Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the
March 23, 2021
Economy in the Wake of COVID-19
Lida R. Weinstock
The Coronavirus Disease 2019 (COVID-19) pandemic caused a swift and deep economic
Analyst in Macroeconomic
downturn from which the country has yet to fully recover. In response to COVID-19, the federal
Policy
government enacted expansionary fiscal policy to provide relief and stimulus to the economy.

Several bills were enacted in FY2020, including the Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic
Security (CARES) Act (P.L. 116-136). The FY2020 federal budget deficit totaled $3.1 trillion,

more than triple its FY2019 value, and the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) and Joint
Committee on Taxation (JCT) project the bills enacted in FY2020 to increase FY2020-FY2030 deficits by $2.6 trillion.
Additional relief and stimulus was enacted in FY2021 in the Consolidated Appropriation s Act, 2021 (P.L. 116-260), which
CBO and JCT estimate would increase deficits by $1 trillion over the 2021-2031 period, $868 billion of which comes from
COVID-19 related provisions. This was followed by the American Rescue Plan Act of 2021 (P.L. 117-2), enacted on March
11, 2021, which CBO and JCT estimate will increase deficits by nearly $2 trillion over the 2021-2031 period. CBO projects
the FY2021 deficit to be 10.3% of gross domestic product (GDP).
To finance these deficits, the government needs to borrow money. The federal debt-to-GDP ratio rose significantly in
FY2020, reaching slightly above 100%. CBO projects that deficits and debt will trend upwards in the coming decades, with
the debt-to-GDP ratio surpassing 200% by 2051 under current policy. The current and projected size of deficits and the rising
debt-to-GDP ratio are a topic of concern for many economists and policymakers given that FY2020 deficits and debt as a
share of GDP were the largest on record since World War II. Some of the possible consequences of persistent deficit
spending include the crowding out of private investment, which can in turn stunt long-term growth; increasingly large
portions of the federal budget being directed toward interest payments on debt, which can crowd out other policy priorities;
and an unsustainable level of debt, which can lead to a fiscal crisis.
Several economic factors are important for the sustainability of incurring debts, including interest rates, inflation, and the
growth rate of real GDP. Both long- and short-term interest rates are relatively low from a historical perspective, and the
Federal Reserve has indicated its intention to keep rates low for the time being , inflation has generally been below 2% for the
past decade, real GDP growth has been smaller in recent decades, and real GDP fell by 3.5% in 2020 as a result of COVID-
19. These are all relevant to the government’s ability to service its debt and continue borrowing as needed.
Lower interest rates can lower the government’s interest payments on its debt, even if the stock of debt increases. The amount
of debt held by the public increased significantly in FY2020, but interest payments still fell from $375 billion in FY2019 to
$337 billion as a result of lower interest rates. While rates remain low, the government is less likely to experience negative
consequences of rising debt. Higher inflation would, all else equal, lower the size of the existing debt in real terms . However,
rising inflation could cause the Federal Res erve to increase interest rates. While inflation is low, the nominal interest paid on
debt is also likely to be low. If the economy grows faster than the debt and is higher than the interest rate paid on the debt,
then, relative to the size of the economy, the debt becomes smaller. Theoretically, if a balance can be struck among the
interest rate, the inflation rate, and the rate of economic growth, a rising level of debt can remain sustainable. However, the
current trajectory of debt, as projected by CBO, indicates that debt will continue rising relative to GDP.
One of the largest concerns about growing debt is the scenario in which, for any number of possible reasons, investors lose
confidence in the government’s ability to service its debt and therefore demand significantly higher interest rates to
compensate for the risk. This type of scenario has led to fiscal crises in other countries. However, the United States is, in
many ways, a different case because of the wide international use of the dollar. In times of crisis, such as COVID-19,
investors tend to flock to the dollar, which may allow the United States to borrow more easily and in larger amounts.
The point at which the level of U.S. debt might become unsustainable is not clear. Given the current economic landscape, the
country is not likely headed to a crisis in the near term. However, depending on the speed and strength of the economic
recovery and the way in which interest rates and inflation change, if at all, the size of the debt may become a more urgent
concern in the future.
Congressional Research Service


link to page 4 link to page 4 link to page 5 link to page 6 link to page 6 link to page 6 link to page 7 link to page 7 link to page 8 link to page 8 link to page 8 link to page 8 link to page 9 link to page 10 link to page 11 link to page 12 link to page 12 link to page 13 link to page 13 link to page 14 link to page 14 link to page 15 link to page 16 link to page 17 link to page 18 link to page 18 link to page 5 link to page 5 link to page 9 link to page 12 link to page 18 link to page 19 Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

Contents
Introduction ................................................................................................................... 1
Recent Trends................................................................................................................. 1
Fiscal Policy and Conventional Economic Theory ................................................................ 2
Benefits of Expansionary Fiscal Policy ......................................................................... 3
Short-Term Risks of Expansionary Fiscal Policy ............................................................ 3

Rising Interest Rate Risk ....................................................................................... 3
Rising Inflation Risk ............................................................................................. 4
Risks of Persistent Expansionary Fiscal Policy ............................................................... 4
Long-Term Growth............................................................................................... 5
Crowding Out Government Spending ...................................................................... 5

The Changing Macroeconomic Landscape .......................................................................... 5
Interest Rate Environment........................................................................................... 5
Interest Rates and Debt ......................................................................................... 6
Inflation ................................................................................................................... 7
Inflation and Debt ................................................................................................ 8
Economic Growth...................................................................................................... 9
Economic Growth and Debt ................................................................................... 9
Critiques of Conventional Theory .................................................................................... 10
Ricardian Equivalence.............................................................................................. 10
Modern Monetary Theory ......................................................................................... 11
Secular Stagnation ................................................................................................... 11

Policy Concerns............................................................................................................ 12
At What Point Is It Appropriate to Remove Stimulus? ................................................... 13
Debt Sustainability .................................................................................................. 14
Projections of the Deficit and Debt........................................................................ 15
“Tipping Points” ................................................................................................ 15


