An Overview of the Corporate Income Tax
April 24, 2023
System
Mark P. Keightley
This report presents information and research on the U.S. corporate income tax to help
Specialist in Economics
policymakers understand and evaluate policies to modify it. The structure of the corporate tax can
influence the performance of the economy, impact fairness in the overall tax system, and have
Donald J. Marples
important administrative consequences. At least two specific policy areas of interest pertaining to
Specialist in Public Finance
the corporate tax appear to be relevant in the current environment. The first involves concern,
expressed by some, over recent deficits and the growing national debt. The corporate tax could be
one tool to raise revenues and address these concerns. The second concerns the global push for
increased international tax coordination led by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD) and G20, which have developed a multilateral framework to address base erosion and profit shifting
agreed to by 142 countries (including the United States) as of December 2022. Implementing certain provisions in the
multilateral framework may affect U.S. corporate tax revenue, employment, and investment.
The corporate income tax generally applies only to C corporations. These corporations—named for Subchapter C of the
Internal Revenue Code, which details their tax treatment—are treated as taxable entities separate from their shareholders.
That is, corporate income is first taxed at the corporate level according to the corporate income tax system. When
shareholders receive corporate dividend payments or realize capital gains from the sale of shares, that income is taxed again
at the individual shareholder level according to the individual tax system. In contrast, noncorporate businesses—including S
corporations, partnerships, and sole proprietorships—pass their income through to their owners, who pay taxes on that
income. Collectively, noncorporate business entities are referred to as “pass-throughs.” For these types of entities, business
income is generally taxed only once, at individual income tax rates.
Corporate income is subject to a flat statutory tax rate of 21%. Before 2018, there was a graduated rate structure, with a
maximum statutory corporate tax rate of 35%. The corporate tax rate alone does not determine how much corporations pay in
taxes. Because of a number of business tax benefits, including general business expenses and certain special deductions and
credits known as tax expenditures, the effective (or actual) tax rate paid by corporations is typically less than the statutory
rate. In 2023, corporate tax expenditures are estimated to result in $164.2 billion of forgone federal tax revenue. In
comparison, individual tax expenditures are estimated to result in over nine and a half times more revenue loss ($1.6 trillion)
to the federal government than corporate tax expenditures.
Relative to the size of the economy and as a share of total revenues, corporate taxes today are less than they were in the years
following World War II. The corporate tax reached its post-World War II era peak in 1952 at 5.9% of gross domestic product
(GDP). In 2021 (the most recent year that is not an estimate), the corporate tax generated revenue equal to approximately
1.7% of GDP. The corporate tax has also decreased in significance relative to other revenue sources. At its post-WWII peak
in 1952, the corporate tax generated 32.1% of all federal tax revenue. In that same year, the individual income tax accounted
for 42.2% of federal revenue and payroll taxes accounted for 9.7% of revenue. In 2021, the corporate tax accounted for 9.2%
of federal tax revenue, whereas the individual and payroll taxes generated 50.5% and 32.5%, respectively. However,
corporate tax revenues are projected to increase modestly in the coming years.
Corporate tax revenues as a percentage of GDP in the United States are below the average of all OECD member countries. In
2020 (most recent data year), the average OECD member collected corporate taxes equal to 2.8% of GDP, while the United
States collected revenues equal to about 1.3% of GDP. Corporate tax receipts in the United States have been below the
OECD average since 1982.
Congressional Research Service
link to page 4 link to page 5 link to page 6 link to page 7 link to page 9 link to page 10 link to page 11 link to page 11 link to page 12 link to page 14 link to page 14 link to page 15 link to page 17 link to page 17 link to page 19 link to page 21 link to page 23 link to page 8 link to page 11 link to page 13 link to page 9 link to page 10 link to page 10 link to page 12 link to page 12 link to page 17 link to page 19 link to page 20 link to page 20 link to page 24
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
Contents
Structure of the Corporate Income Tax ........................................................................................... 1
Corporate Taxable Income ........................................................................................................ 2
Corporate Tax Rates .................................................................................................................. 3
Corporate Tax Expenditures ...................................................................................................... 4
Taxation of Corporate Shareholders .......................................................................................... 6
Corporate Income Tax Revenues ..................................................................................................... 7
International Comparisons............................................................................................................... 8
Tax Rates ................................................................................................................................... 8
Tax Revenues ............................................................................................................................ 9
Economic Considerations ............................................................................................................... 11
Why Have a Corporate Income Tax? ....................................................................................... 11
Corporate Tax Incidence ......................................................................................................... 12
Evaluating the Corporate Income Tax ..................................................................................... 14
Equity ................................................................................................................................ 14
Efficiency .......................................................................................................................... 16
Administrative Simplicity ................................................................................................. 18
Concluding Remarks ..................................................................................................................... 20
Figures
Figure 1. Individual and Corporate Tax Expenditures in FY2023 .................................................. 5
Figure 2. Corporate Tax Revenue as a Percentage of GDP, 1946-2027 .......................................... 8
Figure 3. Corporate Tax Revenue as a Percentage of GDP in 1965-2020 ..................................... 10
Tables
Table 1. Five Largest Corporate Tax Expenditures in FY2023 ....................................................... 6
Table 2. Tax Rates on Capital Gains and Qualified Dividends: Taxable Income Ranges,
2023 .............................................................................................................................................. 7
Table 3. Corporate Tax Rates: Comparing the United States to the Rest of the OECD,
2021 .............................................................................................................................................. 9
Table 4. CBO’s Distribution of Corporate Income Tax ................................................................. 14
Table 5. Treasury’s Distribution of Corporate Income Tax ........................................................... 16
Table 6. Marginal Effective Tax Rates for Debt- and Equity-Financed Investment, 32%
Debt Share .................................................................................................................................. 17
Contacts
Author Information ........................................................................................................................ 21
Congressional Research Service
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
his report presents information and research on the U.S. corporate income tax to help
policymakers understand and evaluate policies to modify it.
Many of the topics and ideas
T discussed here are analyzed in greater detail in the other CRS reports and academic
research referenced throughout. This report first reviews the structure of the corporate income tax.
Next, the report presents and analyzes data on which companies pay the corporate tax, how much
revenue the tax generates, and how the U.S. system compares to the rest of the world. Finally, the
report reviews the economic effects of the corporate tax—including a discussion of the tax’s
purpose, who bears its burden, and how to evaluate alternative corporate tax systems.
Structure of the Corporate Income Tax
The corporate income tax generally applies only to C corporations (also known as regular
corporations).1 These corporations—named for Subchapter C of the Internal Revenue Code
(IRC), which details their tax treatment—are treated as taxable entities separate from their
shareholders.2 That is, corporate income is taxed once at the corporate level according to the
corporate income tax system. When shareholders receive corporate dividend payments or realize
capital gains from the sale of shares, that income is taxed again at the individual shareholder level
according to the individual tax system.3 In contrast, noncorporate businesses—including S
corporations, partnerships, and sole proprietorships—pass their income through to their owners,
who pay taxes on that income.4 Collectively, noncorporate business entities are referred to as
“pass-throughs.” For these types of entities, business income is generally taxed only once, at
individual income tax rates.
Taxes are one factor that influences the decision whether to organize as a C corporation or a pass-
through, but other factors also influence the choice of organizational form. C corporations can be
more administratively complex and financially costly to operate since they require a board of
directors and are subject to more stringent recordingkeeping and reporting requirements. For
example, C corporations under the oversight of the Securities and Exchange Commission
(SEC)—that is, publicly traded corporations—must file comprehensive and publicly available
1 Stock repurchases by publicly traded C corporations may also be subject to a 1% tax put in place by the law
commonly referred to as the Inflation Reduction Act of 2022 (P.L. 117-169 ). Since the tax is an excise tax—that is, a
tax on a specific item (repurchased stock)—it is not part of the corporate
income tax. For more information, see CRS
Report R47397,
The 1% Excise Tax on Stock Repurchases (Buybacks), by Jane G. Gravelle.
2 For more information, see CRS Report R43104,
A Brief Overview of Business Types and Their Tax Treatment, by
Mark P. Keightley.
3 This treatment leads to the so-called “double taxation” of corporate profits. However, since a large share of corporate
equity is held in tax-exempt or foreign accounts, only a portion of corporate income is subject to double taxation in
practice. For more, see Leonard E. Burman, Kimberly A. Clausing, and Lydia Austin, “Is U.S. Corporate Income
Double Taxed?”
National Tax Journal, vol. 70, no. 3 (September 2017), pp. 675-706.
