Capital Gains Taxes: An Overview

Taxes on long-term capital gains (on assets held for at least a year) are imposed at rates that correspond to pre-2018 brackets: a 0% rate for those whose income placed them in the regular 15% bracket or less (now in regular bracket of 12%), and 15% for taxpayers in higher brackets, except for those in the 39.6% bracket. The tax revision adopted in December 2018 (P.L. 115-97) maintained the links to the income level corresponding to the rate brackets in prior law. Therefore, the tax rates on capital gains are affected only by changes in the deductions to arrive at taxable income and the use of a different method of indexing for inflation. Under the new law, the original 10% and 15% brackets are replaced by a single 12% rate bracket that ends at the same point as the end of the 15% bracket. There is no 39.6% bracket (the top rate is 37% and begins at a higher level than the top bracket under previous law). In 2017, the 39.6% bracket began with taxable income of $470,700 for joint returns and $418,400 for single returns. There is also an exclusion of $500,000 ($250,000 for single returns) for gains on home sales.

Tax legislation in 1997 reduced capital gains taxes on several types of assets, imposing a 20% maximum tax rate on long-term gains, a rate temporarily reduced to 15% for 2003-2008, which was extended for two additional years in 2006. Legislation enacted in December 2010 extended the lower rates for an additional two years, thorough 2010. The American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012 (P.L. 112-240) made the lower rates permanent except for very high-income taxpayers.

Health reform legislation in 2010 provided for a tax at Medicare rates of 3.8% on high-income taxpayers on various forms of passive income, including capital gains. The tax applies to passive income in excess of $250,000 for joint returns and $200,000 for single returns.

The capital gains tax had been a tax cut target since the 1986 Tax Reform Act treated capital gains as ordinary income. An argument for lower capital gains taxes is reduction of the lock-in effect. Some also believe that lower capital gains taxes will cost little compared to the benefits they bring and that lower taxes induce additional economic growth, although the magnitude of these potential effects is in some dispute. Others criticize lower capital gains taxes as benefitting higher-income individuals and express concerns about the budget effects, particularly in future years. Another criticism of lower rates is the possible role of a larger capital gains tax differential in encouraging tax sheltering activities and adding complexity to the tax law.

Capital Gains Taxes: An Overview

Updated March 16, 2018 (96-769)
Jump to Main Text of Report

Summary

Taxes on long-term capital gains (on assets held for at least a year) are imposed at rates that correspond to pre-2018 brackets: a 0% rate for those whose income placed them in the regular 15% bracket or less (now in regular bracket of 12%), and 15% for taxpayers in higher brackets, except for those in the 39.6% bracket. The tax revision adopted in December 2018 (P.L. 115-97) maintained the links to the income level corresponding to the rate brackets in prior law. Therefore, the tax rates on capital gains are affected only by changes in the deductions to arrive at taxable income and the use of a different method of indexing for inflation. Under the new law, the original 10% and 15% brackets are replaced by a single 12% rate bracket that ends at the same point as the end of the 15% bracket. There is no 39.6% bracket (the top rate is 37% and begins at a higher level than the top bracket under previous law). In 2017, the 39.6% bracket began with taxable income of $470,700 for joint returns and $418,400 for single returns. There is also an exclusion of $500,000 ($250,000 for single returns) for gains on home sales.

Tax legislation in 1997 reduced capital gains taxes on several types of assets, imposing a 20% maximum tax rate on long-term gains, a rate temporarily reduced to 15% for 2003-2008, which was extended for two additional years in 2006. Legislation enacted in December 2010 extended the lower rates for an additional two years, thorough 2010. The American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012 (P.L. 112-240) made the lower rates permanent except for very high-income taxpayers.

Health reform legislation in 2010 provided for a tax at Medicare rates of 3.8% on high-income taxpayers on various forms of passive income, including capital gains. The tax applies to passive income in excess of $250,000 for joint returns and $200,000 for single returns.

The capital gains tax had been a tax cut target since the 1986 Tax Reform Act treated capital gains as ordinary income. An argument for lower capital gains taxes is reduction of the lock-in effect. Some also believe that lower capital gains taxes will cost little compared to the benefits they bring and that lower taxes induce additional economic growth, although the magnitude of these potential effects is in some dispute. Others criticize lower capital gains taxes as benefitting higher-income individuals and express concerns about the budget effects, particularly in future years. Another criticism of lower rates is the possible role of a larger capital gains tax differential in encouraging tax sheltering activities and adding complexity to the tax law.


What Are Capital Gains and How Are They Taxed?