Figures
Figure 1. Deficit-to-GDP Ratio, FY1980-2020..................................................................... 2
Figure 2. Debt-to-GDP Ratio, FY1980-2020 ....................................................................... 2
Figure 3. Nominal Interest Rates ....................................................................................... 6
Figure 4. Historical Trend in Real GDP Growth ................................................................... 9
Figure 5. Deficit and Debt Projections, FY2021-FY2051 .................................................... 15

Contacts
Author Information ....................................................................................................... 16

Congressional Research Service


Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

Introduction
The Coronavirus Disease 2019 (COVID-19) pandemic caused widespread economic disruption.
Commerce slowed, unemployment reached rates not seen since the Great Depression, and many
businesses were forced to close. In response, the government enacted a series of laws aimed at
providing relief to struggling individuals and businesses and stimulus to improve economic
conditions, most recently the American Rescue Plan Act of 2021 (P.L. 117-2) enacted on March
11, 2021. Altogether, this resulted in large increases in the deficit in FY2020, and a large deficit is
projected for FY2021 as wel .
A deficit occurs when the government’s expenditures are larger than its revenues. The U.S.
government has general y run budget deficits for the past few decades, with the exception of a
short time in the 1990s, when it ran budget surpluses. The budget deficit in FY2020 was the
largest on record in dollar terms1 and resulted in a dramatic increase in U.S. debt held by the
public.2 The debt-to-GDP ratio in FY2020 was the largest on record since World War II,3 leading
to some concerns about the sustainability of the U.S. stock and trajectory of debt. The higher the
debt grows, the larger interest payments on that debt become (assuming no change in interest
rates). Al else equal, this can then result in higher deficits as the government needs to spend more
to service the debt.
Deficits and growing debt can affect the economy in the short term and the long term. However,
the state of the economy simultaneously contributes to the ways in which deficits and the debt are
likely to affect certain parts of the economy. It is therefore necessary to discuss the current state
of the budget and debt in the context of the economy and recent economic trends. This report
discusses the changing macroeconomic landscape, COVID-19, and how both might influence
policy considerations for deficits and the debt.
Recent Trends
The economic downturn caused by COVID-19 and the government’s response to the downturn
has caused a large increase in federal borrowing.4 Several relief bil s were enacted in response to
COVID-19 in FY2020, most notably the Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security
(CARES) Act (P.L. 116-136), which included funds for stimulus payments, forgivable loans to
smal businesses, and increased unemployment benefits, among others. The deficit totaled $3.1
tril ion in FY2020, equal to 14.9% of nominal gross domestic product (GDP)—the highest share

1 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, “Federal Surplus or Deficit,” October 16, 2020, https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/
FYFSD.
2 T he debt held by the public includes all federal debt held by individuals, corporations, state or local governments,
Federal Reserve banks, foreign governments, and other entities abroad. It does not include debt held by other parts of
the federal government. For more information, see U.S. Department of the T reasury, Frequently Asked Questions about
the Public Debt
, May 5, 2020, https://www.treasurydirect.gov/govt/resources/faq/faq_publicdebt.htm.
3 Congressional Budget Office (CBO), Monthly Budget Review: Summary for Fiscal Year 2020, November 9, 2020, p.
1, https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2020-11/56746-MBR.pdf.
4 For more information about fiscal policy, deficit patterns, and the effects of COVID-19-related legislation, see CRS
Report R45723, Fiscal Policy: Econom ic Effects, by Lida R. Weinstock; and CRS Report R46606, COVID-19 and the
U.S. Econom y
, by Lida R. Weinstock.
Congressional Research Service

1

link to page 5 link to page 5

Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

of GDP since the end of World War II.5 The relief measures enacted in FY2020 are projected to
increase FY2020-FY2030 deficits by $2.6 tril ion.6
Figure 1 and Figure 2 below show budget and debt trends over the last several decades. As a
share of GDP, both deficits and debt have trended upwards over the 1980-2020 period. Deficits
do show cyclicality in line with the business cycle, although deficits have also been increasing in
magnitude with every recession beginning in the early 2000s. The upward trend in debt as a share
of GDP is more noticeable over the same time period. The debt-to-GDP ratio does not decrease in
the same way as the deficit-to-GDP ratio has since 2000, although its growth did noticeably
decelerate during the expansion prior to COVID-19. Both the deficit-to-GDP ratio and debt-to-
GDP ratio increased substantial y during COVID-19. How this pattern changes as a result of
COVID-19 and the subsequent fiscal response is discussed in a subsequent section.
Figure 1. Deficit-to-GDP Ratio, FY1980-
Figure 2. Debt-to-GDP Ratio, FY1980-
2020
2020


Source: Congressional Budget Office (CBO) and
Source: CBO and FRED.
Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED).
Note: Gray bars denote recessions.
Note: Gray bars denote recessions.
In December 2020, additional relief and stimulus was enacted in the Consolidated Appropriations
Act, 2021 (P.L. 116-260). The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) and the Joint Committee on
Taxation (JCT) estimated that the act would increase deficits by $1 tril ion over the FY2021-
FY2031 period, $868 bil ion of which comes from COVID-19 related provisions.7 CBO estimates
that the American Rescue Plan Act of 2021 wil increase deficits by over $1.8 tril ion over the
FY2021-FY2031 period.8
Fiscal Policy and Conventional Economic Theory
To provide stimulus for the economy, the government can increase spending, decrease tax
revenue, or use some combination of both. To do this effectively, the government must increase

5 CBO, Monthly Budget Review: Summary for Fiscal Year 2020 , p. 1.
6 CBO, An Update to the Budget Outlook: 2020 to 2030, September 2, 2020, p. 29, at https://www.cbo.gov/system/
files/2020-09/56517-Budget-Outlook.pdf.
7 CBO, Summary Estimate for Divisions M Through FF H.R. 133, Consolidated Appropriations Act, 2021 , January 14,
2021, p. 1, at https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2021-01/PL_116-260_Summary.pdf.
8 CBO, Estimated Budgetary Effects of H.R. 1319, the American Rescue Plan Act of 2021 , March 5, 2021, p. 2, at
https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2021-03/
Estimated_Budget_Effects_of_H.R._1319_as_Engrossed_by_the_House.pdf .
Congressional Research Service