4 An S corporation is a closely held corporation that elects to be treated as a pass-through entity for tax purposes. S
corporations are named for Subchapter S of the IRC, which details their tax treatment. By electing S corporation status,
a business is able to combine many of the legal and business advantages of a C corporation with the tax advantages of a
partnership. A partnership is a joint venture consisting of at least two partners organized to operate a trade or business
with each partner sharing profits, losses, deductions, credits, and the like. A partner is an investor in such an entity and
may be an individual, a trust, a partnership, a corporation, another entity (such as a limited liability company), or a
broker that is holding the ownership interest of an unnamed partner. Corporations and partnerships are established
under the individual laws of each state, although their tax treatment at the federal level is determined by the Internal
Revenue Code (IRC). The most common partnerships include general partnerships, limited liability partnerships,
limited partnerships, publicly traded partnerships, and electing large partnerships. For more information, see CRS
Report R43104,
A Brief Overview of Business Types and Their Tax Treatment, by Mark P. Keightley.
Congressional Research Service
1
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
financial reports. This is in contrast to privately held pass-through businesses.5 At the same time,
the C corporation form allows a business to take advantage of a number of benefits not available
with other forms of organization. Specifically, a C corporation is not limited in the number of
shareholders it may have, the classes of stocks it may issue, the types of shareholders it may have,
or the citizenship of its shareholders.6 Shares of C corporation stock are also traded on well-
developed exchanges, which allows ownership interests to be transferred readily and at low
transaction costs. As a result, C corporations have the ability to raise capital globally from a
variety of investors. Still, with the increase in private equity financing, businesses are able to tap
into capital markets without necessarily “going public” as C corporations. Additionally, some
owners may never see the need to go public when launching a new business and prefer a pass-
through structure.
Taxation of Pass-Through Businesses
Businesses that choose an organizational form other than a C corporation are, in general, not subject to the
corporate income tax. Instead, the income of these businesses passes through to their owners and is taxed
according to individual income tax rates. Examples of these alternative “pass-through” forms of organization
include sole proprietorships, partnerships, subchapter S corporations, and limited liability companies (LLCs). LLCs
are the creation of individual state statutes, and are not addressed in the federal tax code. For purposes of federal
tax treatment, an LLC is treated, by default, as either a partnership (if it has at least two members) or a
“disregarded entity” (if it has a single member) that is taxed as a sole proprietor. Alternatively, an LLC may elect
to be treated as a C corporation for federal tax purposes. For more information on pass-through taxation, see
CRS Report R43104,
A Brief Overview of Business Types and Their Tax Treatment, by Mark P. Keightley.
The corporate income tax is designed as a tax on corporate profits (also known as net income).
Broadly defined, corporate profit is total income minus the cost associated with generating that
income.
The corporate income tax also allows for a number of other special deductions, credits,
and tax preferences. Oftentimes, these provisions are intended to promote particular policy goals
as they reduce the taxes corporations owe if they engage in certain activities.
A corporation’s tax liability calculation can be generalized as:
Taxes = [(Total Income – Deductions) × Tax Rate] – Tax Credits
This summary calculation hides the fact that the corporate tax system becomes increasingly
complex as one examines its details. The following sections discuss some of the more
fundamental features of the tax system.
Corporate Taxable Income
A corporation’s taxable income generally is its total income less allowable deductions. Gross
income is income derived from any source, including gross profit from the sale of goods and
services to customers, rents, royalties, most interest, dividends, gains from the sale of business
and investment assets, plus other sources of income.
Corporate income subject to tax also includes income earned from foreign operations. Foreign
income earned directly by U.S. companies is treated the same as income earned domestically.
Foreign income earned through related legal entities (referred to as controlled foreign
5 A C corporation can also be privately held and not be subject to SEC oversight. That is, its stock is not traded on a
public stock exchange. These are smaller corporations that are outside the common perception of a C corporation.
There are also publicly traded partnerships, which, by default, are treated as C corporations for tax purposes unless
certain criteria are met.
6 This is in contrast to the S corporations, which are limited to offering one class of share and limited in the types of
citizenship of their shareholders.
Congressional Research Service
2
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
corporations [CFCs] in tax jargon) may be taxed in the year earned in some circumstances, while
other foreign income is not. Specifically, certain types of passive or easily shifted income are
taxed under what is referred to as Subpart F. Other foreign income of related corporations is taxed
under global intangible low-taxed income (GILTI) provisions. GILTI is a measure of income
earned by foreign subsidiaries of U.S. companies (i.e., CFCs) after an exclusion for returns on
tangible assets. GILTI is included in income in the year earned after a 50% deduction—resulting
in GILTI being taxed at a lower effective tax rate than domestic profits.7 A similar treatment
applies to intangible income earned abroad from assets held in the United States under the foreign
derived intangible income (FDII) provision. Income eligible for FDII treatment is based on the
share of exports and a proportionate exclusion for returns on tangible investments. FDII is
included in income in the year earned after a 37.5% deduction—resulting in FDII income also
being taxed at a lower effective tax rate than domestic profits.8 Dividends from CFCs, as well as
dividends received by corporations owning at least 10% of the shares of a foreign corporation, are
exempt through a 100% dividends-received deduction. Credits are allowed for all or part of taxes
paid to foreign governments.
Some types of business expenses are deductible in the year incurred. These deductions include
ordinary and necessary business expenditures (e.g., wages and salaries, employee benefit
programs, and repairs), write-offs for bad debts, taxes (other than federal income taxes), and
advertising expenses. Interest paid is also deductible in the year incurred, but subject to
limitations.
Other types of business expenses are deductible over several years. These types of expenses
support the purchase or development of physical or intangible assets that are expected to help
produce income over multiple years. These expenses are recovered over time through
depreciation, amortization, or depletion rules defined in statute. Some investments can
temporarily be recovered more quickly than under general rules through expensing (bonus
depreciation).9
In the event these deductions exceed gross income, a net operating loss (“NOL”) deduction may
be allowed in other years. A NOL is limited to 80% of taxable income with excess NOLs carried
forward to be deducted in future years.10
Corporate Tax Rates
Corporate income is subject to a flat tax rate of 21%.11 Before 2018, there was a graduated rate
structure, with a maximum statutory corporate tax rate of 35%. The graduated rate structure was
intended to benefit smaller corporations, encouraging some small firms to incorporate to take
7 For taxable years beginning after December 31, 2025, the GILTI deduction will be reduced to 37.5%.
8 For taxable years beginning after December 31, 2025, the FDII deduction will be reduced to 21.875%.
9 For property placed in service before January 1, 2023, full or 100% expensing was allowed. Assets placed in service
during 2023 are eligible for expensing of 80% of the value of the asset. The percentage allowed to be expensed will be
60% in 2024, 40% in 2025, 20% in 2026, and zero in 2027 and beyond.
10 NOLs generated in 2018, 2019, 2020 could temporarily be carried back (used to reduce prior year taxable income) up
to five years and those losses could fully offset taxable income. For more information on net operating losses, see CRS
Report R46377,
The Tax Treatment and Economics of Net Operating Losses, by Mark P. Keightley.
11 Before 2018, most corporate income was subject to a 35% statutory tax rate. To generate this flat rate, which applied
to the largest businesses, income was taxed at rates that varied from 15% on the first $50,000 of income to 35% on
income over $18,333,333. Corporations providing services in the fields of health care, law, engineering, architecture,
accounting, actuarial science, the performing arts, and consulting were taxed at a fixed rate of 35%, regardless of their
amount of taxable income.
Congressional Research Service
3
link to page 8
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
advantage of scenarios where paying corporate taxes is less costly than paying according to the
individual tax system.12
The corporate tax rate alone does not determine how much corporations pay in taxes. Because of
a number of business tax benefits, including the deductions discussed above and credits discussed
below, the
effective (or actual) tax rate paid by corporations is typically less than the statutory
rate. Effective tax rates can vary substantially across U.S. corporations, even within the same
industry. For example, some corporations rely more on debt financing (i.e., borrowing money and
paying it back with interest), which the tax code treats more favorably than equity financing (i.e.,
selling a portion of a company’s ownership to raise capital), resulting in lower effective rates.
Some corporations and industries rely on certain physical assets that can be depreciated (“written
off”) more quickly than investments made by companies in other industries, which again leads to
differing effective tax rates. Corporations and industries with more extensive overseas operations
or income may pay lower effective U.S. tax rates through GILTI and FDII (discussed above).
Similar in purpose to Subpart F and interest limitations (discussed above), the base erosion and
anti-abuse tax (BEAT) is intended to reduce incentives to shift income to low-tax jurisdictions.
Unlike Subpart F, BEAT is aimed not at including certain income but at taxing excess
deductions—by imposing a minimum tax equal to 10% of the sum of taxable income and base
erosion payments. BEAT applies only to large corporations (with gross receipts greater than $500
million averaged over three years), and because BEAT is effectively a lower tax rate on a broader
base, it will not apply to all taxpayers who have related-party payments.