Capital gain arises when an asset is sold and consists of the difference between the basis (normally the acquisition price) and the sales price. Corporate stock accounts for 20% to 80% of taxable gains, depending on stock market performance. Real estate is the remaining major source of capital gains, although gain also arises from other assets (e.g., timber sales and collectibles). The appreciation in value can be real or reflect inflation. Corporate stock appreciates both because the firm's assets increase with reinvested earnings and because general price levels are rising. Appreciation in the value of property may simply reflect inflation. For depreciable assets, some of the gain may reflect the possibility that the property was depreciated too quickly.

If the return to capital gains were to be effectively taxed at the statutory tax rate in the manner of other income, real gains would have to be taxed in the year they accrue. Current practice departs from this approach. Gains are not taxed until realized, benefitting from the deferral of taxes. (Taxes on interest income are due as the interest is accrued.) Gains on an asset held until death may be passed on to heirs with the tax forgiven; if the asset is then sold, the gain is sales price less market value at the time of death, a treatment referred to as a "step-up in basis."

Taxes on long-term capital gains (on assets held for at least a year) are imposed at rates that correspond to pre-2018 brackets: a 0% rate for those whose income placed them in the regular 15% bracket or less (now in the 12% bracket), and 15% for taxpayers in higher brackets, except for those in the 39.6% bracket. The tax revision adopted in December 2018 (P.L. 115-97) maintained the links to the income level corresponding to the rate brackets in prior law. Therefore, the tax rates on capital gains are affected only by changes in the deductions to arrive at taxable income and the use of a different method of indexing for inflation. Under the new law, the original 10% and 15% brackets are replaced by a single 12% rate bracket that ends at the same point as the end of the 15% bracket. There is no 39.6% bracket (the top rate is 37% and begins at a higher level than the top bracket under previous law). In 2017, the 39.6% bracket began with taxable income of $470,700 for joint returns and $418,400 for single returns. Gain arising from prior depreciation deductions is taxed at ordinary rates, but there is a 25% ceiling rate on the gain from prior straight-line depreciation on real property. Gain from collectibles is taxed at 28%. There is also an exclusion of $500,000 ($250,000 for single returns) for gains on home sales.

Health reform legislation in 2010 provided for a tax of 3.8% (the same level as the Medicare rate of 3.8% on labor income) on high-income taxpayers on various forms of passive income, including capital gains. The tax applies to passive income in excess of $250,000 for joint returns and $200,000 for single returns.

Gains in partnership interest derived from the performance of investment services (carried interest) are treated as long-term capital gains if held for at least three years.

In contrast to these provisions that benefit capital gains, capital gains are penalized because many of the gains that are subject to tax arise from inflation and therefore do not reflect real income.

A Brief History

Capital gains were taxed when the income tax (with rates up to 7%) was imposed in 1913. An alternative rate of 12.5% was allowed in 1921 (the regular top rate was 73%). Tax rates were cut several times during the 1920s. Capital gain exclusions based on holding period were enacted in 1924, and modified in 1938, to deal with bunching of gains in one year. In 1942 a 50% exclusion was adopted, with an alternative rate of 25%. Over time, the top rate on ordinary income varied, rising to 94% in the mid-1940s, and then dropping to 70% after 1964. In 1969 a new minimum tax increased the gains tax for some; the 25% alternative tax was repealed.

In 1978 the minimum tax on capital gains was repealed and the exclusion increased to 60% with a maximum rate of 28% (0.4 times 0.7). The top rate on ordinary income was reduced to 50% in 1981, reducing the capital gains rate to 20% (0.4 times 0.5). The Tax Reform Act of 1986 reduced tax rates further, but, in order to maintain distributional neutrality, eliminated some tax preferences, including the exclusion for capital gains. This treatment brought the rate for high-income individuals in line with the rate on ordinary income—28%.

In 1989, President Bush proposed a top rate of 15%, halving top rates. The Ways and Means Committee considered two proposals: Chairman Rostenkowski proposed to index capital gains, and Representatives Jenkins, Flippo, and Archer proposed a 30% capital gains exclusion through 1991 followed by inflation indexation. This latter measure was approved by the committee, but was not enacted.

In 1990, the President proposed a 30% exclusion, setting the rate at 19.6% for high-income individuals. The House also passed a 50% exclusion with a lifetime maximum ceiling and a $1,000 annual exclusion, but this provision was not enacted into law. When rates on high-income individuals were set at 31%, however, the capital gains rate was capped at 28%.