2

Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

the size of its deficit and borrow money to finance that stimulus. In this way, running a budget
deficit wil increase the stock of debt. Known as expansionary fiscal policy, increases to
government spending or tax cuts can stimulate the economy during a recession by increasing
aggregate demand (total spending). Increasing government spending directly increases aggregate
demand, while tax cuts indirectly increase aggregate demand by increasing disposable personal
income, which can then be spent.
Benefits of Expansionary Fiscal Policy
Expansionary fiscal policy can stimulate economic activity during an economic downturn, as
described above. During a downturn, as the economy shrinks, people lose their jobs and wage
growth slows, further dampening spending and growth. It can be crucial to a recovery to provide
stimulus to boost overal spending. When spending in the economy increases, employers are able
to hire more employees and pay them higher wages. If not enough stimulus is provided, the
supply of labor may never fully recover, which al else equal would cause potential GDP to be on
a permanently lower trajectory.
As discussed, the federal government used expansionary fiscal policy in response to COVID-19.
In the short term, CBO projects that the policies enacted in FY2020 wil increase real GDP by
3.1% in 2021 and that real GDP wil increase in total by 4.6%.9 When additional y accounting for
the Consolidated Appropriations Act and the American Rescue Plan Act, the Federal Reserve
(Fed) projects that real GDP wil increase by 6.5% in 2021.10
Short-Term Risks of Expansionary Fiscal Policy
Expansionary fiscal policy is general y thought to have certain potential outcomes that can reduce
its effectiveness in the short-term, including crowding out investment and other interest-sensitive
spending, decreasing net exports, and increasing inflation.11
Rising Interest Rate Risk
When the government borrows money to finance deficits, it does so from a supply of loanable
funds available to both the government and private parties. When the government increases its
borrowing of these funds, demand for the funds increases and, subsequently, so does the interest
rate (the price of borrowing the funds). Rising interest rates can crowd out private investment as it
becomes more expensive for firms to borrow and invest in capital.12 Rising interest rates can also
decrease interest-sensitive consumer spending, such as purchases of houses, cars, or large
appliances.13 The Fed can attempt to offset this, if it desires, by lowering the targeted federal
funds rate, which would tend to lower other interest rates.

9 CBO, The Effects of Pandemic-Related Legislation on Output, September 2020, https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/
2020-09/56537-pandemic-legislation.pdf.
10 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Summary of Economic Projections, March 17, 2020, p. 2,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/fomcprojtabl20210317.pdf.
11 Benjamin M. Friedman, Crowding Out or Crowding In? Economic Consequences of Financing Government Deficits,
Brookings Institution, https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2016/11/1978c_bpea_friedman.pdf.
12 Laurence Ball and Gregory Mankiw, What Do Budget Deficits Do?, National Bureau of Economic Research
(NBER), Working Paper no. 5263, September 1995, https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w5263/
w5263.pdf.
13 Ball and Mankiw, What Do Budget Deficits Do?
Congressional Research Service

3

Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

Another potential result of rising interest rates is lowered net exports. As domestic rates rise
relative to foreign rates, investors tend to seek out U.S. investments because the relatively high
interest rates mean relatively high returns on investment. However, as foreign capital flows into
the United States, this can push rates back down as the supply of loanable funds increases,
potential y offsetting the initial rise in rates caused by the stimulus. Nonetheless, increased
demand for U.S. investment from foreign investors also means that the demand for the dollar
would increase as foreign investors exchanged various foreign currencies for dollars that they
could then invest. This increased demand for dollars increases the value of the dollar, referred to
as appreciation. When the dollar appreciates, it becomes more expensive relative to other
currencies—it takes more foreign currency to “purchase” one dollar—and, therefore, U.S. goods
and services become more expensive relative to foreign goods and services, causing exports to
decrease and imports to increase.14
These offsetting effects would be expected to be partial such that stimulus expands aggregate
demand on net, and their magnitude depends on the state of the economy. During a recession,
there is less risk of increasing interest rates due to already depressed demand for investment and
interest-sensitive spending. Because demand for loanable funds is depressed during a recession,
the additional demand created by government borrowing does not increase interest rates as much
and therefore does not crowd out as much private spending or decrease net exports as much as it
would during an economic expansion.15
Rising Inflation Risk
The goal of fiscal stimulus is to increase aggregate demand within the economy. However, if
fiscal stimulus is applied too aggressively or is implemented when the economy is already
operating near full capacity, it can result in “overheating,” a situation in which aggregate demand
outstrips aggregate supply. This can cause inflation to accelerate. A rising inflation rate can
introduce distortions into the economy and impose unnecessary costs on individuals and
businesses.16 The Fed can limit the risk of inflation by increasing interest rates, which would
dampen aggregate demand, if there is any sign of the economy overheating. In doing so, there is a
risk of triggering a recession.
Risks of Persistent Expansionary Fiscal Policy
Persistently applying fiscal stimulus across the business cycle can negatively affect the economy
in the long term. Persistent fiscal stimulus—particularly during economic expansions—can limit
long-term economic growth by crowding out private investment. Additional y, rising debt wil
require a growing portion of the federal budget to be directed toward interest payments on the
debt, potential y crowding out other sources of government spending. Issues of debt sustainability
are discussed in a later section.

