.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve:
Current Policy and Conditions
Marc Labonte
Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
March 31, 2010Joseph R. McCormack
Research Associate
June 15, 2011
Congressional Research Service
7-5700
www.crs.gov
RL30354
CRS Report for Congress
Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress
c11173008
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Summary
The Federal Reserve (Fed) defines monetary policy as the actions it undertakes to influence the
availability and cost of money and credit to help promote its congressionally mandated goals,
achieving a stable price level and maximum sustainable economic growth. Since the expectations
. Since the expectations of market participants play an
important role in determining prices and growth, monetary policy
can also be defined to include
the directives, policies, statements, and actions of the Fed that
influence how the future is
perceived. In addition, the Fed acts as a “lender of last resort” to the
nation’s financial system,
meaning that it ensures its sustainability, solvency, and integrity. This
continued smooth functioning of financial intermediation by providing
financial markets with adequate liquidity. This role has become of great importance with the following the
onset of the recent financial crisis in the summer of 2007.
Traditionally, the Fed has had three means for achieving its goals: open market operations
involving involving
the purchase and sale of U.S. Treasury securities, the discount rate charged to banks
who borrow
from the Fed, and reserve requirements that governed the proportion of deposits that
must be held either as vault cash or as a deposit at the Federal Reservevault cash or deposits with the Fed as a
proportion of deposits. Historically, open market
operations have been the primary means for
executing monetary policy. Recently, in response to
the financial crisis, direct lending has become
important once again and the Fed has created a
number of new ways for injecting reserves, credit,
and liquidity into the banking system, as well
as making loans to firms that are not banks. As
financial conditions normalize, the Fed is moving
back to a more traditional reliance on open market operations.
The Fed traditionally conducts open market operations by setting an interest rate target that it
believes will
allow it to achieve price stability and maximum sustainable growth. The employment. The
interest rate targeted is
the federal funds rate, the price at which banks buy and sell reserves on an
overnight basis. This
rate is linked to other short -term rates and these, in turn, influence longer termlongerterm interest rates.
Interest rates affect interest-sensitive spending –such as business capital
spending on plant and
equipment, household spending on consumer durables, and residential
investment.
In the short run Through this channel, monetary policy can be used to stimulate or slow aggregate spending. While
monetary policy is charged with promoting maximum sustainable economic growth, it does so
only indirectly
spending in the long run by maintaining a stable price level since the direct effect of
monetary policy is primarily on the rate ofshort run. In the long run, monetary policy mainly affects inflation. A low and
stable rate of inflation through the
business cycle promotes price transparency and, thereby, sounder economic decisions by
households and businesses.
The Fed has frequently changed the federal funds target to match changes in expected economic
conditions. Between January 3, 2001, andBeginning June 25, 2003, the target rate was reduced to 1% from
6½%. This policy was reversed on June 30, 2004, and in 17 equal 30, 2004, the target was raised from 1% to 5¼% in 17 equal
increments ending on June 29,
2006, the target rate was raised to 5¼%. No additional 2006. No further changes were made until September 18,
2007,
when, in a series of 10 moves, the target was reduced to a range of 0% to 1/4% on
December 16,
2008, where it now remains. Since then, the Fed has added liquidity to the financial
system system
beyond what is needed to meet its federal funds target through direct lending and, more
recently,
purchases of Treasury and government sponsored enterprise (GSE) securities. This
practice is
sometimes referred to as quantitative easing.
For more information on the Fed’s crisis-response actions, see CRS Report RL34427, Financial
Turmoil: Federal Reserve Policy Responses, by Marc Labonte. Legislative changes to the Fed’s
duties and authority related to financial regulatory reform can be found in CRS Report R40877,
Financial Regulatory Reform: Systemic Risk and the Federal Reserve, by Marc Labonte.
Congressional Research Service
, which has tripled the size of the Fed’s balance sheet
since financial turmoil began. A second round of quantitative easing began in November 2010.
Congress has delegated responsibility for monetary policy to the Fed, but retains oversight
responsibilities to ensure that the Fed is adhering to its statutory mandate “maximum
employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.” H.R. 245 would switch to a
single mandate of price stability. The Dodd-Frank Act enhanced the GAO’s ability to audit the
Fed, including the ability to review its lending programs. H.R. 459/H.R. 1496/S. 202 would
remove all remaining restrictions on GAO’s audit powers. H.R. 1512 would remove the regional
Fed bank presidents from the Federal Open Market Committee.
Congressional Research Service
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Contents
Introduction ................................................................................................................................1
How Does the Federal Reserve Execute Monetary Policy? ..........................................................2
The ImportanceEconomic Effects of Monetary Policy in the Short Run and Long Run ...................................5
Monetary vs. Fiscal Policy .........................................................4
Monetary vs. Fiscal Policy ...........................................6
The Recent and Current Stance of Monetary Policy.................................................................4
Short Run vs. Longer Run.....8
Before the Financial Crisis ....................................................................................................5
The Recent and Current Stance of Monetary Policy8
During and After the Financial Crisis ....................................................................................5
Congressional Oversight and The Near-Term Goals of Monetary Policy.....................................7
The Federal Reserve’s Mandate and Its Independence .................................................................8
Appendixes
Appendix A. Federal Reserve and the Discount Rate ................................................................. 10
Appendix B. Federal Reserve and the Monetary Aggregates ...................................................... 119
The Growth in the Balance Sheet and Bank Reserves .................................................... 11
Congressional Oversight and Disclosure.................................................................................... 12
Humphrey-Hawkins Hearings ............................................................................................. 12
GAO Audits ........................................................................................................................ 12
Disclosure of Lending Records............................................................................................ 13
The Federal Reserve’s Mandate and Its Independence ............................................................... 13
Contacts
Author Contact Information ...................................................................................................... 1115
Acknowledgments .................................................................................................................... 1215
Congressional Research Service
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Introduction
Congress has delegated responsibility for monetary policy to the Federal Reserve, but retains
oversight responsibilities to ensure that the Fed is adhering to its statutory mandate of “maximum
employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.”1 The Federal Reserve’s (Fed’s)
The Federal Reserve’s (Fed’s) responsibilities as the nation’s central bank fall into four main
categories: monetary policy,
ensuring financial stability through the lender of last resort function,
supervision of bank holding
companies, and providing payment system services to financial firms
and the government. This
report will discuss the first two areas of responsibility. 2
The Fed defines monetary policy as the actions it undertakes to influence the availability and cost
of money and credit to promote the goals mandated by Congress: a stable price level and
maximum sustainable economic growth. Since the expectations of
households as consumers and
businesses as the purchasers of capital goods exert an important
influence on the major portion of
spending in the United States, and these expectations are
influenced in important ways by the
actions of the Fed, a broader definition of monetary policy
would include the directives, policies,
statements, forecasts of the economy, and other actions by
the Fed, especially those made by or
associated with the chairman of its Board of Governors, the
nation’s central banker. 13
In addition, governments have traditionally assigned to a central bank the role of “lender of last
resort” to the nation’s financial system. This role means that the Federal Reserve is responsible
for ensuring the sustainability, solvency, and continued functioning of the nation’s financial
system as a whole, although this does not necessarily extend to any individual financial
institution. Thus, in times of financial stress or crisis, the Fed is responsible for ensuring that
financial intermediation does not come to a halt. Historically, Federal Reserve intervention has
been limited to the banking system. Indeed, the impetus for the founding of the Fed was an
outgrowth of the financial panic of 1907. During its nearly 100 -year history, the Federal Reserve
has rarely been called upon to perform this role. It is now widely regarded as having failed to
perform it during the collapse of the U.S. banking system in the contraction of 1929-1933.
However, the financial crisis that began in the summer of 2007 with the bursting of the “housing
price bubble,” has placed this role front and center. The Fed has responded in the conventional
way by making massive additions of reserves available to depository institutions (primarily
commercial banks) through the purchase of U.S. Treasury securities and allowing banks to
discount large amounts of eligible paperthrough lending
facilities. In addition, it has created a number of additional ways
to make credit available to a
broader range of financial institutions as well as making loans
directly to non-financial firmsbank financial
intermediaries. These innovations are still evolvingwere unprecedented and several arewere authorized
only in “unusual and exigent circumstances.”2
Thus, the Federal Reserve has a monetary policy function and a financial stability function. Its
monetary policy function is one of aggregate demand management. The availability and cost of
credit are used to manage aggregate demand in such a way as to promote a stable price level and
1
“unusual and exigent circumstances.”4
1
Section 2A of the Federal Reserve Act, 12 USC 225a.
For background on the make up of the Federal Reserve, see CRS Report RS20826, Structure and Functions of the
Federal Reserve System, by Marc Labonte.
2
3
For a discussion of the important role played by expectations in formulation and execution of monetary policy, see
Santomero, Anthony M. “Great Expectations: The Role of Beliefs in Economics and Monetary Policy.” Business
Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Second Quarter 2004, pp. 1-6, and Sellon, Gordon H., Jr., “Expectations
and the Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism”,,” Economic Review., Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Fourth
Quarter 2004, pp. 4-42.