In 1991, the President again proposed a 30% exclusion, but no action was taken. In 1992, the President proposed a 45% exclusion. The House adopted a proposal for indexation for inflation for newly acquired assets: the Senate passed a separate set of graduated rates on capital gains that tended to benefit more moderate-income individuals. This latter provision was included in a bill (H.R. 4210) containing many other tax provisions that was vetoed by the President.

No changes were proposed by President Clinton or adopted in 1993 and 1994, with the exception of a narrowly targeted benefit for small business stock adopted in 1993. The value of the tax cap was increased, however, in 1993, when new brackets of 36% and 39.6% were added for ordinary income.

In 1994, the "Contract With America" proposed a 50% exclusion for capital gains, and indexing the basis for all subsequent inflation, while eliminating the 28% cap; this exclusion would be about a 40% reduction on average from current rates. The Ways and Means Committee reported out H.R. 1215, which restricted inflation indexing to newly acquired assets (individuals could "mark to market"—pay tax on the difference between fair market value and basis as if the property were sold to qualify for indexation), did not allow indexation to create losses, and provided a flat 25% tax rate for corporations. The 1995 reconciliation bill (H.R. 2491) that was vetoed by the President included these revisions but delayed the indexation provision until 2002. During the 1996 presidential election, Republican nominee Robert J. Dole proposed a slightly larger capital gains cut, and both candidates supported elimination of capital gains taxes on virtually all gains from home sales.

In 1997, President Clinton and Congress agreed to a tax cut as part of the reconciliation. The Administration tax cut proposal included the change in tax treatment of owner-occupied housing. The House bill included a reduction in the 15% and 28% rates to 10% and 20%, about a 30% cut. Capital gains would also be indexed for assets acquired after 2000 and held for three years; mark-to-market would also be allowed. The Senate and the final bill did not include indexing. Under the final legislation, there was a maximum tax of 20% on capital gains held for a year. This change also would have taxed gain from assets held five years and acquired after 2000 at a maximum rate of 18%. For gain in the 15% bracket and below, an 8% rate would apply to any gain on assets held for five years and sold after 2000, with no required acquisition date.

Under law prior to 1997, several rules permitted avoidance or deferral of the tax on gain on owner-occupied housing, including a provision allowing deferral of gain until a subsequent house is sold (rollover treatment) and a provision allowing a one-time exclusion of $125,000 on gain for those 55 and over. These provisions were replaced with a general $500,000 exclusion ($250,000 for a single individual), which cost only slightly more in revenue.

The capital gains issue was briefly revisited in 1998, when the holding period for long-term gains was moved back from the 18 months set in 1997 to the one-year period that has typically applied. The 1999 House bill would have cut the rates to 15% and 10%: the conference version cut rates to 18% and 8% and proposed indexing of future gains, but the bill was vetoed. Capital gains were discussed during the consideration of the economic stimulus bill at the end of 2002, but not included in any legislative proposal (and no proposal was adopted). The temporary provisions for lower rates of 15% for 2003-2008 for those in the higher brackets and to 5% in 2003-2007 and 0% in 2008 for taxpayers in the 15% bracket or lower were adopted in 2003. H.R. 4297, adopted in 2006, extended these lower rates for two more years. P.L. 111-312, enacted in 2010, extended the lower rates for an additional two years, through 2010. The American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012, P.L. 112-240, made these lower rates permanent except for very high incomes.

Health reform legislation in 2010 provided for a tax of 3.8% on high-income taxpayers on various forms of passive income, including capital gains. The tax applies to passive income in excess of $250,000 for joint returns and $200,000 for single returns.

The tax revision in 2017 made numerous changes to individual tax deductions and rates, but kept the different rates of capital gains linked to the old rate brackets. (These individual changes expire after 2025.) The capital gains rate for a given income could be affected by changes in itemized and standard deductions and the repeal of personal exemptions, which will alter the point at which taxable income begins.1 The revision also introduced a different measure of inflation, which will lead to narrower rate brackets and standard deductions and will lead, over time, to somewhat higher capital gains taxes. Gains in partnership interest derived from the performance of investment services (carried interest) are treated as long-term capital gains if held for at least three years (rather than the one-year period in prior law).

Revenue Effects

Over the past several years, a debate has ensued regarding the revenue cost of cutting capital gains taxes. For example, when the President proposed a 30% exclusion in 1990, Treasury estimates showed a $12 billion gain in revenue over the first five years, while the Joint Committee on Taxation found a revenue loss of approximately equal size.

Although the estimates seemed quite different, they both incorporated significant expected increases in the amount of gains realized as a result of the tax cut. For example, the Treasury would have estimated a revenue loss of $80 billion over five years with no behavioral response, and the Joint Tax Committee a loss of $100 billion. (The gap between these static estimates arose from differences in projections of expected capital gains, a volatile series that is quite difficult to estimate.)