14 Olivier Blanchard, Macroeconomics, 5th ed. (Upper Saddle River NJ: Pearson Education, 2009), pp. 450 -451.
15 Alan J. Auerbach and Yuriy Gorodnichenko, “Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy,” American
Econom ic Journal: Economic Policy
, vol. 4, no. 2 (May 2012), https://www.aeaweb.org/articles/pdf/doi/10.1257/
pol.4.2.1.
16 See, for example, Richard G. Anderson, Inflation’s Economic Cost: How Large? How Certain?, Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis, July 2006, https://www.stlouisfed.org/publications/regional-economist/july-2006/inflations-
economic-cost -how-large-how-certain.
Congressional Research Service

4

link to page 9 Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

Long-Term Growth
Long-term growth is determined, in part, by the amount of capital in an economy. Persistent fiscal
stimulus, and the associated budget deficits, can decrease the size of the economy in the long term
as a result of decreased investment in physical capital (long-lasting assets used to produce goods
and services).17 As discussed, the government’s deficit spending can result in higher interest rates,
which general y lead to lower levels of business investment. Physical capital investment al ows
businesses to produce more goods and services with the same amount of labor and raw materials.
Government deficits that lead to lower levels of business investment can therefore result in lower
quantities of physical capital and may therefore reduce the economy’s productive capacity in the
long term.18
Crowding Out Government Spending
Rising debt may also be of concern due to its associated interest payments. Al else equal, an
increase in the level of public debt wil result in an increase in interest payments that the
government must make each year. Rising interest payments may therefore crowd out government
spending on other policy priorities or require higher taxes.
The Changing Macroeconomic Landscape
The likelihood of offsetting effects from running budget deficits depends on certain aspects of the
economy. In the past several decades, some economic trends have emerged in the U.S. economy
that affect the ways in which fiscal policy affects the larger economy and the extent to which the
federal government is able to continue to borrow money without negative consequences. This
section discusses three aspects of the economy—interest rates, inflation, and real GDP growth—
how each has changed over time, and how this change relates to the economics of growing debt.
Interest Rate Environment
Both long- and short-term interest rates have trended downward for the past several decades from
relative highs in the 1980s. This has happened despite periods of significant budget deficits.
There are several reasons why this could be occurring. The first is that the Fed has taken an
increasingly accommodative stance toward monetary policy over the same time period. As shown
in Figure 3, the Fed has targeted increasingly lower federal funds rates—the overnight rate at
which banks lend to one another in the federal funds market. In response to COVID-19, the Fed
lowered the target range for the federal funds rate twice in 2020, once to 1.00%-1.25% on March
3 and then to 0.00%-0.25% on March 16.19 The Fed has indicated it wil maintain the current
range until such a time when “labor market conditions have reached levels consistent with the
Committee’s assessments of maximum employment and inflation has risen to 2 percent and is on
track to moderately exceed 2 percent for some time.”20 The Fed’s intention to keep the federal

17 Infrastructure is a part of the capital stock, and therefore increased public investment financed via deficit spending
can still lead to a higher capital stock overall and therefore increase the productive ca pacity of the economy.
18 Ball and Mankiw, What Do Budget Deficits Do?
19 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Policy Tools, https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/
openmarket.htm.
20 Jerome H. Powell, Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate, February 23, 2021,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/powell20210223a.htm.
Congressional Research Service

5


Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

funds target at the zero lower bound for the foreseeable future is likely to keep short-term interest
rates (which are more substitutable with the federal funds rate than longer term rates) low as wel .
Figure 3. Nominal Interest Rates

Source: FRED.
Note: Gray bars denote recessions.
Another reason rates, including longer-term rates, have been low is that inflation has been low.
Inflation lowers the real return on investment, and as such, investors wil demand higher interest
rates to compensate for this. However, with inflation relatively low since the 1990s, nominal rates
have been able to stay low as wel . Even so, real interest rates have also been low in recent
decades and especial y since the 2007-2009 recession. This is posited to be due, in part, to the
supply of savings exceeding the demand for investment and therefore driving down the real
interest rate in the loanable funds market.21
CBO projects that longer-term interest rates wil increase but remain relatively low throughout
the next decade, with the interest rate on the 10-year Treasury reaching 3.4% in 2031.22 If
economic conditions improve more rapidly or by more than expected, or if expectations of future
inflation increase, then it is possible that longer-term rates wil rise more than expected as wel .
Interest Rates and Debt
The federal government must pay interest on its debt to avoid default, and therefore the interest
rate on any given debt instrument is important to how much money the government needs to
spend on servicing the debt. The higher the rates, the more the government pays. Lower rates can
lower the government’s obligations even if the stock of debt increases. For instance, despite a
roughly 25% increase in the amount of publicly held debt in FY2020,23 interest payments fel to

21 For more information on the causes of low real interest rates, see CRS Insight IN11074, Low Interest Rates, Part 3:
Potential Causes
, by Marc Labonte.
22 CBO, 10-Year Economic Projections, February 2021, https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2021-02/51135-2021-02-
economicprojections.xlsx.
23 U.S. Department of the T reasury, Debt Position and Activity Report for September 2019 and September 2020,
Congressional Research Service

6

Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

$337 bil ion from $375 bil ion in 2019, due in large part to lower interest rates.24 Interest rates are
relatively low currently, and many expect them to stay low for some time to come. If interest rates
do stay low, the federal government’s ability to service the debt—and do so without crowding out
other policy priorities—may be less likely to be an immediate concern.
Additional y, concerns that running persistent budget deficits would lead to rising interest rates
have not yet come to pass. Some interest rates have begun to rise modestly, perhaps in response to
some expectations of high real GDP growth and inflation, but stil remain low by historical
standards.25 If inflation proves to be a problem in the coming months and years, interest rates
would likely be raised to combat this trend. The likelihood of that scenario remains highly
contested.26
Inflation
As discussed, deficit spending can cause temporary increases in inflation. However, the federal
government has been running budget deficits for decades without any significant increases in
inflation. Inflation has been lower than the Fed has desired for several years. As measured by the
personal consumption expenditures index, inflation has largely remained below the Fed’s 2%
target27 since the 2007-2009 recession. Several stimulus and relief laws were enacted in response
to the economic downturn caused by COVID-19, but inflation remained relatively low
nonetheless. Given that aggregate demand was already depressed, it was less likely that stimulus
measures would cause inflation than if they had been enacted during an expansion. The Fed
projects that inflation wil rise modestly to 2.4% in 2021 but decrease to 2% in the longer run.28
However, some economists believe that P.L. 117-2 is too large and wil result in overheating and a
large temporary or sustained increase in inflation.29
One of the reasons inflation is associated with an overheating economy is that when aggregate
demand rises (and in some cases outstrips aggregate supply), unemployment tends to fal , which
al else equal would tend to be accompanied by an increase in wages and prices. Therefore, deficit
spending that brings the economy to or past full employment is associated with rising inflation.

