “addressed in a forward-looking manner before
measures for combating money laundering, terrorist
the launch of any CBD
Cs.”g
financing, and other related threats to the integrity of
the international financial system. It was founded in 1989
and has 37 members, including the United States.
Financial Stability Board (FSB)
Created in 2009, the FSB promotes international
Under the direction of the G-20, the FSB in 2020 developed a
financial stability by coordinating national financial
“roadmap” to address current challenges in cross-border
authorities and international standard-setting bodies.
payments. One focus area is exploring the potential role of new
Members include the G-20 countries plus Hong Kong,
payment infrastructures and arrangements, includ
ing CBDCs.h The
the Netherlands, Singapore, Spain, and Switzerland.
FSB published its first roadmap progress report in Octobe
r 2021.i
Group of 7 (G-7)
With roots back to the 1970s, the G-7 is an informal
In October 2021, G-7 finance ministers and central bank
group of seven of the world’s largest advanced
governors issued a standalone statement on CBDCs. The G-7
economies: Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the
statement says that no G-7 authority has yet taken the “sovereign
United Kingdom, and the United States.
decision” to issue a CBDC and that “careful consideration of the
potential policy implications will continue.
”j
The United Kingdom, as the chair of the G-7 in 2021, published a
companion paper outlining 13 public policy principles for CBD
Cs.k
Among its recommendations, it maintains that “all entities in a
CBDC ecosystem (both public sector and any private sector)
should have operational resilience, data security, and
cybersecurity strategies and operating frameworks consistent with
national and international standards.”
Group of 20 (G-20)
The G-20 is a forum for advancing international
At the 2021 summit, the G-20 leaders encouraged a range of
cooperation and coordination among 20 major advanced
international institutions—including CPMI, BIS, the IMF, and the
and emerging market economies, including the United
World Bank—to “continue deepening the analysis on the
States.
potential role of central bank digital currencies in enhancing cross-
border payments and their wider implications for the international
monetary system.
”l
International Monetary Fund (IMF)
Created after World War II, the IMF is an international
In July 2021, the IMF published a pair of policy papers arguing that,
organization focused on promoting international
within its mandate, the IMF has a critical advisory role to play in
monetary stability. The IMF has 189 members, and the
the widespread adoption of digital money to ensure domestic
United States is the fund’s largest shareholder.
economic and financial stability and the stability of the
international monetary syst
em.m
Source: Compiled by CRS. See footnotes below for sources.
a. BIS,
Ready, Steady, Go? Results of the Third BIS Survey on Central Bank Digital Currency, BIS Papers No. 114,
January 27, 2021.
b. Joint report by the Bank of Canada, European Central Bank, Bank of Japan, Sveriges Riksbank, Swiss
National Bank, Bank of England, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, and Bank for International
Settlements,
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Foundational Principles and Core Features, October 9, 2020.
c. Joint reports by the Bank of Canada, European Central Bank, Bank of Japan, Sveriges Riksbank, Swiss
National Bank, Bank of England, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, and Bank for International
Congressional Research Service
14
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
Settlements,
System Design and Interoperability;
User Needs and Adoption; and
Financial Stability Implications,
September 30, 2021.
d. Benoît Cœuré (Head of BIS Innovation Hub), “Central Bank Digital Currency: The Future Starts Today,”
speech at the Eurofi Financial Forum, September 10, 2021.
e. Basel Committee, “Basel Committee Consults on Prudential Treatment of Cryptoasset Exposures,” press
release, June 10, 2021.
f.
CPMI, BIS Innovation Hub, and the World Bank,
Central Bank Digital Currencies for Cross-border Payments, July
2021.
g. FATF,
Updated Guidance for a Risk-Based Approach: Virtual Assets and Virtual Asset Service Providers, October
2021.
h. FSB,
Enhancing Cross-Border Payments: Stage 3 Roadmap, October 13, 2020.
i.
FSB,
G20 Roadmap for Enhancing Cross-Border Payments: First Consolidated Progress Report, October 13, 2021.
j.
G-7 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors’ Statement on Central Bank Digital Currencies (CBDCs) and
Digital Payments, October 13, 2021.
k.
G-7 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors’ Statement on Central Bank Digital Currencies (CBDCs) and
Digital Payments, October 13, 2021.
l.
G-20 Rome Leaders’ Declaration, Rome Summit, October 30-31, 2021.
m. IMF,
The Rise of Digital Money, Policy Paper, July 2021; and IMF,
The Rise of Digital Money—A Strategic Plan to
Continue Delivering on the IMF’s Mandate, July 2021.
n. Bert Van Roosebeke and Ryan Defina,
Five Emerging Issues in Deposit Insurance, IADI Policy Brief, September
2021.
Policy Issues
As the introduction of a “digital dollar” or U.S. CBDC has potentially significant implications for
the financial landscape, proposals have raised a wide variety of policy issues. As discussed above,
CBDC proposals vary greatly in their specifics (and some are not very specific), and the balance
between costs and benefits for many of these issues depends on the proposal’s details. The
sections below highlight areas where costs and benefits are sensitive to differences in proposals.
What Would a CBDC Compete With? Would a CBDC Crowd Out
Private Financial Services?
Introduction of a CBDC would be unlikely to leave the current financial landscape unchanged.
Given the potential substitutability between CBDC and the following, there is the possibility that
CBDC could, to some degree, crowd out
cash;
private digital currencies, such as Bitcoin;
foreign CBDCs, such as the one planned by China;
existing private payment systems; or
the existing commercial banking system.
In the eyes of many proponents, crowding out is the point of introducing a CBDC, as they view
existing or planned competitors (besides cash) as posing risks to or placing undesirable costs on
the United States. CBDC proponents do not agree on which of these competitors they view as
problematic, however. Thus, the desirable design features of a CBDC would depend greatly on
which competitor(s) pose concern. For example, CBDC proponents may have conflicting views
on whether a CBDC should be designed so that consumers could hold it in an account at the
Federal Reserve. As will be discussed below, some proponents perceive problems with the
Congressional Research Service
15
link to page 32 link to page 32
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
banking system that they assert could be addressed by FedAccounts offered directly to
consumers. Other CBDC proponents, including those concerned primarily with the potential
dominance of private digital currencies or foreign CBDC, might oppose FedAccounts on the
grounds that they would be undesirably disruptive to the existing banking system.
The potential implications of introducing CBDC that compete with or replace cryptocurrencies,
nonbank payment providers, and banks are discussed next. The implications for foreign CBDC
are discussed in the section below entitled
“How Could the U.S. Dollar be Affected by Other
Countries’ CBDCs?”
Cryptocurrencies
Developers and proponents of private digital currencies, such as cryptocurrencies, assert that
these systems could be used for more efficient, less costly, and faster payments, to the benefit of
consumers and merchants.45 As discussed above, they have not realized that promise to date.
