Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve:
Current Policy and Conditions
Marc Labonte
Coordinator of Division Research and Specialist
February 12, 2013Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
January 7, 2014
Congressional Research Service
7-5700
www.crs.gov
RL30354
CRS Report for Congress
Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Summary
The Federal Reserve (the Fed) defines monetary policy as theits actions it undertakes to influence
the availability
and cost of money and credit. Because the expectations of market participants
play an important
role in determining prices and economic growth, monetary policy can also be defined to
include include
the directives, policies, statements, and actions of the Fed that influence how the future is
perceived. In addition, the Fed acts as a “lender of last resort” to the nation’s financial system,
meaning that it ensures continued smooth functioning of financial intermediation by providing
financial markets with adequate liquidityfuture perceptions.
Traditionally, the Fed has implemented monetary policy primarily through open market
operations involving the purchase and sale of U.S. Treasury securities. The Fed traditionally
conducts open market operations by setting an interest rate target that it believes will allow it to
fulfill its with the goal of fulfilling its
statutory mandate of “maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term
interest interest
rates.” The interest rate targeted is the federal funds rate, the price at which banks buy and
sell sell
reserves on an overnight basis. This rate is linked to other short-term rates and these, along
with inflation with
future expectations, influence longer-term interest rates. Interest rates affect interestsensitive interest-sensitive
spending such as business capital spending on plant and equipment, household spending
on on
consumer durables, and residential investment. Through this channel, monetary policy can be
used to stimulate or slow aggregate spending in the short run. In the long run, monetary policy
mainly affects inflation. A low and stable rate of inflation promotes price transparency and,
thereby, sounder economic decisions by households and businesses.
Recently, inIn addition, the Fed acts as a “lender of last resort” to the nation’s financial system, meaning that
it ensures continued smooth functioning of financial intermediation by providing financial
markets with adequate liquidity. In response to the financial crisis, direct lending became
important once again, and the
Fed created a number of new ways for injectingfacilities to inject reserves, credit, and
liquidity into the banking
system, as well as making loans to firms that are not banks. As financial
conditions normalized,
loans were repaid with interest and emergency lending programs have
been wound down, with
the exception of foreign central bank liquidity swaps.
Beginning in September 2007, in a series of 10 moves, the federal funds target was reduced from
5.25% to a range of 0% to 0.25% on December 16, 2008, where it now remains. In December
has remained since. In
December 2012, the Fed pledged to maintain “exceptionally low rates” at least as long as
unemployment is
above 6.5% and inflation is low. With the federal funds target at the “zero lower
bound,” the Fed
has added additional monetary stimulus first through direct lending and, more recently, through
through purchases of Treasury and
government-sponsored enterprise (GSE) securities. This practice is
sometimes popularly referred to as
quantitative easing, which has tripled (“QE”), and it has caused the size of the Fed’s balance sheet to quadruple
since the financial crisis began, to $4 trillion at the end of 2013. On September 13, 2012, the Fed announced
began a new round of asset
purchasesQE, pledging to purchase $40 billion GSE mortgage-backed securities perand Treasury
securities each month until the
labor market improves, as long as price stability is maintained. Coupled with $45 billion in
monthly purchases of Treasury securities, the Fed’s balance sheet is now increasing by about $85
billion each monthprices remain stable. On
December 18, 2013, the Fed announced that it would begin to taper off (gradually reduce the rate
of) its monthly asset purchases. Debate is currently focused on the proper timing for ending
unconventional policy measures and moving away from the zero bound.
Congress has delegated responsibility for monetary policy to the Fed, but retains oversight
responsibilities for ensuring that the Fed is adhering to its statutory mandate. H.R. 4921174/S. 238,
H.R. 492, and S. 215
would switch to a single mandate of price stability. Congressional debate on
Fed oversight has
focused on audits by the Government Accountability Office (GAO). The Dodd-Frank Act
DoddFrank Act enhanced the GAO’s ability to audit the Fed and required an auditaudits of its emergency programs.
programs and governance. H.R. 24, H.R. 33, and S. 209 would remove all remaining statutory
restrictions on GAO’s audit powers audits.
Congressional Research Service
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Contents
Introduction...................................................................................................................................... 1
How Does the Federal Reserve Execute Monetary Policy? ............................................................ 3
Economic Effects of Monetary Policy in the Short Run and Long Run.................................... 56
Monetary vs. Fiscal Policy ........................................................................................................ 67
The Recent and Current Stance of Monetary Policy........................................................................ 89
Before the Financial Crisis ........................................................................................................ 9
Direct Assistance During and After the Financial Crisis ........................................................... 9 10
Central Bank Liquidity Swaps .......................................................................................... 11
Unconventional Policy Measures at the Zero Bound After the Crisis ..................................... 12
Quantitative Easing and the Growth in the Balance Sheet and Bank Reserves ................ 12
Forward Commitment ....................................................................................................... 15
Congressional Oversight and Disclosure ....................................................................................... 1516
The Federal Reserve’s Dual Mandate and Its Independence Proposals for a Single Mandate of Price
Stability ....................................................................................................................................... 17
Regulatory Responsibilities .................................................................................... 16....................... 18
Contacts
Author Contact Information........................................................................................................... 1819
Acknowledgments ......................................................................................................................... 1819
Congressional Research Service
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Introduction
Congress has delegated responsibility for monetary policy to the Federal Reserve (the Fed), but
retains oversight responsibilities to ensure that the Fed is adhering to its statutory mandate of
“maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.”1 It has defined
stable prices as a longer-run goal of 2% inflation. The Fed’s The Fed’s
responsibilities as the nation’s central
bank fall into four main categories: monetary policy,
ensuring financial stability provision of emergency liquidity through the
lender of last resort function, supervision of bank holding
companies, and providingcertain types of banks and other financial firms for
safety and soundness, and provision of payment system services to financial firms and the government. This
report will discuss the first two areas of responsibility
government.2
The Fed’s monetary policy function is one of aggregate demand management. The Fed defines
monetary policy as the actions it undertakes to influence the availability and cost of money and
credit to promote the goals mandated by Congress, a stable price level and maximum sustainable
employment. Because the expectations of households as consumers and businesses as purchasers
of capital goods exert an important influence
Recent Events of Note
on the major portion of spending in the United
States, and these expectations are influenced
•
In the 112th Congress, H.R. 459, legislation
removing
statutory restrictions on GAO audits,
in important ways by the actions of the Fed, a
passed
in
the
House. GAO audits of the Fed
broader definition of monetary policy would
required by the Dodd-Frank Act were released in
include the directives, policies, statements,
July and October 2011 (see “Congressional
forecasts in important ways by the actions of the Fed, a
broader definition of monetary policy would include the directives, policies, statements, forecasts
of the economy, and other actions by
Oversight and Disclosure” below).
the Fed, especially those made by or
•
On September 13, 2012, Fed announced it would
associated with the chairman of its Board of
buy $40 billion MBS per month, with no specified
Governors, the nation’s central banker.
end date, popularly referred to as “QE3.” The
Maturity Extension Program, popularly referred to
as “Operation Twist,” ended at the end of 2012. In
In addition, governments have traditionally
December 2012, the Fed announced that it would
assigned to a central bank the role of “lender
continue purchasing $45 billion in long-term
of last resort” to the nation’s financial system.
Treasury securities, but those purchases would no
This role means that the Federal Reserve is
longer be offset by the sale of short-term Treasury
responsible for ensuring the sustainability,
securities (see “Unconventional Policy Measures at
the Zero Bound”).
solvency, and continued functioning of the
nation’s financial system as a whole, although
•
The Fed renewed use of central bank liquidity swaps
this does not necessarily extend to any
in response to the eurozone crisis (see “Central
Bank Liquidity Swaps” below).
individual financial institution. Thus, in times
of financial stress or crisis, the Fed is
•
In December 2012, the Fed announced that it
responsible for ensuring that financial
expects to maintain “exceptionally low interest
rates” until the unemployment rate reaches 6.5%, as
intermediation does not come to a halt.
long as inflation remains low (see “Congressional
Historically, Federal Reserve intervention has
Oversight and Disclosure” below).
been limited to the banking system. Indeed,
the impetus for the founding of the Fed was an
outgrowth of the financial panic of 1907. During its nearly 100-year history, the Federal Reserve
has rarely been called upon to perform this role. It is now widely regarded as having failed to
perform it during the collapse of the U.S. banking system in the contraction of 1929-1933.
However, the financial crisis that began in the summer of 2007 with the bursting of the “housing
1
Section 2A of the Federal Reserve Act, 12 USC 225a.
For background on the makeup of the Federal Reserve, see CRS Report RS20826, Structure and Functions of the
Federal Reserve System, by Marc Labonte.
2
Congressional Research Service
1
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
price bubble” has placed this role front and center. The Fed has responded by making massive
additions of reserves available to depository institutions (primarily commercial banks) through
the purchase of U.S. Treasury and mortgage-related securities (popularly known as “quantitative
easing”) and through lending facilities. In addition, it has created a number of additional ways to
make credit available to a broader range of financial institutions as well as making loans directly
to non-bank financial intermediaries. These innovations were unprecedented and several were
authorized only in “unusual and exigent circumstances.”3
By 2011, these emergency activities had largely expired, with the exception of the central bank
liquidity swaps. In September 2012, the Fed renewed its large-scale asset purchases (popularly
referred to as “QE3”), pledging to purchase $40 billion of GSE MBS per month. 4 Unlike the
previous two rounds of asset purchases, the Fed specified no planned end date to its purchases,
instead pledging to continue purchases until labor markets improved, in a context of price
stability. Coupled with $45 billion in monthly purchases of Treasury securities, the Fed’s balance
sheet is now increasing by about $85 billion each month. In December 2012, the Fed pledged to
maintain an “exceptionally low” federal funds target at least as long as unemployment is above
6.5% and inflation is low.
The Fed’s unprecedented response to the financial crisis has garnered renewed attention on the
Fed from Congress. On the one hand, the Fed was given new regulatory responsibilities in The
Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (P.L. 111-203) in an attempt to
prevent future crises. On the other hand, the Dodd-Frank Act shifted its consumer protection
responsibilities to the newly created Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, placed restrictions on
the Fed’s emergency powers, and increased oversight of the Fed. Fed oversight and disclosure has
been a focus of recent Congresses. In the 111th Congress, the Dodd-Frank Act allowed the
Government Accountability Office (GAO) to audit the Fed’s monetary and lending activities and
required the Fed to release detailed lending records for the first time. In the 112th Congress, H.R.