https://www.treasurydirect.gov/govt/reports/pd/pd_debtposactrpt.htm.
24 CBO, Monthly Budget Review: Summary for Fiscal Year 2020, p. 5.
25 Paul Kiernan, “Powell Confirms Fed to Maintain Easy-Money Policies,” Wall Street Journal, March 4, 2021,
https://www.wsj.com/articles/feds-powell-to-take-questions-on-job-market -interest-rates-bond-yields-11614872817.
26 For example, see Peter Coy, “Summers and Krugman Debate Stimulus. Here’s a Blow-by-Blow Account,”
Bloom berg Businessweek, February 12, 2021, https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2021-02-12/summers-and-
krugman-debate-stimulus-here-s-a-blow-by-blow-account ; or Joseph E. Gagnon, Inflation Fears and the Biden
Stim ulus: Look to the Korean War, Not Vietnam
, Peterson Institute for International Economics, February 25, 2021,
https://www.piie.com/blogs/realtime-economic-issues-watch/inflation-fears-and-biden-stimulus-look-korean-war-not-
vietnam.
27 In August 2020, the Federal Reserve announced that instead of targeting an inflation r ate of 2%, it would target an
average rate of 2%. For more information, see Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Guide to Changes in
the Statem ent on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy
, https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/
guide-to-changes-in-statement -on-longer-run-goals-monetary-policy-strategy.htm; and CRS Insight IN11499, The
Federal Reserve’s Revised Monetary Policy Strategy Statement
, by Marc Labonte.
28 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Summary of Economic Projections, p. 2.
29 For example, see Olivier Blanchard, In Defense of Concerns over the $1.9 Trillion Relief Plan, Peterson Institute for
International Economics, February 18, 2021, https://www.piie.com/blogs/realtime-economic-issues-watch/defense-
concerns-over-19-trillion-relief-plan, or Lawrence H. Summers, “ Opinion: T he Biden Stimulus Is Admirably
Ambitious. But It Brings Some Big Risks, T oo,” Washington Post, February 4, 2021,
https://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/2021/02/04/larry-summers-biden-covid-stimulus/.
Congressional Research Service

7

link to page 8 Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

The Phil ips Curve is a graphical representation of the relationship between unemployment and
inflation. In the past, the inverse relationship between these two variables appeared strong.
However, this relationship has seemingly weakened in recent years, a phenomenon referred to as
the flattening of the Phil ips Curve. As mentioned, inflation remained relatively low during the
11-year expansion that preceded COVID-19, even as unemployment rates fel below 4% and the
economy arguably neared full employment. Empirical y, since the 2007-2009 recession, periods
of increased deficits and low unemployment have not been met with any notable increases in
inflation.
There are several explanations as to why this might be occurring. One is that the Fed has
successfully targeted inflation, and therefore expectations about inflation (which in part drive
inflation) are more stable than they once were.30 Other explanations include that the relationship
between the labor market and wage growth has weakened31 or that price stickiness has
decreased.32
Inflation and Debt
Inflation reduces the real size of existing debt. Typical y higher inflation is seen as advantageous
to borrowers because it lets the debtor pay back existing debt with money that is worth less than
when it was initial y borrowed. As inflation has been both relatively low and steady in recent
years, the inflation environment would, al else equal, not provide the United States any
significant reduction in the real cost of issuing debt.
As discussed in the above “Interest Rate Environment” section, real interest rates (nominal rates
minus inflation) have also been low in recent years. Real interest rates ultimately matter more for
the economy than nominal rates do because they represent the actual cost of borrowing. In this
sense, the United States has faced very low costs of borrowing.
Depending on the speed and strength of the recovery from the economic downturn caused by
COVID-19, it is possible the United States could see a temporary increase in inflation, which
could, in turn, cause investors to demand higher nominal interest rates to maintain or increase
their real return. As the economy recovers, typical y capital investment also increases, causing an
increase in demand for loanable funds. As the demand for funds increase to meet (or surpass
supply), the real interest rate in the loanable funds market wil also rise. Rising real interest rates
would increase borrowing costs and could also decrease economic activity, the combination of
which would increase the real amount of money the federal government needs to devote to
servicing its debt relative to the size of the economy. This is discussed in more detail in the
following section about economic growth. The likelihood that inflation or real interest rates wil
rise notably and for a prolonged enough period to make debt sustainability a short-term issue
remains low for the time being.

30 Kristie Engemann, What Is the Phillips Curve (and Why Has It Flattened)?, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis,
January 15, 2020, https://www.stlouisfed.org/open-vault/2020/january/what -is-phillips-curve-why-flattened.
31 Sylvain Leduc and Daniel J. Wilson, Has the Wage Phillips Curve Gone Dormant?, Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco, October 16, 2017, https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2017/october/has-
wage-phillips-curve-gone-dormant/.
32 Filippo Occhino, The Flattening of the Phillips Curve: Policy Implications Depend on the Cause, Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, July 10, 2019, https://www.clevelandfed.org/en/newsroom-and-events/publications/economic-
commentary/2019-economic-commentaries/ec-201911-flattening-phillips-curve.aspx.
Congressional Research Service

8

link to page 12
Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

Economic Growth
The U.S. economy has experienced slower real GDP growth in recent decades than in previous
decades. Since the 2007-2009 recession, annual growth has exceeded 3% once, in 2015, out of
the 11 years of expansion prior to COVID-19. Prior to the 1980s, annual growth somewhat
regularly exceeded 5%. Between 1950 and 1979, annual growth averaged about 4%. This
dropped to an average annual growth rate of 2.5% between 1980 and 2020 and is even lower
when only the past decade is considered—annual average growth between 2010 and 2020 was
down to about 1.7%.33 As shown in Figure 4 below, the trend (as represented by the dotted dark
blue line) in real GDP growth over the period 1948-2020 is negative.
Figure 4. Historical Trend in Real GDP Growth
1948-2020

