Reauthorization of the Federal Maritime Commission (FMC): Opportunity to Reexamine the Congressionally Mandated Antitrust Exemption for Ocean Liner Carriers?

The focus of this report is on the commercial aspects of the U.S. liner trade. The report discusses the historical rationale for shipping conferences and legislative history of U.S. shipping law.



Order Code RL34663
Reauthorization of the Federal Maritime
Commission (FMC): Opportunity to Reexamine
the Congressionally Mandated Antitrust
Exemption for Ocean Liner Carriers?
Updated September 18, 2008
John Frittelli
Specialist in Transportation Policy
Resources, Science, and Industry Division

Reauthorization of the Federal Maritime Commission
(FMC): Opportunity to Reexamine the
Congressionally Mandated Antitrust Exemption
for Ocean Liner Carriers?
Summary
Authorization for the Federal Maritime Commission (FMC), the regulatory
agency with jurisdiction over ocean liner carriers, expires at the end of FY2008,
pursuant to P.L. 108-293. Although the FMC does not itself grant the antitrust
exemption that Congress has provided to certain ocean liners in a series of shipping
acts, the agency’s reauthorization might provide an opportunity for Congress to
reconsider the current viability of that exemption, which dates back to the early
1900s. The European Union (EU), for example, recently decided to outlaw collective
rate-setting among container carriers engaged in EU trade lanes.
Shipping lines contend such arrangements are still necessary to stabilize rates
and service in liner shipping. Shippers argue that this exemption is no longer
necessary and allows container carriers to charge more than they would otherwise.
U.S. exporters contend that this exemption is a contributing factor in their inability
to obtain enough containers and vessel space to meet surging demand for their goods.
After years of large U.S. trade imbalances in which imported containers outnumbered
exported containers by more than two to one, the decline in the U.S. dollar and rising
incomes abroad have led to a dramatic rise in demand for U.S. goods. While the
United States is no longer a provider of ocean container services, it is a large user of
them. The persistent U.S. merchandise trade deficit manifests itself in the container
trade. Over three times more containers are imported from Asia than are exported to
that region, while nearly two times more containers are imported from Europe than
are exported to Europe. As a result of this imbalance, outbound shipping rates to Asia
and Europe have been about half as much as inbound rates. While recent market
changes have started a possible revival of the U.S. outbound trade that has long been
non-remunerative, the import market still dominates shipowner decisions about
where to deploy vessel space. The persistent merchandise trade deficit is thus a
double-edged sword for U.S. exporters. Because of it, they ship at below cost, yet it
also means that they are dependent on import market conditions for the supply of
shipping space.
Inasmuch as a desire for international comity is one factor that has shaped U.S.
shipping policy, Congress could decide to follow the EU’s lead and repeal antitrust
immunity, or it could take a “wait-and-see” approach to observe any positive or
negative effects that the repeal may have on European trade. Repealing antitrust
immunity may lead to lower freight rates but also greater price volatility and some
amount of turmoil in the liner market. The historical development of U.S. shipping
law has reflected a balance between maintaining a viable U.S.-owned liner fleet for
national security purposes and consideration of the interests of U.S. importers and
exporters for reliable shipping at competitive rates. Now that the U.S. liner fleet in
foreign commerce has almost disappeared, policymakers may wish to reevaluate that
balance. The focus of this report is on the commercial aspects of the U.S. liner trade.
It does not provide a legal analysis of antitrust immunity as it applies to liner carriers.

Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
Pricing Agreements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
Asset Sharing Agreements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
Historical Rationale for Shipping Conferences . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
Legislative History of U.S. Shipping Law . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
The Shipping Act of 1916 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
The 1961 Amendments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
The Shipping Act of 1984 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
The Ocean Shipping Reform Act of 1998 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
Legislative Activity Since OSRA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
Asian and European Approaches to Liner Conferences . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
Europe . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
Asia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
China . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
India . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
Japan . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
Singapore and Hong Kong . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
Profile of U.S. Overseas Container Trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
Directional Imbalances . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
Recent Shift in Trade Flows . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
Stakeholder Views . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
Liner Carriers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
Ports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
Shippers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
Port Truckers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
Issues for Congress . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
List of Figures
Figure 1. U.S. Waterborne Foreign Container Trade,
Top 10 Trading Partners in 2007 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
Figure 2. Container Ship Freight Rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
List of Tables
Table 1. The Top 15 Container Lines by Size of Fleet . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
Table 2. U.S. Containerized Trade Imbalance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

Reauthorization of the
Federal Maritime Commission (FMC):
Opportunity to Reexamine the
Congressionally Mandated Antitrust
Exemption for Ocean Liner Carriers?
Introduction
Unlike most other industries, which are, generally, fully subject to U.S. antitrust
laws,1 ocean container lines (“liner” carriers) have limited exemption from these laws
and are, therefore, permitted to discuss and set freight rates among themselves. This
exemption dates back to the early 1900s, beginning with the Shipping Act of 1916,2
and has been continued through the present in the 1961 amendments to that act,3 the
Shipping Act of 1984,4 and the Ocean Shipping Reform Act of 1998 (OSRA).5
Permission to engage in joint pricing activity was thought necessary to stabilize rates
and service in liner shipping. Liner carriers argue that this immunity is still needed
due to chronic overcapacity in liner services caused by government programs to
promote national-flag fleets and domestic shipbuilding.
Shippers, the businesses that own the cargo and hire the ocean carriers to
transport it, argue that this exemption is no longer necessary and allows container
carriers to charge more than they would otherwise. U.S. exporters in particular
contend that this exemption is a contributing factor in their inability to obtain enough
containers and vessel space to meet surging demand for their goods. After years of
large U.S. trade imbalances in which imported containers outnumbered exported
containers by more than two to one, the decline in the U.S. dollar and rising incomes
abroad have led to a dramatic rise in demand for U.S.-produced goods. For instance,
in the first five months of 2008, containerized grain exports to Asia were 64% higher
than for the same period last year.6 Yet U.S. agricultural exporters estimate that the
1 These laws include the Sherman Act (15 U.S.C. §§ 1-7), the Clayton Act (15 U.S.C. §§ 12-
27), and the Federal Trade Commission Act (15 U.S.C. §§ 41 et seq.). See CRS Report
RL31026, General Overview of United States Antitrust Law, by Janice E. Rubin.
2 Public No. 260 (64th Congress), 39 Stat. 728, 46 U.S.C. App. §§ 801 et seq.
3 P.L. 87-346.
4 P.L. 98-237, 98 Stat. 67.
5 P.L. 105-258, 112 Stat. 1902.
6 U.S. Department of Agriculture, Grain Transportation Report, August 7, 2008, p. 3.