459, which the House passed as amended on July 25, 2012, would have removed remaining
restrictions on GAO’s audit authority. Similar bills in the 113th Congress include H.R. 24, H.R.
33, and S. 209. H.R. 492 and S. 215 would switch to a single mandate of price stability.
This report provides an overview of monetary policy and issues for Congress. Legislative changes
to the Fed’s duties and authority related to financial regulatory reform can be found in CRS
Report R40877, Financial Regulatory Reform: Systemic Risk and the Federal Reserve, by Marc
Labonte. Lending facilities created by the Federal Reserve and other government agencies during
the financial crisis are discussed in CRS Report R41073, Government Interventions in Response
to Financial Turmoil, by Baird Webel and Marc Labonte.
3
For a discussion of the 2007-2009 financial crisis, its origins, and the innovations by the Federal Reserve, see CRS
Report RL34427, Financial Turmoil: Federal Reserve Policy Responses, by Marc Labonte. For historical perspective
on Federal Reserve’s dealing in non-government debt, see Wheelock, David C. “Conducting Monetary Policy Without
Government Debt: The Fed’s Early Years. Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. May/June 2002, pp. 1-14.
4
Federal Reserve, press release, September 13, 2012, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/
20120913a.htm.
Congressional Research Service
2
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
How Does the Federal Reserve Execute
Monetary Policy?
The Federal Reserve has traditionally relied on three instruments to conduct monetary policy.
Each works by altering the reserves available to depository institutions. These institutions are
required to maintain reserves against their deposit liabilities, primarily checking, saving, and time
(CDs). These reserves can be held in the form of vault cash (currency) or as a deposit at the Fed.
The size of these reserves places a ceiling on the amount of deposits that financial institutions can
have outstanding, and deposit liabilities are related to the amount of assets these institutions can
acquire. These assets are often called “credit” since they represent loans made to businesses and
chairman of its Board of Governors, who is the nation’s central banker. The Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC) meets periodically to consider whether to maintain or change the current
stance of monetary policy.3
The Fed’s conventional tool for monetary policy is to target the federal funds rate, the overnight,
inter-bank lending rate. It influences the federal funds rate through “open market operations,” the
purchase and sale of securities. In December 2008, the Fed lowered the federal funds rate to a
range of 0% to 0.25%, called the “zero lower bound” because the Fed cannot provide any further
stimulus through conventional policy. Since then, it has turned to unconventional policy to
provide further stimulus to the economy.4 It has pledged to keep the federal funds target
“exceptionally low” for an extended period, currently at least as long as unemployment is above
6.5% and inflation is low.
In addition, the Fed has attempted to stimulate the economy through several rounds of large-scale
asset purchases of Treasury securities and securities issued by government-sponsored enterprises
(GSEs) since 2009, popularly referred to as quantitative easing (“QE”). As a result of QE, the size
of the Fed’s balance sheet has quadrupled since the financial crisis began, to $4 trillion at the end
of 2013. Since September 2012, the Fed has made large-scale asset purchases of Treasury
securities and mortgage-backed securities (MBS) issued by the GSEs (referred to as “QE3”).5
Unlike the previous two rounds of asset purchases, the Fed specified no planned end date to its
purchases, instead pledging to continue purchases until labor markets improved, in a context of
1
Section 2A of the Federal Reserve Act, 12 USC 225a.
For background on the makeup of the Federal Reserve, see CRS Report RS20826, Structure and Functions of the
Federal Reserve System, by Marc Labonte.
3
Its policy decisions can be accessed at http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomccalendars.htm.
4
See CRS Report R42962, Federal Reserve: Unconventional Monetary Policy Options, by Marc Labonte.
5
Federal Reserve, press release, September 13, 2012, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/
20120913a.htm.
2
Congressional Research Service
1
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
price stability. In December 2013, the Fed announced that it would begin tapering off those
purchases. Barring a future change in course, this is seen as the first step toward an eventual end
to unconventional monetary policy.
Before 2008, short-term interest rates had never reached the “zero lower bound.”6 It has remained
there for several years since, and is likely to remain there for a couple more years—most
members of the FOMC currently believe that it would not be appropriate to raise the federal funds
target until 2015.7 Debate is currently focused on the proper timing for ending unconventional
policy measures and moving away from the zero bound. Economists who believe that
unconventional policy should continue until conditions improve point to the large output gap (i.e.,
the difference between actual output and potential output) and the fact that inflation ran slightly
below the Fed’s 2% goal throughout 2013. In other words, they justify the continued use of
unconventional policy in terms of both the Fed’s full employment mandate and price stability
mandate. Economists who believe that unconventional policy should end in the near term point
out that the economic recession ended in June 2009 and the economy has been growing steadily
since. Further, the unemployment rate, while still high, has been on a downward trajectory since
2011. Finally, although inflation has remained low thus far, unconventional policy has led to
above-average growth in the money supply. In critics’ eyes, the economy is now functioning close
enough to normal that the risks of unconventional policy outweigh the benefits.
Besides monetary policy, governments have traditionally assigned to their central bank the role of
“lender of last resort” to the nation’s financial system, meaning that it ensures continued smooth
functioning of financial intermediation by providing financial markets with adequate liquidity.
Traditionally, the Fed acted as lender of last resort primarily through its discount window, where
banks can apply for short-term loans from the Fed; in normal times, the discount window is used
sparingly. During the 2007 to 2009 the financial crisis, direct lending became important once
again, both through the discount window and through a number of newly created facilities. These
facilities were used to inject reserves, credit, and liquidity into the banking system, as well as
making loans to firms that are not banks. As financial conditions normalized, loans were repaid
with interest and emergency lending programs have been wound down, with the exception of
foreign central bank liquidity swaps.8
The Fed’s unprecedented response to the financial crisis has garnered renewed attention on the
Fed from Congress. On the one hand, the Fed was given new regulatory responsibilities in the
Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (P.L. 111-203) in an attempt to
prevent future crises. On the other hand, the Dodd-Frank Act shifted the Fed’s consumer
protection responsibilities to the newly created Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, placed
restrictions on the Fed’s emergency powers, and increased oversight of the Fed. Specifically, it
6
The Fed did not target the federal funds rate as its monetary policy instrument until the late 1980s or early 1990s. (See
Daniel Thornton, “When Did the FOMC Begin Targeting the Federal Funds Rate?,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis,
working paper 2004-015B, May 2005, http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2004/2004-015.pdf.) Since 1914, the Fed had
not set its discount rate (the rate charged at the Fed’s discount window) as low as 0.5% before 2008.
7
Economic Projections of Federal Reserve Board Members and Presidents, press release, December 2013,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/fomcprojtabl20131218.pdf. Based on Fed forecasts, raising the
federal funds target in 2015 is consistent with the pledge to keep the target “exceptionally low” until the unemployment
rate reaches 6.5%.
8
Details of the lending facilities created by the Federal Reserve and other government agencies during the financial
crisis are discussed in CRS Report R41073, Government Interventions in Response to Financial Turmoil, by Baird
Webel and Marc Labonte.
Congressional Research Service
2
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
allowed the Government Accountability Office (GAO) to audit the Fed’s monetary and lending
activities and required the Fed to release detailed lending records for the first time. Fed oversight
and disclosure has remained a congressional focus since then. In the 112th Congress, H.R. 459,
which the House passed as amended on July 25, 2012, would have removed remaining
restrictions on GAO’s audit authority, which prevent GAO from analyzing monetary policy on
policy grounds. Similar bills in the 113th Congress include H.R. 24, H.R. 33, and S. 209. H.R.
1174/S. 238, H.R. 492, and S. 215 would switch to a single mandate of price stability. H.R.
1174/S. 238 would also limit the purchase of permissible securities other than Treasury securities
to “unusual and exigent circumstances,” which could last up to five years, increase the voting
power of the Fed’s regional bank presidents on the FOMC, and accelerate the lagged release of
FOMC transcripts.
This report provides an overview of monetary policy and issues for Congress, including
transparency and proposals to change the Fed’s mandate. It ends with a brief overview of the
Fed’s regulatory responsibilities.9
How Does the Federal Reserve Execute
Monetary Policy?
The Federal Reserve has traditionally relied on three instruments to conduct monetary policy.
Each works by altering the reserves available to depository institutions. These institutions are
required to maintain reserves against their deposit liabilities, primarily checking, saving, and time
certificates of deposit (CDs). These reserves can be held in the form of vault cash (currency) or as
a deposit at the Fed. The size of these reserves constrains the amount of deposits that financial
institutions can have outstanding, and deposit liabilities are related to the amount of assets these
institutions can acquire. These assets are often called “credit” since they represent loans made to
businesses and households, among others.
The Federal Reserve has three ways to expand or contract money and credit. The primary method
is called open market operations and it involves the Fed buying existing U.S. Treasury securities
(or those that have been already issued and sold to private investors). Should it buy securities, it
does so with the equivalent of newly issued currency (Federal Reserve notes). This expands the
reserve base and the ability of depository institutions to make loans and expand money and credit.
The reverse is true if the Fed decides to sell securities from its portfolio.
The Fed can also change reserve requirements, controlling a portion of deposits that banks must
hold as vault cash or on deposit at the Fed, which affects the available liquidity within the market.
Currently, banks are required to hold 0% to 10% of their deposits above $79.5 million in reserves. This
in reserves, depending on the
size of the bank. This tool is used rarely—the percentage was last changed in 1998.510 To increase
control over reserve
the growth in the money supply at a time of rapid reserve growth, the Federal
Reserve began to pay interest on required and excess reserves in October
2008, reducing the
opportunity cost of holding that money as opposed to lending it out.
9
Legislative changes to the Fed’s duties and authority related to financial regulatory reform can be found in CRS
Report R40877, Financial Regulatory Reform: Systemic Risk and the Federal Reserve, by Marc Labonte.
10
The deposit threshold is regularly adjusted for inflation. For current reserve requirements, see
http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/reservereq.htm.
Congressional Research Service
3
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Finally, the Fed permits Finally, the Fed permits certain depository institutions to borrow from it directly on a temporary
basis basis at
the discount window. That is, these institutions can “discount” at the Fed some of their own assets
to provide a
temporary means for obtaining reserves. Discounts are usually on an overnight basis.
For this
privilege they are charged an interest rate called, appropriately, the discount rate. The discount
discount rate is set by the Fed at a small markup over the federal funds rate.611 Direct lending,
from the discount
window and other recently created lending facilities, is negligible under normal financial
financial conditions, but was an important source of reserves during the financial crisis.
Because the Fed defines monetary policy as the actions it undertakes to influence the availability
and cost of money and credit, this suggests two ways to measure the stance of monetary policy.