24
For a discussion of the current2007-2009 financial crisis, its origins, and the innovations by the Federal Reserve, see CRS Report
RL34730, Troubled Asset Relief Program: Legislation and Treasury Implementation, by Baird Webel and Edward V.
Murphyand CRS
Report RL34427, Financial Turmoil: Federal Reserve Policy Responses, by Marc Labonte. For
historical perspective
on Federal Reserve’s dealing in non-government debt, see Wheelock, David C. “Conducting
Monetary Policy Without Government Debt: The Fed’s Early Years. Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
May/June 2002, pp. 1-14.
Congressional Research Service
1
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
through it maximum sustainable growth. Its second function is as “lender of last resort” to the
nation’s financial system.
This report will examine the traditional execution of monetary policy. The “lender of last resort”
role since 2007 is examined in CRS Report RL34427, Financial Turmoil: Federal Reserve Policy
Responses, by Marc Labonte. Legislative changes to the Fed’s duties and authority related to
financial regulatory reform can be found in CRS Report R40877, Financial Regulatory Reform:
Systemic Risk and the Federal Reserve, by Marc Labonte.
How Does the Federal Reserve Execute Monetary
Policy?
The Federal Reserve has traditionally relied on three means to conduct monetary policy and they
are used to alter the reserves available to depository institutions. These institutions are required to
maintain reserves in the form of vault cash (currency) or as a deposit at the Fed against their
deposit liabilities, primarily checking, saving, and time (CDs). The size of these reserves places a
ceiling on the amount of deposits that financial institutions can have outstanding and deposit
liabilities are related to the amount of assets these institutions can acquire. These assets are often
called “credit” since they represent loans made to businesses and households, among others.
If the Federal Reserve wishes to expand money and credit, it has three ways to do so. The primary
method is called open market operations and it involves the Fed buying and selling existing U.S.
Treasury securities (or those that have been already issued and sold to private investors). Should
it buy securities, it does so with the equivalent of newly issued currency (Federal Reserve notes).
This expands the reserve base and the ability of depository institutions to make loans and expand
money and credit. The reverse is true if the Fed decides to sell securities from its portfolio. The
Fed can also change reserve requirements, meaning that a given amount of reserves will now
support more or less deposits and, in the process, this will affect the lending capability of
financial institutions. (This tool is rarely used today.) Finally, the Fed permits certain depository
institutions to borrow from it directly on a temporary basis. That is, these institutions can
“discount” at the Fed some of their own assets to provide a temporary means for obtaining
reserves. Discounts are usually on an overnight basis. For this privilege they are charged an
interest rate called, appropriately, the discount rate. Direct lending, from the discount window and
other recently created lending facilities, was negligible until late 2007, but has been an important
source of reserves since then.3 Monetary Policy Without
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
1
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Thus, the Federal Reserve has a monetary policy function and a financial stability function. Its
monetary policy function is one of aggregate demand management. The availability and cost of
credit are used to manage aggregate demand in such a way as to promote a stable price level and
through it maximum sustainable employment. Its financial stability function is as “lender of last
resort” to the nation’s financial system.
The financial crisis and the Fed’s unprecedented response to it has garnered renewed attention
from Congress. On the one hand, the Fed was given new regulatory requirements in The DoddFrank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (P.L. 111-203) in an attempt to prevent
future crises. On the other hand, some Representatives have pressed for enhanced oversight of the
Fed, while others have called for narrowing the scope of its statutory mandate. The Dodd-Frank
Act allowed GAO to audit the Fed’s monetary and lending activities for the first time, and the
Federal Reserve Transparency Act of 2011 (H.R. 459/H.R. 1496/S. 202) would remove remaining
restrictions on GAO’s audit authority. H.R. 245 would change the Fed’s statutory mandate to a
single mandate of price stability.
This report provides an overview of monetary policy and issues for Congress. Legislative changes
to the Fed’s duties and authority related to financial regulatory reform can be found in CRS
Report R40877, Financial Regulatory Reform: Systemic Risk and the Federal Reserve, by Marc
Labonte. Lending facilities created by the Federal Reserve and other government agencies during
the financial crisis are discussed in CRS Report R41073, Government Interventions in Response
to Financial Turmoil, by Baird Webel and Marc Labonte.
How Does the Federal Reserve Execute Monetary
Policy?
The Federal Reserve has traditionally relied on three instruments to conduct monetary policy.
Each works by altering the reserves available to depository institutions. These institutions are
required to maintain reserves against their deposit liabilities, primarily checking, saving, and time
(CDs). These reserves can be held in the form of vault cash (currency) or as a deposit at the Fed.
The size of these reserves places a ceiling on the amount of deposits that financial institutions can
have outstanding and deposit liabilities are related to the amount of assets these institutions can
acquire. These assets are often called “credit” since they represent loans made to businesses and
households, among others.
The Federal Reserve has three ways to expand or contract money and credit. The primary method
is called open market operations and it involves the Fed buying existing U.S. Treasury securities
(or those that have been already issued and sold to private investors). Should it buy securities, it
does so with the equivalent of newly issued currency (Federal Reserve notes). This expands the
reserve base and the ability of depository institutions to make loans and expand money and credit.
The reverse is true if the Fed decides to sell securities from its portfolio.
The Fed can also change reserve requirements, controlling a portion of deposits that banks must
hold as vault cash or in deposit at the Fed, which affects the available liquidity within the market.
(...continued)
Government Debt: The Fed’s Early Years. Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. May/June 2002, pp. 1-14.
Congressional Research Service
2
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Currently, banks with $58.8 million or more in liabilities are required to hold 10.3% of their
liabilities in reserves. This tool is used rarely—the percentage was last changed in 1998.5 To
increase control over reserve growth, the Federal Reserve began to pay interest on required and
excess reserves in October 2008, reducing the opportunity cost of holding that money as opposed
to lending it out.
Finally, the Fed permits certain depository institutions to borrow from it directly on a temporary
basis. That is, these institutions can “discount” at the Fed some of their own assets to provide a
temporary means for obtaining reserves. Discounts are usually on an overnight basis. For this
privilege they are charged an interest rate called, appropriately, the discount rate. The discount
rate is set by the Fed at a markup over the federal funds rate.6 Direct lending, from the discount
window and other recently created lending facilities, was negligible until late 2007, but has been
an important source of reserves since then.
Because the Fed defines monetary policy as the actions it undertakes to influence the availability
and cost of money and credit, this suggests two ways to measure the stance of monetary policy.
One is to look at the cost of money and credit as measured by the rate of interest relative to
inflation (or inflation projections), while the other is to look at the growth of money and credit
itself. Thus, one can look at either interest rates or the growth in the supply of money and credit
in coming to a conclusion about the current stance of monetary policy, that is, whether it is
expansionary, contractionary, or neutral.
3
For a more complete discussion of the role of the discount rate in Federal Reserve policy, see Appendix A.
Congressional Research Service
2
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Since the great inflation of the 1970s, most central banks have preferred to formulate monetary
policy more in terms of the cost of money and credit rather than on their supply. 4 The Federal
Reserve thus conducts monetary policy by focusing on the cost of money and credit as proxied by
an interest rate. In particular, it targets a very short -term interest rate known as the federal funds
rate. This rate is determined in the overnight market for reserves of depository institutions. At the
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) meets every six weeks to choose a federal
funds target and sometimes meets on an ad hoc basis if it wishes to change the target between
regularly scheduled meetings. The FOMC is comprised of the 7 Fed governors, the President of
the New York Fed, and 4 of the other 11 regional Fed bank presidents selected on a rotating
basis.7
The federal funds rate is determined in the private market for overnight reserves of depository
institutions. At the end of a given period, usually a day, depository institutions must calculate how
many dollars of
reserves they want to hold against their reservable liabilities (deposits).58 Some
institutions may
discover a reserve shortage (too few reservable assets relative to those it wants to hold) while
others may have had reservable assets in excess of their wants. A market exists in which these
reserves can be bought and sold on an overnight basis. The interest rate in this market is called
the federal funds rate. It is this rate that the Fed uses as a target for conducting monetary policy. If
it wishes to expand money and credit, it will lower the target which encourages more lending
activity and, thus, demand in the economy. To support this lower target, the Fed must stand ready
to buy more U.S. Treasury securities. Conversely, if it wishes to tighten money and credit, it will
raise the target and remove as many reserves from depository institutions as are necessary to
accomplish its ends. This will require the sale of treasuries from its portfolio of assets.6
The federal funds rate is linked to the interest rates that banks and other financial institutions
charge for loans – or the provision of credit. Thus, while the Fed may directly influence only a
very short term interest rate, this rate influences other longer term rates. However, this
relationship is far from being on a one-to-one basis since the longer
5
The deposit threshold is regularly adjusted for inflation. The Dodd-Frank Act encouraged regulators to implement
heightened liquidity standards, particularly for Systemically Important Financial Institutions (SIFIs), that may affect
reserve requirements once fully implemented. The status of SIFI regulation was discussed in a speech by Federal
Reserve Governor Daniel Tarullo on June 3, 2011. The speech can be seen at http://www.federalreserve.gov/
newsevents/speech/tarullo20110603a.htm.