CRS-2
shortage of containers and vessel space in recent months has held back their export
volume by 20% to 30%.7
A desire for international comity is one factor that has shaped U.S. shipping
policy in the past. Although the European Union (EU) recently decided to repeal
antitrust immunity for container carriers engaged in EU trade lanes, effective this
fall,8 the rest of the world has generally not placed any restrictions on liner collective-
rate setting and therefore traditional shipping conferences (cartel-like organizations)
continue to exist on trade routes not involving the United States or Europe.
Accordingly, Congress may wish to evaluate the need for continued U.S. liner
antitrust immunity as it proceeds to reauthorize the Federal Maritime Commission
(FMC), whose authorization expires at the end of FY2008.9 The FMC is the agency
that exercises jurisdiction over the liner carriers and oversees the conditions Congress
has placed on their rate-setting activities (discussed further below), including their
antitrust exemption. The policy issues Congress might consider include:
! Should the United States follow Europe’s lead and repeal antitrust
immunity, or should it take a “wait-and-see” approach to observe
any positive or negative effects that the repeal may have on
European trade?
! If repeal were to result in lower ocean freight rates but also greater
price volatility with higher peaks and lower troughs, would this
development be a net benefit to the U.S. economy?
! In the past, U.S. shipping policy was shaped by a desire to retain a
U.S.-owned liner fleet engaged in foreign commerce. Now that this
fleet has almost disappeared, should U.S. policy be shaped more by
the interests of U.S. shippers?
! Given the tremendous disparity in total volume and dollar value of
U.S. containerized imports versus exports, should the stated purpose
of U.S. liner shipping policy be expanded to include the interests of
importers in addition to exporters?
This report provides some historical and commercial context for evaluating
these questions. After describing the types of agreements liner carriers have made
with one another, the report discusses the historical rationale for providing liner
carriers with antitrust immunity and how U.S. law has changed over time. Next, it
describes Europe’s and Asia’s approach to liner conferences. The report then profiles
U.S. overseas container trade, describing its importance to the U.S. economy, its
underlying economics, and the reasons for the recent export container shortage. The
report concludes by discussing stakeholder views and issues for Congress. The focus
of this report is on the commercial aspects of the U.S. liner trade. It does not provide
a legal analysis of antitrust immunity as it applies to liner carriers.
7 “Container Shortage Frustrates U.S. Exporters,” Wall Street Journal, May 9, 2008, p. A4.
8 Press Release IP/06/1249, European Commission - Competition: Commission welcomes
Council Agreement to end exemption for liner shipping conferences, 25 September 2006.
Available at [http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/antitrust/legislation/maritime/].
9 P.L. 108-293.

CRS-3
Types of Agreements Among Liner Carriers
Pricing Agreements
Rate discussions among container carriers often focus on “General Rate
Increases” (GRIs) or ancillary surcharges that are added to the base, ocean freight rate
(the port-to-port rate). These GRIs and surcharges have raised the ire of shippers
because they are substantial (in combination they can exceed the base freight rate)
and are typically charged uniformly by the carriers. The surcharges are intended to
recover variable costs or shore-side related costs in ocean shipping, such as
fluctuations in fuel prices and currency values, peak season-related congestion,
repositioning of empty containers, terminal handling charges, and others. The
carriers argue that these charges are properly separated from the base ocean rate
because they are costs out of the carriers’ control and itemizing them on the freight
invoice provides transparency in shipping charges. Of the 219 liner carrier
agreements that were on file with the FMC in 2006, 47 of these agreements related
to pricing of liner services.10 Of the 47, 29 were “discussion” agreements, 8 were
“conference” agreements, and 10 were other types of agreements.
Asset Sharing Agreements
Liner ocean carriers also make agreements with each other to share vessel space,
called vessel sharing agreements (VSAs), or to share chassis11 (chassis pools) at a
given port or rail terminal. VSAs are typically made among two to four ocean
carriers whereby they agree to provide container slots on each other’s vessels in a
given trade route. Sharing chassis among carriers allows them to reduce their
inventory of this equipment and saves valuable space in ports or rail yards. VSAs
and chassis pools are not opposed by shippers as they recognize that pooling
resources among carriers allows for more efficient asset utilization, lowering the
overall price of shipping.12 Of the 219 liner carrier agreements on file with the FMC
in 2006, 172 did not include pricing authority and of these, 139 were VSAs.13
10 Statement of Steven Blust, Chairman of the FMC, before the Antitrust Modernization
Commission, October 18, 2006. Available at [http://govinfo.library.unt.edu/amc/index.html].
11 Chassis are the wheeled frame necessary to haul containers by truck.
12 However, there appears to be a difference of opinion between carriers and shippers over
these so-called “efficiency-enhancing” agreements that involves a legal question: whether
specific antitrust immunity is necessary for carriers to continue to engage in these types of
agreements.
13 Statement of Steven Blust, Chairman of the FMC, before the Antitrust Modernization
Commission, October 18, 2006. Available at [http://govinfo.library.unt.edu/amc/index.html].

CRS-4
Historical Rationale for Shipping Conferences
Shipping conferences first appeared in the latter half of the 19th century as
traditional sailing ships attempted to safeguard their business from the emergence of
faster steamships.14 In the post-World War II era, shipping lines have formed
conferences as a means of counteracting the effects of government support for
merchant fleets. Many governments promote the development of their shipping
industry. Some governments do this because of national pride. Shipbuilding is
viewed by some nations as a sign of industrialization and a fleet of ships is viewed
as a sign of international presence. Some governments support their shipping
industry for national and economic security reasons. The bulk of overseas trade as
well as military supplies (in wartime) is carried by ships. Governments may not want
to be dependent on foreign carriers if overseas trade is vital to their economic
welfare. Governments may want access to a commercial fleet they can control if a
military need arises. For these reasons, many nations provide subsidies and other
preferential treatment to domestic shipyards and shipowners. In a few cases, the
shipyards and ships are owned and controlled directly or indirectly by the
governments themselves.15 This includes two Chinese container lines, China
Shipping and China Ocean Shipping (COSCO), and one from Singapore, APL, that
are major players in the U.S. market.
One of the effects of government intervention in the shipping industry is
oversupply of shipping space. While there are periods of tight supply in a given trade
lane and in a particular direction, more often ocean shipping is plagued by
overcapacity. There are generally more ships available than there is cargo to fill
them. Conference agreements were made among carriers in a particular trade route
in order to limit the supply of shipping space, establish common tariffs (rates) among
themselves, and keep rates from falling to unprofitable levels.
14 The first successful conference appeared in 1875 in the trade between England and
Calcutta.
15 As required by law (46 U.S.C. App. Sec. 1702(3)), the FMC publishes annually a list of
government controlled carriers.