One is to look at the cost of money and credit as measured by the rate of interest relative to
inflation (or inflation projections), while the other is to look at the growth of money and credit
5
The deposit threshold is regularly adjusted for inflation. The Dodd-Frank Act encouraged regulators to implement
heightened liquidity standards, particularly for Systemically Important Financial Institutions (SIFIs), that may affect
reserve requirements once fully implemented. The status of SIFI regulation was discussed in a speech by Federal
Reserve Governor Daniel Tarullo on June 3, 2011. The speech can be seen at http://www.federalreserve.gov/
newsevents/speech/tarullo20110603a.htm.
6
Until 2003, the discount rate was set slightly below the federal funds target, and the Fed used moral suasion to
discourage healthy banks from profiting from this low rate. To reduce the need for moral suasion, lending rules were
altered in early 2003. Since that time, the discount rate has been set at a penalty rate above the federal funds rate target.
However, during the financial crisis, the Fed encouraged banks to use the discount window.
Congressional Research Service
3
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
itself. Thus, one can look at either interest rates or the growth in the supply of money and credit
in coming to a conclusion about the current stance of monetary policy, that is, whether it is
expansionary, contractionary, or neutral.
Since the great inflation of the 1970s, most central banks have preferred to formulate monetary
policy more in terms of the cost of money and credit rather than on their supply. The Federal
Reserve thus conducts monetary policy by focusing on the cost of money and credit as proxied by
an interest rate. In particular, it targets a very short-term interest rate known as the federal funds
rate. The FOMC meets every six weeks to choose a federal funds target and sometimes meets on
an ad hoc basis if it wishes to change the target between regularly scheduled meetings. The
FOMC is comprised of the 7 Fed governors, the President of the New York Fed, and 4 of the
other 11 regional Fed bank presidents selected on a rotating basis.7
The federal funds rate is determined in the private market for overnight reserves of depository
institutions. At the end of a given period, usually a day, depository institutions must calculate how
many dollars of reserves they want to hold against their reservable liabilities (deposits).812 Some
institutions may discover a reserve shortage (too few reservable assets relative to those it wants to
hold) while others may have had reservable assets in excess of their wants. A market private market
exists in
which these reserves can be bought and sold on an overnight basis. The interest rate in
this market
is called the federal funds rate. It is this rate that the Fed uses as a target for
conducting monetary
policy. If it wishes to expand money and credit, it will lower the target ,
which encourages more
lending activity and, thus, demand in the economy. To support this lower
target, the Fed must
stand ready to buy more U.S. Treasury securities. Conversely, if it wishes to
tighten money and
credit, it will raise the target and remove as many reserves from depository
institutions as are
necessary to accomplish its ends. This will require the sale of treasuries from its
portfolio of
assets.9
The federal funds rate is linked to the interest rates that banks and other financial institutions
charge for loans—or the provision of credit. Thus, while the Fed may directly influence only a
very short-term interest rate, this rate influences other longer-term rates. However, this
relationship is far from being on a one-to-one basis since the longer-term market rates are
influenced not only by what the Fed is doing today, but what it is expected to do in the future and
what inflation is expected to be in the future. This highlights the importance of expectations in
explaining market interest rates. For that reason, there is a growing body of literature that urges
the Federal Reserve to be very transparent in explaining what its policy is and will be and making
a commitment to adhere to that policy. 10 In fact, the Fed has responded to this literature and is
increasingly transparent in explaining its policy measures and what these are expected to
accomplish.
7
H.R. 1512 would remove the regional Fed bank presidents from the Federal Open Market Committee. assets.13
11
Until 2003, the discount rate was set slightly below the federal funds target, and the Fed used moral suasion to
discourage healthy banks from profiting from this low rate. To reduce the need for moral suasion, lending rules were
altered in early 2003. Since that time, the discount rate has been set at a penalty rate above the federal funds rate target.
However, during the financial crisis, the Fed encouraged banks to use the discount window.
12
Depository institutions are obligated by law to hold some fraction of their deposit liabilities as reserves. In addition,
they are also likely to hold additional or excess reserves based on certain risk assessments they make about their
portfolios and liabilities. Until very recently these reserves were non-income earning assets. The Fed now pays interest
on both types of reserves. It is too early to assess how this shift in policy will affect bank reserve holdings.
913
For a technical discussion of how this is actually done, see Edwards, Cheryl L., “Open Market Operations in the
1990s,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, November 1997, pp. 859-872.
10
See, for example, Santomero, Anthony M. “Great Expectations: The Role of Beliefs in Economics and Monetary
Policy.” Business Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Second Quarter 2004, pp. 1-6, and Sellon, Gordon H.,
Jr., “Expectations and the Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism,” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, Fourth Quarter 2004, pp. 4-42.
8
Congressional Research Service
4
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Using market interest rates as an indicator of monetary policy is fraught with danger
Congressional Research Service
4
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
The federal funds rate is linked to the interest rates that banks and other financial institutions
charge for loans—or the provision of credit. Thus, while the Fed may directly influence only a
very short-term interest rate, this rate influences other longer-term rates. However, this
relationship is far from being on a one-to-one basis since the longer-term market rates are
influenced not only by what the Fed is doing today, but what it is expected to do in the future and
what inflation is expected to be in the future. This highlights the importance of expectations in
explaining market interest rates. For that reason, there is a growing body of literature that urges
the Federal Reserve to be very transparent in explaining what its policy is and will be and making
a commitment to adhere to that policy.14 In fact, the Fed has responded to this literature and is
increasingly transparent in explaining its policy measures and what these are expected to
accomplish.
Using market interest rates as an indicator of monetary policy is potentially misleading, however.
The interest rate that is essential to decisions made by households and businesses to buy capital
goods is what economists call the “real” interest rate. It is often proxied by subtracting from the
market interest rate the actual or expected rate of inflation. The real rate is largely independent of
the amount of money and credit since over the longer run, it is determined by the interaction of
saving and investment (or the demand for capital goods). The internationalization of capital
markets means that for most developed countries the relevant saving and investment that
determines the real interest rate is on a global basis. Thus, real rates in the United States depend
not only on our national saving and investment, but on the saving and investment of other
countries as well. For that reason, national interest rates are influenced by international credit
conditions and business cycles.
The recent financial crisis underlines that open market operations alone can be insufficient at
times for meeting the Fed’s statutory mandate. Since the crisis, many economists and central
bankers have argued that a macroprudential approach to supervision and regulation is needed, and
this may affect conduct of monetary policy to maintain maximum employment and price
stability.1115 Whereas traditional open market operations managed to contain systemic risk
following the bursting of the “dot-com” bubble in 2000, direct lending by the Fed on a large scale
was unable to contain systemic risk in 2008. In a recent speech, Fed Chairmanspeech, Ben Bernanke said he
is was committed to
serving on and working closely with the Financial Stability Oversight Committee,
created by the
Dodd-Frank Act, to safeguard against systemic risk.1216 He also described how the
Fed has recently
restructured its internal operations to facilitate a macroprudential approach to
supervision and regulation.13
regulation.17
14
See, for example, Santomero, Anthony M. “Great Expectations: The Role of Beliefs in Economics and Monetary
Policy.” Business Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Second Quarter 2004, pp. 1-6, and Sellon, Gordon H.,
Jr., “Expectations and the Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism,” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, Fourth Quarter 2004, pp. 4-42.
15
Bank for International Settlements, “Monetary Policy in a World with Macro Prudential Policy,” speech by Jaime
Caruana on June 11, 2011, http://www.bis.org/speeches/sp110610.htm.
16
For more information, see CRS Report R41384, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act:
Systemic Risk and the Federal Reserve, by Marc Labonte.
17
Chairman Ben Bernanke, “Implementing a Macroprudential Approach to Supervision and Regulation,” speech at the
47th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Chicago, Illinois, Federal Reserve, May 5, 2011,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20110505a.htm.
Congressional Research Service
5
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Economic Effects of Monetary Policy in the Short Run and
Long Run
How do changes in short-term interest rates affect the overall economy? In the short run, an
expansionary monetary policy that reduces interest rates increases interest-sensitive spending, all
else equal. Interest-sensitive spending includes physical investment (i.e., plant and equipment) by
firms, residential investment (housing construction), and consumer-durable spending (e.g.,
automobiles and appliances) by households. As discussed in the next section, it also encourages
exchange rate depreciation that causes exports to rise and imports to fall, all else equal. To reduce
spending in the economy, the Fed raises interest rates, and the process works in reverse. An
examination of U.S. economic history will show that money- and credit-induced demand
expansions can have a positive effect on U.S. GDP growth and total employment. The extent to
which greater interest-sensitive spending results in an increase in overall spending in the
economy in the short run will depend in part on how close the economy is to full employment.
When the economy is near full employment, the increase in spending is likely to be dissipated
through higher inflation more quickly. When the economy is far below full employment,
11
Bank for International Settlements, “Monetary Policy in a World with Macro Prudential Policy,” speech by Jaime
Caruana on June 11, 2011, http://www.bis.org/speeches/sp110610.htm.
12
For more information, see CRS Report R41384, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act:
Systemic Risk and the Federal Reserve, by Marc Labonte.
13
Chairman Ben Bernanke, “Implementing a Macroprudential Approach to Supervision and Regulation,” speech at the
47th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Chicago, Illinois, Federal Reserve, May 5, 2011,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20110505a.htm.
Congressional Research Service
5
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
inflationary pressures are more likely to be muted. This same history, however, also suggests that
over the longer run, a more rapid rate of growth of money and credit is largely dissipated in a
more rapid rate of inflation with little, if any, lasting effect on real GDP and employment. (Since
the crisis, the historical relationship between money growth and inflation has not held so far, as
will be discussed below.)
Economists have two explanations for this paradoxical behavior. First, they note that, in the short
run, many economies have an elaborate system of contracts (both implicit and explicit) that
makes it difficult in a short period for significant adjustments to take place in wages and prices in
response to a more rapid growth of money and credit. Second, they note that expectations for one
reason or another are slow to adjust to the longer -run consequences of major changes in monetary
policy. This slow adjustment also adds rigidities to wages and prices. Because of these rigidities,
changes in the growth of money and credit that change aggregate demand can have a large initial
effect on output and employment albeit with a policy lag of six to eight quarters before the
broader economy fully responds to monetary policy measures. Over the longer run, as contracts
are renegotiated and expectations adjust, wages and prices rise in response to the change in
demand and much of the change in output and employment is undone. Thus, monetary policy can
matter in the short run but be fairly neutral for GDP growth and employment in the longer run.1418
It is noteworthy that in societies where high rates of inflation are endemic, price adjustments are
very rapid. During the final stages of very rapid inflations, called hyperinflation, the ability of
more rapid rates of growth of money and credit to alter GDP growth and employment is virtually
nonexistent, if not negative.