6
Until 2003, the discount rate was set slightly below the federal funds target, and the Fed used moral suasion to
discourage healthy banks from profiting from this low rate. To reduce the need for moral suasion, lending rules were
altered in early 2003. Since that time, the discount rate has been set at a penalty rate above the federal funds rate target.
However, during the financial crisis, the Fed encouraged banks to use the discount window.
7
H.R. 1512 would remove the regional Fed bank presidents from the Federal Open Market Committee.
8
Depository institutions are obligated by law to hold some fraction of their deposit liabilities as reserves. In addition,
they are also likely to hold additional or excess reserves based on certain risk assessments they make about their
portfolios and liabilities. Until very recently these reserves were non-income earning assets. The Fed now pays interest
on both types of reserves. It is too early to assess how this shift in policy will affect bank reserve holdings.
Congressional Research Service
3
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
hold) while others may have had reservable assets in excess of their wants. A market exists in
which these reserves can be bought and sold on an overnight basis. The interest rate in this market
is called the federal funds rate. It is this rate that the Fed uses as a target for conducting monetary
policy. If it wishes to expand money and credit, it will lower the target which encourages more
lending activity and, thus, demand in the economy. To support this lower target, the Fed must
stand ready to buy more U.S. Treasury securities. Conversely, if it wishes to tighten money and
credit, it will raise the target and remove as many reserves from depository institutions as are
necessary to accomplish its ends. This will require the sale of treasuries from its portfolio of
assets.9
The federal funds rate is linked to the interest rates that banks and other financial institutions
charge for loans—or the provision of credit. Thus, while the Fed may directly influence only a
very short-term interest rate, this rate influences other longer-term rates. However, this
relationship is far from being on a one-to-one basis since the longer-term market rates are
influenced not only by what the Fed is doing today, but what it is expected to do in the future and
what inflation is expected to be in the future. This highlights the importance of expectations in
explaining market interest rates. For that reason, there is a growing body of literature that urges
the Federal Reserve to be very transparent in explaining what its policy is and will be and making
a commitment to adhere to that policy. In fact, the Fed has responded to this literature and is
increasingly transparent in explaining its policiespolicy measures and what theythese are expected to
accomplish.
Using market interest rates as an indicator of monetary policy is fraught with danger, however.
The interest rate that is essential to decisions made by households and businesses to buy capital
goods is what economists call the “real” interest rate. It is often proxied by subtracting from the
market interest rate the actual or expected rate of inflation. The real rate is largely independent of
the amount of money and credit since over the longer run, it is determined by the interaction of
saving and investment (or the demand for capital goods). The internationalization of capital
markets means that for most developed countries the relevant saving and investment that
determines the real interest rate is on a global basis. Thus, real rates in the United States depend
not only on our national saving and investment, but on the saving and investment of other
countries as well. For that reason national interest rates will be influenced by international credit
conditions and business cycles.
4
For a discussion of why the Federal Reserve does not conduct monetary policy by targeting the monetary aggregates,
see Appendix B.
5
Depository institutions are obligated by law to hold some fraction of their deposit liabilities as reserves. In addition,
they are also likely to hold additional or excess reserves based on certain risk assessments they make about their
portfolios and liabilities. Until very recently these reserves were non-income earning assets. The Fed now pays interest
on both types of reserves. It is too early to assess how this shift in policy will affect bank reserve holdings.
6
For a technical discussion of how this is actually done, see Edwards, Cheryl L., “Open Market Operations in the
1990s,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, November 1997, pp. 859-872.
Congressional Research Service
3
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
The Importance of Monetary Policy
It has been said the “money matters” and the case for this statement can be made in at least two
different contexts. In one, monetary policy is compared with fiscal policy and, given the current
international financial system with flexible exchange rates and a high degree of capital mobility
between countries, the ability of changes in monetary policy to affect aggregate demand is great
compared with fiscal policy. In the other context, changes in monetary policy have the potential
to bring about major changes in the growth of GDP and employment only in the short run. Most
economists do not believe that this holds true over the longer run. Over the more extended
horizon, monetary policy has its primary effect on the rate of inflation. A brief discussion of the
two contexts summarized above follows.
Monetary vs. Fiscal Policy
The standard open economy macroeconomic model makes a compelling case for the relative
importance of monetary policy in a world whose financial arrangements involve the use of
flexible exchange rates and where capital is highly mobile between countries. To see this, fiscal
and monetary expansion will be contrasted.
Allow the full employment budget deficit to rise (or the full-employment surplus to fall) through
either a tax rate cut or a rise in appropriated expenditures. While the increase in this budget deficit
(or fall in surplus) raises aggregate demand, it also reduces national saving. The fall in the supply
of saving relative to domestic investment demand causes domestic interest rates (both real and
market) to rise relative to those in other financial centers. The rise in domestic interest rates
makes U.S. financial assets more attractive to foreigners. They, in turn, increase the demand for
dollars in foreign exchange markets to acquire the wherewithal to purchase U.S. assets. The
increased demand for dollars causes the dollar to appreciate. Dollar appreciation then reduces the
cost of foreign goods and services to Americans and raises the price of American goods and
services to foreigners. As a result, U.S. spending on imports tends to rise and foreign spending on
U.S. exports tends to fall. Thus, any expansionary effects on domestic demand from the larger
budget deficit tends to be offset in part or total by a reduced foreign trade surplus or a larger
foreign trade deficit.7
Monetary policy stimulus (as shown by a reduction in the target rate for federal funds) initially
serves to lower U.S. interest rates (both real and market) relative to those in other financial
centers. Foreign financial assets become more attractive to U.S. investors, the supply of dollars on
the foreign exchange markets rises as U.S. investors attempt to acquire foreign currencies to buy
foreign assets, and the dollar depreciates. Dollar depreciation then makes foreign goods and
services more expensive to Americans and American goods and services cheaper to foreigners. As
a result, the United States spends less on imports and foreigners spend more on U.S. exports. A
falling foreign trade deficit or rising trade surplus thus reinforces any stimulus to domestic
demand that comes from lower U.S. interest rates.
7
It is important to note that this explanation requires the full employment or structural budget deficit to rise. Budget
deficits produced by a fall in income, or cyclical deficits need not produce these results.
Congressional Research Service
4
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
The implication from the standard open economy macroeconomic model is that monetary policy
is more powerful than fiscal policy in influencing GDP growth and employment given current
international financial arrangements.8
Short Run vs. Longer Run
The analysis above suggests that a more expansive monetary policy can cause domestic demand
to expand. An examination of U.S. economic history will show that money and credit induced
demand expansions can have a positive effect on U.S. GDP growth and total employment. This
same history, however, also suggests that over the longer run, a more rapid rate of growth of
money and credit is largely dissipated in a more rapid rate of inflation with little if any lasting
effect on real GDP and employment.
Economists have two explanations for this paradoxical behavior. First, they note that, in the short
run, many economies have an elaborate system of contracts (both implicit and explicit) that
makes it difficult in a short period for significant adjustments to take place in wages and prices in
response to a more rapid growth of money and credit. Second, they note that expectations for one
reason or another are slow to adjust to the longer run consequences of major changes in monetary
policy. This slow adjustment also adds rigidities to wages and prices. Because of these rigidities,
changes in the growth of money and credit that change aggregate demand can have a large initial
effect on output and employment. Over the longer run, as contracts are renegotiated and
expectations adjust, wages and prices rise in response to the change in demand and much of the
change in output and employment is undone. Thus, monetary policy can matter in the short run
but be fairly neutral for GDP growth and employment in the longer run.9
It is noteworthy that in societies where high rates of inflation are endemic, the short run may be
very short indeed. During the final stages of very rapid inflations, called hyperinflation, the
ability of more rapid rates of growth of money and credit to alter GDP growth and employment is
virtually nonexistent, if not negative.
The Recent and Current Stance of Monetary Policy
Following the 2001 recession, unemployment continued rising until mid-2003. Fearful that the
economy would slip back into recession, the Fed kept the federal funds rate extremely low. 10 The
federal funds target reached a low of 1% by mid-2003. As the expansion gathered momentum and
prices began to rise, the federal funds target was slowly increased in a series of moves to 5¼% in
mid-2006. Short-term interest rates followed and by the end of 2006, the yield curve (the
8
It might be thought that this highly stylized account of monetary and fiscal policy is irrelevant to a world whose
financial institutions and practices are undergoing rapid change. For a contrary view, see Sellon, Gordon H., Jr., “The
Changing U.S. Financial System: Some Implications for the Monetary Transmission Mechanism,” Economic Review,
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, First Quarter 2002, pp. 5-36.
9
Two interesting papers bearing on what monetary policy can accomplish by two former officials of the Federal
Reserve are Santomero, Anthony M. “What Monetary Policy Can and Cannot Do”, Business Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, First Quarter 2002, pp. 1-4, and Mishkin, Frederic S. “What Should Central Banks Do?, Review,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, November/December 2000, pp. 1-14.