In addition, a corporate alternative minimum tax (CAMT) of 15% is levied on the adjusted
financial statement income of large corporations.13 The CAMT applies to public and private
corporations. Corporations pay the larger of the minimum tax or the regular tax, which is imposed
at a 21% rate and includes any additional tax from BEAT. The CAMT applies to taxable years
beginning after December 31, 2022.
Corporate Tax Expenditures
A variety of corporate tax incentives known formally as tax expenditures exist to encourage
certain types of behaviors and to assist certain industries or the corporate sector more generally.
Tax expenditures include special credits, deductions, exemptions, exclusions, and tax rates that
depart from what economists consider a “comprehensive” taxation of income.14 Tax expenditures
typically result in a revenue loss, although there are some that increase revenue.15 Tax
expenditures are not exclusive to the corporate tax system. In fact, individual tax expenditures are
estimated to result in over nine and a half times more revenue loss to the federal government than
corporate tax expenditures (
see Figure 1), while the individual income tax collects about six
12 For more information on benefits for small businesses in the corporate tax system, see CRS Report RL32254,
Small
Business Tax Benefits: Current Law and Main Arguments For and Against Them, by Gary Guenther.
13 For more information on the corporate alternative minimum tax, see CRS Report R47328,
The 15% Corporate
Alternative Minimum Tax, by Jane G. Gravelle.
14 The Budget Control Act of 1974 (P.L. 93-344) officially defines a tax expenditure as “revenue losses attributable to
provisions of the Federal tax laws which allow a special exclusion, exemption, or deduction from gross income or
which provide a special credit, a preferential rate of tax, or a deferral of tax liability.” The Joint Committee on Taxation
(JCT) generally produces an estimate of most individual and corporate tax expenditures each year. The latest tax
expenditure estimates are available at http://www.jct.gov/. There is debate among economists about the specifics of
what a system that taxes income in a “comprehensive” manner would look like, but the consensus is that it is one that
taxes income as computed in a broad and theoretical economic sense.
15 Two examples of tax expenditures that raise revenue are the limits on deducting net operating losses and net interest.
Congressional Research Service
4
link to page 9 link to page 9
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
times the amount of revenue. The individual tax expenditures include those benefiting pass-
through businesses, which are not subject to the corporate income tax.
Figure 1. Individual and Corporate Tax Expenditures in FY2023
Billions of Dollars
Source: CRS calculations using estimates in U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation,
Estimates of Federal
Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2022-2026, committee print, prepared by Joint Committee on Taxation, 117th
Cong., December 22, 2022, JCX-22-22.
Note: Totals do not include tax expenditures of less than $50 mil ion (annually). The JCT does not provide
estimates in these cases. Additionally, the sum of the tax expenditure estimates may not equal the total value of
tax expenditures because of interaction effects. Tax expenditure estimates are projections of foregone revenue
(or revenue cost) associated with various tax provisions and thus do not reflect actual revenue loss.
Table 1 lists the five largest corporate tax expenditure provisions in FY2023.16 The estimated sum
of all corporate tax expenditures in FY2023 is $162.4 billion, 78.3% ($127.1 billion) of which is
attributed to the five largest tax expenditures.17 The largest corporate tax expenditure in 2023 is
the reduced tax rate on the active income of controlled foreign corporations, with an estimated
revenue loss of $45.1 billion.18 The four next largest expenditures are accelerated and bonus
16 The values of three tax expenditures listed in
Table 1 are scheduled to fall over time due to scheduled changes
stemming from P.L. 115-97, sometimes referred to as the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 (TCJA). The 50% deduction
allowed under GILTI will be reduced to 37.5% for tax years starting after 2025. This will lower the tax expenditure
estimate for the reduced tax rate on active income of controlled foreign corporations. The full and immediate expensing
(100% bonus depreciation) for equipment is reduced by 20% per year for four years starting in 2023. And the 37.5%
deduction for foreign-derived intangible income will be reduced to 21.875% for tax years starting after 2025.
17 The sum of all corporate tax expenditures is calculated using the estimates provided in U.S. Congress, Joint
Committee on Taxation,
Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2022-2026, committee print, prepared
by Joint Committee on Taxation, 117th Cong., December 22, 2022, JCX-22-22.
18 For additional background, see CRS Report R45186,
Issues in International Corporate Taxation: The 2017 Revision
(P.L. 115-97), by Jane G. Gravelle and Donald J. Marples, and the entry for “Reduced Tax Rate on Active Income of
Congressional Research Service
5
link to page 9
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
depreciation ($38.5 billion), the credit for research and development expenses ($17.0 billion), the
deduction for the foreign-derived intangible income of U.S. multinational corporations ($14.9
billion), and the low-income housing tax credit ($11.6 billion).19
Table 1. Five Largest Corporate Tax Expenditures in FY2023
Billions of Dollars
Corporate Tax Expenditure
Estimated Revenue Loss in in FY2023
Reduced tax rate on active income of control ed
$45.1
foreign corporations
Depreciation of equipment in excess of the
$38.5
alternative depreciation system
Credit for increasing research activities
$17.0
Deduction for foreign-derived intangible income
$14.9
from trade or business within the United States
Credit for low-income housing
$11.6
Five Largest Corporate Tax Expenditures
$127.1
All Corporate Tax Expenditures
$162.4
Source: CRS analysis using estimates in U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation,
Estimates of Federal Tax
Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2022-2026, committee print, prepared by Joint Committee on Taxation, 117th Cong.,
December 22, 2022, JCX-22-22.
Notes: The sum of the tax expenditure estimates may not equal the total value of tax expenditures because of
interaction effects. Tax expenditure estimates are projections of foregone revenue (or revenue cost) associated
with various tax provisions and thus do not reflect actual revenue loss. Columns may not sum due to rounding.
Table 1 does not show a tax provision that occasionally garners attention: the foreign tax credit.
The income of U.S. corporations with overseas operations is potentially subject to taxation in the
country where it is earned. Additionally, income earned abroad may be subject to U.S. taxation
depending on how the income is classified. U.S. corporations may be eligible for a tax credit
equal to foreign taxes paid (up to a limit) to prevent double taxation. The JCT does not consider
this credit, known as the foreign tax credit, a tax expenditure.
Taxation of Corporate Shareholders
In addition to being taxed under the corporate income tax, after-tax corporate profits are typically
subject to tax again when taxable shareholders realize capital gains or receive dividend
distributions. Net long-term capital gains—or gains recognized from the sale of assets (e.g.,
Controlled Foreign Corporations” in U.S. Congress, Senate Committee on the Budget,
Tax Expenditures: Compendium
of Background Material on Individual Provisions—A Committee Print Prepared for the Senate Committee on the
Budget, 2022, committee print, prepared by Congressional Research Service, 117th Cong., 2nd sess., 2022. That entry
states that the tax expenditure for the reduced tax rate on active income of controlled foreign corporations “measures
the difference between taxing all income of CFCs at full rates (allowing foreign tax credits) and the current taxes which
are reduced due to GILTI deductions and the GILTI foreign tax credit rules.”
19 For more on these tax expenditures, see CRS Report RL31852,
The Section 179 and Section 168(k) Expensing
Allowances: Current Law and Economic Effects, by Gary Guenther; CRS Report RL31181,
Federal Research Tax
Credit: Current Law and Policy Issues, by Gary Guenther; CRS Report R45186,
Issues in International Corporate
Taxation: The 2017 Revision (P.L. 115-97), by Jane G. Gravelle and Donald J. Marples; CRS Report RS22389,
An
Introduction to the Low-Income Housing Tax Credit, by Mark P. Keightley; and CRS Report RL31181,
Federal
Research Tax Credit: Current Law and Policy Issues, by Gary Guenther.
Congressional Research Service
6
link to page 10 link to page 11
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
corporate stock) held for more than a year less any losses—are taxed at rates that are generally
lower than the rates applied to individuals’ ordinary incom
e (Table 2).20 Qualified dividend
income is taxed using the same tax rates that apply to capital gains.21 Under current law, the tax
rate on capital gains and dividends is 0%, 15%, or 20% depending on a taxpayer’s taxable
income.
Table 2. Tax Rates on Capital Gains and Qualified Dividends: Taxable Income Ranges,
2023
Married filing Jointly
Head of Household
Single
0%
$0 - $89,250
$0 - $59,750
$0 - $44,625
15%
$89,251 - $553,850
$59,751 - $523,050
$44,626 - $492,300
20%
$553,851+
$523,051+
$492,301+
Source: Internal Revenue Code §1(h).
Income from capital gains and dividends may also be subject to a net investment income tax.22
Since 2013, a 3.8% tax is imposed on the lesser of (1) net investment income; or (2) the excess of
modified adjusted gross income (MAGI) above a threshold amount. This threshold amount is
$250,000 for taxpayers filing a joint return, $200,000 for single filers, and $125,000 for married
filers filing separately.