18
Two interesting papers bearing on what monetary policy can accomplish by two former officials of the Federal
Reserve are Santomero, Anthony M. “What Monetary Policy Can and Cannot Do,” Business Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, First Quarter 2002, pp. 1-4, and Mishkin, Frederic S. “What Should Central Banks Do?,” Review,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, November/December 2000, pp. 1-14.
Congressional Research Service
6
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Monetary vs. Fiscal Policy
Either fiscal policy (defined here as changes in the structural budget deficit) or monetary policy
can be used to alter overall spending in the economy. However, there are several important
differences to consider between the two.
First, economic conditions change rapidly, and in practice monetary policy can be much more
nimble than fiscal policy. The Fed meets every six weeks to consider changes in interest rates,
and can call an unscheduled meeting any time in between. Large changes to fiscal policy typically
occur once a year at most. For example, there were three large tax cuts from the 2001 recession
through 2006;15 in the same period, interest rates were changed 29 times. Once a decision to alter
Once a decision to alter fiscal policy has been made, the proposal must
travel through a long and arduous legislative
process that can last months before it can become law, while monetary policy changes are made
instantly.16
14
Two interesting papers bearing on what monetary policy can accomplish by two former officials of the Federal
Reserve are Santomero, Anthony M. “What Monetary Policy Can and Cannot Do,” Business Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, First Quarter 2002, pp. 1-4, and Mishkin, Frederic S. “What Should Central Banks Do?,” Review,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, November/December 2000, pp. 1-14.
15
The tax cuts are the Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act (P.L. 107-16), the Job Creation and
Worker Assistance Act (P.L. 107-147), and the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act (P.L. 108-27).
16
To some extent, fiscal policy automatically mitigates changes in the business cycle without any policy changes
because tax revenue falls relative to GDP and certain mandatory spending (such as unemployment insurance) rises
when economic growth slows, and vice versa.
Congressional Research Service
6
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
law, while monetary policy changes are made instantly.19
In addition to differences in implementation lags, both monetary and fiscal policy face lags due to
“pipeline effects.” In the case of monetary policy, interest rates throughout the economy may
change rapidly, but it takes longer for economic actors to change their spending patterns in
response. For example, in response to a lower interest rate, a business must put together a loan
proposal, apply for a loan, receive approval for the loan, and then put the funds to use. In the case
of fiscal policy, once legislation has been enacted, it may take some time for authorized spending
to be outlayed. An agency must approve projects and select and negotiate with contractors before
funds can be released. In the case of transfers or tax cuts, recipients must receive the funds and
then alter their private spending patterns before the economy-wide effects are felt. For both
monetary and fiscal policy, further rounds of private and public decision-making must occur
before “multiplier” or “ripple” effects are fully felt.
Second, political constraints have led to fiscal policy being employed mostly in only one
direction. Over the course of the business cycle, aggregate spending in the economy can be
expected to be too high as often as it is too low. This means that stabilization policy should be
tightened as often as it is loosened, yet increasing the budget deficit has proven to be much more
popular than implementing the spending cuts or tax increases necessary to reduce it. As a result,
the budget has been in deficit in all but five years since 1961. This has led to an accumulation of
federal debt that gives policymakers less leeway to potentially undertake a robust expansionary
fiscal policy, if needed, in the future. By contrast, the Fed is more insulated from political
pressures,1720 and experience shows that it is as willing to raise interest rates as it is to lower them.
Third, the long -run consequences of fiscal and monetary policy differ. Expansionary fiscal policy
creates federal debt that must be serviced by future generations. Some of this debt will be “owed
to ourselves,” but some (presently, about half) will be owed to foreigners. To the extent that
expansionary fiscal policy “crowds out” private investment, it leaves future national income
lower than it otherwise would have been.1821 Monetary policy does not have this effect on
generational equity, though different levels of interest rates will affect borrowers and lenders
19
To some extent, fiscal policy automatically mitigates changes in the business cycle without any policy changes
because tax revenue falls relative to GDP and certain mandatory spending (such as unemployment insurance) rises
when economic growth slows, and vice versa.
20
For more information, see CRS Report RL31056, Economics of Federal Reserve Independence, by Marc Labonte.
21
An exception to the rule would be a situation where the economy is far enough below full employment that virtually
no crowding out takes place because the stimulus to spending generates enough resources to finance new capital
spending.
Congressional Research Service
7
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
though different levels of interest rates will affect borrowers and lenders
differently. Furthermore, the government faces a budget constraint that limits the scope of
expansionary fiscal policy—it can only issue debt as long as investors believe that the debt will
be honored—even if economic conditions require larger deficits to restore equilibrium.1922
Fourth, openness of an economy to highly mobile capital flows changes the relative effectiveness
of fiscal and monetary policy. Expansionary fiscal policy would be expected to lead to higher
interest rates, all else equal, which would attract foreign capital looking for a higher rate of
return.2023 Foreign capital can only enter the United States on net through a trade deficit. Thus,
higher foreign capital inflows lead to higher imports, which reduces spending on domestically
produced substitutes, and lower spending on exports. The increase in the trade deficit would
cancel out the expansionary effects of the increase in the budget deficit to some extent (in theory,
entirely). This theory is supported by experience—as the budget deficit increased, so did the trade
17
For more information, see CRS Report RL31056, Economics of Federal Reserve Independence, by Marc Labonte.
An exception to the rule would be a situation where the economy is far enough below full employment that virtually
no crowding out takes place because the stimulus to spending generates enough resources to finance new capital
spending.
19
The analogous constraint on monetary policy is that after a certain limit, expansionary monetary policy would
become highly inflationary. But from the current starting point of price stability, problems with inflation would
presumably only occur after a point where the economy had returned to full employment.
20
For more information, see CRS Report RL31235, The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit, by Brian W.
Cashell.
18
Congressional Research Service
7
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
deficit.21 Expansionary monetary policy would have the opposite effect—lower interest rates
would cause capital to flow abroad in search of higher rates of return elsewhere. Foreign capital
outflows would reduce the trade deficit through an increase in spending on exports and
domestically produced import substitutes. Thus, foreign capital flows would (tend to) magnify the
expansionary effects of monetary policy.
Fifth, fiscal policy can be targeted to specific recipients. In the case of normal open market
operations, monetary policy cannot. This difference could be considered an advantage or
disadvantage. On the one hand, policymakers could target stimulus to aid the sectors of the
economy most in need, or most likely to respond positively to stimulus. On the other hand,
stimulus could turn out to be allocated on the basis of political or other non-economic factors that
reduce the macroeconomic effectiveness of the stimulus. As a result, both fiscal and monetary
policy have distributional implications, but the latter’s are largely incidental, whereas the former’s
can be explicitly chosen.
In cases where economic activity is extremely depressed, monetary policy may lose some of its
effectiveness. When interest rates become extremely low, interest-sensitive spending may no
longer be very responsive to further rate cuts. Furthermore, interest rates cannot be lowered below
zero. In this scenario, fiscal policy may be more effective. As is discussed in the next section,
some would argue that the U.S. economy experienced this scenario following the recent financial
crisis.
Of course, using monetary and fiscal policy to stabilize the economy are not mutually exclusive
policy options. But because of the Fed’s independence from Congress and the Administration, the
two policy options are not always coordinated. If compatible fiscal and monetary policies are
chosen by Congress and the Fed, respectively, then the economic effects would be more powerful
than if either policy were implemented in isolation. For example, if stimulative monetary and
fiscal policies were implemented, the resulting economic stimulus would be larger than if one
policy were stimulative and the other were neutral. But if incompatible policies are selected, they
could partially negate each other. For example, a stimulative fiscal policy and contractionary
monetary policy may end up having little net effect on aggregate demand (though there may be
considerable distributional effects). Thus, when fiscal and monetary policymakers disagree in the
current system, they can potentially choose policies with the intent of offsetting each others’
actions.22 Whether this arrangement is better or worse for the economy depends on what policies
are chosen. If one actor chooses inappropriate policies, then the lack of coordination usefully
allows the other actor to try to negate its effects.
The Recent and Current Stance of Monetary Policy
Until financial turmoil emerged in 2007, a consensus had emerged among economists that a
relatively stable business cycle could be maintained through prudent and nimble changes to
21
See CRS Report RS21409, The Budget Deficit and the Trade Deficit: What Is Their Relationship?, by Marc Labonte
and Gail E. Makinen.
22
It is important to take this possibility into consideration when evaluating the potential effects of fiscal policy on the
business cycle. Because the Fed presumably chooses (and continually updates) a monetary policy that aims to keep the
economy at full employment, the Fed would need to alter its policy to offset the effects of any stimulative fiscal policy
changes that moved the economy above full employment. Thus, the actual net stimulative effect of a fiscal policy
change (after taking into account monetary policy adjustments) could be less than the effects in isolation.
Congressional Research Service
8
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
other’s
22
The analogous constraint on monetary policy is that after a certain limit, expansionary monetary policy would
become highly inflationary. But from the current starting point of price stability, problems with inflation would
presumably only occur after a point where the economy had returned to full employment.
23
For more information, see CRS Report RL31235, The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit, by Brian W.
Cashell.
Congressional Research Service
8
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
actions.24 Whether this arrangement is better or worse for the economy depends on what policies
are chosen. If one actor chooses inappropriate policies, then the lack of coordination allows the
other actor to try to negate its effects.
The Recent and Current Stance of Monetary Policy
Until financial turmoil emerged in 2007, a consensus had emerged among economists that a
relatively stable business cycle could be maintained through prudent and nimble changes to
interest rates via transparently communicated and signaled open market operations. That
consensus would break down as the financial crisis worsened, and the Fed took increasingly
unconventional and unprecedented steps to restore financial stability.
Before the Financial Crisis
As the U.S. economy was coming out of the short and shallow 2001 recession, unemployment
continued rising until mid-2003. Fearful that the economy would slip back into recession, the Fed
kept the federal funds rate extremely low.2325 The federal funds target reached a low of 1% by mid2003. As the expansion gathered momentum and prices began to rise, the federal funds target was
slowly increased in a series of moves to 5¼% in mid-2006.