10
Historical and current targets for the federal funds rate can be found at http://www.federalreserve.gov/fomc/
fundsrate.htm.
Congressional Research Service
5
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
relationship between short- and long-term interest rates) became inverted, with shorter term rates
higher than longer term rates. 11
It is now argued by many economists that the financial crisis was, at least in part, due to Federal
Reserve policy to ensure that the then-ongoing expansion continued. In particular, critics now
claim that the low short-term rates prevailing from 2001 through 2004 caused an increased
demand for housing leading to a “price bubble.” The shift in financing housing from fixed to
variable rate mortgages made this sector of the economy increasingly vulnerable to movements in
short-term interest rates. One consequence of the tightening of monetary policy, critics now
claim, was to burst this “price bubble” (a bubble that was also due, in part, to lax lending
standards that were subject to regulation by the Fed and others). The net result was the onset of a
financial crisis affecting not only depository institutions, but other segments of the financial
sector involved with housing finance as the delinquency rates on home mortgages rose to record
numbers and the subsequent losses of financial institutions made national headlines. The
contagious nature of this development was soon obvious as other types of loans and credit
became adversely affected. This, in turn, spilled over into the broader economy as the lack of
credit soon had a negative effect on both production and aggregate demand. In December 2007,
the economy entered a recession.
As the magnitude of the financial crisis, as well as its international scope, became apparent, the
Fed responded to the expected economic slump by reducing the federal funds target and the
discount rate. Beginning on September 18, 2007, and ending on December 16, 2008, the target
was reduced from 5¼% to a range between 0% and ¼%.
What began to concern the monetary authorities is that liquidity provided to the banking system
was not reaching other parts of the financial system. It would appear that the traditional
transmission mechanism for monetary policy is not working. To circumvent this problem, the Fed
began to employ a little used emergency provision, Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act, 12
that allows it to make loans to other financial institutions and to non-financial firms as well.
The magnitude of direct lending has been large. Total borrowing from the Federal Reserve during
November 2007 was $366 million. In mid-November 2008, it reached a high of $725 billion.
Direct lending did not fall below $100 billion until March 2009. The worsening of the crisis in
September 2008 was accompanied by an unprecedented increase in the reserves of depository
institutions. They increased from about $44.6 billion in August 2008 to $167 billion at the end of
2008 to $1,139 billion at the end of 2009. This is clearly not a “business as usual” monetary
policy, but something quite extraordinary, sometimes referred to as “quantitative easing.”
11
Yield curve inversions pose potentially difficult problems for depository institutions since they squeeze their
profitability and possibly undermine their capital structure. The reason for this is that depository institutions generally
lend long and borrow short. Thus, their borrowing (their ability to attract and retain deposits which are the source of
their funds) costs are very sensitive to movements in short term interest rates. Since they lend long, only a fraction of
their assets, their new loans, are affected by movements in longer term rates. Thus, when short term rates rise relative to
long term rates, depository institutions find their costs rising sharply as they struggle to retain and attract deposits,
while the gross earnings from their assets rise only slowly – the classic case of a profit squeeze. In fact, if losses ensue,
they undermine the capital base of these institutions setting in motion the possibility of failure. In any case, an inverted
yield curve generally has negative effects on credit creation and is often a leading indicator of an impending economic
downturn (see CRS Report RS22371, The Pattern of Interest Rates: Does It Signal an Impending Recession?, by Marc
Labonte and Gail E. Makinen.
12
12 U.S.C. 343.
Congressional Research Service
6
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Quantitative easing can be defined as increasing the reserves of the banking system beyond the
amount needed to meet the Fed’s interest rate target.
With direct lending falling as financial conditions normalize, the Fed found other tools to
maintain the current level of liquidity in the financial system. On March 17, 2009, the FOMC
announced plans for a massive purchase of agency and Treasury securities in excess of $1.0
trillion to further ease credit market conditions and stimulate spending. (Agency securities are
here defined as securities of Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and Ginnie Mae.) These purchases were
completed by the end of March 2010. Once the economy returns to normal, the task facing the
Fed will be to remove this huge amount of credit from the financial system quickly enough to
prevent inflation from taking hold.
It should not go unnoticed that a potential complication for the conduct of monetary policy
emerges when the federal funds rate is at or near zero, its floor, as it is now. A zero federal funds
rate does not constrain the Federal Reserve from supplying additional reserves and liquidity to the
financial system, as the Fed is now doing through purchases of Treasury and agency securities.
Whether the additional reserves will be lent out, resulting in lower market interest rates and an
expansion of new spending, as posited in the text book explanation of how monetary policy
works, is another story. Recent experience is not reassuring, as excess bank reserves held at the
Fed have remained unusually high. 13
Congressional Oversight and The Near-Term
Goals of Monetary Policy
Congress has delegated monetary policy decisions to the Fed but retains oversight
responsibilities. The primary form of congressional oversight of the Federal Reserve is the semiannual hearings with the Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs and the
House Committee on Financial Services. At these hearings, which take place in February and
July, the Fed Chairman presents the Fed’s Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, testifies, and
responds to questions from committee members. These hearings and reporting requirements were
established by the Full Employment Act of 1978 (P.L. 95-523, 92 Stat 1897), also known as the
Humphrey-Hawkins Act, and renewed in the American Homeownership and Economic
Opportunity Act of 2000 (P.L. 106-569).
The semiannual Monetary Policy Report presents a review of recent economic and monetary
policy developments, as well as economic projections for three years. Since monetary policy
plays an important role in determining economic outcomes, these projections can be viewed as
the Fed’s perceptions of how today’s monetary policy stance will influence future economic
conditions. To increase the transparency of monetary policy, the Fed in 2007 began to publicly
provide additional forecasts. They now appear quarterly.
13
For a recent discussion of this issue by the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, see Bullard, Thomas.
Effective Monetary Policy in a Low Interest Rate Environment, The Henry Thornton Lecture, Cass Business School,
London (March 24, 2009).
Congressional Research Service
7
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
The Federal Reserve’s Mandate and Its
Independence
The Constitution grants Congress the power to “coin money, and regulate the value thereof.... ”
However, operational responsibility for making U.S. monetary policy has been delegated by
Congress to the Fed. Congress is still responsible for oversight, setting the Fed’s mandate and
approving the President’s nominations for the Fed’s Board of Governors, but several institutional
features grant it significant “independence” from the political process. 14 The Federal Reserve
system is quasi-public in structure: it is owned by its member banks. The governors are appointed
to staggered 14-year terms, and can only be removed by Congress for cause. It is self-funded and
does not receive appropriations. While it must follow its congressional mandate, it has been
granted broad discretion to interpret and carry out that mandate as it sees fit on a day-to-day
basis. Most economists argue that good monetary policy depends on independence because it
reduces the temptation to raise inflation in the long run in order to lower unemployment in the
short run. Researchers have made cross-country comparisons to try to make the case that
countries with independent central banks are more likely to have low inflation rates and better
economic performance. 15
As a practical matter, the Fed’s mandate can be seen as a further source of political independence
by giving it broad policy discretion. The Federal Reserve Act of 1977 (P.L. 95-188, 91 Stat. 1387)
charged the Fed with “the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term
interest rates.” Note that the Fed controls none of these three indicators directly; it controls only
overnight interest rates. Because it has only one instrument at its disposal and three goals, there
will be times when the goals will be at odds with each other, and the Fed will have to choose to
pursue one at the expense of the other two. Critics have argued that the ambiguity inherent in the
current mandate makes for less than optimal transparency and accountability. It may also
strengthen political independence if it allows the Fed to deflect congressional criticism by
pointing, at any given time, to whatever goal justifies its current policy stance.
The most popular alternative to the current mandate is to replace it with a single mandate of price
stability. Under this proposal, the Fed would typically be given (or, under the version mooted by
Chairman Bernanke, give itself) a numerical inflation target, and would then be required to set
monetary policy with the goal of meeting the target on an ongoing basis.16 Proponents of inflation
targeting say that maximum employment and moderate interest rates are not meaningful policy
goals because monetary policy has no long-term influence over either one. They argue a mandate
that is focused on keeping inflation low would deliver better economic results and improve
transparency and oversight.17 Opponents, including former Chairman Greenspan, say that the
14
For more information, see CRS Report RL31056, Economics of Federal Reserve Independence, by Marc Labonte.
15
For a review of the research and criticisms, see CRS Report RL31955, Central Bank Independence and Economic
Performance: What Does the Evidence Show?, by Marc Labonte and Gail E. Makinen.
16
See CRS Report 98-16, Should the Federal Reserve Adopt an Inflation Target?, by Marc Labonte.
17
In a recent speech, Fed Vice Chairman Donald Kohn reports that the Fed Governors and Reserve Bank presidents
continue “to discuss whether an explicit numerical objective for inflation would be beneficial. Under current
circumstances, those benefits would include underscoring our understanding that our legislative mandate for promoting
price stability encompasses both preventing inflation from falling too low in the near term and from rising too far as the
economy recovers.” See Monetary Policy in the Financial Crisis, a Conference in Honor of Dewey Daane, Nashville,
Tennessee, April 18, 2009.