CRS-5
Promotion of the U.S. Merchant Fleet
The United States promotes its maritime industry by providing
government-backed loans for the purchase of U.S.-built ships, prohibiting
foreign-built and operated ships from engaging in U.S. coastal trade, and reserving a
significant portion of “government impelled” cargoes, like food aid, for U.S.-flag
carriers. The U.S. Navy keeps a fleet of cargo ships on standby in case of war or
national emergency. It has also made agreements with privately owned and operated
liner carriers to turn over their ships for the U.S. military’s use when needed. These
ships receive an operating subsidy to partially offset the additional cost of sailing
under the U.S.-flag. Forty out of the 47 U.S.-flag container ships currently engaged in
foreign commerce are parties to this agreement. The forty ships are owned by
Maersk, APL, and Hapag-Lloyd.16 Like some other industrialized nations seeking to
retain a merchant fleet, the United States recently changed its tax structure to allow
U.S.-flag carriers engaged in foreign trades to pay a flat tax based on the size of their
fleet rather than paying tax based on their earnings.17 The prior tax system, based on
income earned from shipping, is blamed by some for the sale of U.S.-based carriers
like Sea-Land and APL to foreign buyers.
Shipowners assert that the economic structure of liner shipping is another cause
for persistent overcapacity. In the near term, the supply of shipping space is fixed as
carriers must adhere to their advertised sailing schedules. Moreover, the supply of
shipping space is “lumpy”compared with its demand. A new container ship can cost
about $60 to $70 million, require one to three years to plan and construct, and has a
service-life of about 25 years. While demand in a particular trade route may increase
or decrease incrementally (measurable in container units or container “slots” on a
ship), supply can only adjust by adding or withdrawing an entire ship. Also, if
demand falls, ships cannot be easily converted to some other use, so they tend to
remain in service, exacerbating overcapacity. Once a ship is in service in a given
trade lane, the cost of carrying an additional container on that ship is almost nothing.
In a perfectly competitive market, price tends to approach marginal cost. Driven by
the desire to fill their ships, carriers frequently find themselves carrying cargo at rates
that are, at best, marginally profitable.
For the above reasons, a persistent “boom and bust” cycle characterizes the liner
shipping market. The current market is a case in point. While U.S. exporters are
frustrated by a shortage of vessel space to Asia and Europe, vessel owners fear
pending global overcapacity. Carriers ordered new ships in recent years because of
steady, yearly increases in cargo volumes. However, these new ships are being
delivered just in time for a significant slowdown in global trade. Forecasters predict
that there will now be an increase in scrapping of older vessels and a lay up of some
additional vessels.18
16 U.S. Maritime Administration, “U.S. Fleet, Year-End 2007,” Excel file.
17 P.L. 108-357, § 248 (26 U.S.C. § 1352).
18 Global Insight, “Trends in World Economics and Trade,” vol. 2, June 2008, p. 2.

CRS-6
Legislative History of U.S. Shipping Law
During the initial era of conferences, some conferences began using “fighting
ships” and “deferred rebates” to limit competition from non-conference carriers. A
conference would deploy a fighting ship that would underprice the non-conference
carrier. The conference carriers would share in the losses of the fighting ship until
the new entrant was forced out of the trade or agreed to join the conference. Another
controversial practice was the “deferred rebate system” in which carriers would
return a portion of their freight earnings to the shipper but only after two subsequent
periods in which the shipper demonstrated exclusive loyalty to the conference. Thus,
a shipper would suffer a substantial monetary penalty if it shipped with a non-
conference carrier. This practice was meant to “tie” the shipper to the conference and
keep their business away from competing carriers.
The anti-competitive practices described above led shippers to complain and
prompted governments to scrutinize the shipping market more closely. In the United
States, this scrutiny has resulted in a series of regulatory acts that endorsed
conferences but also included provisions eroding their influence over time. The
historical development of U.S. shipping law reflects a struggle between the national
interest in a viable U.S.-owned liner fleet and the interests of U.S. importers and
exporters for reliable shipping at competitive rates. While U.S. law reflects a
recognition of the potential benefits of conferences it also established a regulatory
regime to curb their abusive practices.
The Shipping Act of 191619
Congress began investigating shipping conferences in the early 1900s. Congress
concluded that the conferences were used to restrict competition but that overall, they
were beneficial for international commerce because they provided price and service
stability in ocean shipping. They also were seen as a necessary device to protect
small shippers against large shippers who could extract rate discounts from carriers.
The Shipping Act of 1916 legitimized conferences, exempting them from U.S.
antitrust laws. However, the act also established ground rules for conference
activities in U.S. trade lanes. The act created the U.S. Shipping Board, a predecessor
to today’s FMC, to regulate the activities of the conferences. The act required that
conferences serving the U.S. trade be “open,” meaning that they could not restrict
new carriers from joining as “closed” conferences did. The act also required that
conference rate agreements be approved by the Shipping Board. “Fighting ships” and
“deferred rebates” were outlawed. The sanctioning of liner conferences in the
context of government control has become the foundation of present-day regulation.
The Shipping Act of 1916 represented a compromise between the United States’
general desire for free enterprise and a recognition that the rest of the world generally
condoned shipping conferences.
Much of the 1916 Act pertained to promoting a national merchant fleet rather
than for regulating the foreign trades. At the time of its passage, it was the provisions
providing promotional authority to enlarge a U.S.-owned liner fleet that were
19 Public No. 260 (64th Congress), 39 Stat. 728, 46 U.S.C. App. §§ 801 et seq.

CRS-7
considered the most important provisions in the act. The Shipping Board was given
promotional duties in addition to regulatory powers. Later, in 1961, these functions
were divided between the present day Maritime Administration (promotional duties)
and the FMC (regulatory duties).
The 1961 Amendments20
After the 1916 Act, conferences began the practice of offering “dual-rate
contracts” which offered discounts (usually 15 %) to shippers that promised to ship
a certain amount of their cargo with them. Unlike the outlawed “deferred rebates”
described above, this discount was made available at the time the shipper paid the
freight bill. Non-conference carriers objected to these contracts and the U.S.
Supreme Court outlawed them in 1958, finding that their purpose was to stifle
competition.21 In 1961, Congress legislatively reversed the Supreme Court’s decision
with passage of what are commonly known as the 1961 Amendments. They required
that all ocean carriers file their tariffs with the FMC. While the 1961 Amendments
recognized the need for conferences and reaffirmed their immunity from U.S.
antitrust laws, it also streamlined the FMC and gave it more power to scrutinize liner
conferences.
The Shipping Act of 198422
Congress overhauled the 1916 Act with the Shipping Act of 1984. The
Shipping Act of 1984 was passed in the context of a move towards deregulation that
occurred in other modes of transportation in the late 1970s and early 1980s. The
Staggers Rail Act of 198023 and the Motor Carrier Act of 198024 helped to streamline
inland transport of shipping containers by allowing for through bills of lading and
cooperative agreements among intermodal carriers. The 1984 Shipping Act further
strengthened and clarified carriers’ antitrust immunity by providing that shippers
could not seek antitrust relief under the Clayton Antitrust Act for practices that
violated the Shipping Act. The 1984 Act was a response to court decisions that
reinterpreted the antitrust immunity provisions in the 1916 Act and actions by the
Department of Justice which resulted in significant fines against ocean carriers.
However, the 1984 Act weakened the cohesiveness of shipping conferences because
it allowed individual carriers within a conference to enter into individual service
contracts with shippers at lower rates than the conference rate. In exchange for the
lower rate, the shipper agreed to ship a certain amount of cargo during the life of the
contract (usually a year). These contracts had to be made public and the carrier had
to give the same offer to similarly situated shippers (i.e., “common carriage”). The
conference could not interfere with the independent actions taken by their member
carriers.
20 P.L. 87-346.
21 See Federal Maritime Board v. Isbrandtsen Co., 356 U.S. 481 (1958).
22 P.L. 98-237, 98 Stat. 67, 46 U.S.C. App. §§ 1701 et seq.
23 P.L. 96-448, 94 Stat. 1895.
24 P.L. 96-296, 94 Stat. 793.