Corporate Income Tax Revenues
Relative to the size of the economy and as a share of total revenues, corporate taxes today are less
than they were in the years following World War II. The corporate tax reached its post-World War
II era peak in 1952 at 5.9% of gross domestic product (GDP) (se
e Figure 2). In 2021 (the most
recent year that is not an estimate), the corporate tax generated revenue equal to approximately
1.7% of GDP. The corporate tax has also decreased in significance relative to other revenue
sources over time. At its post-WWII peak in 1952, the corporate tax generated 32.1% of all
federal tax revenue. In that same year, the individual tax accounted for 42.2% of federal revenue
and payroll taxes accounted for 9.7% of revenue.23 In 2021, the corporate tax accounted for 9.2%
of federal tax revenue, whereas the individual and payroll taxes generated 50.5% and 32.5%,
respectively.24
20 For individual income tax rates by taxable income level, see CRS Report RL34498,
Federal Individual Income Tax
Brackets, Standard Deduction, and Personal Exemption: 1988 to 2023, by Gary Guenther. The tax rate on the gain
from investments held less than a year (short-term capital gains) is equal to the taxpayer’s ordinary income tax rate.
21 Qualified dividends include those received by an individual from a domestic corporation or a qualified foreign
corporation, where the holding period requirement is satisfied.
22 For more information, see CRS In Focus IF11820,
The 3.8% Net Investment Income Tax: Overview, Data, and
Policy Options, by Mark P. Keightley.
23 For more information on the various components of the U.S. tax system, see CRS Report R45145,
Overview of the
Federal Tax System in 2022, by Molly F. Sherlock and Donald J. Marples; and CRS Report R47062,
Payroll Taxes: An
Overview of Taxes Imposed and Past Payroll Tax Relief, by Anthony A. Cilluffo and Molly F. Sherlock.
24 Data on the percent of revenue by source comes from the Office of Management and Budget, Table 2.2,
https://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/historical-tables/.
Congressional Research Service
7
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
Figure 2. Corporate Tax Revenue as a Percentage of GDP, 1946-2027
Source: CRS graphic based on data from Office of Management and Budget, FY2023 Budget, Historical Tables,
Table 2.2 and Table 2.3, https://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/historical-tables.
Notes: Data for years 2022 to 2027 are estimates.
Several factors help explain declines in the significance of the corporate tax over the post-WWII
period.25 First, the average effective corporate tax rate has decreased over time, mostly because of
reductions in the statutory rate and changes affecting the tax treatment of investment and capital
recovery (depreciation). Second, the increasing fraction of business activity conducted by pass-
throughs (particularly partnerships and S corporations) has led to an erosion of the corporate tax
base.26 In recent years, corporate tax revenues have fluctuated with changes in economic
conditions and changes in corporate tax policy.
International Comparisons
Tax Rates
Comparing U.S. corporate tax rates with those of other countries may help policymakers
understand how the U.S. tax system affects corporate decisionmaking. Non-economists tend to
25 For a more detailed analysis of declining corporate tax revenues, see CRS Report R42113,
Reasons for the Decline in
Corporate Tax Revenues, by Mark P. Keightley.
26 For more on the effects on international profit shifting, see CRS Report R40623,
Tax Havens: International Tax
Avoidance and Evasion, by Jane G. Gravelle; CRS Report R47003,
Corporate Income Taxation in a Global Economy,
by Jane G. Gravelle, Mark P. Keightley, and Donald J. Marples; Kimberly A. Clausing, “The Revenue Effects of
Multinational Firm Income Shifting,”
Tax Notes, March 28, 2011, pp. 1580-1586; Kimberly A. Clausing,
“Multinational Firm Tax Avoidance and Tax Policy,”
National Tax Journal, vol. 62 (December 2009), pp. 703-725;
Martin A. Sullivan, “U.S. Multinationals Shifting Profits Out of the United States,”
Tax Notes, March 10, 2008, p.
1078-1082; and Martin A. Sullivan, “Shifting of Profits Offshore Costs U.S. Treasury $10 Billion or More,”
Tax Notes,
September 27, 2004, pp. 1477-1481.
Congressional Research Service
8
link to page 12 link to page 12 link to page 13
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
focus on comparing statutory rates. Economists, however, generally prefer to examine effective
tax rates when making international comparisons because every country has a different tax
system, and the statutory tax rate is just one component. For example, some countries may have
higher or lower rates, allow for faster capital recovery (i.e., deprecation), or offer corporate tax
credits not available in other countries. Effective tax rates attempt to account for all the system
differences and are more indicative of the tax burden in each country.
When making comparisons between U.S. and worldwide tax rates, it is also important to indicate
whether tax rates are simple (unweighted) averages or are adjusted (weighted) to account for the
size of the economies being compared. If the U.S. tax rate is compared to world tax rates that do
not account for the size of other economies, then a small economy, such as Iceland, can have the
same effect on the average international rate as a large economy, such as Germany or Japan. It is
therefore more contextually appropriate to compare the U.S. tax rate to a weighted average of
international tax rates to understand where the U.S. tax system stands in a global economic
context. Typically, each country’s tax rate is weighted by its gross domestic product (GDP) when
computing the average.
Table 3 compares the statutory tax rate and the weighted effective marginal rate in the United
States to the remainder of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD) and G7 countries,27 showing that the U.S. statutory tax rate is near the weighted OECD
average and below the weighted G7 average.28
Table 3 also shows that the tax rate most relevant
for investment decisions—the weighted effective marginal rate—is lower in the United States
than in other OECD and G7 countries. The OECD and G7 countries, however, exclude several
large economies, in particular China and Brazil.29
Table 3. Corporate Tax Rates: Comparing the United States
to the Rest of the OECD, 2021
United States
Non-U.S. Weighted
Non-U.S. Weighted
Tax Rate Measure
OECD Average
G7 Average
Statutory Tax Rate
25.8%
25.7%
26.9%
Effective Marginal Tax Rate
(EMTR)
-2.7%
5.7%
1.9%
Source: CRS calculations based on
various OECD statistics, https://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=
CTS_CIT, downloaded March 3, 2023.
Note: Tax rates include corporate taxes at both the national and subnational level. Negative effective tax rates
reflect a net subsidy delivered through the tax code.
Tax Revenues
Corporate tax revenues as a percentage of GDP in the United States are below the average of all
OECD member countries
. Figure 3 displays the average corporate tax revenues for OECD
27 The effective marginal tax rate (EMTR) is a forward-looking measure that summarizes tax-based incentives to invest
in certain types of assets. The EMTR combines the statutory tax rate with other features of the tax code (e.g., tax credits
and the timing of depreciation deductions).
28 The unweighted OECD average statutory tax rate is 2.6 percentage points lower than the U.S. statutory tax rate, and
the unweighted G7 average statutory rate is 0.6 percentage points higher.
29 OECD members are generally countries with advanced economies. The OECD works closely with other large
economies that are less economically advanced. For more information on current OECD members, see
http://www.oecd.org/about/membersandpartners/. The G7 is an informal grouping of seven of the world’s largest
advanced economies, including Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States.
Congressional Research Service
9
link to page 11
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
member countries and the United States as a percentage of GDP from 1965 through 2020. In
2020, the average OECD member collected corporate taxes equal to 2.8% of GDP, while the
United States collected revenues equal to about 1.3% of GDP. Corporate tax receipts in the
United States have been below the OECD average since 1982.
Figure 3. Corporate Tax Revenue as a Percentage of GDP in 1965-2020
OECD Member Countries
Source: OECD Tax on Corporate Profits, https://data.oecd.org/tax/tax-on-corporate-profits.htm, downloaded
April 14, 2022.
Note: Tax on corporate profits includes taxes levied by all levels of government.
There are several reasons why the United States collects less in federal corporate tax revenue than
other countries. For example, a
s Figure 2 shows, corporate tax revenues in the United States have
generally declined since WWII, and that decline appears to have accelerated after 2017. At the
same time, corporate tax revenues in other OECD countries (particularly European countries)
have remained relatively stable even in the face of declining tax rates.30 Some countries have
adopted base-broadening policies to offset tax rate decreases, typically in the form of reduced
investment credits, less generous loss offset rules, and limitations on interest deductibility and
depreciation.31 Recent research also suggests that there has been a shift from the noncorporate to
the corporate sector in some countries, and that in other countries limited liability outside the
corporate form is not available, making it more attractive to shift to a corporate form.32
Combined, these factors appear to explain why corporate tax rates have fallen elsewhere while
revenues have held steady.
30 Ruud A. DeMooij and Gaetan Nicodeme,
Corporate Tax Policy, Entrepreneurship and Incorporation in the EU,
European Commission, Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs, no. 263, January 2007, p. 6,
http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/publication808_en.pdf.
31 Ibid.,
p. 13.