Congressional Research Service
8
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
flexibility inherent in the current system has served the United States well in the past 25 years,
delivering both low inflation and economic stability, and there is little reason to fix a system that
is not broken. They argue that some focus on employment is appropriate given that monetary
policy has powerful short-term effects on it, and that too great a focus on inflation could lead to
an overly volatile business cycle. Various forms of inflation targeting have been adopted abroad.18
Another policy proposal that has gained prominence during the financial crisis is a removal of the
statutory restrictions on Government Accountability Office (GAO) audits of the Fed. Currently,
GAO cannot audit Fed actions related to monetary policy, including emergency lending
activities. 19 Various proposals have been put forth to remove all audit restrictions or audit
restrictions related to emergency lending. Another goal of some has been to require the Fed to
disclose the identities of borrowers, which are currently kept confidential. Proponents of these
proposals cite the need for more information to aid Congress in its oversight duties, while
opponents predict that audits would have a negative effect on Fed independence and disclosing
borrowers could cause runs on those institutions. 20
18
See CRS Report RL31702, Price Stability (Inflation Targeting) as the Sole Goal of Monetary Policy: The
International Experience, by Marc Labonte and Gail E. Makinen.
19
Currently, GAO can (and does) audit the Fed’s regulatory and payment system duties. S. 896, which was signed into
law on May 20, 2009 (P.L. 111-22), allows GAO audits of “any action taken by the Board under ... Section 13(3) of the
Federal Reserve Act with respect to a single and specific partnership or corporation.” This would allow GAO audits of
the Maiden Lane facilities and the asset guarantees of Citigroup and Bank of America, but would maintain audit
restrictions on non-emergency activities and broadly accessed emergency lending facilities.
20
The current legislative status of these proposals can be found in CRS Report R40877, Financial Regulatory Reform:
Systemic Risk and the Federal Reserve, by Marc Labonte.
Congressional Research Service
9
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Appendix A. Federal Reserve and the Discount Rate
The Federal Reserve has preferred to conduct monetary policy primarily through its target for the
federal funds rate. This method has allowed the Federal Reserve to adopt an activist stance in the
conduct of monetary policy. The Board of Governors controls another interest rate, the discount
rate. Financial institutions can borrow on a temporary basis directly from the Fed at this rate
through the Fed’s discount window. The Board can either grant or deny the loan. The initiation of
the loan, however, is at the discretion of the borrowing financial institution. In this sense, the Fed
is passive in the process. Although the discount rate has long been a tool of central banking, the
discount window has not been used much in the United States over the past several decades until
market turmoil in 2008 gave it a more prominent role. Financial institutions prefer to borrow
overnight in the federal funds market because they can obtain what they need without having to
subject their borrowing needs to the purview of the Fed.21 In conducting monetary policy, the
Board has moved the discount rate in sympathy with the federal funds target.
Until 2003, the discount rate was set slightly below the federal funds target, and the Fed used
moral suasion to discourage healthy banks from profiting from this low rate. To reduce the need
for moral suasion, lending rules were altered in early 2003. Since that time, the discount rate has
been set above the federal funds rate target and is now a penalty rate. However, following the
financial crisis, the Fed has not discouraged banks in their use of the discount window.
21
A certain stigma was once attached to using the discount window to obtain reserves. Since banks “borrow” from their
depositors to acquire assets, it was thought to be a sign of unsound banking to also borrow from the Federal Reserve.
Congressional Research Service
10
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Appendix B. Federal Reserve and the Monetary
Aggregates
Because the amount of money in circulation is an important determinant of money spending, it
might appear to some as curious that the Fed does not target the money supply in the conduct of
monetary policy. Such a target has not been popular with the Fed. However, the Fed did define
several measures of money (designating them, ultimately, as M1, M2, and M3), published data on
them on a monthly basis, and set growth rate ranges for each on a annual basis.
Early on, the Fed encountered problems with its defined measures of money. These monetary
aggregates were not stably and predictably related to money spending (in the technical language
of the economist, the demand for these measures of money was unstable). Hence, their usefulness
as a target for monetary policy was questionable and deemed inferior to using an interest rate
target. This the Fed ultimately recognized, and the Fed de-emphasized the importance of the
aggregates in the 1990s.22 In the Monetary Policy Report submitted to Congress on July 20, 2000,
the Board of Governors stated:
At its June meeting, the FOMC did not establish ranges for the growth of money and debt in
2000 and 2001. The legal requirement to establish and to announce such ranges had expired,
and owing to uncertainties about the behavior of the velocities of debt and money, these
ranges for many years have not provided useful benchmarks for the conduct of monetary
policy. Nevertheless, the FOMC believes that the behavior of money and credit will continue
to have value for gauging economic and financial conditions....
Even this view of the usefulness of the aggregates changed. The Board of Governors announced
in November 2005 that beginning in March 23, 2006, it would no longer publish data on M3. In
the words of the Board: “... publication of M3 was judged to be no longer generating sufficient
benefit in the analysis of the economy or of the financial sector to justify the costs of
publication.”23
Author Contact Information
Marc Labonte
Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
mlabonte@crs.loc.gov, 7-0640
22
For a discussion of their usefulness in the conduct of monetary policy, see CRS Report RL31416, Monetary
Aggregates: Their Use in the Conduct of Monetary Policy, by Marc Labonte; Dotsey, Michael, Carl Lanta, and
Lawrence Santucci, “Is Money Useful in the Conduct of Monetary Policy? Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond, Vol. 86, No. 4 (Fall 2000), pp. 23-48, and Meyer, Laurence H. “The 2001 Homer Jones Memorial Lecture,”
Washington University, St. Louis, Missouri, March 28, 2001. When this lecture was given, Laurence Meyer was a
governor of the Federal Reserve.
23
Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, February 15, 2006, p. 22.
Congressional Research Service
11
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Acknowledgments
This report was originally authored by Gail E. Makinen, formerly of the Congressional Research
Service.
Congressional Research Service
12are influenced by international credit
conditions and business cycles.
The recent financial crisis underlines that open market operations alone can be insufficient at
times for meeting the Fed’s statutory mandate. Since the crisis, many economists and central
bankers have argued that a macroprudential approach to supervision and regulation is needed, and
this may affect conduct of monetary policy to maintain maximum employment and price
stability.10 Whereas traditional open market operations managed to contain systemic risk
following the bursting of the “dot-com” bubble in 2000, direct lending by the Fed on a large scale
was unable to contain systemic risk in 2008. In a recent speech, Fed Chairman Bernanke said he
is committed to serving on and working closely with the Financial Stability Oversight Committee,
created by the Dodd-Frank Act, to safeguard against systemic risk.11 He also described how the
9
For a technical discussion of how this is actually done, see Edwards, Cheryl L., “Open Market Operations in the
1990s,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, November 1997, pp. 859-872.
10
Bank for International Settlements, “Monetary Policy in a World with Macro Prudential Policy,” speech by Jaime
Caruana on June 11, 2011, http://www.bis.org/speeches/sp110610.htm.
11
For more information, see CRS Report R41384, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act:
Systemic Risk and the Federal Reserve, by Marc Labonte.
Congressional Research Service
4
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Fed has recently restructured its internal operations to facilitate a macroprudential approach to
supervision and regulation. 12
Economic Effects of Monetary Policy in the Short Run and Long
Run
How do changes in short-term interest rates affect the overall economy? In the short run, an
expansionary monetary policy that reduces interest rates increases interest-sensitive spending, all
else equal. Interest-sensitive spending includes physical investment (i.e., plant and equipment) by
firms, residential investment (housing construction), and consumer-durable spending (e.g.,
automobiles and appliances) by households. As discussed in the next section, it also encourages
exchange rate depreciation that causes exports to rise and imports to fall, all else equal. To reduce
spending in the economy, the Fed raises interest rates, and the process works in reverse. An
examination of U.S. economic history will show that money- and credit-induced demand
expansions can have a positive effect on U.S. GDP growth and total employment. The extent to
which greater interest-sensitive spending results in an increase in overall spending in the
economy in the short run will depend in part on how close the economy is to full employment.
When the economy is near full employment, the increase in spending is likely to be dissipated
through higher inflation more quickly. When the economy is far below full employment,
inflationary pressures are more likely to be muted. This same history, however, also suggests that
over the longer run, a more rapid rate of growth of money and credit is largely dissipated in a
more rapid rate of inflation with little, if any, lasting effect on real GDP and employment. (Since
the crisis, the historical relationship between money growth and inflation has not held so far, as
will be discussed below.)