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.
COVID-19 caused a significant loss to real GDP, which fel by 3.5% in 2020.34 As mentioned
previously, the Fed projects real GDP to grow by 6.5% in 2021. The Fed further projects that real
GDP growth wil remain elevated at 3.3% in 2022 and 2.2% in 2021 but wil slow again and grow
at a rate of 1.8% in the longer run.35
Economic Growth and Debt
When debating questions of debt sustainability, one of the most common metrics to consider is
the debt-to-GDP ratio. The nominal value of the stock of debt matters less in theory than the debt-
to-GDP ratio does because, so long as the economy is growing faster than the debt, the
government should not have difficulty servicing the debt. For example, if the stock of debt is
growing at 1% per year and GDP is growing at 2% per year, then the debt is actual y getting

33 Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), National Income and Product Accounts, https://www.bea.gov/products/
national-income-and-product -accounts.
34 BEA, Gross Domestic Product, Fourth Quarter and Year 2020 (Second Estimate) , February 25, 2021,
https://www.bea.gov/data/gdp/gross-domestic-product .
35 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Summary of Economic Projections, p. 2.
Congressional Research Service

9

Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

smal er relative to the size of the economy, and the government’s ability to meet its obligations is
higher, despite the stock of debt rising. Additional y, it is important that the nominal growth rate
in the economy is larger than the average interest rate paid on debt so that the government needs
to devote smal er portions of its budget to paying interest on the debt.
The trend toward lower economic growth in recent decades is, al else equal, more likely to result
in higher debt-to-GDP ratios. The fact that the debt-to-GDP ratio was so high in 2020 is not
necessarily cause for immediate concern, however. In a recession, typical y growth decelerates
and debt increases as the government uses fiscal policy to stimulate the economy. In other words,
the increased rate of debt incurred is likely to result in increased rates of growth that wil , in turn,
help compensate for the increased debt. The larger concern is that a trend toward lower growth
rates wil result in a trend toward higher debt-to-GDP ratios. To reverse such a trend, the federal
government would need to increase growth, decrease debt, or use a combination of the two.
Economists do not always agree on the best way to accomplish a decreasing debt-to-GDP ratio, as
is discussed in the following section.
Critiques of Conventional Theory
There are several alternate theories that in some way counter the tenets of conventional economic
theory. These fal across the political spectrum and, in some cases, point to the changing
macroeconomic context for questions of the efficacy of fiscal policy and debt sustainability. This
section discusses three alternative theories: Ricardian equivalence, Modern Monetary Theory, and
secular stagnation.
Ricardian Equivalence
The theory known as Ricardian equivalence, original y developed in the early 19th century by
David Ricardo but later elaborated on by Robert Barro, disputes the idea that expansionary fiscal
policy actual y provides effective stimulus to the economy. The theory assumes that individuals
are consumption smoothers, meaning that people behave in a way so as to spend, or consume, the
same amount in al periods of their lives. A simple example of this is saving for retirement.
In the context of expansionary fiscal policy, Ricardian equivalence posits that individuals wil not
respond to fiscal stimulus with increased spending but rather with increased saving. In a world of
perfect consumption smoothing, individuals wil expect that increases in government spending or
decreases in taxes now wil lead to decreases in government spending or increases to taxes later.
To smooth consumption, individuals wil save more during periods of fiscal expansion while
personal income is higher so that they can consume similar amounts later when personal income
is lower. In this way, expansionary fiscal policy would not have a stimulative effect on spending
in the short term, because higher public spending wil be offset by lower private spending.36
The extent to which Ricardian equivalence holds in the real world is debated among economists,
and perfect equivalence is not a feature of wel -known economic forecasting or policy analysis
models. Many economists accept that some amount of consumption smoothing over the lifetime
of an individual does take place, but there is also some empirical evidence to suggest that this

36 Eric Sims, Fiscal Policy and Ricardian Equivalence, University of Notre Dame, 2016, pp. 10-11,
https://www3.nd.edu/~esims1/fiscal_policy_slides.pdf.
Congressional Research Service

10

Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

does not happen perfectly37 and that fiscal stimulus does affect current consumption.38 Evidence
from the 2007-2009 recession suggests that for every dollar of government spending, GDP
increased by more than one dollar,39 which would not be expected if individuals were perfect
consumption smoothers.40
While both personal income and personal saving have risen in aggregate during the COVID-19
pandemic,41 this is not necessarily reason to conclude it is proof of equivalence in action. The
COVID-19 economic downturn is unusual in that it is a result of a public health crisis. Many
forms of spending that require in-person contact have remained low because of fears of viral
spread and mandates designed to limit spread.
Modern Monetary Theory
Economists disagree about how much debt the government can issue without causing any
significant distortions to the economy. A theory that has gained attention in recent years is
Modern Monetary Theory (MMT), pioneered by economist Stephanie Kelton. At its core, MMT
argues that a government that issues its own currency can print currency to meet its obligations.
In this way, there would be no point at which the level of debt would be unsustainable.42
There has been significant pushback among economists against some of the theory’s assumptions.
Some, such as economist Paul Krugman, admit that fiscal stimulus may be the best way to get an
economy to full employment when interest rates are low, and therefore monetary policy alone
may not be able to create enough stimulus, but they disagree that this is the case in other
economic contexts.43 Others take this argument even further and argue that MMT both
overestimates the effectiveness of fiscal policy and underestimates the effectiveness of monetary
policy and that excessive increases in the money supply would therefore lead to an inflation crisis
that could not be controlled under the theory’s policy framework.44
Secular Stagnation
There are some economists who largely accept the conventional economic framework
surrounding fiscal policy but also point out that the extent to which the government should use