CRS-8
In addition to allowing independent action by conference members, the 1984
Act included other provisions that gave carriers the flexibility to respond more
quickly to market changes. The act extended antitrust immunity to cover intermodal
through rates. Intermodal through rates include the price of inland carriage by truck,
rail, or a combination thereof for overland connections to and from final destinations
and origins. This feature expanded the carriers’ ability to offer “one-stop shopping”
to those customers seeking door-to-door (as opposed to merely port-to-port) service.
The 1984 Act also expedited the process for approving new or modified conference
agreements. It required that they become effective 45 days after being submitted
unless the FMC filed suit with the federal courts against the proposed agreement.
Previously, a conference filing did not become effective until the FMC approved it,
a process that could take years.
The Ocean Shipping Reform Act of 199825
The 1984 Act set up an Advisory Committee to study the effects of the act,
beginning five and one-half years after its enactment. The Advisory Committee
reported its findings to Congress in 1992,26 stimulating further legislative debate and
ultimately leading to the Ocean Shipping Reform Act of 1998 (OSRA).27 The intent
of OSRA was to expand the flexibility of carriers and shippers to tailor their
contractual relationships in a manner that best meets their needs. In contrast to the
1984 Act, a significant provision in the 1998 Act stated that contracts no longer had
to be made public and carriers did not have to offer the same rates to similarly
situated shippers. Thus, conferences lost the ability to enforce agreed-upon terms
among their members. Shippers were dissatisfied with the 1984 Act because
requiring service contracts to be made public had enabled the conference to police
its members. The act essentially represented a move away from “common carriage”
to one of “contract carriage.”28 About 95% of liner cargo now moves under a
confidential service contract, according to the container line shipping association.29
The 1984 and 1998 Acts undermined the influence of conferences. Since then,
conferences have become less relevant and to a large extent have been replaced with
more loosely structured “discussion groups” or “stabilization agreements.” These
discussion groups may include conference and non-conference carriers and are
supposed to be voluntary agreements on prices rather than binding arrangements.
Also undermining the influence of conferences has been the improved service
25 P.L. 105-258, 112 Stat. 1902.
26 U.S. Advisory Commission on Conferences in Ocean Shipping, Report to the President
and Congress of the Advisory Commission on Conferences in Ocean Shipping,
Washington,
D.C., April 10, 1992.
27 For further information, see Ira Lewis and David B. Vellenga, “The Ocean Shipping
Reform Act of 1998,” Transportation Journal, Summer 2000, p. 27.
28 Drew H.M. Stapleton and Soumen N. Ghosh, “The Ocean Shipping Reform Act: Practical
Implications for Both Buyers and Sellers,” 67 Journal of Transportation Law, Logistics, and
Policy
53 (Fall 1999).
29 Statement of Stanley Sher, World Shipping Council, before the Antitrust Modernization
Commission, October 18, 2006, p. 2.

CRS-9
performance of independent (non-conference) carriers. Historically, independents
competed with conference carriers by offering lower rates, but it was recognized that
their service may not be as reliable. More recently, that perception of lower service
quality has been erased.
The focus of rate discussions may be the “base rate” for ocean transport, but
more often, as mentioned earlier, the focus is on ancillary surcharges such as
“container repositioning charge,” “peak-season surcharge,” or “general rate
increases” (GRI), among others. These surcharges are resented by shipper groups
and are usually the focus of their opposition to antitrust immunity because they are
generally not included in the fixed terms of a contract. Whether or not member
carriers of a discussion agreement actually charge their customers these surcharges
is highly dependent on market conditions and the potential volume of cargo a given
shipper has to offer a carrier. The rate established by the discussion agreement
typically serves as a benchmark from which a discount is negotiated between carrier
and shipper.
Legislative Activity Since OSRA
In the 106th Congress, Representative Henry J. Hyde, then Chairman of the
House Judiciary Committee, introduced the Free Market Antitrust Immunity Reform
Act of 1999 (FAIR Act, H.R. 3138). The FAIR Act was reintroduced in the 107th
Congress (H.R. 1253) by Hyde’s successor as Chairman of the Judiciary Committee,
Representative F. James Sensenbrenner, Jr. and the committee held a hearing on June
5, 2002. These bills were not acted upon by their respective committees and no bills
regarding liner shipping antitrust immunity were introduced in the 108th and 109th
Congresses, nor as of yet, the 110th Congress. The last reauthorization of the FMC
(P.L. 108-293, §§ 501-502, which authorizes the FMC through the end of FY2008)
does not address the issue of antitrust immunity.
The House Transportation and Infrastructure Committee, Subcommittee on
Coast Guard and Maritime Transportation held a hearing on May 3, 2000 to review
the effect of OSRA on ocean shipping. In the 110th Congress, the same committee
held a hearing on the FMC and the regulation of international liner shipping on June
19, 2008.
Liner shipping antitrust immunity was one of the subjects studied by the
Antitrust Modernization Commission (AMC) which was established by Congress in
P.L. 107-273. The AMC held a hearing on ocean antitrust immunity in October
2006. While its final report to Congress does not make any specific recommendation
to repeal ocean antitrust immunity, it does appear highly skeptical of the need for the
continued existence of such immunity. Some of the commissioners, in separate
statements, called for a repeal.30 The FMC also testified before the AMC, with the
Chairman testifying in support of continued antitrust immunity and describing
current shipper — carrier relations as “relatively harmonious.” One FMC
30 Reports, transcripts, and testimonies of the AMC are available on its website at
[http://www.amc.gov].

CRS-10
Commissioner submitted a separate statement calling for repeal of antitrust
immunity.
Asian and European Approaches
to Liner Conferences
Relative to the United States, most countries have taken a laissez faire approach
to liner conferences — that is, they have allowed them to exist without much
government intervention. However, Europe’s recent change in course on this issue
has spurred debate among Asian nations about the merits of shipping conferences.
A 2002 OECD report calling for the repeal of antitrust immunity has also stimulated
debate on this issue.31
Europe
The European Commission’s Regulation 4056/86, enacted in 1986, had granted
liner carriers a block exemption from Europe’s competition laws allowing shipping
conferences to continue on trade routes to and from Europe. Unlike the United
States, however, the exemption did not include inland transportation. The EU
repealed the exemption from competition law in September 2006 (EC Regulation
1419/2006) and this repeal will come into effect on October 18, 2008. The coming
repeal of the antitrust exemption will prohibit carriers from engaging in collective
rate setting and discussing capacity utilization in detail, but carriers will be allowed
to continue vessel-sharing agreements and other “efficiency-enhancing” operational
agreements.32 Shippers do not oppose vessel-sharing agreements.
Asia
The Asian Shippers Council (ASC) has been pushing for repeal of antitrust
immunity among Asian nations but with mixed success. The chairman of this
council notes that different Asian countries have different dominant roles in liner
service, which partly explains the respective position of these countries with respect
to liner conferences.33 China and India are net users of liner services, Japan is a net
provider of liner services, and Hong Kong and Singapore are primarily facilitators
of liner services. The focal point over rate-setting practices in Asia has been the
assessment of terminal handling charges that were instituted by the liner carriers
starting in 2001.
China. Chinese maritime regulations are under the jurisdiction of the Ministry
of Commerce which allows collective agreements among shipping lines. However,
31 OECD, Competition Policy in Liner Shipping, April 16, 2002.
32 “Antitrust: Commission Adopts Guidelines on Application of Competition Rules to
Maritime Transport Services,” IP/08/1063, July 1, 2008. The guidelines are available at
[http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/antitrust/legislation/maritime/].
33 “Final Front is Asia,” American Shipper, November 2007, pp. 6-10.