32 U.S. Department of the Treasury,
Treasury Conference on Business Taxation and Global Competitiveness:
Background Paper, July 23, 2007, p. 18, https://home.treasury.gov/system/files/136/archive-documents/07230-r.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
10
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
Economic Considerations
Why Have a Corporate Income Tax?
Economists and policymakers have offered a variety of reasons supporting the existence of a
corporate tax since the enactment of the Corporate Tax Act of 1909 (P.L. 61-4). To avoid
constitutionality issues, Congress initially structured the tax as an excise tax on the privilege of
doing business in the corporate form (i.e., limited liability and access to capital markets).33 While
the new corporate income tax was challenged by several corporations that claimed it to be
unconstitutional, the Supreme Court accepted its rationale and ruled that the privilege of doing
business in the corporate form could be measured by profits.34 The privilege-based rationale for
the corporate tax is generally not accepted by economists today. Economists tend to view the risk-
sharing from limited liability and pooling of financial capital to finance investment in productive
physical capital to be beneficial to the economy.
A more generally accepted rationale for the corporate tax is that it ensures the income tax system
is comprehensive. Absent a corporate income tax, corporate earnings would not be taxed until
they were paid out to individuals. Thus, corporations would have an incentive to avoid taxes by
retaining earnings. Shareholders would avoid taxes so long as corporations did not pay out
earnings. Further, shareholders would benefit when corporations retained earnings over long
periods of time, as delaying payouts would reduce the present value of the tax burden (assuming
no change in tax rates over time).35 Additionally, without a corporate tax there would be an
incentive for business owners and higher-income individuals to incorporate in order to reduce
taxes. Relatedly, without a corporate tax it could be difficult to collect tax on dividends and
capital gains earned by foreign shareholders. Thus, the corporate tax serves as a withholding tax
on foreign investors.
Some economists also support the corporate tax as a tax on economic rents.36 Economic rents,
also known as excess profits, are defined as profits greater than is
required by a corporation to
make an investment or engage in a line of business.37 If the corporate tax could be designed to tax
only excess profits, then it would not create economic distortions or induce efficiency losses
because firms would still be earning levels of profit that satisfied their required returns, thus
corporate output would be unchanged.38 In practice, excess profits are difficult to measure, and,
33 In 1895, the Supreme Court found that portions of an income tax enacted a year earlier were an unconstitutional
direct tax not apportioned among the states according to population. See
Pollock v. Farmers’ Loan and Trust Co, 157
U.S. 429 (1895). The individual income tax was enacted in 1913, following ratification of the Sixteenth Amendment
(Amendment XVI) to the U.S. Constitution, which allowed Congress to levy a tax on income, regardless of source,
without apportioning it among the states.
34 Joseph A. Pechman,
Federal Tax Policy, 4th ed. (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institute, 1983), p. 129.
35 Additionally, a significant share of gain is never taxed given the current structure of the estate tax system. Heirs, as
recipients of corporate stock, are not taxed on the decedent’s gain.
36 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD),
Fundamental Reform of Corporate Income Tax,
Tax Policy Studies, no. 16, November 2007, https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/fundamental-reform-of-corporate-
income-tax_9789264038127-en.
37 The term “excess profits” is being used here strictly in the economics textbook meaning of profits above which
would be expected in a perfectly competitive market. In a perfectly competitive market, firms earn zero economic
profits. Thus, excess profits correspond to positive economic profits.
38 A pure tax on profits would tax only economic profits, where economic profits are revenues less both accounting
costs and economic costs, such as the opportunity costs associated with a firm’s factors of production. The opportunity
cost of capital, for example, is the return the company could earn if it were employed in its highest return alternative
use.
Congressional Research Service
11
link to page 4 link to page 4
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
therefore, taxes are levied on accounting profits, as described above (see
“Structure of the
Corporate Income Tax ”). Therefore, the corporate tax as currently applied is not a tax on excess
profits or economic rents. Consequently, the corporate tax distorts economic decisionmaking,
which can reduce overall economic output.
The corporate tax can also be used to achieve distributional objectives. As discussed in the
following section, the traditional view of the corporate tax has been that it is primarily borne (or
eventually paid) by corporate shareholders in the form of lower after-tax returns. To the extent
corporate income, in the form of dividends and capital gains, accrues disproportionally to higher-
income individuals, the corporate tax can be adjusted to increase or decrease the progressivity of
the overall tax code.
Corporate Tax Incidence
Since corporations are legal entities (i.e., they exist only on paper), they cannot bear the ultimate
burden of taxes. Instead, the corporate tax must be passed along to individuals—including, to
varying degrees, owners of capital (corporate shareholders and bondholders, as well as
noncorporate business owners), corporate employees, and corporate customers. For example, the
tax can be passed along to these individuals in the form of lower dividends or capital gains
(corporate owners), reduced salaries and fringe benefits (employees), or higher prices
(customers). The literature, however, generally finds that the corporate tax is not passed along to
consumers.
The question of whether the corporate tax burden falls more heavily on capital or labor has been
the source of a great deal of theoretical and empirical research over the years, and continues
today. Traditional analysis of the corporate tax, in a closed economy, indicates that corporate
owners bear the burden of the corporate tax in the short run, and the owners of capital more
generally—across both the corporate and noncorporate sectors—bear it in the long run. The
burden of the corporate tax spreads to the noncorporate sector as the tax causes capital to flow to
the noncorporate sector, which, in turn, reduces the after-tax return to capital in that sector.39 In
contrast, a number of more recent theoretical studies find that labor bears the majority of the tax
burden in an open economy.40 The theoretical findings, however, appear to rely critically on
particular assumptions that drive the results, specifically highly mobile capital and highly
substitutable products. When these assumptions are relaxed, the burden of the corporate tax is
found to fall mostly on capital—in line with the traditional analysis. In recent years, a number of
economists have taken a statistical (empirical) approach to determine the incidence of the
corporate tax. While these studies tend to conclude that a substantial portion of the corporate tax
burden falls on labor, methodological limitations leave these results open to skepticism.41
Given the questions about recent empirical research, and the consistency of traditional theoretical
models, some economists have been reluctant to move away from traditional incidence
39 The traditional view on the incidence of the corporate tax originated with the development of the “Harberger model”
in 1962 and subsequent refinements. See Arnold Harberger, “The Incidence of the Corporate Tax,”
The Journal of
Political Economy, vol. 70 (June 1962), pp. 215-240.
40 A review and critique of recent theoretical research, as well as a discussion of the extensions of the Harberger model
can be found in Jennifer Gravelle, “Corporate Tax Incidence: A Review of General Equilibrium Estimates and
Analysis,”
National Tax Journal, vol. 66, no. 1 (March 2013), pp. 185-214.
41 These studies are reviewed in Jennifer Gravelle, “Corporate Tax Incidence: A Review of Empirical Estimates and
Analysis,” Congressional Budget Office, Working Paper 2011-01, Washington, DC, June 2011; and CRS Report
RL34229,
Corporate Tax Reform: Issues for Congress, by Jane G. Gravelle.
Congressional Research Service
12
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
assumptions, where owners of capital are assumed to bear most of the burden of the corporate
tax.42 Other economists tend to support the results showing the corporate tax burden falls
primarily on labor.43
Government agencies that analyze how the incidence of the corporate tax is distributed have
changed the assumptions they use to produce distribution tables over time. The Congressional
Budget Office (CBO) now assumes that 75% of the burden of the corporate income tax falls on
owners of capital, with the remaining 25% assigned to households in proportion to their labor
income.44 Prior to this change, CBO assumed that the entire burden of the corporate tax was
borne by owners of capital. Until 2008, the Department of the Treasury made a similar
assumption. In 2012, the Treasury reported that it changed its incidence assumption to allocate
82% of the corporate income tax burden to owners of capital and 18% to labor income.45 In 2013,
the Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT) explained that it also assumes the majority (75%) of the
corporate tax burden falls on owners of capital, with the remaining 25% falling on labor.46
Assumptions about the corporate tax incidence have important implications for policy analysis.
When analysis assumes that the entire burden of the corporate tax is borne by capital, revenue-
neutral changes in the tax burden do not change the distribution of the tax burden. This means
that base-broadening, rate-reducing tax reforms would not change how the tax burden is allocated
across households. For example, a corporate tax rate cut financed by decreased depreciation
deductions would not change the distribution of the corporate tax because the same people would
ultimately pay the tax. However, when analysis assumes that a portion of the corporate tax burden
falls on labor, changes in tax rates and changes in deductions that are revenue-neutral may change
how the tax burden is distributed. Rate cuts financed by reduced depreciation deduction
allowances, for example, would tend to reduce the progressivity of the corporate tax system when
part of the burden falls on labor.47
42 For further discussion, see Kimberly A. Clausing, “In Search of Corporate Tax Incidence,”
Tax Law Review, vol. 65,
no. 3 (Spring 2012), pp. 433-472.