37 Scott A. Wolla, Smoothing the Path: Balancing Debt, Income, and Saving for the Future, Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis, November 2014, https://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/page1-econ/2014/11/01/smoothing-the-path-
balancing-debt-income-and-saving-for-the-future/.
38 B. Douglas Bernheim, Ricardian Equivalence: An Evaluation of Theory and Evidence, NBER, Working Paper no.
2330, July 1987, p. 72, https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w2330/w2330.pdf.
39 For a more in-depth discussion of fiscal multipliers, see CRS Report R46460, Fiscal Policy and Recovery from the
COVID-19 Recession
, by Jane G. Gravelle and Donald J. Marples.
40 Daniel J. Wilson, The COVID-19 Fiscal Multiplier: Lessons from the Great Recession, Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco, May 26, 2020, https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2020/may/covid-19-
fiscal-multiplier-lessons-from-great-recession/.
41 BEA, Effects of Selected Pandemic Response Programs on Personal Income, January 2021 , February 26, 2021,
https://www.bea.gov/sites/default/files/2021-02/effects-of-selected-federal-pandemic-response-programs-on-personal-
income-january-2021.pdf.
42 For a more in-depth analysis of MMT , see CRS Report R45976, Deficit Financing, the Debt, and “Modern Monetary
Theory”
, by Grant A. Driessen and Jane G. Gravelle.
43 Paul Krugman, “Running on MMT (Wonkish),” New York Times, February 25, 2019, https://www.nytimes.com/
2019/02/25/opinion/running-on-mmt-wonkish.html.
44 Patrick Horan, 5 Problems with MMT, Mercatus Center, March 18, 2019, https://www.mercatus.org/bridge/
commentary/5-problems-mmt.
Congressional Research Service

11

Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

fiscal stimulus or the extent to which debt sustainability is an immediate concern depends largely
upon the economic landscape, and given that the interest rate, inflation, and growth environment
have been changing, the calculus for policymakers ought to also be changing.
As discussed, since the 2007-2009 recession, interest rates have been historical y low, the real
GDP annual growth rate has general y been low by historical standards,45 and inflation has
general y remained below 2% despite significant expansionary monetary policy.46 Given this
situation, some economists think that the U.S. economy has been suffering from secular
stagnation.
Secular stagnation, a theory pioneered by economist Alvin Hansen in the 1930s but popularized
more recently by economists such as Lawrence Summers, considers the implications of running
budget deficits and adding to the national debt during a period of long-term growth stagnation. In
this context, secular refers to the long term. In the long term, the economy’s size is dependent
upon the amount of labor, capital, and technological growth. The size of the capital stock is, in
turn, dependent upon the amount of private sector investment in capital. Secular stagnation is said
to occur when the private sector has an excessive propensity to save rather than invest, thus
inhibiting the long-term size of the economy.47
Proponents of secular stagnation believe that under current economic conditions, fiscal stimulus
is the only viable way to spur growth and increase inflation, which would al ow the Federal
Reserve to raise interest rates.48 Higher interest rates give the Fed more room to effectively use
monetary policy during a recession. For example, when the Fed lowered the federal funds rate in
response to COVID-19, it could do so only by a few percentage points before hitting the zero
lower bound. Monetary policy might have a greater stimulative effect if rates could be
significantly lowered during a downturn.
In conventional theory, fiscal stimulus that increases the debt has a future trade-off in that
crowding out wil bequeath a smal er economy to future generations. Proponents of secular
stagnation believe this trade-off is currently desirable because crowding out is unlikely to be
significant during secular stagnation, in which case the benefits of creating sustained growth wil
outweigh it. Until such a time when the economy is no longer in a period of secular stagnation,
theorists argue that debt sustainability is not a problem because fiscal stimulus contributes to
growth and low interest rates keep interest payments on the debt relatively low.
Policy Concerns
The size of deficits and debt can impact policy decisions. This section discusses two often-
discussed questions surrounding fiscal policy and the growing debt.

45 BEA, National Income and Product Accounts, https://www.bea.gov/products/national-income-and-product-accounts.
46 BEA, National Income and Product Accounts.
47 Lawrence H. Summers, “T he Age of Secular Stagnation: What It Is and What to Do About It,” Foreign Affairs,
March/April 2016, https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2016-02-15/age-secular-stagnation.
48 Lawrence H. Summers, “Accepting the Reality of Secular Stagnation,” International Monetary Fund Finance and
Developm ent
, vol. 57, no. 1 (March 2020), https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2020/03/larry-summers-on-
secular-stagnation.htm.
Congressional Research Service

12

Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

At What Point Is It Appropriate to Remove Stimulus?
COVID-19 caused a swift and deep economic downturn the likes of which had not been seen
since the Great Depression. As a result, both Congress and the Fed implemented unprecedented
relief and stimulus policies. Following these policies, several unusual phenomena occurred, such
as record-breaking stock prices, a general y robust financial sector, and overal increases in
personal income across 2020. Nonetheless, COVID-19 has hurt some industries and individuals
more than others.49 Unemployment remains elevated, and the level of real GDP remains
depressed.
The economic downturn caused by COVID-19 is unusual in that many aspects of dampened
demand have been caused by the nature of the public health crisis as opposed to a problem with
economic or financial fundamentals. As such, it is possible that aggregate demand wil rebound
quickly once the health crisis comes to an end. In this way, the current situation may differ from
past recessions, and the need for stimulus may diminish quickly. However, the longer the
pandemic persists, the more likely there are to be lasting impacts that could affect aggregate
demand and supply even once the crisis has passed. Given the uneven nature of the impacts of
COVID-19, it might further be expected that the recovery wil be uneven, which could also result
in the need for additional targeted stimulus.
No consensus exists in economic or policy communities regarding how long or how much
stimulus is appropriate as it relates to recessions general y or COVID-19 specifical y. One might
look to past fiscal stimulus to help answer these sorts of queries, but economists continue to
debate the efficacy and timing of past stimulus. For example, there is debate in the economic
community about the effectiveness of the fiscal response to the 2007-2009 recession, with one of
the concerns being that stimulus was removed too soon.50
As it relates to COVID-19, many economists are concerned about the growing debt and the
historical y large debt-to-GDP ratio. However, many also feel that stimulus should not be
withdrawn until the crisis is over and the economy is fully recovered.51 Others believe that
stimulus should be eased and deficit-reduction measures put in place sooner rather than later.52
Stil others argue that stimulus should have already been removed and that short-term gains based
on deficit spending wil hurt longer term growth and stability as future generations are forced to
pay for the economic decisions of today.53
To some extent, even if in agreement about the economic fundamentals of a situation, economists
may proffer different policy advice. For example, one economist may prefer to continue stimulus
while another may not because the former believes that the risks of a slow or incomplete recovery