Economists have two explanations for this paradoxical behavior. First, they note that, in the short
run, many economies have an elaborate system of contracts (both implicit and explicit) that
makes it difficult in a short period for significant adjustments to take place in wages and prices in
response to a more rapid growth of money and credit. Second, they note that expectations for one
reason or another are slow to adjust to the longer run consequences of major changes in monetary
policy. This slow adjustment also adds rigidities to wages and prices. Because of these rigidities,
changes in the growth of money and credit that change aggregate demand can have a large initial
effect on output and employment albeit with a policy lag of six to eight quarters before the
broader economy fully responds to monetary policy measures. Over the longer run, as contracts
are renegotiated and expectations adjust, wages and prices rise in response to the change in
demand and much of the change in output and employment is undone. Thus, monetary policy can
matter in the short run but be fairly neutral for GDP growth and employment in the longer run.13
It is noteworthy that in societies where high rates of inflation are endemic, price adjustments are
very rapid. During the final stages of very rapid inflations, called hyperinflation, the ability of
12
Chairman Ben Bernanke, “Implementing a Macroprudential Approach to Supervision and Regulation,” speech at the
47th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Chicago, Illinois, Federal Reserve, May 5, 2011,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20110505a.htm.
13
Two interesting papers bearing on what monetary policy can accomplish by two former officials of the Federal
Reserve are Santomero, Anthony M. “What Monetary Policy Can and Cannot Do,” Business Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, First Quarter 2002, pp. 1-4, and Mishkin, Frederic S. “What Should Central Banks Do?,” Review,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, November/December 2000, pp. 1-14.
Congressional Research Service
5
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
more rapid rates of growth of money and credit to alter GDP growth and employment is virtually
nonexistent, if not negative.
Monetary vs. Fiscal Policy
Either fiscal policy (defined here as changes in the structural budget deficit) or monetary policy
can be used to alter overall spending in the economy. However, there are several important
differences to consider between the two.
First, economic conditions change rapidly, and in practice monetary policy can be much more
nimble than fiscal policy. The Fed meets every six weeks to consider changes in interest rates,
and can call an unscheduled meeting any time in between. Large changes to fiscal policy typically
occur once a year at most. For example, there were three large tax cuts from the 2001 recession
through 2006;14 in the same period, interest rates were changed 29 times. Once a decision to alter
fiscal policy has been made, the proposal must travel through a long and arduous legislative
process that can last months before it can become law, while monetary policy changes are made
instantly.15
In addition to differences in implementation lags, both monetary and fiscal policy face lags due to
“pipeline effects.” In the case of monetary policy, interest rates throughout the economy may
change rapidly, but it takes longer for economic actors to change their spending patterns in
response. For example, in response to a lower interest rate, a business must put together a loan
proposal, apply for a loan, receive approval for the loan, and then put the funds to use. In the case
of fiscal policy, once legislation has been enacted, it may take some time for authorized spending
to be outlayed. An agency must approve projects and select and negotiate with contractors before
funds can be released. In the case of transfers or tax cuts, recipients must receive the funds and
then alter their private spending patterns before the economy-wide effects are felt. For both
monetary and fiscal policy, further rounds of private and public decision-making must occur
before “multiplier” or “ripple” effects are fully felt.
Second, political constraints has led to fiscal policy being employed mostly in only one direction.
Over the course of the business cycle, aggregate spending in the economy can be expected to be
too high as often as it is too low. This means that stabilization policy should be tightened as often
as it is loosened, yet increasing the budget deficit has proven to be much more popular than
implementing the spending cuts or tax increases necessary to reduce it. As a result, the budget has
been in deficit in all but five years since 1961. This has led to an accumulation of federal debt that
gives policymakers less leeway to potentially undertake a robust expansionary fiscal policy, if
needed, in the future. By contrast, the Fed is more insulated from political pressures,16 and
experience shows that it is as willing to raise interest rates as it is to lower them.
Third, the long run consequences of fiscal and monetary policy differ. Expansionary fiscal policy
creates federal debt that must be serviced by future generations. Some of this debt will be “owed
14
The tax cuts are the Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act (P.L. 107-16), the Job Creation and
Worker Assistance Act (P.L. 107-147), and the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act (P.L. 108-27).
15
To some extent, fiscal policy automatically mitigates changes in the business cycle without any policy changes
because tax revenue falls relative to GDP and certain mandatory spending (such as unemployment insurance) rises
when economic growth slows, and vice versa.
16
For more information, see CRS Report RL31056, Economics of Federal Reserve Independence, by Marc Labonte.
Congressional Research Service
6
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
to ourselves,” but some (presently, about half) will be owed to foreigners. To the extent that
expansionary fiscal policy “crowds out” private investment, it leaves future national income
lower than it otherwise would have been. 17 Monetary policy does not have this effect on
generational equity though different levels of interest rates will affect borrowers and lenders
differently. Furthermore, the government faces a budget constraint that limits the scope of
expansionary fiscal policy—it can only issue debt as long as investors believe that the debt will
be honored—even if economic conditions require larger deficits to restore equilibrium. 18
Fourth, openness of an economy to highly mobile capital flows changes the relative effectiveness
of fiscal and monetary policy. Expansionary fiscal policy would be expected to lead to higher
interest rates, all else equal, which would attract foreign capital looking for a higher rate of
return.19 Foreign capital can only enter the United States on net through a trade deficit. Thus,
higher foreign capital inflows lead to higher imports, which reduces spending on domestically
produced substitutes, and lower spending on exports. The increase in the trade deficit would
cancel out the expansionary effects of the increase in the budget deficit to some extent (in theory,
entirely). This theory is supported by experience—as the budget deficit increased, so did the trade
deficit. 20 Expansionary monetary policy would have the opposite effect—lower interest rates
would cause capital to flow abroad in search of higher rates of return elsewhere. Foreign capital
outflows would reduce the trade deficit through an increase in spending on exports and
domestically produced import substitutes. Thus, foreign capital flows would (tend to) magnify the
expansionary effects of monetary policy.
Fifth, fiscal policy can be targeted to specific recipients. In the case of normal open market
operations, monetary policy cannot. This difference could be considered an advantage or
disadvantage. On the one hand, policymakers could target stimulus to aid the sectors of the
economy most in need, or most likely to respond positively to stimulus. On the other hand,
stimulus could turn out to be allocated on the basis of political or non-economic factors that
reduce the macroeconomic effectiveness of the stimulus. As a result, both fiscal and monetary
policy have distributional implications, but the latter’s are largely incidental, whereas the former’s
can be explicitly chosen.
In cases where economic activity is extremely depressed, monetary policy may lose some of its
effectiveness. When interest rates become extremely low, interest-sensitive spending may no
longer be very responsive to further rate cuts. Furthermore, interest rates cannot be lowered below
zero. In this scenario, fiscal policy may be more effective. As is discussed in the next section,
some would argue that the U.S. economy experienced this scenario following the recent financial
crisis.
17
An exception to the rule would be a situation where the economy is far enough below full employment that virtually
no crowding out takes place because the stimulus to spending generates enough resources to finance new capital
spending.
18
The analogous constraint on monetary policy is that after a certain limit, expansionary monetary policy would
become highly inflationary. But from the current starting point of price stability, problems with inflation would
presumably only occur after a point where the economy had returned to full employment.
19
For more information, see CRS Report RL31235, The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit, by Brian W.
Cashell.
20
See CRS Report RS21409, The Budget Deficit and the Trade Deficit: What Is Their Relationship?, by Marc Labonte
and Gail E. Makinen.
Congressional Research Service
7
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Of course, using monetary and fiscal policy to stabilize the economy are not mutually exclusive
policy options. But because of the Fed’s independence from Congress and the Administration, the
two policy options are not always coordinated. If compatible fiscal and monetary policies are
chosen by Congress and the Fed, respectively, then the economic effects would be more powerful
than if either policy were implemented in isolation. For example, if stimulative monetary and
fiscal policies were implemented, the resulting economic stimulus would be larger than if one
policy were stimulative and the other were neutral. But if incompatible policies are selected, they
could partially negate each other. For example, a stimulative fiscal policy and contractionary
monetary policy may end up having little net effect on aggregate demand (though there may be
considerable distributional effects). Thus, when fiscal and monetary policymakers disagree in the
current system, they can potentially choose policies with the intent of offsetting each others’
actions.21 Whether this arrangement is better or worse for the economy depends on what policies
are chosen. If one actor chooses inappropriate policies, then the lack of coordination usefully
allows the other actor to try to negate its effects.
The Recent and Current Stance of Monetary Policy
Until financial turmoil emerged in 2007, a consensus had emerged among economists that a
relatively stable business cycle could be maintained through prudent and nimble changes to
interest rates via transparently communicated and signaled open market operations. That
consensus would break down as the financial crisis worsened, as the Fed took increasingly
unconventional and unprecedented steps to restore financial stability.
Before the Financial Crisis
As the U.S. economy was coming out of the short and shallow 2001 recession, unemployment
continued rising until mid-2003. Fearful that the economy would slip back into recession, the Fed
kept the federal funds rate extremely low. 22 The federal funds target reached a low of 1% by mid2003. As the expansion gathered momentum and prices began to rise, the federal funds target was
slowly increased in a series of moves to 5¼% in mid-2006.