43 For further discussion, see Stephin Entin, “Labor Bears Much of the Cost of the Corporate Tax,” Tax Foundation,
Special Report, no. 238 (October 2017), pp. 1-22.
44 CBO provides background information on the changes in corporate tax rate distribution assumptions in
Congressional Budget Office,
The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2008 and 2009, Washington,
DC, July 2012, pp. 13-15, http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/43373-
AverageTaxRates_screen.pdf.
45 Julie-Anne Cronin et al.,
Distributing the Corporate Income Tax: Revised U.S. Treasury Methodology, Office of Tax
Analysis, Department of the Treasury, Technical Paper 5, Washington, DC, May 2012. Part of the tax on capital is
allocated to owners of capital in general, with another portion allocated to capital earning economic rents.
46 The JCT is tasked with a slightly different challenge than CBO or Treasury: JCT must also estimate tax policy
changes and the associated distributional effects over a 10-year budget window. In the short-run, the JCT assumes that
100% of the burden of a corporate tax
change falls on the owners of capital, in line with the conventional economic
thinking. In the long-run, it assumes incidence distributions reported above. The concepts of the “short-run” and “long-
run” assist economists with understanding economic impacts over time and are not set time periods. For more on JCT’s
methodology, see U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation,
Modeling the Distribution of Tax on Business Income,
114th Cong., October 16, 2013, JCX-14-13. For an earlier discussion on estimating tax burdens, see U.S. Congress,
Joint Committee on Taxation,
Methodology and Issues in Measure Changes in the Distribution of Tax Burdens, 103rd
Cong., June 14, 1993, JCS-7-93. For a recent example of JCT estimates of the distributional effect of a corporate tax
change, see U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation,
Distributional Effects of P.L. 115-97, 116th Cong., March 27,
2019, JCX-10-19.
47 This result arises in part since rate changes are predicted to affect normal returns to capital and labor, and
supernormal returns to capital (i.e., returns in excess of the required rate of return). Changes in depreciation deductions
are predicted to affect normal returns to capital and labor. Because higher-income persons receive a disproportionate
share of the supernormal returns to capital, rate cuts provide a greater benefit to higher-income groups.
Congressional Research Service
13
link to page 17 link to page 17 link to page 17 link to page 17 link to page 18 link to page 18
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
Evaluating the Corporate Income Tax
The corporate income tax can be evaluated using three criteria that are well accepted by
economists: equity, efficiency, and administrative simplicity. These criteria can also help
policymakers evaluate proposed modifications to the current system. Equity examines how the
corporate tax burden is distributed across individuals, both of similar and different abilities to
bear the tax. Efficiency looks at whether resources are being directed to their most productive use
in the economy. The administrative simplicity criterion evaluates the corporate tax by the
compliance costs imposed on taxpayers by the tax system and the resources needed to administer
it. A fourth metric discussed in policy debates is “competitiveness.” Policymakers frequently note
that the U.S. tax system should be competitive. The precise definition of this concept, however, is
often unclear.
Equity
CBO periodically publishes statistics on the distribution of household income and federal taxes;
the most recent available estimates are for 2019.48 These estimates, a selected portion of which
are reproduced in
Table 4, provide insights into the distribution of the corporate tax across
incomes. Specifically
, Table 4 displays how household income, corporate income tax liabilities
(burden), and average corporate income tax rates vary across the income distribution. The upper
portion of
Table 4 breaks U.S. households into quintiles, or equal 20% groups, according to
household income. The lowest quintile represents the poorest 20% of households (accounting for
4.0% of household income) and the highest quintile represents the richest 20% of households
(accounting for 54.6% of household income). The lower portion of
Table 4 provides a more
detailed breakdown of the highest-income households.
According to CBO’s estimates, the corporate income tax is progressive—meaning its burden
increases with the taxpayer’s income. 49 For example, the average effective corporate tax rate for
those in the highest income quintile is 2.2%, whereas it is 0.5% for those in the lowest income
quintile. Providing further evidence of the corporate tax’s progressive nature, those in the top 1%
of the income distribution faced an average corporate tax rate of 4.2% in 2019. Additionally, CBO
estimates that households in the lowest quintile bore 1.4% of all corporate tax liabilities, while
those in the highest quintile bore 77.3%. The top 1% of households bore 43.9% of corporate
taxes.
Table 4. CBO’s Distribution of Corporate Income Tax
2019
Average
Share of
Share of
Corporate
Corporate
Household Income
Household
Income Tax
Income Tax
Groupa
Income
Rateb
Liabilities
Lowest Quintile
4.0%
0.5%
1.4%
Second Quintile
8.7%
0.6%
3.3%
Middle Quintile
13.6%
0.7%
6.0%
48 Congressional Budget Office,
The Distribution of Household Income, 2019, Washington, DC, November 2022,
https://www.cbo.gov/publication/58353.
49 Tax system progressivity is measured by the proportion of taxes paid by various income groups, relative to their
share of income received.
Congressional Research Service
14
link to page 18 link to page 18 link to page 19 link to page 15 link to page 17
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
Average
Share of
Share of
Corporate
Corporate
Household Income
Household
Income Tax
Income Tax
Groupa
Income
Rateb
Liabilities
Fourth Quintile
20.4%
0.8%
10.4%
Highest Quintile
54.6%
2.2%
77.3%
All Households
100.0%
1.5%
100.0%
91st to 95th
10.4%
1.2%
8.3%
Percentiles
96th to 99th
13.5%
1.8%
15.7%
Percentiles
Top 1%
15.9%
4.2%
43.9%
Source: Congressional Budget Office,
The Distribution of Household Income, 2019, November 2022,
https://www.cbo.gov/publication/58353, and the report’s data supplement.
Notes: For purposes of determining the distribution of corporate income tax liabilities and average corporate
tax rate, CBO assumes that workers bear 25% of the burden of the corporate income tax.
a. CBO’s definition of household income, or “income before transfers and taxes,” is market income plus social
insurance benefits. CBO defines market income as the sum of labor income, business income, capital
income (including capital gains), and income received in retirement for past services and nongovernment
sources of income. Social insurance benefits are the sum of benefits from Social Security, Medicare,
unemployment insurance, and workers’ compensation.
b. CBO computes average corporate tax rates as federal corporate taxes divided by income before transfers
and taxes.
The Treasury also publishes statistics on the distribution of household income and federal taxes,
the most recent of which are for 2023 and are presented i
n Table 5.50 However, the Treasury uses
a different measure of income (known as “cash income”) than CBO and, as was discussed in the
“Corporate Tax Incidence” section, allocates less of the corporate income tax burden to workers
than does CBO (18% vs 25%).51 Still, the story is the same: Treasury’s analysis finds that the
corporate income tax is progressive. The average corporate income tax rate for households in the
lowest quintile was 0.5% compared to 2.8% for those in the highest quintile and 5.2% for the top
1% of households. Treasury also estimates that households in the lowest quintile bore 0.6% of all
corporate tax liabilities, while those in the highest quintile bore 82.3% of corporate taxes. The top
1% of households bore 48.1% of corporate taxes.
50 See U.S. Department of the Treasury,
Distributional Analysis of the U.S. Tax System, https://home.treasury.gov/
policy-issues/tax-policy/office-of-tax-analysis.
51 For CBO’s definition of household income, see note a in
Table 4. Treasury explains in its analysis that “cash income
consists of wages and salaries, net income from a business or farm, taxable and tax-exempt interest, dividends, rental
income, realized capital gains, unrealized gains at death, cash and near-cash transfers from the government, retirement
benefits, and employer-provided health insurance (and other employer benefits). Employer contributions for payroll
taxes and the federal corporate income tax are added to place cash on a pre-tax basis.” See U.S. Department of the
Treasury, Distributional Analysis of the U.S. Tax System, 2019 Distribution of Income, https://home.treasury.gov/
policy-issues/tax-policy/office-of-tax-analysis.
Congressional Research Service
15
link to page 19 link to page 19 link to page 19 link to page 20
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
Table 5. Treasury’s Distribution of Corporate Income Tax
At 2023 Income Levels
Average
Share of
Corporate
Corporate
Cash Income
Share of Cash
Income Tax
Income Tax
Groupa
Income
Rateb
Liabilities
Lowest Quintile
2.6%
0.5%
0.6%
Second Quintile
6.7%
0.6%
1.9%
Middle Quintile
11.4%
0.8%
4.4%
Fourth Quintile
19.6%
1.1%
10.2%
Highest Quintile
60.2%
2.8%
82.3%
All Household
sc
100.0%
2.1%
100.0%
90th to 95th Percentiles
10.9%
1.6%
8.5%
95th to 99th Percentiles
15.0%
2.2%
16.0%
Top 1%
19.0%
5.2%
48.1%
Source: CRS analysis of U.S. Department of the Treasury,
Distributional Analysis of the U.S. Tax System, 2023
Distribution of Income, https://home.treasury.gov/policy-issues/tax-policy/office-of-tax-analysis.