CBDC might possess the technological advantages of private digital currencies without the
shortcomings that to date have prevented them from effectively serving the economic functions of
money. If successful, CBDCs might make private digital currencies less attractive or viable,
although introduction of a CBDC alone is unlikely to entirely displace them given that some of
their appeal, such as anonymity and decentralized control, might not apply to CBDCs. If
introducing a CBDC forestalled the widespread use of private digital currencies, it would
prevent—for better or worse—some of the broader policy implications associated with them.46
Many private digital currencies feature a certain degree of pseudonymity (i.e., identifying
information for participants’ real-world identity is not disclosed on the ledger) that offers greater
financial privacy than when payments are routed through banks, which generally record and store
information on individuals’ transactions.47 Greater privacy may appeal to individuals who
mistrust that their money and private information is safe at traditional financial institutions.
However, pseudonymity has facilitated money laundering and other crimes, including
ransomware attacks where the attacker demanded payment in cryptocurrency, raising the issue of
whether existing regulations appropriately and effectively guard against this possibility.48
There are also concerns that cryptocurrencies expose consumers and the financial system to
significant risks. Many consumers may lack familiarity with cryptocurrencies and how they work
and derive value, and thus may be exposed to risks that they are not aware of when they hold
them. In addition, although at present cryptocurrency ledgers appear safe from manipulation,
individuals, cryptocurrency exchanges, and other companies that offer services to cryptocurrency
holders have been hacked or targeted in scams. Accordingly, critics of cryptocurrencies have
raised concerns that existing laws and regulations do not adequately protect consumers dealing in
these currencies. In addition, if cryptocurrencies become a widely used form of money, it could
pose systemic risk and adversely affect the ability of the Federal Reserve and other central banks
45 Paul Schrodt, “Cryptocurrency Will Replace National Currencies By 2030 According to This Futurist,”
Time.com,
March 1, 2018, at http://time.com/money/5178814/the-future-of-cryptocurrency/.
46 See CRS Report R45427,
Cryptocurrency: The Economics of Money and Selected Policy Issues, by David W.
Perkins.
47 Leonid Bershidsky, “Bitcoin and the Value of Financial Freedom,”
Bloomberg, December 20, 2017, at
https://www.bloomberg.com/view/articles/2017-12-20/bitcoin-and-the-value-of-financial-freedom.
48 Report of the Attorney General’s Cyber Digital Task Force,
Cryptocurrency Enforcement Framework, U.S.
Department of Justice, October 2020, at https://www.justice.gov/archives/ag/page/file/1326061/download.
Congressional Research Service
16
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
to implement and transmit monetary policy.49 For example, stablecoins that are not backed
exclusively by currency holdings and insured bank deposits could be susceptible to runs.50
Within the universe of cryptocurrencies, critics differ in which types they view as problematic. At
one end of the cryptocurrency spectrum, some, such as Bitcoin, are not centrally issued or
controlled. This poses regulatory and law enforcement challenges but also limits the systemic
importance of the issuer. On the other end of the spectrum, were a “Big Tech” firm to introduce a
stablecoin, such as Facebook’s proposed Diem, that became a dominant vehicle for payments and
financial services more broadly, that would create implications for economic and political
concentration, as these firms are already some of the largest companies in the United States.
Users are more likely to substitute CBDC for private digital currencies in areas where the two
share common uses (e.g., legal payments) than where they do not overlap (e.g., private digital
currencies held as speculative investments or as payment for illicit activity). Thus, CBDC may be
a more effective competitor with stablecoins than with other types of cryptocurrencies.
Private Payment Systems
Among the CBDC design features not yet settled is whether the Fed would provide only money
for use in private payment systems or also the payment system itself over which CBDC would be
exchanged. Thus, introducing a CBDC for use in retail payments would have an uncertain effect
on competition among payments providers. It could enhance competition by reducing the natural
monopoly a private payment provider might enjoy from network effects, potentially lowering
costs to users. Greater competition could encourage further innovation.51 Alternatively, it could
drive private competitors out of the marketplace.52
If nonbank payment providers could hold and exchange CBDC directly and provide CBDC
services to merchants and consumers, it might increase their role—and decrease banks’ role—in
the financial system. Alternatively, if a CBDC were easy and inexpensive for individuals to
exchange on a Fed-provided network, it could crowd out both traditional and new payments
platforms. Although some view these platforms as too expensive for merchants and consumers,
supplanting them would not necessarily benefit consumers in the long run. There has been rapid
innovation in digital retail payments in recent years that has brought down some costs. Once
CBDCs were in place, the Fed might struggle to provide the same degree of technological
innovation as the private sector.
Commercial Banks
If a CBDC could be held inexpensively by consumers outside of banks (even if banks provided
CBDC services to customers53), a portion of consumers would likely shift their deposits away
49 For a more detailed analysis of these issues, see CRS Report R45427,
Cryptocurrency: The Economics of Money and
Selected Policy Issues, by David W. Perkins.
50 Joe Light, “Crypto Lode of $100 Billion Stirs U.S. Worry Over Hidden Danger,”
Bloomberg, June 16, 2021,
https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2021-06-16/crypto-lode-of-100-billion-stirs-u-s-worry-over-hidden-danger.
51 Federal Reserve,
Money and Payments.
52 See BIS et al,
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Foundational Principles and Core Features; Davis Polk,
Digital
Dollars/Central Bank Digital Currencies; and Tobias Adrian and Tommaso Mancini-Griffoli,
Central Bank Digital
Currencies: 4 Questions and Answers, IMF Blog, December 12, 2019, at https://blogs.imf.org/2019/12/12/central-
bank-digital-currencies-4-questions-and-answers.
53 Greg Baer and Bill Nelson, “A Costly Misunderstanding About CBDC,” Bank Policy Institute, December 17, 2021,
https://bpi.com/a-costly-misunderstanding-about-cbdc/.
Congressional Research Service
17
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
from private banks and toward CBDC, which would be a safe, government-backed liquid asset.
Bank accounts are only insured by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation for bank failure up
to a dollar limit, whereas all CBDC would be backed by the Fed. (CBDCs would be more likely
to crowd out banking services if they paid interest to holders.54) This shift would reduce the role
of commercial banks in payments and financial intermediation more broadly, and potentially
expand the Fed’s role. Commercial banks would need to find a new source of funding to replace
deposits that would be more expensive or less reliable, and this could result in them reducing
their lending.55 Critics assert that if CBDCs were to displace private bank deposits, the Fed would
have to increase its asset holdings, support lending markets (directly or by lending to banks), and
otherwise provide a number of credit intermediation activities that private institutions currently
perform in response to market conditions to avoid a reduction in credit availability.56 Critics argue
that taking on such a direct and influential role in private financial markets is an inappropriately
expansive role for a central bank, and political considerations would be inevitable, which could
reduce its independence. The Fed raises potential crowding out of banking activity in its CBDC
report as a risk consideration in introducing a CBDC.57
Would CBDCs Be Less Costly and More Efficient Than the
Current System?