Empirical evidence on capital gains realizations does not clearly point to a specific response and revenue cost. Recent research suggests long-run responses may be more modest than those suggested by the economics literature during the 1990 debate, but the short-run response is still difficult to ascertain.2

Any revenue feedback effect will be smaller the larger the tax reduction and any feedback that reduces revenues will be larger the larger the tax increase, under the presumption that the response rises with the tax rate. When the tax reduction is large, although there will be a larger response, any induced revenues will be taxed at the new lower rates. Thus, a 50% exclusion will not have as large a feedback effect relative to the static estimate as a 30% exclusion. Moreover, allowing a prospective tax cut that depends on selling and acquiring a new asset to qualify (or marking to market) as is the case for the reduction from 20% to 18% for five-year property causes a gain in the short run as well.

Arguments have also been made that a capital gains tax cut will induce additional savings, also resulting in a feedback effect as taxes are imposed on new income. This effect is uncertain, as it is not clear that an increase in the rate of return will increase savings (savings can decrease if the income effect is more powerful than the substitution effect) and what the magnitude of the response might be.3 There is also a debate about the effect of the capital gains tax on growth through its effect on innovation. Regardless of these empirical uncertainties, any effect of savings on taxable income in the short run is likely to be quite small due to the slow rate of capital accumulation. (Net savings are typically only about 2% to 3% of the capital stock, so that even a 10% increase in the savings rate would result in only a 2/10 to 3/10 of a percent first-year increase in the capital stock.) A related argument is that the tax cut will increase asset values; such an effect is only temporary, however, and will, if it occurs, only shift revenues from the future to the present.4

Impact on Effective Tax Burdens

The tax burden on an investment is influenced by both the tax rate and any benefits allowed or penalties imposed. One way to measure this tax burden is to calculate a marginal effective tax rate that captures in a single number all of the factors that affect tax burden. It is the percentage difference between the before- and after-tax return to investment, or the estimated statutory rate that would be applied to economic income to give the taxpayer the same burden as the combination of tax benefits and penalties.

The effective tax rate on capital gains can be either higher or lower than the statutory rate, depending on the inflation rate relative to the real appreciation rate and the holding period. Also, assets held until death are not subject to tax. For example, assuming a 20% statutory tax rate, the gain on a growth stock (paying no dividends) with a real appreciation rate of 7% and an inflation rate of 3% would, if held for 1 year, 7 years, 20 years, and until death, be subject respectively to tax rates of 27%, 22%, 14%, and 0%. With no inflation and a 20% rate, the rates would be 19%, 16%, 12%, and 0%; inflation penalizes assets held a shorter period more heavily than assets held for a longer period. Because less than half of gains that are accrued are realized, the effective tax rate is probably lower than the statutory tax rate. These benefits are larger for individuals in the highest tax brackets because the capital gains tax rate is capped at 15% or 20%, while ordinary tax rates can be as high as 37%.

Issues: Efficiency, Growth, Distribution, and Complexity

One argument in favor of reducing the capital gains tax is the lock-in effect. If this effect is large, the tax introduces significant distortions in behavior with relatively little revenue gain. Another way to reduce lock-in is accrual taxation (i.e., tax gains on a current basis as accrued), but this approach is only feasible when assets can be easily valued (e.g., publicly traded corporate stock). Another way to reduce lock-in is to tax gains passed on at death. These solutions may face technical problems, and taxation of gains at death has been unpopular.

For owner-occupied housing, although there were many ways to avoid the tax under current law, the rules may have resulted in individuals remaining in houses that are too large if economic circumstances have declined (for example, through job loss or retirement or from a preference for a smaller home, or if there is relocation to a lower-cost area).

A case might be made for lower capital gains taxes on corporate stock because corporate equity capital is subject to heavy taxation. This heavy taxation encourages corporations to take on too much debt and directs too much capital to the noncorporate sector. Alternatively, lower capital gains taxes increase the relative penalty that applies to dividends and introduce tax distortions in the decisions of the firm to retain earnings. This latter effect, however, does not occur under the temporary tax cuts that benefit dividends as well as capital gains. In addition, most corporate stock is held by tax-exempt or foreign investors not subject to capital gains taxes.5

Arguments have also been made that lower gains taxes will increase economic growth and entrepreneurship. Although evidence on the effect of tax cuts on savings rates and, thus, economic growth is difficult to obtain, most evidence does not indicate a large response of savings to an increase in the rate of return. Indeed, not all studies find a positive response, because a higher rate of return may allow individuals to save less while reaching their desired goal. A more effective route to increasing savings may be to take revenues that might otherwise finance a tax cut and reduce the debt.