Notes: For purposes of determining the distribution of corporate income tax liabilities and average corporate
tax rate, Treasury assumes that workers bear 18% of the burden of the corporate income tax.
a. Treasury notes in its analysis that “cash income consists of wages and salaries, net income from a business
or farm, taxable and tax-exempt interest, dividends, rental income, realized capital gains, unrealized gains at
death, cash and near-cash transfers from the government, retirement benefits, and employer-provided
health insurance (and other employer benefits). Employer contributions for payrol taxes and the federal
corporate income tax are added to place cash on a pre-tax basis.”
b. Treasury computes average corporate tax rates as total corporate tax burden for the income group divided
by cash income for the income group.
c. Based on Treasury’s data notes, households with negative incomes are excluded from the lowest quintile
but are included in the “All Households” line. Thus, the sum of the quintiles may not equal the “All
Households” line.
Efficiency
Economists look toward estimated effective tax rates across the economy to gain insight into the
efficiency impact of the corporate (and overall) tax system. If tax rates vary across investments
and activities, corporations could be making decisions based on taxes rather than on real
economic factors. Unless there is an economic policy rationale for using taxes to incentivize
certain corporate investments and activities (e.g., a market failure or distributional concerns),
differing tax rates can reduce economic efficiency. However, distilling the tax system’s efficiency
impact down to a single figure is difficult given the complexity of the tax system and various
factors that affect investment decisions. As a result, researchers are required to make certain
assumptions about temporary versus permanent tax provisions, financing sources, and type of
investment.
Along these lines
, Table 6 presents estimates for the marginal effective tax rates across various
corporate domestic investments made shortly after the enactment of P.L. 115-97, sometimes
referred to as the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 (TCJA). Estimates that account for temporary
Congressional Research Service
16
link to page 20
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
provisions and permanent provisions are presented separately. The estimates assume the
investments would be financed with 68% equity and 32% debt and do not incorporate
shareholder-level taxes. However, the exact mixture of debt and equity used to finance an
investment will alter these rates, which, in turn, raises economic efficiency concerns because the
U.S. corporate tax system contains a tax-induced bias toward debt financing. The primary factor
contributing to this bias is the fact that interest payments can be deducted (subject to a limit) from
income, while dividend payments cannot. Therefore, all else equal, the effective tax rate on a
given investment will fall the more debt financing is used.52
Table 6 shows that marginal effective tax rates can vary considerably depending on the
investment being made. For example, investments in nonresidential and residential structures face
marginal effective tax rates of 10.7% and 8.2%, respectively, whereas most other investments
face large
negative tax rates. The marginal effective tax rate also varies depending on whether one
considers the temporary provisions included in the TCJA that affect the cost recovery of
investment (i.e., expensing of equipment and research costs) or the permanent provisions in TCJA
(i.e., equipment and five-year amortization for research).53
Table 6. Marginal Effective Tax Rates for Debt- and Equity-Financed Investment, 32%
Debt Share
Post TCJA: Temporary
Post TCJA: Permanent
Asset
Provisions
Provisions
Equipment
-9.6%
5.4%
Public Utility Structures
-9.6%
5.8%
Nonresidential Structures
10.7%
10.7%
Residential Structures
8.2%
8.2%
Intangibles
Research
-95.4%
-52.2%
Advertising
-9.6%
-9.6%
Other
-9.6%
-9.6%
Total
-6.6%
1.8%
Source: CRS Report R45186,
Issues in International Corporate Taxation: The 2017 Revision (P.L. 115-97), by Jane G.
Gravelle and Donald J. Marples.
Some of the exemptions, credits, deductions, and other tax preferences in the U.S. tax system that
result in varying tax rates represent attempts to address instances where markets fail to maximize
economic efficiency. Take, for example, tax incentives for research and development (R&D)
related activities.54 R&D that leads to technological innovation is associated with positive
externalities (spillovers). That is, there are benefits to R&D that accrue to those not directly
involved in or paying for the research itself. Economic theory suggests that markets tend to
underinvest in activities that generate positive externalities. Thus, granting a tax subsidy for R&D
52 See Tables 1 and 2 in CRS Report R45186,
Issues in International Corporate Taxation: The 2017 Revision (P.L.
115-97), by Jane G. Gravelle and Donald J. Marples.
53 For more information on cost recovery, see CRS In Focus IF11187,
Tax Depreciation of Qualified Improvement
Property: Current Status and Legislative History, by Gary Guenther.
54 For background on tax incentives for R&D, see CRS Insight IN11887,
Tax Treatment of Research Expenses: Current
Law and Policy Issues, by Gary Guenther.
Congressional Research Service
17
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
could lead to additional R&D and improve overall economic efficiency by directing additional
economic resources to R&D-related activities.55
However, providing tax preferences that narrow the tax base may necessitate higher tax rates to
raise sufficient federal revenues over time. The potential for economic distortions caused by
higher marginal rates should be weighed against the potential efficiency gains associated with
various tax preferences to evaluate net efficiency gains. Tax preferences or tax expenditures that
narrow the tax base and that do not otherwise enhance economic efficiency can ultimately reduce
economic efficiency by requiring higher marginal rates over time.56
Removing certain provisions, such as accelerated depreciation, in exchange for reduced tax rates
will not necessarily improve economic efficiency. Slowing depreciation, and making depreciation
more neutral across different types of assets, could increase the cost of capital. Additionally,
modifying depreciation to be more neutral across assets while reducing the corporate tax rate
provides a windfall benefit to existing capital that was the result of investment decisions made
under the previous corporate tax rate. The burden on new investments increases from slower
depreciation, but all capital benefits from reduced tax rates.
The differential treatment of domestic and foreign-source income by U.S. multinational
corporations also raises concerns that their business decisions may be motivated by tax policy
rather than nontax business factors. If multinationals allocate real economic resources (i.e., capital
and labor) differently than they would under a neutral tax policy, current tax policy creates
economic inefficiencies, barring the existence of externalities. If, however, resource reallocation
in response to tax rate differentials is limited (i.e., there is limited capital mobility), then
efficiency losses may be small. A corporation’s decision of how to allocate real economic
resources, however, can be different from its decision of how to allocate its global profits to
minimize taxes. Even if real resource allocation is relatively unresponsive to tax differentials,
policymakers may still be concerned about profit shifting and the resulting loss in tax revenues.
Finally, the economic efficiency of the corporate tax depends on what is actually being taxed. If a
corporate tax can be designed such that the tax is levied only on economic profits (i.e.,
supernormal returns), the tax should not change firms’ output decisions in the short run, and thus
should have limited efficiency consequences. In practice, however, the corporate tax is not levied
on pure economic profits. In this sense, the corporate tax acts as a tax on capital, and could
discourage capital formation in the corporate sector.
Administrative Simplicity
Complexity in the tax code contributes to increased compliance costs as taxpayers are required to
devote more time and economic resources to tax preparation.57 Tax code compliance creates
inefficiencies to the extent that resources devoted to tax preparation are not available for other
55 The effectiveness of the research tax credit depends on whether the credit motivates additional research activity,
rather than simply rewards companies for engaging in research activity that would have taken place without a tax
credit. For more on this issue, see U.S. Government Accountability Office,
The Research Tax Credit’s Design and
Administration Can Be Improved, GAO-10-136, November 2009, http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d10136.pdf.
56 The government also has alternative revenue generating options, including taxes on individuals. If less revenue is
raised through the corporate tax system, the federal government may look to alternative revenue sources.
57 GAO estimated that the costs associated with tax compliance are roughly 1% of GDP. This estimate includes costs of
complying with individual as well as corporate income taxes. See U.S. Government Accountability Office,
Summary of
Estimates of the Costs of the Federal Tax System, GAO-05-878, August 2005, http://www.gao.gov/new.items/
d05878.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
18
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
productive activities. Further, complex tax systems may put certain taxpayers at a disadvantage,
as those with limited resources may not be able to claim all the tax benefits to which they are
legally entitled.58 Thus, complex tax systems may be viewed as unfair or inequitable. Tax code
complexity also increases administrative and enforcement costs. Simplifying the current tax
system could help reduce the tax gap.59
One general approach for accomplishing this would be to eliminate some or all tax expenditures.
To the extent that policymakers want to retain certain tax preferences, perhaps over efficiency
concerns, another approach could be to look for overlap or redundancy in the tax code. The
additional revenue generated from eliminating redundancies could be used to finance a reduction
in the corporate tax rate, which, along with a broader tax base, could improve economic
efficiency.