Proponents of CBDCs generally argue that CBDCs could provide efficiency gains over traditional
legacy systems and contend that central banks could use the technologies underlying digital
currencies to deploy a faster, less costly payment system.58 For this to be the case, lower
operating costs when the system was up and running would have to offset the upfront
infrastructure costs of creating a new system (or modifying the existing system). With no
concrete, detailed proposal to introduce a CBDC in the United States, the claim cannot be
evaluated.
A CBDC cost advantage could potentially derive from efficiency gains or an implicit subsidy.
Critics fear that when the Fed competes with the private sector, its services would inevitably be
provided below market price because the Fed does not finance its capital expenditures in private
financial markets. If true, a CBDC could undercut private competitors. The Monetary Control Act
(12 U.S.C. 248a) attempts to prevent this by requiring the Fed to charge market prices for its
services, including “the return on capital that would have been provided had the services been
furnished by a private business firm,” but that concept is nebulous in this context. For example,
54 Tobias Adrian and Tommaso Mancini-Griffoli,
Central Bank Digital Currencies: 4 Questions and Answers.
55 Banks could seek alternative funding sources, but these would likely be more expensive after adjusting for risk,
which would reduce which loans are profitable at the margins. Alternatively, in today’s financial system characterized
by abundant bank reserves, banks could respond by reducing reserves instead of loans, if accommodated by the Fed.
56 BIS et al,
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Foundational Principles And Core Features, pp. 9-14
. Alternatively,
asset holdings and lending decisions could be shifted from the Fed to the federal government, but this would raise
another set of policy issues (e.g., greater potential political interference in credit markets), in addition to those
discussed above. For more on financial inclusion, see CRS Report R45979,
Financial Inclusion and Credit Access
Policy Issues, by Cheryl R. Cooper.
57 Federal Reserve,
Money and Payments.
58 Eswar Prasad,
Central Banking in a Digital Age: Stock-Taking and Preliminary Thoughts, Hutchins Center on Fiscal
and Monetary Policy at Brookings, April 2018, p. 14, at https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2018/04/
es_20180416_digitalcurrencies.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
18
link to page 31
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
the Fed does not charge consumers for the service provided by currency (although it benefits
financially from their use, as it would from CBDC).59
One of the main arguments critics—including various central bank officials—make against
CBDCs is that, in Fed Governor Lael Brainard’s words, there is no “compelling demonstrated
need” for such a currency, because central banks and private banks already operate trusted
electronic payment systems that generally offer fast, easy, and inexpensive transfers of value.60
Retail digital payment options that operate through the traditional payments system are widely
available and improving rapidly. According to Governor Brainard, one question that would need
to be answered in the affirmative to justify introducing a CBDC is whether it would “reduce
complexity in payments, improve end-to-end processing, or simplify recordkeeping.”61
In its CBDC report,62 the Fed notes the advantages of the current system that limit the potential
benefits of a CBDC—the robust use of physical cash, high confidence in the dollar as the reserve
currency, a robust banking system that meets the public’s needs, and, in the words of Governor
Brainard, the “widely available and expanding variety of digital payment options that build on the
existing institutional framework and the applicable safeguards.”63 Were the use of cash to
continue to decline in the future, that could strengthen the case for a CBDC.
In addition to the issue of cost, there is the potential for CBDC to increase convenience, which
would be of value to the public and businesses. Retail payment systems are currently
interoperable to the extent that they are linked through the banking system, but this means that
transactions between different systems can be slower and more costly than those within a system.
If CBDC leads to greater interoperability or becomes the ubiquitous payment method, payments
between systems may become more seamless.
The Fed has also noted that ongoing improvements to the existing system could potentially yield
many of the benefits of a CBDC without the risks. Notably, the Fed is in the process of
implementing FedNow, which would allow real-time electronic settlement of payments.64 In April
2021, Chair Powell questioned whether there would be a role for a CBDC once FedNow was
operational.65
The Fed has highlighted cross-border payments as an area ripe for reforms that could yield cost
savings and efficiency gains, as discussed in the next section.
Would International Coordination on CBDC Improve the
Efficiency of Cross-Border Transactions?
Although U.S. domestic payments are already relatively inexpensive and rapid (and scheduled to
become instantaneous soon), cross-border payments generally are not. Some commentators have
raised the possibility that larger efficiency gains are possible if cross-border payments could be
59 See the section below entitled
“Would CBDCs Generate More Government Seigniorage Than the Current System?” 60 Brainard, “Cryptocurrencies, Digital Currencies, and Distributed Ledger Technologies.”
61 Brainard, “The Digitalization of Payments and Currency.”
62 Federal Reserve,
Money and Payments.
63 Brainard, “Digital Currencies, Stablecoins, and the Evolving Payments Landscape.”
64 See CRS Report R45927,
U.S. Payment System Policy Issues: Faster Payments and Innovation, by Cheryl R.
Cooper, Marc Labonte, and David W. Perkins.
65 Federal Reserve,
Transcript of Chair Powell’s Press Conference, April 28, 2021, at https://www.federalreserve.gov/
mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20210428.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
19
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
made with a CBDC. To the extent a CBDC competes with bank and credit union accounts, it may
be worth noting that a type of cross-border payment known as remittances is largely carried out
by nonbank financial institutions, such as money transmitters.66 While banks and credit unions do
provide cross-border payment services, these transactions tend to involve several thousand
dollars, whereas many remittances are smaller, around a few hundred dollars.67 Cross-border
payments and remittances must often be completed through correspondent banks in order to link
banks in different countries, which can add cost, time, and complexity.68 Cross-border remittances
and payments can both have relatively high transaction costs.69
Without knowing the design features of a CBDC, it is unclear whether the use of CBDCs could
reduce cross-border costs and increase speed.70 For example, communities that depend on money
transmitters due to the proximity of branches overseas may find that CBDCs, although potentially
faster, are not as convenient if they do not possess the technology to convert the CBDC
remittance into a usable currency in their economy. If a U.S. CBDC proved to be more efficient, it
might help bolster the dollar’s role as the world’s dominant reserve currency.71
The Fed CBDC report noted that significant international cooperation would be needed to realize
efficiency and cost gains in cross-border payments.72 Beyond a handful of bilateral cross-border
testing arrangements, there has been relatively little international coordination among countries in
their CBDC efforts in comparison to other international financial issues, such as financial
regulatory reform after the 2008-2009 global financial crisis. Variation in national approaches
allows for experimentation and innovation, but if each central bank adopts varying technologies
and standards, it may be difficult to create interconnections between these systems to facilitate
cross-border payments. A fragmented system of CBDCs could make it more complicated and
expensive for U.S. consumers and businesses to complete cross-border transactions.