CRS-11
in March 2007, China’s Ministry of Communication issued a requirement that
shipping lines first discuss any proposed rate increases with their customers and that
they file their conference and discussion agreements with the Ministry fifteen days
before they become effective, raising speculation that the government will be
scrutinizing the liner conferences more closely.34 Moreover, China passed a
competition law in August 2007 that came into force in August 2008. The new law
does not exempt liner conferences from the law’s antitrust provisions.35 According
to one report, the ASC is ready to go to court if this new law does not take
precedence over Chinese maritime regulations.36 Thus, Chinese policy appears to be
in flux, but it is not clear as of yet what the exact implications will be for liner
carriers calling at Chinese ports.
India. India is also purportedly moving in the direction of outlawing collective
rate-setting. The Competition Commission of India (CCI), created by a law passed
in 2002 but whose actions have been delayed by litigation, appears to be in favor of
banning collective-rate setting and has advised India’s Ministry of Shipping to curb
the practice. However, India’s Ministry of Shipping appears to favor further
oversight of current shipping practices rather than an outright ban on conferences.37
The apparent conflict of interest has prompted a liner conference operating in this
trade route to request clarification.
Japan. Japan appears to favor the status quo — that is, allowing the
conference system to continue. Japan may prove to be a holdout for the conference
system due to the fact that large shippers are linked to large ocean carriers in Japan
through the keiretsu or “group system” of business organization.38 Also, Japan may
favor the carrier’s perspective because Japanese ocean carriers rely more on trade
outside Japan than they do on trade to or from Japan. As the ASC chairman stated,
“Japan will not want to let go of the maritime exemption. Why should it? The liners
get money substantially into the country.”39
Singapore and Hong Kong. Singapore and Hong Kong, like Japan, are also
home to major ocean carriers and are world rivals as container transfer hubs, but
neither are home to large producers or importers of liner cargo. Understandably, a
concern of the Hong Kong and Singapore governments is that they not be too far out
of step with the maritime regulatory regimes of the major trading nations using their
transport services. Hong Kong’s strong tradition for laissez faire policies may
explain its lack of a competition law, but it appears to be evaluating the need for a
34 “China’s Own FMC?” American Shipper, May 2007, p. 46.
35 “China’s Anti-trust Act to Outlaw Liner Conferences,” Lloyd’s List, September 18, 2007,
p. 1.
36 “Asian Shippers Ready To Go To Court Over Price-Fixing, ASC Says China’s Antitrust
Law Must Be Obeyed,” Lloyd’s List, August 20, 2008, p. 1.
37 “Asia’s Antitrust Revolution,” American Shipper, November 2007, pp. 10-12.
38 “Internal Struggle,” American Shipper, June 2007, pp. 50-55.
39 “Asia Confident of Liner-block Move; Region Expected to Follow in Footsteps of
European Repeal,” Lloyd’s List, September 20, 2007, p. 7.

CRS-12
competition policy in the liner sector. Hong Kong has lost some of its market share
to mainland Chinese ports, partly because of higher terminal handling charges that
are applied across the board by the shipping lines calling at Hong Kong. Singapore
granted a five year exemption for liner carriers from its new competition law that
came into effect on January 1, 2006. The Singapore Competition Commission stated
that “it was seeking to create a regulatory environment for shipping lines operating
through Singapore that was broadly aligned with that in other major jurisdictions.”40
Profile of U.S. Overseas Container Trade
Liner carriers sail on a defined trade route with regularly scheduled arrivals and
departures at designated ports. Today, liner carriers predominantly operate container
ships but car carriers (roll-on/roll-off vessels) also fall under this category. A marine
container is a large steel box that is used to consolidate cargo into a standardized
unit.41 Liner carriers load and unload containers at each scheduled port somewhat
like a city bus picking up and dropping off passengers at scheduled bus stops.
Because container ships typically call at three or four ports along a coast, ports with
a short access channel from the ocean are preferred over ports requiring a long transit
up a bay or river. Liner ships are distinguished from “tramp” vessels which typically
carry bulk commodities, such as grain, iron ore, or coal, sail wherever demand
dictates, and contract with the shipper on a per-voyage basis.
Although it was an American company that started the “container revolution”
in liner shipping, today almost all of U.S. foreign liner trade is carried by foreign-
owned carriers. Two large U.S.-based container lines were sold to foreign interests
in the late 1990s. In 1999, Sea-Land Service, the U.S. company that pioneered
container shipping in the late 1950s was sold to Maersk Lines, a Danish carrier. As
the name “Sea-Land” suggests, this company’s business model was capitalizing on
the easy transferability of containers from ships to trucks and railroads. The
container has now become synonymous with the term “intermodal” transportation.
In 1997, American President Lines (APL), a pioneer in the development of double-
stack container rail service in the mid-1980s, greatly improving the efficiency of
inland container transport, was sold to Neptune Orient Lines, a carrier controlled by
the Government of Singapore. In 2003, a new U.S.-based company tried to establish
a foothold in the trans-Pacific trade, reviving the name of a venerable predecessor,
United States Lines, but it was acquired by a French carrier in 2007. Table 1 lists the
top fifteen container carriers based on the TEU capacity of their fleet and the location
of their world headquarters.42 The virtual disappearance of the U.S. liner fleet raises
40 “Singapore Antitrust Immunity Stays for Liner Groupings,” The Business Times
Singapore,
October 5, 2006.
41 Standard sizes are 8x8x20 feet and 8x8x40 feet, but the 40-foot container, which is
roughly equivalent to a truck load, is the most commonly used. Containers are measured in
20-foot equivalent units, or TEUs. A 40-foot container is equal to two TEUs.
42 Journal of Commerce, July 23, 2007, p. 27, based on data as of July 12, 2007, from AXS-
Alphaliner.