It is now argued by some economists that the financial crisis was, at least in part, due to Federal
Reserve policy to ensure that the then-ongoing expansion continued.2426 In particular, critics now
claim that the low short-term rates were kept too low for too long after the 2001 recession had
ended, and this caused an increased demand for housing that resulted in a “price bubble.” The
” (a
bubble that was also due, in part, to lax lending standards that were subject to regulation by the
Fed and others). The shift in financing housing from fixed to variable rate mortgages made this
sector of the economy
increasingly vulnerable to movements in short-term interest rates. An
alternative perspective,
championed by ChairmanBen Bernanke and others, was that the low mortgage rates
that helped fuel
the housing bubble were mainly caused by a “global savings glut” over which the
Fed had little
control.2527 One consequence of the tightening of monetary policy later in the decade,
critics now
claim, was to burst this “price bubble” (a bubble that was also due, in part, to lax lending
standards that were subject to regulation by the Fed and others)..”
24
It is important to take this possibility into consideration when evaluating the potential effects of fiscal policy on the
business cycle. Because the Fed presumably chooses (and continually updates) a monetary policy that aims to keep the
economy at full employment, the Fed would need to alter its policy to offset the effects of any stimulative fiscal policy
changes that moved the economy above full employment. Thus, the actual net stimulative effect of a fiscal policy
change (after taking into account monetary policy adjustments) could be less than the effects in isolation.
25
Historical and current targets for the federal funds rate can be found at http://www.federalreserve.gov/fomc/
fundsrate.htm.
26
In a Wall Street Journal opinion article, six economists are polled regarding if the Fed was to blame for creating the
housing bubble that in part led to the recent financial crisis, and five of six responded that the Fed in some degree was
to blame. See David Henderson, “Did the Fed Cause the Housing Bubble?,” Wall Street Journal, March 27, 2009.
27
See Ben Bernanke, “The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit,” speech at the Virginia
Association of Economists, March 10, 2005.
Congressional Research Service
9
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Direct Assistance During and After the Financial Crisis
The bursting of the housing bubble led to the onset of a financial crisis that affected both
depository institutions and other segments of the financial sector involved with housing finance.
As the delinquency rates on home mortgages rose to record numbers, financial firms exposed to
the mortgage market suffered capital losses and lost access to liquidity. The contagious nature of
this development was soon obvious as other types of loans and credit became adversely affected.
This, in turn, spilled over into the broader economy, as the lack of credit soon had a negative
effect on both production and aggregate demand. In December 2007, the economy entered a
recession.
As the spillover effects from the housing slump to the financial system, as well as its international
scope, became apparent, the Fed responded by reducing the federal funds target and the discount
rate.2628 Beginning on September 18, 2007, and ending on December 16, 2008, the federal funds
target was
reduced from 5¼% to a range between 0% and ¼%, where it currently remains.
23
Historical and current targets for the federal funds rate can be found at http://www.federalreserve.gov/fomc/
fundsrate.htm.
24
In a WSJ opinion article, six economists are polled regarding if the Fed was to blame for creating the housing bubble
that in part led to the recent financial crisis, and five of six responded that the Fed in some degree was to blame. See
David Henderson, “Did the Fed Cause the Housing Bubble?,” Wall Street Journal, March 27, 2009.
25
See Ben Bernanke, “The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit,” speech at the Virginia
Association of Economists, March 10, 2005.
26
For a detailed account of the Fed’s role in the financial crisis, see CRS Report RL34427, Financial Turmoil: Federal
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
9
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
reduced from 5¼% to a range between 0% and ¼%, where it currently remains.
With liquidity problems persisting as the federal funds rate was reduced, it appeared that the
traditional transmission mechanism linking monetary policy to activity in the broader economy
was not working. It also began to concern the monetary authorities that the liquidity provided to
the banking system was not reaching other parts of the financial system. Using only traditional
monetary policy tools, additional monetary stimulus cannot be provided once the federal funds
rate has reached its zero bound. To circumvent this problem, the Fed decided to use nontraditional methods to provide additional monetary policy stimulus.
First, the Federal Reserve introduced a number of emergency credit facilities to provide increased
liquidity directly to financial firms and markets. The first facility was introduced in December
2007, and several were added after the worsening of the crisis in September 2008. These facilities
were designed to fill perceived gaps between open market operations and the discount window.
The loans primarily provided by these facilities were designed to provide short-term loans backed
by collateral that exceedsexceeded the value of the loan.2729 A number of the recipients were non-banks that
are outside the regulatory umbrella of the Federal Reserve; this marked the first time that the Fed
lent to non-banks since the Great Depression. The Fed began to employ a seldom used emergency
provision, Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act,2830 that allows it to make loans to other
financial institutions and to non-financial firms as well. The Fed justified their pursuit of this
policy on emergency lending on
the grounds that it falls under its mandate to “promote effectively the goals of
maximum maximum
employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.”2931
The Fed provided assistance through liquidity facilities, which included both the traditional
discount window and the newly created emergency facilities previously mentioned, and through
direct support to two specific institutions, AIG and Bear Stearns.32 The magnitude of this assistance
28
For a detailed account of the Fed’s role in the financial crisis, see CRS Report RL34427, Financial Turmoil: Federal
Reserve Policy Responses, by Marc Labonte.
29
See CRS Report R41073, Government Interventions in Response to Financial Turmoil, by Baird Webel and Marc
Labonte.
30
12 U.S.C. 343.
31
Federal Reserve Act, Section 2A, 12 USC 225a.
32
In 2011, the Dodd-Frank Act (P.L. 111-203) changed Section 13(3) to rule out direct support to specific institutions
in the future.
Congressional Research Service
10
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
assistance has been large. Total assistance from the Federal Reserve at the beginning of August
2007 was
approximately $234 million provided through liquidity facilities, with no direct support
given. In
mid-December 2008, it reached a high of $1.6 trillion, with a near high of $108 billion
given in
direct support. From that point on, it fell steadily. Assistance provided through liquidity facilities
facilities fell below $100 billion in February 2010, and support to specific institutions fell below
$100
billion in January 2011.30 By 2012, central33 Central bank liquidity swaps, discussed below, was the only
in the next section, are the
only facility created during the crisis that was still active, although some expired facilities still held
legacy assetsis still active. With one exception, all assistance through
expired facilities has been fully repaid
with interest, and eventual repayment in that case is expected.31
(...continued)
Reserve Policy Responses, by Marc Labonte.
27
See CRS Report R41073, Government Interventions in Response to Financial Turmoil, by Baird Webel and Marc
Labonte.
28
12 U.S.C. 343.
29
Federal Reserve Act, Section 2A, 12 USC 225a.
30
Data from “Recent Balance Sheet Trends,” Credit and Liquidity Programs and the Balance Sheet,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_recenttrends.htm. Values include totals from credit extended
through Federal Reserve liquidity facilities and support for specific institutions.
31
One facility, the Term Securities Lending Facility, still had long-term loans outstanding. The Fed expects that all
assistance through this facility will be repaid with interest once the loans mature. For more information, see
http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/talf.htm.
Congressional Research Service
10
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
expected.34
Central Bank Liquidity Swaps
The Fed’s central bank liquidity swap lines, or temporary reciprocal currency agreements, are the
only lending facility introduced during the recent financial crisis that is still active. The first swap
lines were created in December 2007. Overall, ten10 central banks have drawn on the swap lines at
some point, and four4 more were eligible to—but did not—use the swap lines.3235 In October 2008,
the the
Fed made the swap lines with certain countries unlimited in size. The swap lines expired in
February 2010, but were subsequently reopened in May 2010 with the Bank of Canada, the Bank
of England, the European Central Bank (ECB), the Bank of Japan, and the Swiss National Bank
in response to the eurozone crisis. The Fed has extended the expiration date of the swap lines
several times, most recently to February 1, 2014and in October 2013, it converted them to permanent standing arrangements.
Under a swap with, say, the ECB, the ECB temporarily receives U.S. dollars and the Fed
temporarily receives euros. After a fixed period of time (up to three months), the transaction is
reversed. Interest on swaps is paid to the Fed at 0.5 percentage points above the U.S. dollar
overnight index swap rate (OIS), a private borrowing rate. The temporary swaps are repaid at the
exchange rate prevailing at the time of the original swap, meaning that there is no downside risk
for the Fed if the dollar appreciates in the meantime (although the Fed also does not enjoy upside
gain if the dollar depreciates). Except in the unlikely event that the borrowing country’s currency
becomes unconvertible in foreign exchange markets, there is no credit risk involved because the
swap is with other central banks (the foreign central bank bears losses if the private bank it lends
the dollars to defaults). The Fed has reported no losses under the program. The swaps were
created under the section of the Federal Reserve Act providing authority for open market
operations (Section 14); they did not require the emergency authority found in Section 13(3) of
the Federal Reserve Act.33
36
33
Data from “Recent Balance Sheet Trends,” Credit and Liquidity Programs and the Balance Sheet,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_recenttrends.htm. Values include totals from credit extended
through Federal Reserve liquidity facilities and support for specific institutions.
34
One expired facility, the Term Securities Lending Facility, still has a small amount of long-term loans outstanding.
The Fed expects that all assistance through this facility will be repaid with interest once the loans mature. For more
information, see http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/talf.htm.
35
U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal Reserve System: Opportunities Exist to Strengthen Policies and
Processes for Managing Emergency Assistance, GAO-11-696, July 21, 2011, Appendix IX, http://www.gao.gov/
new.items/d11696.pdf.
36
Prior to the crisis, currency swaps had been used sporadically dating back to 1962, including after September 11,
2011. See William Dudley, Testimony Before the Committee on Oversight and Government Reform, U.S. House of
Representatives, December 16, 2011.
Congressional Research Service
11
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Swaps outstanding peaked at $583 billion in December 2008 and fell to zero by March 2010.
After reestablishment in May 2010, small amounts were drawn from May 2010 to March 2011.
They were then unused between March and August 2011. Swaps outstanding increased suddenly
in December 2011, averaging more than $100 billion from late December to February 2012. Their
use has since declined, and less than $101 billion was outstanding by the end of 20122013. To date,
most most
of the swaps have been with the European Central Bank; the Bank of Japan has been the
second largest secondlargest counterparty.
Swap lines are intended to provide liquidity to private banks in non-domestic denominations.
Because banks lend long-term and borrow short-term, a solvent bank can become illiquid,
meaning it cannot borrow in private markets to meet short-term cash flow needs. For example,
many European banks have borrowed in dollars to finance dollar-denominated transactions.