Although arguments are made that lower gains taxes stimulate innovation and entrepreneurship, there is little evidence in history to connect periods of technical advance with lower taxes or even high rates of return. The extent to which entrepreneurs take tax considerations into account is unclear; however, there is some reason to doubt that capital gains taxes are important in obtaining large amounts of venture capital, in part because much of this capital is supplied by those not subject to the capital gains tax (i.e., pension funds, foreign investors). Moreover, there is no evidence that longer corporate stock holding periods lead to more investments in long-term assets, including R&D, a rationale for lowering rates for assets with longer holding periods. (Note that indexing, initially proposed, and then dropped, favors assets with shorter holding periods.)

A major complaint made by some about lower gains rates cut is that they primarily benefit very high-income individuals. Capital gains are concentrated among higher-income individuals because these individuals tend to own capital and because they are likely to own capital that generates capital gains. The Tax Policy Center has estimated, for 2017, that 92.5% of the benefit of lower tax rates on capital gains and dividends (dividends are also eligible for the lower rates) accrue to the top quintile of the income distribution, and 73% accrue to the top 1%.6 The benefit of the lower rates on capital gains alone would be more concentrated because a larger proportion of capital gains accrues to those with higher incomes, compared with dividends. A study by the Joint Committee on Taxation found that 76.1% of the total of dividends and capital gains is received by those with $200,000 of income, compared with 84.1% of capital gains alone.7 The distributional effects of the capital gains relief for homes are somewhat less concentrated at the higher end (although lower-income individuals are much less likely to own homes). The revisions may also enhance horizontal equity by treating taxpayers in different circumstances more evenly.

Critics of lower capital gains taxes cite the contribution of preferential capital gains treatment to tax sheltering activities and complexity. For example, individuals may borrow (while deducting interest in full) to make investments that are eligible for lower capital gains tax rates, thereby earning high rates of return. These effects are, however, constrained in some cases (i.e., a passive loss restriction limits the deductions allowed in real estate ventures). Capital gains differentials complicate the tax law, especially as applied to depreciable assets where capital gains treatment can create incentives for churning assets unless recapture provisions are adopted. Indexing capital gains for inflation is more complicated than a simple exclusion, since different basis adjustments must apply to different vintages of assets and proper indexing of gains on depreciable property is especially difficult. Thus, foregoing indexing probably kept the tax law simpler.

Author Contact Information

[author name scrubbed], Senior Specialist in Economic Policy ([email address scrubbed], [phone number scrubbed])

Footnotes

1.

The new law increases the standard deduction and repeals personal exemptions, with the higher standard deduction amount more than offsetting the loss of the personal exemption for the taxpayer(s) and an increased child credit offsetting the loss of personal exemptions for children. For those formerly taking a standard deduction, the exempt amounts (amounts deducted before taxable income begins) will be increased from $21,300 (a standard deduction of $13,000 and two personal exemptions of $4,150) to $24,000 for a married couple and from $10,650 (a standard deduction of $6,500 and a personal exemption of $4,140) to $12,000. Married couples with children and heads of household with more than one child will find their exempt levels reduced. Individuals formerly taking the itemized deduction are more likely to find exempt levels reduced because some minor itemized deductions are eliminated and others are subject to limits or increased limits.

2.

See CRS Report R41364, Capital Gains Tax Options: Behavioral Responses and Revenues, by [author name scrubbed], for a review of this evidence.

3.

See CRS Report R43381, Dynamic Scoring for Tax Legislation: A Review of Models, by [author name scrubbed], for a discussion of the empirical evidence.

4.

For a discussion of savings and asset valuations, see testimony of [author name scrubbed], Congressional Research Service, before the Senate Finance Committee, February 15, 1995, and the House Ways and Means Committee, March 19, 1997.

5.

See CRS Report R44638, Corporate Tax Integration and Tax Reform, by [author name scrubbed].

6.

Tax Policy Center, Table T17-0137, Tax Benefit of the Preferential Rates on Long Term Capital Gains and Qualified Dividends, Baseline: Current law, Distribution of Federal Tax change by Expanded Cash Income Percentile, 2017, April 18, 2017, http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/model-estimates/individual-income-tax-expenditures-april-2017/t17-0137-tax-benefit-preferential.

7.

Joint Committee on Taxation, Present Law and Background Information on Certain Expiring Tax Provisions,JCX-50-05, June 30, 2005, http://www.jct.gov/x-50-05.pdf.