It is now argued by some economists that the financial crisis was, at least in part, due to Federal
Reserve policy to ensure that the then-ongoing expansion continued.23 In particular, critics now
claim that the low short-term rates were kept too low for too long after the 2001 recession had
ended, and this caused an increased demand for housing that resulted in a “price bubble.” The
shift in financing housing from fixed to variable rate mortgages made this sector of the economy
increasingly vulnerable to movements in short-term interest rates. An alternative perspective,
21
It is important to take this possibility into consideration when evaluating the potential effects of fiscal policy on the
business cycle. Because the Fed presumably chooses (and continually updates) a monetary policy that aims to keep the
economy at full employment, the Fed would need to alter its policy to offset the effects of any stimulative fiscal policy
changes that moved the economy above full employment. Thus, the actual net stimulative effect of a fiscal policy
change (after taking into account monetary policy adjustments) could be less than the effects in isolation.
22
Historical and current targets for the federal funds rate can be found at http://www.federalreserve.gov/fomc/
fundsrate.htm.
23
In a WSJ opinion article, six economists are polled regarding if the Fed was to blame for creating the housing bubble
that in part led to the recent financial crisis, and five of six responded that the Fed in some degree was to blame. See
David Henderson, “Did the Fed Cause the Housing Bubble?,” Wall Street Journal, March 27, 2009.
Congressional Research Service
8
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
championed by Chairman Bernanke and others, was that the low mortgage rates that helped fuel
the housing bubble were mainly caused by a “global savings glut” over which the Fed had little
control.24 One consequence of the tightening of monetary policy later in the decade, critics now
claim, was to burst this “price bubble” (a bubble that was also due, in part, to lax lending
standards that were subject to regulation by the Fed and others).
During and After the Financial Crisis
The bursting of the housing bubble led to the onset of a financial crisis that affected both
depository institutions and other segments of the financial sector involved with housing finance.
As the delinquency rates on home mortgages rose to record numbers, financial firms exposed to
the mortgage market suffered capital losses and lost access to liquidity. The contagious nature of
this development was soon obvious as other types of loans and credit became adversely affected.
This, in turn, spilled over into the broader economy, as the lack of credit soon had a negative
effect on both production and aggregate demand. In December 2007, the economy entered a
recession.
As the spillover effects from the housing slump to the financial system, as well as its international
scope, became apparent, the Fed responded by reducing the federal funds target and the discount
rate.25 Beginning on September 18, 2007, and ending on December 16, 2008, the target was
reduced from 5¼% to a range between 0% and ¼%, where it currently remains.
With liquidity problems persisting as the federal funds rate was reduced, it appeared that the
traditional transmission mechanism linking monetary policy to activity in the broader economy
was not working. It also, began to concern the monetary authorities that the liquidity provided to
the banking system was not reaching other parts of the financial system. Under traditional
monetary policy tools, additional monetary stimulus cannot be provided once the federal funds
rate has reached its zero bound. To circumvent this problem, the Fed decided to use more nontraditional methods to provide additional monetary policy stimulus.
First, the Federal Reserve introduced a number of emergency credit facilities to provide increased
liquidity directly to financial firms and markets. The first facility was introduced in December
2007, and several were added after the worsening of the crisis in September 2008. These facilities
were designed to fill perceived gaps between open market operations and the discount window.
The loans primarily provided by these facilities were designed to provide short-term loans backed
by collateral that exceeds the value of the loan.26 A number of the recipients were non-banks that
are outside the regulatory umbrella of the Federal Reserve; this marked the first time that the Fed
lent to non-banks since the Great Depression. The Fed began to employ a seldom used emergency
provision, Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act,27 that allows it to make loans to other
financial institutions and to non-financial firms as well. The Fed justified their pursuit of this
24
See Ben Bernanke, “The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit,” speech at the Virginia
Association of Economists, March 10, 2005.
25
For a detailed account of the Fed’s role in the financial crisis, see CRS Report RL34427, Financial Turmoil: Federal
Reserve Policy Responses, by Marc Labonte.
26
See CRS Report R41073, Government Interventions in Response to Financial Turmoil, by Baird Webel and Marc
Labonte.
27
12 U.S.C. 343.
Congressional Research Service
9
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
policy on the grounds that it falls under its mandate to “promote effectively the goals of
maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.”28
The Fed provided assistance through liquidity facilities, which included both the traditional
discount window and the newly created emergency facilities previously mentioned, and through
direct support to two specific institutions, AIG and Bear Stearns. The magnitude of this assistance
has been large. Total assistance from the Federal Reserve at the beginning of August 2007 was
approximately $234 million provided through liquidity facilities, with no direct support given. In
mid-December 2008, it reached a high of $1.6 trillion, with a near high of $108 billion given in
direct support. From that point on, it fell steadily. Assistance provided through liquidity facilities
fell below $100 billion in February 2010, and support to specific institutions fell below $100
billion in January 2011.29 The majority of these facilities expired at the beginning of February
2010, and all those that have expired to date saw all transactions repaid with interest.
With direct lending falling as financial conditions began to normalize and the federal funds rate at
its zero bound, the Fed found other tools to maintain the elevated level of liquidity in the financial
system in order to prevent a removal of monetary stimulus while the economy was still fragile. In
March 2009, the Fed announced plans to purchase $300 billion of Treasury securities, $200
billion of Agency (Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac) debt (later revised to $175 billion), and $1.25
trillion of Agency mortgage-backed securities. These purchases were completed by the end of
March 2010.
Beginning in November of 2010 the Federal Reserve, dissatisfied with the high level of
unemployment, took steps to encourage economic growth by purchasing an additional $600
billion of Treasury securities and continuing the practice of replacing maturing securities. The
purchases were made at a pace of $75 billion a month and were completed in about six months.
The Fed has focused on purchasing securities with maturities between 2½ and 10 years in
length.30 According to the Fed, these actions were taken to promote a stronger pace of economic
recovery because current progress towards the Fed’s policy objectives has been “disappointingly
slow.”31
This is clearly not a “business as usual” monetary policy, but something quite extraordinary,
sometimes referred to as “quantitative easing.” While there may not be a universally accepted
definition of quantitative easing, this report defines it as actions to further stimulate the economy
through growth in the Fed’s balance sheet once the federal funds rate has reached the “zero
bound.”
28
Federal Reserve Act, Section 2A, 12 USC 225a.
29
Data from “Recent Balance Sheet Trends,” Credit and Liquidity Programs and the Balance Sheet,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_recenttrends.htm. Values include totals from credit extended
through Federal Reserve liquidity facilities and support for specific institutions.
30
CRS Report R41540, Quantitative Easing and the Growth in the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet, by Marc
Labonte.
31
Federal Open Market Committee, Federal Reserve, “press release,” November 3, 2010,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20101103a.htm.
Congressional Research Service
10
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
The Growth in the Balance Sheet and Bank Reserves
The assistance provided by the Federal Reserve to banks and non-bank institutions is considered
an asset on the Federal Reserve balance sheet because it represents money owed to or assets
owned by the Fed. This assistance and its holdings of Treasury securities, mortgage-backed
securities and government sponsored enterprise debt comprise most of the assets on the Fed’s
balance sheet.
From the time its first emergency lending facility was introduced in December 2007 until the
crisis worsened in September 2008, the Fed “sterilized” the effects of lending on its balance sheet
by selling Treasury securities. After September 2008, the Fed allowed its balance sheet to grow,
and between September and November 2008, it more than doubled in size, increasing from under
$1 trillion to over $2 trillion. The increase in assets during this time took the form of direct
assistance through emergency facilities.
From November 2008 to November 2010, the overall size of the Fed’s balance sheet did not vary
much; however, its composition changed. As of December 2010, loans made up $46 billion of the
$2,427 billion of the Fed’s balance sheet and securities made up $2,225 billion. When the
purchases of Treasury securities announced in November 2010 is complete, the balance sheet is
expected to be about $600 billion larger.
This increase in the Fed’s assets must be matched by a corresponding increase in its liabilities on
its balance sheet, mostly in the form of currency, bank reserves, and cash deposited by the U.S.
Treasury at the Fed. Bank reserves increased from about $46 billion in August 2008 to $820
billion at the end of 2008 to $1,138 billion at the end of 2009. As of January 2011 total reserves
still remained high with $1,077 billion still being held by banks. The increase in bank reserves
can be seen as the inevitable outcome of the increase in assets held by the Fed because they, in
effect, financed the Fed’s asset purchases and loan programs. The lending facilities increased
reserves because the loan amounts are credited to the recipients’ reserve accounts at the Fed. 32
Whether the additional reserves will be lent out by banks, resulting in lower market interest rates
and an expansion of new spending, as posited in the textbook explanation of how monetary policy
works, is another story. Recent experience is not reassuring, as the large volume of reserves added
to the banking system by the Fed have remained as excess bank reserves. Some economists fear
that the response of banks to additional reserves is a sign that the economy has entered a
“liquidity trap,” where total spending in the economy (aggregate demand) is unresponsive to
additional monetary stimulus. This phenomenon could help explain why the unprecedented
growth in the monetary base (the portion of the money supply controlled by the Fed) has not
translated into higher inflation to date. Critics fear that it is simply a matter of time before
quantitative easing leads to high inflation, and argue that these long-term risks outweigh any
modest short-term benefits.33
By contrast, the Fed has argued that quantitative easing has successfully stimulated the economy,
mainly through lower long-term interest rates.34 Janet Yellen, Vice Chair of the Board of
32
See H.3. Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, Aggregate Reserves of Depository Institutions and the Monetary Base
at http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h3/Current.