CRS-13
the issue of whether the Shipping Act of 1984, which has a stated purpose of
promoting the U.S.-liner fleet, needs to be revisited.
Table 1. The Top 15 Container Lines by Size of Fleet
Ship Operator
Home Base
Market Share
1) A.P. Moller-Maersk
Copenhagen, Denmark
16.2%
2) Mediterranean Shipping
Geneva, Switzerland
10.5%
3) CMA CGM Group
Marseilles, France
7.6%
4) Evergreen Line
Taipei, Taiwan
5.1%
5) Hapag-Lloyd
Hamburg, Germany
4.0%
6) COSCO
Shanghai, China
3.8%
7) APL
Singapore
3.6%
8) China Shipping
Shanghai, China
3.4%
9) NYK Line
Tokyo, Japan
3.3%
10) Hanjin/Senator
Seoul, South Korea
3.0%
11) MOL
Tokyo, Japan
2.9%
12) OOCL
Hong Kong
2.8%
13) “K” Line
Tokyo, Japan
2.4%
14) Zim
Haifa, Israel
2.4%
15) Yang Ming
Keelung, Taiwan
2.3%
Source: Journal of Commerce, July 21, 2008, p. 15, based on data as of July 12,
2008, from AXS-Alphaliner.
While the United States is no longer a provider of ocean container services, it
is a large user of them. The United States is the second-largest maritime container
trading nation (after China), accounting for 11% of worldwide container traffic.43
This means that about one in every nine containers moving globally is bound to or
from the United States. U.S. container traffic nearly doubled over the past decade.44
The top five U.S. trading partners in maritime container trade are all Asian nations:
China, Japan, Taiwan, South Korea, and Hong Kong. China’s role in the U.S.
container trade is hard to overstate, as shown in Figure 1, which lists the top 10 U.S.
containerized cargo trading partners in 2007.
43 U.S. DOT, Bureau of Transportation Statistics, America’s Container Ports, Delivering
the Goods
, March 2007.
44 Ibid.


CRS-14
Figure 1. U.S. Waterborne Foreign Container Trade,
Top 10 Trading Partners in 2007
Source: U.S. Maritime Administration, based on PIERS database.
Compared to other types of waterborne cargo, such as bulk or break-bulk cargo,
containerized cargo has a higher value-to-weight ratio. While containerized cargo
accounts for only 20% of U.S. overseas waterborne tonnage, it accounts for about
55% of the total dollar value of U.S. overseas waterborne trade.45 Imports of
containerized cargo are dominated by consumer goods. The “box” ship has been
instrumental in the success of “big box” retailers such as Wal-Mart, Target, Home
Depot, Lowes, Costco, and Ikea which are among the top importers of containerized
cargo. Other leading importers include consumer goods producers such as Dole
Foods, Philips Electronics, Heineken, Canon, and Nike. Exports of containerized
cargo are dominated by wastepaper, forest products, chemicals, plastics, rubber,
agricultural commodities, and machinery. America Chung Nam (a wastepaper
exporter), Weyerhaeuser, DuPont, Cargill, Procter and Gamble, General Electric and
the competitors of these companies are the largest U.S. exporters of containerized
cargo.46 Automobile manufacturers are significant exporters and importers of
containerized cargo. Because U.S. containerized imports tend to be higher value
finished goods while U.S. containerized exports tend to be lower value primary or
intermediate goods, and because the United States imports about twice as many
containers as it exports, the dollar value of containerized imports is nearly three times
45 Calculation from Global Trade Information Services, Inc., World Trade Atlas, using 2007
trade data.
46 For a list of the top 100 importers and exporters of containerized cargo, see Journal of
Commerce,
vol. 2, issue 21, May 28, 2007, pp. 16A-24A and 40A-48A.

CRS-15
greater than that of exports while the tonnage of imports exceeds exports by over one
and one-half times.47
Directional Imbalances
The persistent U.S. merchandise trade deficit manifests itself in the container
trade. Over three times more containers are imported from Asia than are exported
to that region, while nearly two times more containers are imported from Europe than
are exported (see Table 2). Container trade with South America is more balanced
but it is of much smaller scale than trade with Asia and Europe.
Table 2. U.S. Containerized Trade Imbalance
(millions of TEUs)
Year
Asia to USA
USA to Asia
Europe to USA
USA to Europe
2005
12.4
4.4
3.8
2.1
2006
13.9
4.6
3.9
2.3
2007(forecast)
14.8
5.0
3.9
2.4
Source: UNCTAD, Review of Maritime Transport, 2007, p. 74.
As a result of the imbalance, outbound rates to Asia and Europe have been
consistently much lower than inbound rates. Outbound rates for “dry” containers
(non-refrigerated) may merely reflect the variable costs of moving a container back
to Asia or Europe, since the container would otherwise be returned empty. Figure
2
shows the market average freight rate for 2006 and the first two quarters of 2007
for trade routes to and from Asia and Europe.
47 Calculation from Global Trade Information Services, Inc., World Trade Atlas, using 2007
trade data.


CRS-16
Figure 2. Container Ship Freight Rates
Source: UNCTAD, Review of Maritime Transport, 2007, p. 73.
Recent Shift in Trade Flows
The recent decline of the U.S. dollar has significantly dampened the once
burgeoning Asia to North America liner trade. In this trade lane, trade volume
increased by 10% in 2006, 2.2% in 2007, but is expected to decrease 7.1% in 2008.48
As a result of the slowdown in 2007, shipowners shifted vessels from this trade lane
to the more robust Asia to Europe trade, which grew 19.9% in 2007. But a softening
in this trade lane is also now occurring and is forecasted to increase by 9.9% in
2008.49 On the outbound side, North America to Asia container trade grew by 5.3%
in 2006, 12.7% in 2007, and is forecast to increase 21.6% in 2008.50 In addition to
the decline of the dollar, rising standards of living in China and India are believed to
be fueling U.S. export growth to Asia. Despite this shift in trade growth from
inbound to outbound, export volumes to Asia are still only about a third of import
volumes from Asia.51
While the U.S. dollar’s decline has started a possible revival of the long-time,
non-remunerative U.S. outbound trade, the import market still dominates shipowner
decisions about where to deploy vessel space. Even though the current demand for
outbound vessel space is raising outbound rates, they must increase substantially to
48 Global Insight, “Trends in World Economics and Trade,” vol. 2, June 2008, pp. 2 and 26.
49 Ibid. p. 25, and “Slo-Mo in Europe; Special Report: Asia - Europe Shipping,” Journal of
Commerce,
August 11, 2008, pp. 13-16.
50 Ibid. p. 26.
51 UNCTAD, Review of Maritime Transport, 2007, p. 74.