Would CBDC Promote Financial Inclusion?
Some CBDC proponents argue that it would promote financial inclusion. The Fed CBDC report
argued that the issue, while desirable, required further research.73 CBDC proposals featuring
FedAccounts available to the public have the greatest implications for financial inclusion.74 At the
66 For background, see CRS Report R43217,
Remittances: Background and Issues for Congress, by Martin A. Weiss.
67 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Report to the Congress on the Use of the ACH System and Other
Payment Mechanisms for Remittance Transfers to Foreign Countries, May 2015, at https://www.federalreserve.gov/
publications/otherreports/files/ACH_report_201505.pdf.
68 See CRS In Focus IF10873,
Overview of Correspondent Banking and “De-Risking” Issues, by Rena S. Miller.
69 The World Bank keeps track of transaction costs associated with remittances. For more detail, see, World Bank,
“Remittance Prices Worldwide,” at https://remittanceprices.worldbank.org/en.
70 BIS et al.,
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Foundational Principles and Core Features, Box 2.
71 “Reserve currency” refers to the high international demand for dollars and dollar-denominated assets due to
international demand for safe, liquid assets and the dollar’s dominance in international trade and financial transactions.
See CRS In Focus IF11707,
The U.S. Dollar as the World’s Dominant Reserve Currency, coordinated by Rebecca M.
Nelson.
72 Federal Reserve,
Money and Payments.
73 Federal Reserve,
Money and Payments.
74 Morgan Ricks et al.,
Central Banking for All: A Public Option for Bank Accounts, The Greater Democracy Initiative,
June 2018, at https://greatdemocracyinitiative.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/06/FedAccountsGDI.pdf; Tobias Adrian
and Tommaso Mancini-Griffoli,
Central Bank Digital Currencies: 4 Questions and Answers, IMF Blog.
Congressional Research Service
20
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
other end of the spectrum, a CBDC used only by financial institutions might have few
implications for inclusion.
Policymakers are concerned about the 5.4% of households who are “unbanked” (i.e., do not have
an account at an insured depository institution), as well as other households who are
“underbanked” (i.e., have an account but obtain nonbank alternative financial services).75 Some
observers believe that more Americans could be brought into the banking system if lower-cost,
more convenient banking services were available.76 If this were the primary factor for why some
households are unbanked or underbanked, some argue the creation of CBDC and individual
accounts at the Fed to hold CBDC could reduce the number of unbanked or underbanked.
(However, a Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation [FDIC] survey casts doubt on the premise
that cost is the primary reason why some households are unbanked.77) The extent to which this
policy goal was achieved would depend on what services the Fed offered to CBDC account
holders. To reduce the number of unbanked, a FedAccount would need to provide the services of
a checking account, allowing an account holder to be able to readily convert a CBDC into cash
and make retail payments from the account. For a CBDC to reduce the number of underbanked, a
FedAccount would have to provide other banking services, such as loans.
On the other hand, the introduction of a CBDC could accelerate the declining use of physical
cash, which could have negative implications for financial inclusion.78 Using a CBDC could
require a basic level of technological proficiency and access that could be prohibitive for some
people, assuming it would be accessed through a digital interface, such as a smartphone.79
Opponents also question whether a CBDC would be more affordable than private banking
services. Although this is unknowable in the absence of concrete proposals, under the Monetary
Control Act, services provided by the Fed must reflect the costs of provision. If costs are
calculated accurately—and the Monetary Control Act provides a detailed description of what
costs should include—it does not necessarily follow that the Fed could provide retail banking
services that were less expensive than those already provided by at least some private-sector
firms.
Independent of the question of cost is the issue discussed in the previous section—beyond the
basics of a CBDC, is there an economic rationale for the Fed to provide bank-like services to the
public? Proponents might argue that FedAccounts would improve economic efficiency by
pointing to the negative externalities to society as a whole that some households are unbanked or
underbanked. But opponents might counter that costs and benefits are sufficiently internalized by
75 Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC),
How America Banks: Household Use of Banking and Financial
Services, 2019 FDIC Survey, October 2020, at https://www.fdic.gov/analysis/household-survey/2019report.pdf.
76 For a more detailed examination of financial inclusion issues, see CRS Report R45979,
Financial Inclusion and
Credit Access Policy Issues, by Cheryl R. Cooper.
77 This point is debatable. In the FDIC’s unbanked survey, the top three reasons given are not related to convenience
and fees and are unlikely to be solved by a CBDC. They are (1) “do not have enough money to keep in account,” (2)
“don’t trust banks,” (3) “avoiding banks gives more privacy.” Four of the remaining six reasons given relate to cost or
convenience.
78 See CRS Report R45716,
The Potential Decline of Cash Usage and Related Implications, by David W. Perkins.
79 To address this issue, some proponents have called for a government-provided vehicle, such as a physical card, for
accessing, storing, and using CBDC. The features and capabilities of this vehicle might be limited compared to a digital
interface, however, depending on the vehicle and what other services were available to users. See Rohan Grey,
testimony before the U.S. House of Representatives Committee on Financial Services, Task Force on Financial
Technology, hearing on “Digitizing the Dollar: Investigating the Technological Infrastructure, Privacy, and Financial
Inclusion Implications of Central Bank Digital Currencies,” 117th Congress, 1st Session, June 15, 2021; John Miedema
et al., “Designing a CBDC for Universal Access,” Bank of Canada, Staff Analytical Note 2020-10, June 2020.
Congressional Research Service
21
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
the unbanked and underbanked to undermine any economic case for public provision, and that
other potential losses to economic efficiency (e.g., associated with monopoly provision by the
Fed) might outweigh any efficiency gains.
Would a CBDC Enable Faster and More Efficient
Government Payments?
Challenges in rapidly delivering Economic Impact Payments (“stimulus checks”) and accurately
identifying recipients during the pandemic80 led some to argue that such payments, and
potentially any other government payments to individuals, could be more effectively and
expeditiously made using a CBDC linked to FedAccounts.81 While households who received their
economic stimulus payment by direct deposit would likely receive their payments at most one
business day faster with a FedAccount, other recipients potentially would receive payments
significantly faster. (Once FedNow is operational, government payments made via direct deposit
for customers of participating banks could be delivered in real time in their regular bank accounts
without the need for a FedAccount.) The main lag, however, involves the government making
payments—for example, the time it takes agencies to obligate and outlay the funding and identify
eligible individuals and the correct payment details—not the delivery of payments once initiated.
The former would presumably be unaffected by the introduction of FedAccounts, absent other
changes in government administration.
Further, accurately identifying eligible individuals and the information needed to deliver federal
payments to them is hampered by the lack of a centralized federal government database with
comprehensive personal and financial information of U.S. residents. There are many policy
reasons beyond the scope of this report why policymakers have chosen not to create such a
database. But in order to facilitate more digital federal payments, FedAccounts might end up
replicating such a database—only with the database controlled by the Fed instead of some other
Federal agency.