National Competitiveness
National competitiveness arguments are frequently put forth as a rationale to enact certain
corporate tax policies. It is less frequently asked whether competitiveness has meaning for the
country
as a whole. A competition involves two or more parties in a contest, and a contest implies
there will be a winner and loser(s), with the gains of the former exactly offsetting the losses of the
latter. A competition is therefore a zero-sum game and does not allow for multiple winners. For
example, if a consumer purchases an iPhone, that purchase is at the expense of Apple’s
competitors (such as Samsung) in the form of customers, profits, and market share. Thus,
individual companies undoubtedly compete against each other.
In contrast, nations engage in economic trade, which involves mutually beneficial economic
exchanges that allow countries to focus their production efforts on those goods that they are
relatively most efficient at producing and trade for those goods that they are
relatively least
efficient at producing. A fundamental tenet of economics is that a country cannot be the most
efficient at producing everything simultaneously.60 Therefore, divvying up production efforts
across countries according to each’s relative (or comparative) advantage and engaging in trade
can increase the well-being of all trading partners. That is, trade is not a zero-sum game because it
allows for multiple winners. Thus, while individual firms may compete, countries trade.61
Additionally, strong economic growth in one country does not imply slower growth for other
countries. Nor does enhanced economic well-being in one country generally reduce economic
opportunities in other countries. In fact, if one country experiences economic growth, those
58 It has been reported that small- and mid-sized companies forgo certain tax benefits because the costs associated with
claiming tax benefits exceeds the value of certain incentives. See John D. McKinnon, “Firms Pass Up Tax Breaks,
Citing Hassles, Complexity,”
Wall Street Journal, July 23, 2012, p. A1, U.S. Edition.
59 The Internal Revenue Service (IRS) defines the
gross tax gap as the difference between the aggregate tax liability
imposed by law for a given tax year and the amount of tax that taxpayers pay
voluntarily and timely for that year.
Relative to the size of corporate tax revenues, the tax gap is generally believed to be small. For additional background,
see CRS In Focus IF11887,
Federal Tax Gap: Size, Contributing Factors, and the Debate Over Reducing It, by Gary
Guenther.
60 More formally, this is known as the Law of Comparative Advantage. Nearly 200 years ago, David Ricardo pointed
out that even if a country is more efficient than other nations at producing everything, it is still beneficial for it to focus
its production efforts on those goods that it is
relatively most efficient at producing and trading for items that it is
r
elatively least efficient at producing.
61 Numerous economists have made this point, including Paul Krugman, “Competitiveness: A Dangerous Obsession,”
Foreign Affairs, vol. 73, no. 2 (March/April 1994), pp. 28-44; and Jane G. Gravelle, “Does the Concept of
Competitiveness Have Meaning in Formulating Corporate Tax Policy?”
Tax Law Review, vol. 65 (2012), pp. 323-348.
Congressional Research Service
19
link to page 7
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
benefits tend to spill over to that country’s trading partners, as higher domestic incomes increase
the demand for imported goods and services. As such, the United States benefits from strong
growth abroad because it increases the demand for U.S. products and provides U.S. businesses
access to expanding markets.
Some economists, in an attempt to define “competitiveness,” have noted that “competitive”
policies are those that promote domestic business globally, while increasing the U.S. standards of
living.62 Krugman (1994) argues that this and similar definitions are flawed, noting that “the
growth rate of living standards essentially equals the rate of domestic productivity growth—not
productivity relative to competitors.”63 The policy objective of promoting domestic business
globally is also not clear. Is the goal to have tax policies that encourage U.S. firms to invest
abroad to better compete in international markets? Or is the goal to prevent the movement of U.S.
business operations overseas? These are two different policy objectives often promoted in the
name of “competitiveness.”64
Given the confusion surrounding national “competitiveness” (in an economic context) as a policy
objective, focusing on designing a tax system that is efficient, equitable, and relatively
straightforward to administer may be useful. At the same time, there may be important national
security issues that policymakers may want to consider. These issues fall outside the realm of
standard international economic theory and are beyond the scope of this report.
Concluding Remarks
The structure of the corporate tax can influence the performance of the economy, impact fairness
in the overall tax system, and have important administrative consequences. Additionally, the
corporate tax generates a nontrivial amount of revenue, although its estimated 10.8% of federal
tax revenues in 2023 ranks behind the individual income tax (50.6% of revenue) and payroll taxes
(32.6% of revenue). If history is any guide, there will be continued interest in and debate over the
structure of the corporate tax and even the necessity for its existence, both within academia and
among policymakers.
At least two specific policy areas of interest pertaining to the corporate tax appear to be relevant
in the current environment. The first involves concern, expressed by some, over recent deficits
and the growing national debt. The corporate tax could be one tool to raise revenues and address
these concerns. Policymakers could increase the corporate tax rate, subject more corporate
activity to tax (e.g., broaden the base), or enact a combination of the two approaches. Pursuing
either approach to generate more corporate tax revenue would require careful consideration given
the potential impact on the economy and fairness in the tax system.
For example, base broadening would involve repealing or limiting corporate tax expenditures. As
discussed previously (see
“Corporate Tax Expenditures”), the estimated sum of all corporate tax
expenditures in 2023 is $162.4 billion. One potential issue is that $127.1 billion (78.3%) of this
total is attributed to the five largest tax expenditures, several of which increase the after-tax
returns to investment—specifically, expensing of research and experimental expenditures,
accelerated depreciation, and the low-income housing tax credit. Removing these types of
62 See, for example, Richard H.K. Vietor and Matthew Weinzierl, “Macroeconomic Policy and U.S. Competitiveness,”
Harvard Business Review, March 2012, http://hbr.org/2012/03/macroeconomic-policy-and-us-competitiveness/ar/1.
63 Paul Krugman, “Competitiveness: A Dangerous Obsession,”
Foreign Affairs, vol. 73, no. 2 (March/April 1994), p.
34.
64 For further discussion, see Jane G. Gravelle, “Does the Concept of Competitiveness Have Meaning in Formulating
Corporate Tax Policy?”
Tax Law Review, vol. 65 (2012), pp. 323-348.
Congressional Research Service
20
An Overview of The Corporate Income Tax System
expenditures could increase the effective tax rate on capital investment, which would likely
reduce investment, and therefore output, wages, and short-run employment. However, this may
need to be balanced with the potential negative effects deficits and the debt can have on future
economic growth because of higher interest rates and potentially higher future taxes or lower
future spending.
A second policy area of interest pertaining to the corporate tax is the global push for increased
international tax coordination, which is related to revenue concerns but also involves issues of
economic efficiency. One driver for these efforts is the revenue loss attributed to base erosion and
profit shifting (BEPS), which one post-TCJA analysis estimated at $77 billion annually.65 The
OECD and G20 have developed a multilateral framework to address BEPS. As of December
2022, 142 countries have agreed to work toward implementing a series of actions to reduce global
corporate tax avoidance.66 Taken together, these actions are aimed at reducing the ability of
corporations to shift profits to low-tax countries. However, this overall reduction may need to be
balanced with how the implementation of these provisions may affect U.S. corporate revenue,
employment, and investment in the United States.67
Author Information
Mark P. Keightley
Donald J. Marples
Specialist in Economics
Specialist in Public Finance
Disclaimer
This document was prepared by the Congressional Research Service (CRS). CRS serves as nonpartisan
shared staff to congressional committees and Members of Congress. It operates solely at the behest of and
under the direction of Congress. Information in a CRS Report should not be relied upon for purposes other
than public understanding of information that has been provided by CRS to Members of Congress in
connection with CRS’s institutional role. CRS Reports, as a work of the United States Government, are not
subject to copyright protection in the United States. Any CRS Report may be reproduced and distributed in
its entirety without permission from CRS. However, as a CRS Report may include copyrighted images or
material from a third party, you may need to obtain the permission of the copyright holder if you wish to
copy or otherwise use copyrighted material.
65 Tax Justice Network,
The State of Tax Justice 2021, November 2021, https://taxjustice.net/wp-content/uploads/2021/
11/State_of_Tax_Justice_Report_2021_ENGLISH.pdf.
66 See CRS Report R44900,
Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS): OECD/G20 Tax Proposals, by Jane G. Gravelle,
for information on the specific actions; and https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/inclusive-framework-on-beps-
composition.pdf for the list of countries.
67 See Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development,
Members of the OECD/G20 Inclusive Framework
on BEPS, December 2022, https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/inclusive-framework-on-beps-composition.pdf; CRS Report
R47174,
The Pillar 2 Global Minimum Tax: Implications for U.S. Tax Policy, by Jane G. Gravelle and Mark P.
Keightley; and CRS In Focus IF11874,
International Tax Proposals Addressing Profit Shifting: Pillars 1 and 2, by
Jane G. Gravelle for discussions concerning the revenue and incentive effects of the BEPS project.
Congressional Research Service
R47519
· VERSION 1 · NEW
21