Normally, foreign banks could finance their dollar-denominated borrowing through the private
inter-bank lending market. As some banks have become reluctant to lend to each other through
this market, central banks at home and abroad have taken a much larger role in providing banks
with liquidity directly. Normally, banks can only borrow from their home central bank, and central
central banks can only provide liquidity in their own currency. The Fed’s swap lines allow foreign central
central banks to provide needed liquidity to their country’s banks in dollars. News articles indicate that
32
U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal Reserve System: Opportunities Exist to Strengthen Policies and
Processes for Managing Emergency Assistance, GAO-11-696, July 21, 2011, Appendix IX, http://www.gao.gov/
new.items/d11696.pdf.
33
Prior to the crisis, swaps had been used sporadically dating back to 1962, according to William Dudley, Testimony
Before the Committee on Oversight and Government Reform, U.S. House of Representatives, December 16, 2011.
Congressional Research Service
11
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
indicate that access to dollar liquidity deteriorated for European banks when the eurozone crisis has
has worsened.3437 Initially, the swap lines were designed to provide foreign central banks with
access to
U.S. dollars. In April 2009, the swap lines were modified so that the Fed could access foreign
foreign currency to provide to its banks as well; to date, the Fed has not done so.
Unconventional Policy Measures at the Zero Bound After the Crisis
Quantitative Easing and the Growth in the Balance Sheet and Bank Reserves
With direct lending falling as financial conditions began to normalize in 2009 and the federal
funds rate at its zero bound since December 2012, the Fed was faced with the decision of whether
to try to provide
additional monetary stimulus through unconventional measures. Its first decision
was whether to
maintain the elevated level of liquidity in the financial system now that assistance
through its
liquidity facilities was declining, in order to. To prevent a removal of monetary stimulus while the
economy was still fragile. It, the Fed decided to keep the liquidity in place, and in March 2009, the Fed
Fed announced plans to purchase $300 billion of Treasury securities, $200 billion of Agency debt
(later revised to $175 billion), and $1.25 trillion of Agency mortgage-backed securities. These
purchases were completed by the end of March 2010.3538 This was clearly not a “business as usual”
monetary policy, but something quite extraordinary, sometimes referred to as “quantitative
easing.” 39 While there may not be a universally accepted definition of quantitative easing, this
report defines it as actions to further stimulate the economy through growth in the Fed’s balance
sheet once the federal funds rate has reached the “zero bound.”
37
See, for example, “The Dash for Cash,” The Economist, December 3, 2011, p. 85.
In this context, Agency securities and MBS are primarily securities issued by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, with
some securities issued by the Federal Home Loan Banks and Ginnie Mae. The amounts announced in March 2009
included Agency securities and MBS that the Fed began purchasing in late 2008.
39
See CRS Report R42962, Federal Reserve: Unconventional Monetary Policy Options, by Marc Labonte.
38
Congressional Research Service
12
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Beginning in November of 2010, the Federal Reserve, dissatisfied with the high level of
unemployment, took steps to encourage economic growth by purchasing an additional $600
billion of Treasury securities and continuing the practice of replacing maturing securities. The
purchases were made at a pace of $75 billion a month and were completed in about eight months.
The Fed has focused on purchasing securities with maturities between 2½ and 10 years in
length.36
This policy became popularly known as “QE2.” According to the Fed, these actions
were taken to
promote a stronger pace of economic recovery because progress to date toward the
Fed’s policy
objectives had been “disappointingly slow.”3740
After the completion of QE2, the Fed took no further monetary policy actions for about six
months. On September 21, 2011, the Fed announced the Maturity Extension Program, which has
been popularly coined “Operation Twist” after a similar 1961 program.38 Under this program, the
Fed purchased $667 billion in long-term Treasury securities and sold an equivalent amount of
34
See, for example, “The Dash for Cash,” The Economist, December 3, 2011, p. 85.
In this context, Agency securities and MBS are primarily issued by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, with some
securities issued by the Federal Home Loan Banks and Ginnie Mae. The Fed began purchasing Agency securities and
MBS in smaller quantities in late 2008.
36
CRS Report R41540, Quantitative Easing and the Growth in the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet, by Marc Labonte.
37
Federal Reserve, “Federal Open Market Committee,” press release, November 3, 2010,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20101103a.htm.
38
The original Operation Twist was devised as a way to stimulate the economy given that monetary policy was
constrained by the need to maintain the gold standard. Since such a constraint does not exist today under the current
market-determined exchange rate, the Fed could have stimulated the economy through expansionary monetary policy
instead, although at the zero bound, this would have been limited to unconventional forms of stimulus, such as
quantitative easing.
35
Congressional Research Service
12
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
short-term Treasury securities from its portfolio. The program expired at the end of 2012. The Fed
has argued that the Maturity Extension Program will stimulate the economy by reducing longterm borrowing rates throughout the economy.3941 Under this program, the
Fed purchased $667 billion in long-term Treasury securities and sold an equivalent amount of
short-term Treasury securities from its portfolio. Unlike “quantitative easing,” the Maturity
Extension Program hashad no effect on the size of the Fed’s balance sheet, bank reserves, or the
monetary base. For this reason, the Maturity Extension Program would be expected to have a
smaller effect on economic growth, interest rates, and inflation than if an equivalent amount of
Treasury securities were bought through quantitative easing (i.e., if the purchase of long-term
Treasury securities were not “sterilized” by the sale of short-term securities). The Maturity
Extension Program endedexpired at the end of 2012. The, at which point, the Fed announced that it would
continue to
purchase $45 billion inof long-term Treasury securities each month, but would no
longer offset
those purchases through the sale of short-term Treasury securities.
On September 13, 2012, in light of continuing high unemployment and inflation slightly below its
long-term target, the Fed announced it would restart large-scale asset purchases (popularly
referred to as “QE3”), pledging to purchase $40 billion of government-sponsored enterprise
(GSE) mortgage-backed securities (MBS) per month. Coupled with its monthly purchases of
TreausryTreasury securities, QE3 is a modestly higher monthly purchase rate than QE2. Unlike the
previous two rounds of asset purchases, the Fed specified no planned end date to its purchases,
instead pledging to continue purchases until labor markets improved, in a context of price
stability. 4042 Some economists have argued that pledging to pursue a policy for “as long as it takes”
is more effective than announcing a limited and predetermined duration.41
, although it has an
unclear effect on market uncertainty.43 In December 2013, the Fed began to gradually taper off its
asset purchases. Smaller asset purchases can still be considered an expansionary monetary policy,
but one that adds less stimulus to the economy than previously. Barring a future change in course,
this is seen as the first step toward an eventual end to unconventional monetary policy.
40
Federal Reserve, “Federal Open Market Committee,” press release, November 3, 2010,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20101103a.htm.
41
The original Operation Twist was devised as a way to stimulate the economy given that monetary policy was
constrained by the need to maintain the gold standard. Since such a constraint does not exist today under the current
market-determined exchange rate, the Fed could have stimulated the economy through expansionary monetary policy
instead, although at the zero bound, this would have been limited to unconventional forms of stimulus, such as
quantitative easing.
42
Federal Reserve, Press Release, September 13, 2012, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/
20120913a.htm.
43
Michael Woodford, “Methods of Policy Accommodation at the Interest-Rate Lower Bound,” working paper, August
2012, available at http://www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/sympos/2012/mw.pdf?sm=jh083112-4.
Congressional Research Service
13
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
To understand the effect of quantitative easing on the economy, it is first necessary to describe its
effect on the Fed’s balance sheet. The loans and other assistance provided by the Federal Reserve
to banks and
non-bank institutions isare considered an assetassets on the Fed’s balance sheet because it represents
they
represent money owed to or assets owned by the Fed. This assistance and its holdings of Treasury
securities, MBS, and GSE debt comprise most of the assets on the Fed’s balance sheet.
From the time its first emergency lending facility was introduced in December 2007 until the
crisis worsened in September 2008, the Fed “sterilized” the effects of lending on its balance sheet
by selling Treasury securities. After September 2008, the Fed allowed its balance sheet to grow,
and between September and November 2008, it more than doubled in size, increasing from under
$1 trillion to over $2 trillion. The increase in assets during this time took the form of direct
assistance to the financial sector through emergency liquidity facilities.
From November 2008 to
November 2010, the overall size of the Fed’s balance sheet did not vary
much; however, its
composition changed. As of December 2010, loans made up $46 billion of the
$2,427 billion of the Fed’s balance sheet and securities made up $2,225 billion. The purchases of
The amount of Fed loans fell until it was less than $50 billion at the end of
2010, while holdings of securities rose from under $500 billion in November 2008 to over $2
trillion in November 2010. The purchases of $600 billion in Treasury securities increased the
balance sheet from $2.3 trillion in November
2010 to $2.9 trillion mid-2011. It remained around
that level until September 2012, when it began rising at
roughly the same monthly rate as asset purchases ($85 billion since December 2012) for the
for the duration of QE3. It was about $3 trillion at the end of 2012.
39
Federal Reserve, Press Release, September 21, 2011, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/
20110921a.htm.
40
Federal Reserve, Press Release, September 13, 2012, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/
20120913a.htm.
41
Michael Woodford, “Methods of Policy Accommodation at the Interest-Rate Lower Bound,” working paper, August
2012, available at http://www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/sympos/2012/mw.pdf?sm=jh083112-4.
Congressional Research Service
13
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
trillion at the end of 2012 and about $4 trillion at the end of 2013.
This increase in the Fed’s assets must be matched by a corresponding increase in its liabilities on
its balance sheet, which mostly intakes the form of currency, bank reserves, and cash deposited by
the U.S.
Treasury at the Fed. Bank reserves increased from about $46 billion in August 2008 to
$820
billion at the end of 2008. Since October 2009, bank reserves held at the Fed have been betweenexceeded
$1 trillion and $1.7 trillion. 42, reaching $2.5 trillion by the end of 2013.44 The increase in bank reserves can be seen
as the inevitable outcome
of the increase in assets held by the Fed because they, in effect,
financed the Fed’s asset purchases
and loan programs. Reserves increase because the loans or
proceeds from asset purchases are
credited to the recipients’ reserve accounts at the Fed.
Whether the additional reserves will be lent out by banks, resulting in lower market interest rates
and an expansion of new spending, as posited in the textbook explanation of how monetary policy
works, is another story. Recent experience is not reassuring, as the large volume of reserves added
to the banking system by the Fed have remained as excess bank reserves, without commensurate
increases in lending or other activities by banks. Some economists fear that the response of banks
to additional reserves is a sign that the economy has entered a “liquidity trap,” where total
spending in the economy (aggregate demand) is unresponsive to additional monetary stimulus.
This phenomenon could help explain why the unprecedented growth in the monetary base (the
portion of the money supply controlled by the Fed) since 2008 has not translated into higher
inflation to date.