If the underlying policy goal is to get government payments to significantly more individuals
more quickly than the status quo, then a key determinant of whether that would be accomplished
would be whether individuals—or at least those who were not already using direct deposit—were
required to receive payments through FedAccounts. If individuals could choose whether to create
an account with the Fed or continue receiving payments through their current method, it is
unclear whether a significant number of individuals who are not currently receiving government
payments by direct deposit would create a FedAccount. Without details on the costs and terms
that would be offered, it is difficult to speculate how attractive a FedAccount would be to the
unbanked. The top reasons offered for why individuals do not have bank accounts could also
make FedAccounts unattractive, depending on the terms offered.82 Assuming FedAccounts would
have to be accessed digitally, they could also be unattractive to some without access to or comfort
with the required technologies.
If FedAccounts were required for an individual to receive government payments, then the
immediate policy goal (faster receipt of payments) would be more effectively accomplished.
80 See CRS Insight IN11393,
Delivery of Economic Impact Payments (EIPs), by Gary Guenther.
81 U.S. Congress, House Committee on Financial Services,
Inclusive Banking During a Pandemic: Using FedAccounts
and Digital Tools to Improve Delivery of Stimulus Payments, 116th Cong., 2nd sess., June 11, 2020.
82 In the FDIC’s most recent survey of the unbanked, the top four reasons offered for not using banking services are
“Do not have enough money to keep in account,” “Don’t trust banks,” “Avoiding bank gives more privacy,” and
“Account fees too high.” See FDIC,
How America Banks: Household Use of Banking and Financial Services, 2019
FDIC Survey, October 2020, at https://www.fdic.gov/analysis/household-survey/2019report.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
22
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
However, the debate about the general costs and benefits of FedAccounts (as discussed above)
would also become more salient. Financial inclusion and faster payments would increase if the
system were universal, but concerns such as privacy, creating a
de facto national database of
personal information, cybersecurity risk, and crowding out of private business activity would be
amplified.
How Would a CBDC Affect Privacy and Illicit Activity?
Cash and some cryptocurrencies provide users with the ability to anonymously or
pseudonymously make transactions and store wealth. This has advantages (e.g., providing users
with privacy) and disadvantages (e.g., facilitating illicit activity). A decision would need to be
made about what level of user privacy should be provided, bearing in mind that a CBDC could
potentially substitute for cash, cryptocurrency, and digital payments.
Were individuals allowed to have unfettered access to CBDC, total anonymity (as offered by
cash) would be unlikely, and privacy would be harder to maintain under FedAccounts. In April
2021, Chair Powell stated that a CBDC similar to that planned in China—the aims of which
include increasing the government’s control of the economy and ability to monitor transactions—
would not work in the United States because of privacy concerns.83
But total anonymity is not a feature of traditional payment systems either—banks and other
electronic payments providers must comply with anti-money-laundering and bank secrecy laws.
Complete CBDC privacy would be inconsistent with the enforcement of those laws. According to
Governor Brainard, “If (a CBDC) is designed to be financially transparent and provide safeguards
against illicit activity, a central bank digital currency for consumer use could conceivably require
the central bank to keep a running record of all payment data using the digital currency.”84 This
would far exceed the data on private spending that the government routinely has access to
currently, for better or worse. For example, it could provide useful information to law
enforcement in the pursuit of financial crimes, but would also have “big brother” implications for
government monitoring of private activity. Steps could be taken to increase privacy, such as
holding and exchanging CBDC on an outside distributed ledger using cryptography, but
preventing illicit activity would require suspicious transactions to be able to be scrutinized by the
relevant authorities. The Fed CBDC report argued that the intermediated model (where users
access CBDC services through financial firms) could best balance tradeoffs between privacy and
preventing illicit activity.85
What Effect Would a CBDC Have on Systemic Stability?
Introducing a CBDC could potentially increase or decrease systemic risk. Advocates argue that a
CBDC available to any individual could increase systemic stability by imposing additional
market discipline on commercial banks and other providers of money-like assets, including
stablecoins. If consumers could make unlimited safe deposits directly with the central bank,
commercial banks likely would have to offer interest rates and limit risks at levels necessary to
attract deposits above the deposit insurance limit.86 Proponents argue that
83 Federal Reserve,
Transcript of Chair Powell’s Press Conference, April 28, 2021, at https://www.federalreserve.gov/
mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20210428.pdf.
84 Brainard, “Digital Currencies, Stablecoins, and the Evolving Payments Landscape.”
85 Federal Reserve,
Money and Payments.
86 Aleksander Berentsen and Fabian Schar, “The Case for Central Bank Electronic Money and the Non-case for Central
Congressional Research Service
23
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
The disciplining effect on commercial banks will be reinforced by the fact that, in the event
of a loss of confidence, customers’ money can be quickly transferred to central bank
electronic money accounts. In order to avoid this, the banks must make their business
models more secure by, for example, taking fewer risks or by holding more reserves and
capital, or they must offer higher interest rates.87
This “disciplining effect” is the same argument that skeptics of CBDCs argue would create a less
stable system, by making it more prone to runs. These critics argue that at the first signs of
distress at an individual bank, depositors would transfer their funds (or at least their uninsured
funds) to this alternative liquid, government-backed asset with a “simple swipe.”88 The Fed
CBDC report argues that the availability of CBDC “could make runs on financial firms more
likely or more severe.”89 This scenario could also have implications for taxpayers if runs on the
banking or broader financial system require a sudden ramp up of Fed lending to support illiquid
firms.90
Would a CBDC Increase or Decrease Cybersecurity Risk?
The Fed notes cybersecurity risks as one of its main considerations in determining whether to
introduce a CBDC. A CBDC would impose new cybersecurity risks on the Fed, but to the extent
that a CBDC substitutes for private services, it could reduce cybersecurity risk for the private
sector. In other words, all electronic payments and financial transactions face cybersecurity risk—
the main issue is whether the Fed or the private sector can cope with them better.91 The Fed has a
generally successful cybersecurity track record—unlike some private actors—in operating its
existing payment systems, but might be less nimble or innovative in addressing future cyber
threats. Depending on its characteristics, a CBDC would likely introduce new vulnerabilities that
are not inherent in the Fed’s current systems, which can only be accessed by a limited number of
highly regulated entities (mainly banks). In some CBDC proposals, CBDC services would be
offered to customers by financial intermediaries, which could introduce new cybersecurity
vulnerabilities by creating new entry points into Fed payment systems.92 Also, if a CBDC were to
become a dominant payment method, there is the issue of whether systemic risk from
cybersecurity risk is greater because there would be a single provider. For example, a single
dominant provider would offer users fewer alternatives if it became disabled, which would
increase the systemic impact of a breach.
What Other Risks Does a CBDC Pose to the Fed?