CRS-17
approach inbound rates and attract vessels to the trade. As one shipping line
executive stated,52
The problem isn’t boxes. If I suddenly got 10 times more equipment in North
America, exporters might get boxes, but they’re not going to get more space on
ships. The problem is vessel capacity, and the capacity is what it is because the
inbound market has turned negative in terms of growth.
In other words, carrier capacity is driven by the more lucrative import market, and
export volume alone does not presently justify investment in new services.
In the smaller trans-Atlantic market, however, the eastbound market (U.S. to
Europe) is expected to be larger than the westbound market (Europe to the U.S.) In
2008 for the first time since 1996.53 In 2008, North America to Europe container
volume is expected to increase 11.1% while trade going the other way is expected to
decrease 3.7%.54 If current trends continue, the traditional back-haul to Europe could
become what carriers call the “head-haul,” or the route that drives the business, and
carriers would begin to design their services around the eastbound leg rather than the
westbound leg. However, at least one carrier executive does not think this will
happen in the near term, stating “The true definition of a head-haul is the leg that
pays the underlying cost of the trade, and we’re not there yet. We still need a
significant increase in eastbound rates or a significant decrease in westbound rates
to get there.”55
From a liner carrier’s perspective, a number of factors limit the profitability of
U.S. export cargo. U.S. export cargo generally is of lower value than import cargo
because export cargo tends to be primary or intermediate goods while import cargo
tends to be finished, consumer goods. Higher value cargo can bear a higher transport
rate. During periods of peak demand on the import leg, carriers may even consider
returning some containers empty, even if payloads are available, because empty
containers can be turned around faster overseas than loaded containers.
Because current export cargoes are generally heavier than import cargoes, an
outbound container ship cannot carry as many loaded containers as an inbound ship.
An outbound vessel may reach its load line with only 70% of its container slots filled.
Draft limitations in the Panama Canal further restrict the load capacity of certain
classes of ships bound to Asia from U.S. east coast ports.56 The reduced capacity of
outbound ships reduces the revenue generated by these voyages. Another inhibitor
in the profitability of U.S. export cargo is empty container repositioning costs. In the
52 Ron Widdows, CEO of APL, as quoted in Journal of Commerce, “Searching for
Solutions,” pp. 11-13.
53 “Too Much, Too Soon,” Journal of Commerce, July 30, 2008.
54 Global Insight, “Trends in World Economics and Trade,” vol. 2, June 2008, p. 27.
55 “Going With The Flow: Surging Exports Bring Trans-Atlantic Trade Into Balance —
Almost,” Journal of Commerce, August 18, 2008, p. 27.
56 “Unchartered Waters; Costs, Strong Exports Complicate This Year’s Trans-Pacific Peak
Season,” Journal of Commerce, June 30, 2008, p. 14.

CRS-18
United States, import containers are primarily destined for cities while exports tend
to originate in agricultural production areas. The cost of repositioning containers
from import unloading centers to export loading centers is generally covered in the
import rate since this has traditionally been the “head-haul” leg. In Asia, empty
containers are repositioned on feeder vessels from Southeast Asia to China. This is
because while China is the dominant point of origin of U.S. imports from Asia, U.S.
exports to Asia are slightly more dispersed, and include exports to India, Indonesia,
and Southeast Asia.
The persistent merchandise trade imbalance is a double-edged sword for U.S.
exporters. Because of it, they ship at below cost, yet it also means that they are
dependent on the import market for the supply of shipping space. Exporters are
facing an empty container shortage because there is a shortage of import shipments
to subsidize container repositioning costs.
Two developments could increase the revenue generated by U.S. export cargo
for container carriers. With rising standards of living in China and India, meat
products could become an increasingly important revenue source for liner carriers.
Frozen or chilled meat products are a higher margin cargo for container carriers.
Secondly, if the relative weakness in the value of the U.S. dollar were to persist over
the long term, higher value manufactured goods, like machinery parts, could become
a more significant part of the export mix.
Rising fuel costs have led to speculation as to how the current geography of
trade might change. Containerization, by lowering transport costs, is credited as
being as influential as free trade agreements in spurring overseas trade growth in
recent decades. For instance, it is estimated that the cost of shipping a pair of
sneakers from Asia amounts to as little as 26 cents in a $50 pair of shoes.57
Reportedly, fuel now accounts for about 50% to 60% of the total cost of operating
a vessel.58 To save on fuel, container ships have begun “slow steaming,” reducing
cruising speed from 24 to 25 knots to 19 or 20 knots. However, because of “soaring
oil costs,” according to one trade observer, “the explosion in global transport costs
has effectively offset all the trade liberalization efforts of the last three decades,” and
current “transport costs are equivalent to an average tariff rate of more than 9%.”59
While labor cost differentials are still a significant factor in U.S. trade with China and
Southeast Asia, there is some speculation that some production for the U.S. market
could shift from there to Mexico to save on transport costs.60 A similar development
could occur with respect to Europe, China, and eastern Europe.61 Asia to North
57 “Opposing Views Emerge on Liner Shipping,” The Business Times Singapore, June 11,
2008.
58 “Uncharted Waters; Costs, Strong Exports Complicate This Year’s Trans-Pacific Peak
Season,” Journal of Commerce, June 30, 2008, p. 14.
59 Jeff Rubin and Benjamin Tal, CIBC World Markets, Inc. “Will Soaring Transport Costs
Reverse Globalization?” May 27, 2008.
60 Ibid.
61 “Slo-Mo in Europe; Special Report: Asia - Europe Shipping,” Journal of Commerce,
(continued...)

CRS-19
America and Asia to Europe are the two largest container trade routes, by far. The
effect of higher fuel costs on trade will depend on the value of the goods being
traded. Containerized cargoes exhibit a wide range of cargo values.
Stakeholder Views
Some impartial observers argue that the issue of antitrust immunity is somewhat
moot because the rise of independent (non-conference) carriers and the advent of
confidential contracts has significantly diminished the pricing power carriers once
enjoyed. Some believe that since OSRA, market forces, not carriers, essentially
dictate freight rates. Other observers, while acknowledging that the influence of
conferences has certainly declined, contend that the emergence of discussion groups,
which include rate discussions between conference and independent carriers, means
that price collusion has extended to a larger group of carriers, giving carriers more
market power.
Liner Carriers. Shipowners and other defenders of antitrust immunity argue
that immunity is needed to keep rates from falling so low that carriers are forced into
bankruptcy, leaving cargo stranded at docks, and creating an uncertain and chaotic
environment for ocean-borne commerce. They believe repealing antitrust immunity
would result in greater potential for monopolistic behavior because the number of
carriers would dwindle due to bankruptcies. Currently, in terms of container ship
capacity, the top five container lines have a combined market share of 43%, the top
ten have a market share of 61%, and the top twenty have a market share of 83%.62
They believe the carriers most likely to prevail would not necessarily be the most
efficient ones but the ones that receive the most government support. They argue that
price collusion acts as an artificial stabilizer, ensuring a reliable and predictable
market for ocean shipping services. They view antitrust immunity as a necessary
price for maintaining scheduled services.
Moreover, carriers argue that their “efficiency-enhancing agreements” allow
them to pass on operational cost savings to the shippers in the form of lower rates.
They argue that these arrangements have increased competition in the market because
they make it easier for carriers to enter into additional trade lanes. By allowing
carriers to share ship space rather than independently deploying their own ships, the
cost of entering into new markets is lower. They argue that a repeal of the exemption
could encourage shipowners to return to the use of smaller vessels as VSAs decline,
thus losing the economies of scale that larger vessels allow. These types of
agreements are not contested by shippers and their supporters.
Ports. Marine terminal operators are also exempted from antitrust immunity.
They argue that they must be able to discuss rate and service issues in order to assess
surcharges to finance security related improvements in ports, allocate labor among
61 (...continued)
August 11, 2008, pp. 13-16.
62 “Special Report: Container Shipping,” Journal of Commerce, July 21, 2008, p. 15.