Critics fear that it is simply a matter of time before quantitative easing leads to
high inflation, and
argue that these long-term risks outweigh any modest short-term benefits.43
of
QE.45 In particular, there is concern that the Fed’s “exit strategy” for returning to conventional
monetary policy is untested and may not prove successful.46
44
See H.3. Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, Aggregate Reserves of Depository Institutions and the Monetary Base
at http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h3/Current.
45
See, for example, “An Open Letter to Chairman Bernanke,” November 15, 2010, http://economics21.org/
commentary/e21s-open-letter-ben-bernanke.
46
The Fed’s exit strategy has been laid out in a number of speeches by Fed officials, such as testimony of Ben
Bernanke, “Federal Reserve’s Exit Strategy,” testimony before U.S. Congress, House Committee on Financial
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
14
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
By contrast, the Fed has argued that quantitative easing has successfully stimulated the economy,
mainly through lower long-term interest rates.44 Janet Yellen, vice chair of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, defended these policies in a recent speech. She argues47 Janet Yellen has defended these policies, arguing
that the evidence has shown that the financial securities purchases by the Federal Reserve have
proven effective in easing financial conditions and stimulating economic activity. With
. With unemployment remaining high and
expectations that inflation will be low over the medium run,
she argues that the accommodative
stance of the Fed regarding their monetary policy is appropriate.45
appropriate to achieve the Fed’s mandate and that the economic costs have thus far proven
small.48 Some critics have questioned
whether quantitative easing has been effective, given
economic growth remains sluggish.
Another concern is that by purchasing MBS, the Fed is allocating credit to the housing sector,
putting the rest of the economy at a disadvantage compared with that sector. Arguments in favor
of MBS purchases are that housing is the sector of the economy most in need of stabilization,
given the nature of the crisis (this argument becomes less persuasive as the housing market
continues to rebound); MBS markets are more liquid than most alternatives, limiting the
potential potential
for the Fed’s purchases to be disruptive; and that there are few other assets that the Fed
is legally permitted to purchase, besides Treasury securities.
42
See H.3. Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, Aggregate Reserves of Depository Institutions and the Monetary Base
at http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h3/Current.
43
See, for example, “An Open Letter to Chairman Bernanke,” November 15, 2010, http://economics21.org/
commentary/e21s-open-letter-ben-bernanke.
44
For a thorough discussion and defense of the Fed’s recent actions, see Chairman Ben Bernanke, “Monetary Policy
Since the Onset of the Crisis,” speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Symposium, August 31,
2012, available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20120831a.htm. See also Thomas
Bullard, Effective Monetary Policy in a Low Interest Rate Environment, The Henry Thornton Lecture, Cass Business
School, London, March 24, 2009.
45
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “2011 International Conference,” speech by Janet L. Yellen on
June 1, 2011, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20110601a.htm.
Congressional Research Service
14
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
permitted to purchase, besides Treasury securities.49
The Fed’s securities holdings earn interest that the Fed uses to fund its operations. (The Fed
receives no appropriations from Congress.) The Fed’s income exceeds its expenses, and it remits
most of its net income to the Treasury, which uses it to reduce the budget deficit. While the
increase in first lending and then mortgage-related securities increased the potential riskiness of
the Fed’s balance sheet, its ex-post effect was to more than double the Fed’s net income and
remittances to Treasury. Remittances to Treasury rose from $35 billion in 2007 to $79 billion in
2010, and were $89 billion in 2012.
Forward Commitment
Another tool that the Fed has used recently in an attempt to achieve additional monetary stimulus
at the zero bound is to announce that the Fed planspledge to keep the federal funds rate low for an
extended period of time,
which has been called “forward guidance” or “forward commitment.”
The Fed believes that this
will stimulate economic activity because businesses, for example, will be more likely to take on
long-term investment commitments if they are confident that rates will be low over the life of a
loan. Over time, this forward guidance has become more detailed and explicit. In September
2012, the
Fed extended its expected time frame for “exceptionally low levels for the federal funds
rate”
from late 2014 to mid-2015. In December 2012, the Fed replaced the date threshold with an
(...continued)
Services, February 10, 2010, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20100210a.htm.
47
For a thorough discussion and defense of the Fed’s recent actions, see Chairman Ben Bernanke, “Monetary Policy
Since the Onset of the Crisis,” speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Symposium, August 31,
2012, available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20120831a.htm. See also Thomas
Bullard, Effective Monetary Policy in a Low Interest Rate Environment, The Henry Thornton Lecture, Cass Business
School, London, March 24, 2009.
48
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Challenges Confronting Monetary Policy,” speech by Janet L.
Yellen on March 4, 2013, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20130302a.htm.
49
H.R. 1174/S. 238 would allow the Fed to purchase MBS only if two-thirds of the FOMC finds that there are unusual
and exigent circumstances and limits the Fed’s holdings of MBS to a maximum of five years.
Congressional Research Service
15
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
economic threshold: it pledged to maintain an “exceptionally low” federal funds target at least as
long as unemployment is above 6.5% and inflation is low.
It is difficult to pinpoint how effective the forward guidance tool has been, in part because it
depends on how credible the market finds the commitment. A problem with this approach is that
economic conditions may unexpectedly change (e.g., inflation isturns out to be higher than
expected), so this
commitment is likely only a contingent one.
Congressional Oversight and Disclosure
Critics of the Federal Reserve have long argued for more oversight, transparency, and
disclosure.4650 Criticism intensified following the extensive assistance provided by the Fed during
the financial crisis. More specifically, critics have focused on the Government Accountability
Office (GAO) audits of the Fed and the disclosure of details on the identities of borrowers and the
terms of those loans.
Some critics have downplayed the degree of Fed oversight and disclosure that already takes
place. For oversight, the Fed has been required by statute to report to and testify before the House
and Senate committees of jurisdiction semi-annually since 1978. At these hearings, which take
place in February and July, the Fed Chairmanchairman presents the Fed’s Monetary Policy Report to the
Congress, testifies, and responds to questions from committee members.4751 In addition, these
committees periodically hold more focused hearings on Fed topics. On January 25, 2012, the Fed
began publishing its forecasts for its federal funds rate target, and announced a longer-run goal of
2% for inflation. The Fed hopes that greater transparency about its intentions will strengthen
understanding of its actions by financial market participants, thereby making its actions more
effective.
46
For more information, see CRS Report R42079, Federal Reserve: Oversight and Disclosure Issues, by Marc
Labonte.
47
These hearings and reporting requirements were established by the Full Employment Act of 1978 (P.L. 95-523, 92
Stat 1897), also known as the Humphrey-Hawkins Act, and renewed in the American Homeownership and Economic
Opportunity Act of 2000 (P.L. 106-569).
Congressional Research Service
15
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Contrary to popular belief, GAO has conducted frequent Contrary to popular belief, GAO has conducted audits of the Fed since 1978, subject to
statutory statutory
restrictions. In addition, the Fed’s financial statements are audited by private-sector
auditors. The
Dodd-Frank Act (P.L. 111-203) resultedrequired in an audit of the Fed’s emergency
activities during the
financial crisis, released in July 2011, and an audit of Fed governance,
released in October 2011.
The effective result of the audit restrictions remaining in law is that
GAO cannot evaluate the
economic merits of Fed policy decisions. In the 112th Congress, the
House passed H.R. 459 on
July 25, 2012, which would removehave removed all statutory restrictions on GAO
audits. audits. Similar bills
in the 113th Congress include H.R. 24, H.R. 33, and S. 209.
For disclosure, the Fed has publicly released extensive information on its operations, mostly on a
voluntary basis. For example, it has long released a weekly summary of its balance sheet. The
expanded scope of its lending activities during the financial crisis eventually led it to release a
monthly report that offered more detailed information.
Historically, the Fed had never released
information on individual loans, such as the names of
borrowers or amounts borrowed, however.
In December 2010, as a result of the Dodd-Frank Act,
the Fed released individual lending records
for emergency facilities, revealing borrowers’
identities. Going forward, individual records for
discount window and open market operation transactions will be released with a two-year lag. In
addition, Freedom of Information Act lawsuits filed by Bloomberg and Fox News Network
resulted in the release of individual lending records for the discount window (the Fed’s traditional
50
For more information, see CRS Report R42079, Federal Reserve: Oversight and Disclosure Issues, by Marc
Labonte.
51
These hearings and reporting requirements were established by the Full Employment Act of 1978 (P.L. 95-523, 92
Stat 1897), also known as the Humphrey-Hawkins Act, and renewed in the American Homeownership and Economic
Opportunity Act of 2000 (P.L. 106-569).
Congressional Research Service
16
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
transactions will be released with a two-year lag. In addition, Freedom of Information Act
lawsuits filed by Bloomberg and Fox News Network resulted in the release of individual lending
records for the discount window (the Fed’s traditional lending facility for banks).
Although oversight and disclosure are often lumped together, they are separate issues and need
not go together. Oversight relies on independent evaluation of the Fed; disclosure is an issue of
what internal information the Fed releases to the public. Contrary to a common misperception, a
GAO audit would not, under current law, result in the release of any confidential information
identifying institutions that have borrowed from the Fed or the details of other transactions.
A potential consequence of greater oversight is that it could undermine the Fed’s political
independence, which is discussed in the next section. The challenge for Congress is to strike the
right balance between a desire for the Fed to be responsive to Congress and for the Fed’s
decisions to be somewhat immune from political calculations. A potential drawback to greater
disclosure is that publicizing the names of borrowers could potentially stigmatize them in a way
that causes runs on those borrowers or causes them to shun access to needed liquidity. Either
outcome could result in a less stable financial system. A potential benefit of publicizing borrowers
is to safeguard against favoritism or other conflicts of interest.
The Federal Reserve’s Dual Mandate and Proposals
for a Single Mandate of Price Stability
The Fed’s current statutory mandate calls for it to “promote effectively the goals of maximum
employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.”52 Although this mandate
includes three goals, it is often referred to by economists as a “dual mandate” of maximum
employment and stable prices. Some economists have argued that this mandate should be
replaced with a single mandate of price stability.
Often the proposal for a single mandate is paired with a more specific proposal that the Fed
should adopt an inflation target. Under an inflation target, the goal of monetary policy would be
to achieve an explicit, numerical target or range for some measure of price inflation. Inflation
targets could be required by Congress or voluntarily adopted by the Fed as a way to pursue price
stability, or a single mandate could be adopted without an inflation target. Alternatively, an
inflation target could be adopted under the current mandate. In January 2012, the Fed voluntarily
introduced a “longer-run goal for inflation” of 2%, which some might consider an inflation target.