The Fed faces operational risk in providing a new and, in some ways, untested technology that
could become central to the financial system. Some aspects of a CBDC might be built using
Bank Cryptocurrencies,”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, vol. 100, no. 2 (second quarter 2018), at
https://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/2018/02/13/the-case-for-central-bank-electronic-money-and-the-
non-case-for-central-bank-cryptocurrencies/.
87 Berentsen and Schar, “The Case for Central Bank Electronic Money and the Non-case for Central Bank
Cryptocurrencies.”
88 Brainard, “The Digitalization of Payments and Currency,” p. 16.
89 Federal Reserve,
Money and Payments.
90 Tobias Adrian and Tommaso Mancini-Griffoli,
Central Bank Digital Currencies: 4 Questions and Answers, IMF
Blog, December 12, 2019, at https://blogs.imf.org/2019/12/12/central-bank-digital-currencies-4-questions-and-answers.
91 To some extent, this argument depends on whether CBDC is supplanting or supplementing existing private sector
activity.
92 Federal Reserve,
Money and Payments.
Congressional Research Service
24
link to page 9 link to page 9
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
existing Fed infrastructure, but others would take the Fed into areas where it has not previously
developed or tested technology or expertise. According to Governor Brainard,
A myriad of other operational challenges would need to be addressed, including electronic
counterfeiting and cyber risks. It is worth noting that the technologies used currently for
private-sector digital currencies do not provide the same level of information technology
reliability, integrity, and scalability as central bank systems in use today. Many of these
technologies do not provide for clear, predictable, and final settlement, which is a core
tenet of payment systems.93
As with any innovation, technical “hiccups” in a CBDC’s rollout, implementation, or functioning
could cause financial disruption or, at the extreme, financial instability. If there were technical
problems with CBDC, it could harm public confidence in the Fed’s overall competence. This is
referred to as a “reputational risk,” and could harm the Fed’s independence.
The Fed has more independence from Congress and the Administration than most government
agencies. Economists generally believe that for monetary policy to be effective, the public must
have a high degree of confidence in a central bank’s expertise and political independence. The
theoretical case for independence is stronger for monetary policy than for the Fed’s other
functions, particularly the business-like services it provides. Arguably, the Fed’s response to the
2007-2009 financial crisis demonstrates that when it moves into new policy areas, public and
political consensus in favor of its independence weakens. If this is generally true, offering
services directly to the public could weaken the Fed’s independence. Decisions about pricing of
services and availability surrounding CBDCs would arguably be subject to political pressure. A
shift to CBDCs from bank deposits that required the Fed to provide funding to the banking
system could also be subject to political pressure.
The Fed was designed as a “banks’ bank” that does not provide services directly to the public.
Depending on how a CBDC was designed, it could require the Fed to start providing services
directly to the public—particularly if individuals could hold accounts or digital wallets at the Fed.
According to the Fed, the number of CBDC accounts could number in the hundreds of millions.
The Fed has not developed expertise or staffing in areas required to serve the general public, such
as customer service.
Would New Regulation Be Needed?
Regulatory policy considerations for U.S. CBDC would depend significantly on what form it
took. As discussed above, CBDC proposals to date vary widely and are generally not well fleshed
out. Furthermore, it is undetermined whether a CBDC would or could be issued under existing
statutory authority. These unknowns mean that only a few very general and speculative points can
be made about how CBDC might be regulated.
Governments regulate private activities and actors. U.S. CBDC itself would not require third-
party regulation because it is issued by the Fed, which would likely set standards based on public
feedback. However, its use by the public and the firms providing CBDC services would likely
require some regulation, as they would pose risk to the Fed, consumers, and the financial system.
(What types of firms would provide those services and what those services would entail are some
of the undetermined CBDC features, as discussed in the section entitled
“U.S. CBDC Design
Options”.)
CBDCs might be used for retail payments. Currently, retail payments generally include transfers
of money effectuated by cash, checks, debit cards, or credit cards. While the use of cash is
93 Brainard, “Digital Currencies, Stablecoins, and the Evolving Payments Landscape.”
Congressional Research Service
25
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
generally unregulated (outside of tax obligations), checks, debit cards, and credit cards are subject
to an array of banking, consumer protection, and anti-money-laundering laws and regulations.
Further, transfers of money (including those that are initiated with physical currency by the payor
or involve the receipt of paper currency) face a range of reporting requirements for certain
transactions and suspicious activities, regardless of whether the transfer occurs from bank to bank
through wires, on P2P platforms such as PayPal or Venmo, or through more traditional money
transmitters such as Western Union or MoneyGram. These reporting requirements are generally
pursuant to Internal Revenue Service tax regulations and Financial Crimes Enforcement Network
(FinCEN) anti-money-laundering regulations. Thus, policymakers would need to decide whether
to treat U.S. CBDC like cash or other payment methods for regulatory purposes.
CBDC services might be provided by banks or nonbank financial institutions. Banks are already
highly regulated and supervised for consumer protection (including payments made through
banks) and safety and soundness by the Fed and other federal regulators. Regulatory oversight
includes their participation in payment systems. By contrast, when payments flow through
nonbank payment providers and networks and private payment systems, they face limited federal
regulation and are regulated largely at the state level.94 For example, money services businesses
are largely subject to state licensing rules and federal registration requirements with FinCEN.95
These entities face some reporting requirements for certain types of transactions but relatively
light federal oversight for other areas of risks such as safety and soundness.96 Further, payment
networks such as Visa and Mastercard are generally not regulated by bank regulators. Rather, the
banks that issue the cards are regulated.97 Private digital currencies also face limited federal
regulation.
If nonbank payment providers were able to use U.S. CBDC and provide U.S. CBDC services to
consumers, it raises the question of whether new regulation would be required to address policy
issues related to law enforcement, consumer protection, systemic risk, and cybersecurity risks.
One view would be that the relevant policy issues relate to payments regardless of the form they
take, and so there would be no need to change regulatory policy based on a change in the form of
payment alone. An alternative view would be that U.S. CBDC would create a new direct
relationship between the Fed and payment providers, subjecting the Fed to a direct exposure to
the firms that would warrant federal regulatory scrutiny beyond the current state licensing model
for nonbank payment providers. In either case, it remains to be determined whether new statutory
94 The Fed’s role in operating payment systems and regulating banks gives it some influence over private payment
systems. Furthermore, interoperability of certain private and Fed payment systems gives the Fed additional influence.
The Fed has authority to subject payments systems designated as systemically important to heightened prudential
standards, but it is unlikely that this authority could be extended to any payment provider using CBDC.
95 See CRS Report R46486,
Telegraphs, Steamships, and Virtual Currency: An Analysis of Money Transmitter
Regulation, by Andrew P. Scott. FinCEN is a bureau in Treasury that is generally responsible for implementing the
Bank Secrecy Act.