33
See, for example, “An Open Letter to Chairman Bernanke,” November 15, 2010, http://economics21.org/
commentary/e21s-open-letter-ben-bernanke.
34
For a recent discussion of this issue by the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, see Bullard, Thomas.
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
11
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, defended these policies in a recent speech. She argues
that the evidence has shown that the financial securities purchases by the Federal Reserve have
proven effective in easing financial conditions. With unemployment remaining high and
expectations that inflation will be low over the medium run, she argues that the accommodative
stance of the Fed regarding their monetary policy is appropriate.35
Congressional Oversight and Disclosure
Humphrey-Hawkins Hearings
Congress has delegated monetary policy decisions to the Fed but retains oversight
responsibilities. A primary form of congressional oversight of the Federal Reserve is the semiannual hearings with the Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs and the
House Committee on Financial Services. At these hearings, which take place in February and
July, the Fed Chairman presents the Fed’s Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, testifies, and
responds to questions from committee members. These hearings and reporting requirements were
established by the Full Employment Act of 1978 (P.L. 95-523, 92 Stat 1897), also known as the
Humphrey-Hawkins Act, and renewed in the American Homeownership and Economic
Opportunity Act of 2000 (P.L. 106-569).
The semiannual Monetary Policy Report presents a review of recent economic and monetary
policy developments, as well as economic projections for three years. Since monetary policy
plays an important role in determining economic outcomes, these projections can be viewed as
the Fed’s perceptions of how today’s monetary policy stance will influence future economic
conditions. To increase the transparency of monetary policy, the Fed in 2007 began to publicly
provide additional forecasts. They now appear quarterly.
GAO Audits
In the wake of the financial crisis there was a strong push to remove the statutory restrictions on
the Government Accountability Office’s (GAO’s) ability to audit the Fed. This restriction was
modified by Title XI of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (P.L.
111-203).36 As a result, the GAO can now audit the Fed’s monetary actions and lending programs
for issues such as operational integrity, accounting and financial reporting, and internal controls,
but is still unable to conduct policy evaluations of those activities. Further, any confidential
information that the GAO gathers cannot be released until it is first made public by the Fed.
(...continued)
Effective Monetary Policy in a Low Interest Rate Environment, The Henry Thornton Lecture, Cass Business School,
London, March 24, 2009.
35
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “2011 International Conference,” speech by Janet L. Yellen on
June 1, 2011, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20110601a.htm.
36
More details on the changes made in the Dodd-Frank Act can be found in CRS Report R40877, Financial Regulatory
Reform: Systemic Risk and the Federal Reserve, by Marc Labonte.
Congressional Research Service
12
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Some Representatives have pressed for greater GAO oversight than provided in the Dodd-Frank
Act. The Federal Reserve Transparency Act of 2011 (H.R. 459/H.R. 1496/S. 202) would remove
remaining audit restrictions and require a GAO audit of the Fed.
Disclosure of Lending Records
As a result of another section of the Dodd-Frank Act, the Fed is required, for the first time, to
publicly disclose information on the identities of borrowers, amount borrowed, rate charged, and
collateral pledged or assets transferred within one year after a credit facility is terminated and
within two years after the transaction for discount window loans or open market operations. On
December 1, 2010, the Federal Reserve released the summary of all transactions made since
December 1, 2007, under programs created during the crisis; however, this release did not include
information on discount window transactions. Separately, Bloomberg and Fox News Network
sued the Federal Reserve under the Freedom of Information Act for the release of internal records
pertaining to lending activities, including the discount window, for the period of August 2007 to
March 2010. As a result, the Fed released this information on March 31, 2011.
Greater disclosure and outside evaluation could potentially help Congress perform its oversight
duties more effectively. A main argument against increasing Fed oversight would be that it could
be perceived to reduce the Fed’s operational independence from Congress. While few
policymakers argue for total independence or total disclosure and oversight, the policy challenge
is to strike the right balance between the two. The Fed’s independence is discussed in the next
section.
The Federal Reserve’s Mandate and Its
Independence
The Constitution grants Congress the power to “coin money, and regulate the value thereof.... ”
However, operational responsibility for making U.S. monetary policy has been delegated by
Congress to the Fed. Congress is still responsible for oversight, setting the Fed’s mandate and
approving the President’s nominations for the Fed’s Board of Governors, but several institutional
features grant it significant “independence” from the political process. 37 The Federal Reserve
system is quasi-public in structure: its regional banks are owned by its member banks. The
governors are appointed to staggered 14-year terms, and can only be removed by Congress for
cause. It is self-funded and its budget is not subject to the congressional appropriation process. It
has been granted broad discretion to interpret and carry out its congressional mandate as it sees fit
on a day-to-day basis.
Although the Fed’s statutory mandate might be expected to be a significant curb on its
independence, The Federal Reserve Act of 1977 (P.L. 95-188, 91 Stat. 1387) charged the Fed with
“the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.” Note
that the Fed controls none of these three indicators directly; it controls only overnight interest
rates through the use of open market operations, the discount window, and reserve requirements.
There will be times when the goals will be at odds with each other, and the Fed will have to
37
For more information, see CRS Report RL31056, Economics of Federal Reserve Independence, by Marc Labonte.
Congressional Research Service
13
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
choose to pursue one at the expense of the other two. For example, an energy price shock would
be expected to raise prices and reduce employment. In this case, the current mandate could be
used to justify expansionary monetary policy in response to lower employment or contractionary
monetary policy in response to higher prices. Critics have argued that the ambiguity inherent in
the current mandate makes for less than optimal transparency and accountability. It may also
strengthen political independence if it allows the Fed to deflect congressional criticism by
pointing, at any given time, to whatever goal justifies its current policy stance.
The most popular alternative to the current mandate is to replace it with a single mandate of price
stability.38 H.R. 245 is an example of such a bill in the 112th Congress. This proposal is often
coupled with a proposal for the Fed to be given (or, under the version mooted by Chairman
Bernanke, give itself) a numerical inflation target, and the Fed would then be required to set
monetary policy with the goal of meeting the target on an ongoing basis. Proponents of inflation
targeting say that maximum employment and moderate interest rates are not meaningful policy
goals because monetary policy has no long-term influence over either one. They argue a mandate
that is focused on keeping inflation low would deliver better economic results and improve
transparency and oversight.39 Opponents, including former Fed chairman Greenspan, say that the
flexibility inherent in the current system has served the United States well in the past 25 years,
delivering both low inflation and economic stability, and there is little reason to fix a system that
is not broken. They argue that some focus on employment is appropriate given that monetary
policy has powerful short-term effects on it, and that too great a focus on inflation could lead to
an overly volatile business cycle. Various forms of inflation targeting have been adopted abroad.40
Other economists argue that a single mandate would do little to curb the Fed’s independence, and
would therefore have little practical effect on its decision making.
Most economists argue that central bank independence leads to good monetary policy because it
reduces the temptation to raise inflation in the long run in order to lower unemployment in the
short run. Researchers have made cross-country comparisons to try to make the case that
countries with independent central banks are more likely to have low inflation rates and better
economic performance. 41 As noted in the previous section, independence from Congress may
make oversight less effective, however.
38
See CRS Report R41656, Changing the Federal Reserve’s Mandate: An Economic Analysis, by Marc Labonte.
In a 2009 speech, then Fed Vice Chairman Donald Kohn reports that the Fed Governors and Reserve Bank presidents
continue “to discuss whether an explicit numerical objective for inflation would be beneficial. Under current
circumstances, those benefits would include underscoring our understanding that our legislative mandate for promoting
price stability encompasses both preventing inflation from falling too low in the near term and from rising too far as the
economy recovers.” See Monetary Policy in the Financial Crisis, a Conference in Honor of Dewey Daane, Nashville,
Tennessee, April 18, 2009.
40
See CRS Report RL31702, Price Stability (Inflation Targeting) as the Sole Goal of Monetary Policy: The
International Experience, by Marc Labonte and Gail E. Makinen.
39
41
For a review of the research and criticisms, see CRS Report RL31955, Central Bank Independence and Economic
Performance: What Does the Evidence Show?, by Marc Labonte and Gail E. Makinen.
Congressional Research Service
14
.
Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and Conditions
Author Contact Information
Marc Labonte
Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
mlabonte@crs.loc.gov, 7-0640
Joseph R. McCormack
Research Associate
Acknowledgments
This report was originally authored by Gail E. Makinen, formerly of the Congressional Research
Service. This report was updated with the assistance of Joseph R. McCormack, Research
Associate.
Congressional Research Service
15