In the 113th Congress, H.R. 1174/S. 238 and S. 215 would strike the goal of maximum
employment from the mandate, leaving a single goal of price stability, and require the Fed to
adopt an inflation target. Were a single mandate to be adopted in the United States, it would
follow an international trend that has seen many foreign central banks adopt single mandates or
inflation targets in recent decades.
Arguments made in favor of a price stability mandate are that it would better ensure that inflation
was low and stable; increase the predictability of monetary policy for financial markets; narrow
the potential to pursue monetary policies with short-term political benefits but long-term costs;
52
This mandate was added to statute by The Federal Reserve Act of 1977 (P.L. 95-188, 91 Stat. 1387).
Congressional Research Service
17
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
remove statutory goals that the Fed has no control over in the long run; limit policy discretion;
and increase transparency, oversight, accountability, and credibility.
Defenders of the current mandate argue that the Fed has already delivered low and stable inflation
for the past two decades, unemployment is a valid statutory goal since it is influenced by
monetary policy in the short run, and discretion is desirable to respond to unforeseen economic
shocks. A case could also be made that changing the mandate alone would not significantly alter
policymaking, because Fed discretion, transparency, oversight, and credibility are mostly
influenced by other factors, such as the Fed’s political independence.
Discontent with the Fed’s performance in recent years has led to calls for legislative change. It is
not clear that a single mandate would have altered its decision making, however. Criticizing the
Fed for the depth and length of the recession arguably leads to the prescription that monetary
policy should have been more stimulative, which points to greater weight on the employment part
of the dual mandate. Whether or not the Fed allowed the housing bubble to inflate, it is not clear
that a single mandate would have changed matters because the housing bubble did not result in
indisputably higher inflation. Some economists believe that the Fed’s recent policy of
“quantitative easing” (large-scale asset purchases) will result in high inflation. Inflation has not
increased to date, but even if these economists are correct, the Fed has discretion to pursue
policies it believes are consistent with its mandate. It has argued that quantitative easing was
necessary to maintain price stability by avoiding price deflation, and it could still make this
argument under a single mandate. Since the recent financial crisis, the problem has generally been
modestly lower-than-desired inflation.
For more information, see CRS Report R41656, Changing the Federal Reserve’s Mandate: An
Economic Analysis, by Marc Labonte.
Regulatory Responsibilities
The Fed is both a central bank and a regulator. Its main regulatory responsibilities are as follows:
•
Bank regulation. The Fed supervises bank holding companies (BHCs) and thrift
holding companies (THCs), which include all large and hundreds of small
depositories, for safety and soundness.53 The Dodd-Frank Act (P.L. 111-203)
requires the Fed to subject BHCs with more than $50 billion in consolidated
assets to enhanced supervision (i.e., stricter standards than similar firms are
subjected to) in an effort to mitigate the systemic risk they pose.54 The Fed is also
the prudential regulator of U.S. branches of foreign banks and state banks that
have elected to become members of the Federal Reserve System. Often in
concert with the other banking regulators,55 it promulgates rules and supervisory
53
The Fed was assigned regulatory responsibility for THCs as a result of the Dodd-Frank Act, which eliminated the
Office of Thrift Supervision.
54
For more information, see CRS Report R42150, Systemically Important or “Too Big to Fail” Financial Institutions,
by Marc Labonte.
55
The federal financial regulatory system is charter based. Other types of depositories are regulated by the OCC and
FDIC. A BHC is typically regulated by the Fed at the holding company level and the other banking regulators at the
bank subsidiary level. For more info, see CRS Report R43087, Who Regulates Whom and How? An Overview of U.S.
Financial Regulatory Policy for Banking and Securities Markets, by Edward V. Murphy.
Congressional Research Service
18
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
guidelines that apply to banks in areas such as capital adequacy, and it examines
depository firms under its supervision to ensure that those rules are being
followed and those firms are conducting business prudently.
•
Prudential supervision of non-bank systemically important financial
institutions. The Dodd-Frank Act allows the Financial Stability Oversight
Council (FSOC)56 to designate non-bank financial firms as systemically
important. Designated firms are supervised by the Fed for safety and soundness.
•
Regulation of the payment system. The Fed regulates the retail and wholesale
payment system for safety and soundness. It also operates parts of the payment
system, such as inter-bank settlements and check clearing. The Dodd-Frank Act
subjects payment, clearing, and settlement systems designated as systemically
important by the FSOC to enhanced supervision by the Fed (along with the SEC
and CFTC, depending on the type of system).
•
Margin requirements. The Fed sets margin requirements on the purchases of
certain securities, such as stocks, in certain private transactions. The purpose of
margin requirements are to mandate what proportion of the purchase can be made
on credit.
Through these regulatory responsibilities, as well as its lender of last resort activities and its
participation on the FSOC (whose mandate is to identify risks and respond to emerging threats to
financial stability), the Fed attempts to mitigate systemic risk and prevent financial instability.
Author Contact Information
Marc Labonte
Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
mlabonte@crs.loc.gov, 7-0640
Acknowledgments
This report was originally authored by Gail E. Makinen, formerly of the Congressional Research
Service.
56
The FSOC is an interagency council consisting of financial regulators and headed by the Treasury Secretary. For
more information, see CRS Report R42083, Financial Stability Oversight Council: A Framework to Mitigate Systemic
Risk, by Edward V. Murphy.
Congressional Research Service
19Mandate and
Its Independence
The Constitution grants Congress the power to “coin money, and regulate the value thereof.... ”
However, operational responsibility for making U.S. monetary policy has been delegated by
Congress to the Fed. Congress is still responsible for oversight, setting the Fed’s mandate, and
approving the President’s nominations for the Fed’s Board of Governors, but several institutional
features grant the Fed significant “independence” from the political process.48 The Federal
Reserve system is quasi-public in structure: its regional banks are owned by its member banks.
48
For more information, see CRS Report RL31056, Economics of Federal Reserve Independence, by Marc Labonte.
Congressional Research Service
16
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
The governors are appointed to staggered 14-year terms, and can only be removed by Congress
for cause. It is self-funded and its budget is not subject to the congressional appropriations
process. It has been granted broad discretion to interpret and carry out its congressional mandate
as it sees fit on a day-to-day basis.
Although the Fed’s statutory mandate might be expected to be a significant curb on its
independence, The Federal Reserve Act of 1977 (P.L. 95-188, 91 Stat. 1387) charged the Fed with
“the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.” Note
that the Fed controls none of these three indicators directly; it controls only overnight interest
rates through the use of open market operations, the discount window, and reserve requirements.
There will be times when the goals will be at odds with each other, and the Fed will have to
choose to pursue one at the expense of the other two. For example, an energy price shock would
be expected to raise prices and reduce employment. In this case, the current mandate could be
used to justify expansionary monetary policy in response to lower employment or contractionary
monetary policy in response to higher prices. Critics have argued that the ambiguity inherent in
the current mandate makes for less than optimal transparency and accountability. It may also
strengthen political independence if it allows the Fed to deflect congressional criticism by
pointing, at any given time, to whatever goal justifies its current policy stance.
The most popular alternative to the current mandate is to replace it with a single mandate of price
stability.49 This proposal is often coupled with a proposal for the Fed to be given a numerical
inflation target, and the Fed would then be required to set monetary policy with the goal of
meeting the target on an ongoing basis. Proponents of inflation targeting say that maximum
employment and moderate interest rates are not meaningful policy goals because monetary policy
has no long-term influence over either one. They argue a mandate that is focused on keeping
inflation low would deliver better economic results and improve transparency and oversight.
Opponents, including former Fed chairman Greenspan, say that the flexibility inherent in the
current system has served the United States well in the past 25 years, delivering both low
inflation and economic stability, and there is little reason to fix a system that is not broken. They
argue that some focus on employment is appropriate given that monetary policy has powerful
short-term effects on it, and that too great a focus on inflation could lead to an overly volatile
business cycle. Various forms of inflation targeting have been adopted abroad.50 Other economists
argue that a single mandate would do little to curb the Fed’s independence, and would therefore
have little practical effect on its decision making.
Without any statutory changes, the Fed has taken steps similar to some of the features of an
inflation targeting regime by publishing its longer-run goal for inflation (which it set at a 2%
increase in the personal consumption expenditures price index) and releasing its projections of
inflation and the federal funds rate target beginning in January 2012. Whether this amounts to de
facto inflation targeting will depend on how monetary policy will react to future deviations from
this longer-run goal.
Most economists argue that central bank independence leads to good monetary policy because it
reduces the temptation to raise inflation in the long run in order to lower unemployment in the
short run. Researchers have made cross-country comparisons to try to make the case that
49
See CRS Report R41656, Changing the Federal Reserve’s Mandate: An Economic Analysis, by Marc Labonte.
See CRS Report RL31702, Price Stability (Inflation Targeting) as the Sole Goal of Monetary Policy: The
International Experience, by Marc Labonte and Gail E. Makinen.
50
Congressional Research Service
17
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
countries with independent central banks are more likely to have low inflation rates and better
economic performance.51 As noted in the previous section, independence from Congress may
make oversight less effective, however.
Other policymakers express concern about the Fed’s independence from the private banks that are
members of the Federal Reserve System. National banks are required to, and state banks can
choose to, pay into the capital stock of the Fed to become members. The Fed regulates its
member banks for safety and soundness, and lends to them through the discount window.
Currently, six of the nine directors of the 12 Federal Reserve regional banks are chosen by the
member banks, and three of those six directors are from the banking industry. The regional bank
directors primarily play an advisory role, although the six directors that are not from the banking
industry choose the Fed’s regional bank presidents.52 Further, policy is set by the Board, not the
regional banks, with the exception of monetary policy, which is set by the Federal Open Market
Committee, composed of the seven governors, the President of the New York Fed, and four other
regional bank presidents on a rotating basis. Past proposals have sought to strengthen the powers
of the regional bank presidents at the expense of the Board of Governors, and vice versa. Other
proposals have sought to remove the member banks’ representatives from the boards of the
Federal Reserve regional banks.
Author Contact Information
Marc Labonte
Coordinator of Division Research and
Specialist
mlabonte@crs.loc.gov, 7-0640
Acknowledgments
This report was originally authored by Gail E. Makinen, formerly of the Congressional Research
Service.
51
For a review of the research and criticisms, see CRS Report RL31955, Central Bank Independence and Economic
Performance: What Does the Evidence Show?, by Marc Labonte and Gail E. Makinen.
52
The selection of regional bank presidents was altered by the Dodd-Frank Act (P.L. 111-203). Previously, all nine
directors of the regional banks selected the regional bank presidents.
Congressional Research Service
18