96 Some states have recently developed more expansive regulatory frameworks for cryptocurrency markets. For
instance, Wyoming’s special purpose depository institution charter has been used by cryptocurrency firms to set up
custody banks. For more information on this charter, see Wyoming Division of Banking, “Special Purpose Depository
Institutions,” https://wyomingbankingdivision.wyo.gov/banks-and-trust-companies/special-purpose-depository-
institutions. Additionally, New York implemented its “BitLicense” for virtual currency firms in 2015. For more, see
New York State Department of Financial Services, “Virtual Currency Business Activity,” https://www.dfs.ny.gov/
apps_and_licensing/virtual_currency_businesses.
97 One example of this is Regulation II, which caps interchange fees on debit cards charged by banks. For more on
interchange and its regulation, see CRS In Focus IF11893,
Merchant Discount, Interchange, and Other Transaction
Fees in the Retail Electronic Payment System, by Andrew P. Scott; and CRS Report R41913,
Regulation of Debit
Interchange Fees, by Darryl E. Getter.
Congressional Research Service
26
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
authority would be required or whether new regulation could be implemented under existing
authority.98
For each aspect of the U.S. CBDC market, Congress could grant new regulatory authority to the
Fed or to another regulator. One option would be to make the Fed, as the provider of CBDC,
regulator of all U.S. CBDC service providers. The Fed’s relationship with providers could be a
regulatory one, involving supervisory and enforcement powers, or a business one, involving only
agreed-to business standards, similar to the Fed’s relationship with the primary dealers.99 Another
option would be the payment systems model, where insured depositories whose primary federal
regulator is either the Fed, the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, or the FDIC can all
access Fed payment systems on equal terms. But even though the Fed does not regulate all
depositories, it still controls discretion over which ones may access its payment systems.100
Would CBDCs Make Monetary Policy More Effective?
A CBDC would be unlikely to have a first order effect on the conduct of monetary policy, as the
Fed already controls the supply of currency and bank reserves, and the money supply is largely
already transmitted digitally. According to the Fed CBDC report, the Fed expected it would be
able to maintain control over monetary policy but might need to maintain a larger balance sheet to
the extent that CBDC replaced bank reserves as a Fed liability.101
Nevertheless, observers also disagree over whether CBDCs would have a desirable effect on the
Fed’s ability to carry out monetary policy at the margins. A CBDC would have a greater influence
on overall financial conditions—thereby increasing the effectiveness of monetary policy—if the
Fed was allowed to pay interest on it. Proponents argue that, if individuals held a CBDC on
which the central bank set interest rates, the central bank could directly transmit a policy rate to
the macroeconomy, rather than achieving transmission through the rates the central bank charges
banks, which has an indirect influence on interest rates offered to consumers and businesses.102
Some have argued that introducing a CBDC is necessary to prevent the Fed from losing some
control over monetary policy in a scenario where a private digital currency becomes a dominant
payment method and the use of cash wanes. As noted above, no private digital currency has
become widespread, let alone dominant, in payments thus far. And private digital currency would
not end the Fed’s monopoly over the supply of bank reserves and the interest rate on bank
reserves, which is how the Fed typically conducts monetary policy.103
98 For example, a current debate is whether fintech payment providers should be allowed to operate under a special
purpose banking charter issued by the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency. A condition of granting the charter
could be compliance with regulatory requirements.
99 See Federal Reserve Bank of New York, “Primary Dealers,” https://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/
primarydealers.html.
100 The extension of bank charters to fintech firms has raised this policy issue for the Fed: Should any firm with a bank
charter be granted access to Fed payment systems? The Fed has issued a request for comment on a proposal to set
formal guidelines on requirements for an institution to access Fed payment systems. Any applicant would be required,
among other things, to adhere to a proposed risk management framework. In other words, legal eligibility (e.g., a bank
charter) would be a necessary but not sufficient condition for access. See “Proposed Guidelines for Evaluating Account
and Services Requests,” 86
Federal Register 25865, May 11, 2021, https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/FR-2021-05-
11/pdf/2021-09873.pdf.
101 Federal Reserve,
Money and Payments.
102 BIS et al.,
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Foundational Principles And Core Features, pp. 11-12.
103 John Kiff et al.,
A Survey of Research on Retail Central Bank Digital Currency, International Monetary Fund
working paper WP/20/104, June 2020, at https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2020/06/26/A-Survey-of-
Congressional Research Service
27
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
In addition, if holding cash (which in effect has a 0% interest rate) were no longer an option for
consumers, central banks potentially would be less constrained by the
zero lower bound.104 The
zero lower bound is the idea that the ability of individuals and businesses to hold cash and thus
avoid negative interest rates limits central banks’ ability to transmit negative interest rates to the
economy. Negative interest rates raise of host of other policy issues that bear consideration,
however, including effects on savers and bank profitability.105
Would CBDCs Generate More Government Seigniorage Than the
Current System?
CBDCs could increase government revenue through a seigniorage-like mechanism. An expansive
definition of seigniorage is that it is the income the government obtains from having government
(including central bank) liabilities act as money. Physical money—because it is liquid and low-
risk—earns no interest rate and carries a cost to produce. Money—both physical and electronic
(i.e., bank reserves) in the traditional system—is also a balance sheet liability to the issuing
authority, such as the Fed or other central banks.106 Money earns the government seigniorage
because its costs to produce are lower than the yield on securities that the Fed invests in. (The Fed
pays interest on bank reserves, but typically at a lower rate than the yield on its securities
holdings.)
If the Fed allowed individuals to hold a CBDC, the Fed would issue low- or no-interest liabilities
to individuals (as electronic entries in a ledger produced at lower marginal cost than physical
currency).107 Then, as happens now, the Fed would use those liabilities to fund purchases of
securities that earn a higher interest rate than what the Fed pays on its liabilities.108 This would
produce income, perhaps greater income than is earned through traditional seigniorage.
Seigniorage would be greater if CBDC holdings earned no interest.109
The amount of seigniorage the government earns is dependent in part on the amount of
government liabilities issued, which demands on both domestic and foreign demand for the
dollar. Much of the foreign demand for the dollar stems from its role as a reserve currency,
discussed in the next section.
Research-on-Retail-Central-Bank-Digital-Currency-49517.
104 Eswar Prasad,
Central Banking in a Digital Age: Stock-Taking and Preliminary Thoughts, Hutchins Center on
Fiscal and Monetary Policy at Brookings, April 2018, pp. 19-20, at https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/
2018/04/es_20180416_digitalcurrencies.pdf.
105 See CRS Insight IN10481,
Negative Interest Rates, by Marc Labonte (out of print; available to congressional clients
upon request from the author).
106 Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan, “Regulation of Electronic Payment Systems,” remarks at the U.S.
Treasury Conference on Electronic Money and Banking: The Role of Government, Washington, DC, September 19,
1996, at https://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/1996/19960919.htm.