CRS-20
the various terminals in a port, implement clean air initiatives, and reduce truck
congestion at ports.
Shippers. Some shippers and other opponents of antitrust immunity argue that
immunity allows carriers to charge higher rates, especially when supply is tight, than
shippers would otherwise have to pay. They contend that price fixing arrangements
protect the least efficient members of carrier conferences or discussion groups
because prices are set so that all members will achieve some level of profitability.
For this reason, they argue, antitrust immunity is a contributing factor to the chronic
oversupply problems. By keeping prices artificially high, carriers are driven to over-
invest in capacity and have less incentive to innovate and operate more efficiently.
While they acknowledge that repealing antitrust exemption may cause some short-
term instability, over the long-term, they believe the most efficient carriers will
survive, resulting in lower rates. Rather than having carriers fix prices among
themselves, shippers argue that the solution to rate volatility is for carriers to fix
prices with their customers by means of time-volume service contracts.
Shippers also contend that the claim by shipowners that their protection from
antitrust laws is warranted because of the unique characteristics of their industry is
not a valid argument. Shippers contend that railroads, air carriers, and pipeline
carriers also have high fixed costs, provide regularly scheduled service, and
experience seasonal and directional imbalances in cargo flow, but do not require
collective price setting in order to prosper.
Port Truckers. Drayage carriers (truckers that “dray” shipping containers
between the port and shipper or between the port and rail terminus) also oppose
ocean antitrust immunity because they believe it gives ocean carriers an unfair
advantage in negotiating rates and service parameters.
Issues for Congress
Congress could decide to follow the EU’s lead and repeal antitrust immunity or
it could take a “wait-and-see” approach to observe any positive or negative effects
that the repeal may have on the European liner trade. Both shippers and carriers
generally believe that a repeal would likely result in lower freight rates, but also
greater rate volatility with higher peaks and lower troughs.63 In addition to the lowest
possible transport cost, importers and exporters seek some amount of rate stability
for the same reason they seek stable exchange rates. Traders seek some assurance as
to future market conditions in order to guide investment decisions.
If antitrust immunity were to be repealed, in the short run, one could expect rate
wars to ensue, with some carriers unable to survive. Over the long term, carrier
consolidation could reduce their costs and shippers believe that service quality will
improve. Deregulation of the airline, railroad, and trucking industries may provide,
more or less, some insights into a further deregulated liner industry. According to
63 “Continental Drift: End of Conferences in Europe May Produce More Volatility in Rates
and Surcharges,” Journal of Commerce, July 14, 2008, pp. 10-13.

CRS-21
most observers, some market turmoil in the short run can be expected, but there is far
less consensus as to the long run outcome.

One rationale for granting antitrust immunity to liner carriers is that other
nations did the same and thus doing otherwise would put U.S. firms at a
disadvantage, due to the international nature of the shipping business. In the case of
Europe’s decision to ban conferences, this argument can now be made in reverse. If
repeal of antitrust immunity leads to lower rates in the European trades, then
Congress might consider whether carriers would attempt to recoup their revenue
losses in other trade lanes, such as the U.S. trans-Pacific. The largest carriers today
participate in all the major trade routes.
Beyond evaluating the commercial effects of repealing antitrust immunity,
Congress may reconsider the objectives of U.S. liner shipping policy. The following
four objectives are stated in current law:64
! to establish a nondiscriminatory regulatory process for the common
carriage of goods by water in the foreign commerce of the United
States with a minimum of government intervention and regulatory
costs;
! to provide an efficient and economic transportation system in the
ocean commerce of the United States that is, insofar as possible, in
harmony with, and responsive to, international shipping practices;
! to encourage the development of an economically sound and
efficient United States-flag liner fleet capable of meeting national
security needs; and
! to promote the growth and development of United States exports
through competitive and efficient ocean transportation and by
placing a greater reliance on the marketplace.
The first three of these objectives were established by the Shipping Act of 1984 while
the fourth objective was added with the Ocean Shipping Reform Act of 1998.
In the past, U.S. liner policy sought to balance the interest of shippers with an
interest in preserving the U.S. liner fleet for national security purposes. The virtual
disappearance of the U.S. liner fleet in foreign trade raises the issue whether the
interests of shippers should be given greater weight in shaping policy. Since
continuing antitrust immunity appears to have had no effect in preserving a U.S. liner
fleet, it would seem incapable of aiding in the re-establishment of a U.S. fleet. Other
policy instruments, such as direct subsidies, could be more effective, but even these
have had little success in the face of competition from “flag of convenience” nations
and lower cost foreign suppliers, whether their lower cost is due to comparative
advantages or larger government subsidies.
National security issues aside, Congress might consider whether the United
States needs a U.S. liner fleet to protect its commercial interests. As identified
earlier, there is a strong correlation between the home base of the world’s leading
64 46 U.S.C. App. 1701.

CRS-22
container ship operators and economies that are highly dependent on their export
industries. These nations may feel compelled to protect their liner fleets so that they
can have some influence over their terms of trade. For instance, Japanese automobile
manufacturers do not rely on Korean shipping lines to reach their overseas markets,
nor do rival Korean automobile manufacturers rely on Japanese shipping lines. On
the other hand, Weyerhaeuser, the second-largest U.S. exporter of containerized
cargo, owns a liner carrier — Westwood Shipping, but it is contemplating the sale
of this line.65 As overseas merchandise trade continues to grow in importance to the
U.S. economy (from 14.3% of GDP in 1984 to 22.7% in 2007),66 policymakers may
consider whether fleet nationality is a relevant consideration. The ratio of goods
exports to goods GDP (the proportion of GDP produced by the goods sectors) rose
from 15% in 1970 to 43% in 2000.67 Yet containerized exports account for only 21%
of the tonnage of U.S. waterborne exports.68 Dry and liquid bulk shipping, carrying
grain and energy products, dominates outbound tonnage. Measured in dollar value,
air cargo is the leading mode for U.S. overseas exports, carrying lighter and much
higher-value products compared to ships. International trade brings about increased
specialization, and thus the nation’s imports look different than its exports and
require different conveyances for efficient transport.
In addition to balancing the interests of carriers and shippers, policymakers
might consider the interests of both exporters and importers. As indicated above, one
purpose of current policy is to promote U.S. exports but makes no mention of
imports. While exports increase producer income and create jobs, imports increase
consumer income by lowering prices. Between 1997 and 2004, for instance, the real
price of audio equipment decreased by 26%, TV sets by 51%, toys by 34%, and
clothing by 9%, all goods imported in containers.69 Policymakers may consider
whether promoting both imports and exports are not equally legitimate goals of U.S.
shipping policy. Given the large disparity in volume and total dollar value of import
versus export containerized cargo, policymakers might consider which is producing
the greatest income effect for the U.S. economy.
65 “Weyerhaeuser Considers Sale of Westwood Shipping,” Pacific Shipper, June 9, 2008,
n.p.
66 Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Economic Accounts, Table 1.1.10. Percentage
Shares of GDP.
67 U.S. Bureau of Transportation Statistics, U.S. International Trade and Freight
Transportation Trends
, 2003, p. 14.
68 U.S. Maritime Administration, U.S. Water Transportation Statistical Snapshot, May 2008,
p. 1.
69 Economic Report of the President, February 2006, p. 156.