107 For simplicity, this discussion abstracts from the upfront costs of creating a CBDC and to what extent and how long
it would take the Fed to recoup those costs. As discussed above, current statute requires the Fed to recoup costs from
users.
108 While the Fed has always earned positive income using this strategy, it is possible for the Fed to lose income if the
interest on its liabilities exceeds the interest on its securities holdings. In particular, this could occur when the yield
curve is inverted (i.e., when long-term interest rates are lower than short-term rates).
109 If CBDC paid interest and only substituted for physical currency, seigniorage would decline.
Congressional Research Service
28
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
How Could the U.S. Dollar be Affected by Other
Countries’ CBDCs?
As central banks around the world launch, or work towards launching, digital currencies, there
could be implications for the role of the U.S. dollar in the global economy.110 Since World War II,
the U.S. dollar has functioned as the world’s dominant reserve currency. A reserve currency is a
currency held by central banks in significant quantities.111 It is widely used to conduct
international trade and financial transactions, eliminating the costs of settling transactions
involving different currencies. Today, central banks hold about 60% of their foreign exchange
reserves in dollars, about half of international trade is invoiced in dollars, and about half of all
international loans and global debt securities are denominated in dollars.112 In foreign exchange
markets, where currencies are traded, dollars are involved in nearly 90% of all transactions.113
The U.S. economy generally benefits from the dollar’s status as the world’s dominant reserve
currency, including by lowering borrowing costs for the U.S. government.
Some policymakers have expressed concerns that if another central bank succeeds in developing
a broadly adopted digital currency before the United States does so, the use of U.S. dollars in the
global economy could decline. For example, in a 2019 letter to Fed Chair Jerome Powell,
Representatives French Hill and Bill Foster wrote, “We are concerned that the primacy of the
U.S. Dollar could be in long-term jeopardy from a wide adoption of digital fiat currencies.”114 To
date, there is little evidence of a pivot away from the U.S. dollar towards other currencies,
although no major economy has yet launched a digital currency. It is also worth noting that some
central banks are specifically motivated to create digital currencies to boost international usage of
their currency. Most notably, China’s government is pursuing a digital currency to boost the use
of the RMB for trade, lending, borrowing, and investing internationally. The European
Commission has also made it a goal to boost the euro’s use outside the Euro area, and the ECB
has stressed that a digital euro could increase the currency’s appeal.115 One of the undetermined
features of a CBDC is whether it would be available for use abroad or only domestically. Making
it available internationally would bolster the dollar’s reserve currency status but could make some
of the risks, such as preventing money laundering, more difficult to manage.116
110 See CRS In Focus IF11707,
The U.S. Dollar as the World’s Dominant Reserve Currency, coordinated by Rebecca
M. Nelson.
111 Other reserve currencies include the euro, the yen, the British pound, the renminbi (RMB), the Canadian dollar, the
Swiss franc, and the Australian dollar.
112 IMF, Currency Composition of Official Foreign Exchange Reserves (COFER) Database, updated March 31, 2021;
Economist, “America’s Aggressive Use of Sanctions Endangers the Dollar’s Reign,” January 18, 2020; BIS,
US Dollar
Funding: An International Perspective, Committee on the Global Financial System Papers No. 65, June 18, 2020.
113 BIS,
Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange and Over-the-Counter (OTC) Derivatives Markets in
2019, September 16, 2019.
114 Letter from Rep. French Hill and Rep. Bill Foster to the Honorable Jerome H. Powell, Chairman of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September 30, 2019.
115 “Digital Euro Could Boost Single Currency’s International Use, ECB Says,” Reuters, June 2, 2021.
116 Federal Reserve Governor Christopher Waller, “CBDC: A Solution in Search of a Problem?,” speech, August 5,
2021, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/waller20210805a.htm.
Congressional Research Service
29
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
The Role of Congress
As CBDC proposals, pilots, and initiatives take shape around the world, it is unclear whether the
Fed plans to introduce a CBDC under its existing authority and, if it did so, what characteristics it
would have. Before that happens, Congress could decide to legislate to require or block the
creation of a CBDC. Depending on its policy objectives, Congress could consider legislation
stipulating to the Fed the time frame and features for developing a U.S. CBDC. Alternatively,
Congress may choose to defer to the Fed on CBDC policy matters. For its part, the Fed has stated
that it “does not intend to proceed with issuance of a CBDC without clear support from the
executive branch and from Congress, ideally in the form of a specific authorizing law.”117
Whether the Fed would need any additional statutory authority to introduce a CBDC would
depend, in part, on what form the CBDC took, and CBDC proposals vary widely. Congress could
require the Fed to report to Congress on the legal changes that might be needed and the policy
implications of introducing a CBDC. Congress could also pass legislation requiring the
Administration to analyze and report on the implications of other countries’ CBDC efforts.
As Congress considers its policy approach to CBDCs, it faces a range of policy issues. Congress
may want to consider whether there are specific policy problems that could be addressed by a
digital dollar and, if so, how that should inform the design of a digital currency. Congress may
also consider how to weigh all the various benefits, costs, and uncertainties surrounding a digital
dollar, and how it could build consumer trust in a digital currency, particularly relating to privacy
and cybersecurity. Congress may also consider how the cost of developing a new digital currency
should be defrayed.
In light of other countries’ efforts, Congress may consider whether there is a first-mover
advantage to creating a CBDC in terms of usage and standard-setting, or whether there are
advantages from taking a wait-and-see or lessons-learned approach. Congress may also consider
how the United States should respond to other countries’ CBDC initiatives, and whether the
United States should take a leadership role in international coordination and collaboration on
CBDCs by directing the Administration to lead international efforts through various international
forums, such as the G-7, the G-20, the IMF, and the BIS, among others.
Author Information
Marc Labonte
Rebecca M. Nelson
Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
Specialist in International Trade and Finance
Acknowledgments
David Perkins of the Congressional Research Service coauthored an earlier version of material that appears
in this report. Andrew Scott of the Congressional Research Service also contributed to an earlier version of
this material.
117 Federal Reserve,
Money and Payments.
Congressional Research Service
30
Central Bank Digital Currencies: Policy Issues
Disclaimer
This document was prepared by the Congressional Research Service (CRS). CRS serves as nonpartisan
shared staff to congressional committees and Members of Congress. It operates solely at the behest of and
under the direction of Congress. Information in a CRS Report should not be relied upon for purposes other
than public understanding of information that has been provided by CRS to Members of Congress in
connection with CRS’s institutional role. CRS Reports, as a work of the United States Government, are not
subject to copyright protection in the United States. Any CRS Report may be reproduced and distributed in
its entirety without permission from CRS. However, as a CRS Report may include copyrighted images or
material from a third party, you may need to obtain the permission of the copyright holder if you wish to
copy or otherwise use copyrighted material.
Congressional Research Service
R46850
· VERSION 4 · UPDATED
31