49 For more details on hard-hit industries, see CRS Insight IN11564, COVID-19: Employment Across Industries, by
Lida R. Weinstock.
50 Gerald A. Carlino, Did the Fiscal Stimulus Work?, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Economic Insights, vol. 2,
no. 1 (First Quarter 2017), pp. 6-16.
51 For example, see Committee for a Responsible Federal Budget, Policymakers Should Avoid Austerity in Addressing
the Debt
, November 25, 2020, http://www.crfb.org/blogs/policymakers-should-avoid-austerity-addressing-debt; and
Richard Kogan and Paul N. Van De Water, Rising Federal Debt Should Not Shortchange Response to COVID-19
Crisis
, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, September 9, 2020, https://www.cbpp.org/research/federal-budget/
rising-federal-debt-should-not-shortchange-response-to-covid-19-crisis.
52 For example, see Sita Slavov and Alan Viard, “Sound the Alarm on the Federal Debt,” The Hill, November 23, 2020,
https://thehill.com/opinion/finance/527146-sound-the-alarm-on-the-federal-debt?rl=1.
53 Veronique de Rugy, As Bastiat Would Say, Peer Past the Obvious with Pandemic Policies, Mercatus Center, July 2,
2020, https://www.mercatus.org/commentary/bastiat -would-say-peer-past-obvious-pandemic-policies.
Congressional Research Service

13

Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

are greater than the risks of persistent stimulus, while the latter believes the opposite to be true. A
significant but unlikely risk currently is that the fiscal path becomes unsustainable. This risk is
discussed in more detail in the following section.
Debt Sustainability
Debt sustainability is an issue with widespread and significant economic ramifications. Persistent
fiscal stimulus can result in a rising debt-to-GDP ratio and lead to an unsustainable level of debt.
A rising debt-to-GDP ratio can be problematic if the perceived or real risk of the government
defaulting on that debt begins to rise. As the perceived risk of default begins to increase, investors
wil demand higher interest rates as compensation. If rates become high enough fast enough, it
could cause a fiscal crisis in which the government is unable to service its debts or is forced to
print a significant amount of money to cover such costs, which could result in rapidly increasing
inflation.54
Fiscal crises have occurred many times in other countries, and perhaps some wisdom can be
drawn from those foreign experiences. However, the United States may prove a different case
because of the wide use of the dollar. Foreign fiscal crises have often occurred during recessions
as governments were forced to borrow above their means and faced a choice between defaulting
on loans and printing currency to meet their obligations, which could then cause the currency to
depreciate. This is less likely to happen in the United States during a recession as investors tend
to flock to the dollar as a “safe haven” currency, causing it to appreciate. Further, the United
States may be able to issue more debt relative to largely similar counterparts, because U.S. debt is
often seen as one of the safest investments in the world and is widely used to underpin global
financial transactions.55 Foreigners make up one of the largest categories of holders of U.S.
debt,56 and some believe that foreigners might be more skittish about dollar confidence than
Americans are, although this has not been proven.
To date, it does not appear that the United States has an immediate concern with respect to
sustainability given that interest rates are historical y low,57 although the unpredictability of
interest rates has led to some cal s for caution.58 If investors currently thought the debt was
unsustainable, interest rates would likely not be so low. However, investor sentiment and interest
rates can both change rapidly.
The point at which debt might become unsustainable is not clear. The debt-to-GDP ratio in
FY2020 was the highest since World War II and is projected to remain high given the ongoing
pandemic and recession.59 The debt cannot grow faster than GDP forever, but future policy
changes could alter the current trajectory for the better (or worse).

54 CBO, Federal Debt and Risk of a Fiscal Crisis, July 27, 2010, p. 1, https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/111th-
congress-2009-2010/reports/07-27_debt_fiscalcrisis_brief.pdf.
55 CBO, Federal Debt and Risk of a Fiscal Crisis, p. 5.
56 U.S. Department of the T reasury/Federal Reserve Board, Major Foreign Holders of Treasury Securities, March 15,
2021, https://ticdata.treasury.gov/Publish/mfh.txt.
57 Olivier Blanchard, Reexamining the Economic Costs of Debt, Peterson Institute for International Economics,
November 20, 2019, https://www.piie.com/commentary/testimonies/reexamining-economic-costs-debt.
58 John Cochrane, “Debt Denial,” December 9, 2020, https://johnhcochrane.blogspot.com/2020/12/debt-denial.html.
59 CBO, Monthly Budget Review: Summary for Fiscal Year 2020, p. 1.
Congressional Research Service

14

link to page 18 link to page 18 link to page 7
Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

Projections of the Deficit and Debt
CBO publishes annual reports that include long-term budget projections for 30 years, assuming
no changes to tax and spending laws. As shown in Figure 5, CBO projects a deficit-to-GDP ratio
of 10.3% in FY2021, lower than in FY2020 but stil high by historical standards. Deficits are then
expected to decrease further as the pandemic subsides and the economy recovers but remain
relatively high and begin to increase again in the latter half of the decade. In the longer term, this
trend is expected to continue, resulting in a projected deficit-to-GDP ratio of 13.3% by FY2051.
Given the expected trend in deficit spending, debt is likewise expected to rise substantial y. As
shown in Figure 5, CBO predicts a debt-to-GDP ratio of 102% in FY2021, 107% in FY2031, and
202% by FY2051.60 These projected increases have led to concerns about the growth and
sustainability of the debt.
Figure 5. Deficit and Debt Projections, FY2021-FY2051

Source: Congressional Budget Office.
Notes: FY2020 included for reference and is not a projection.
“Tipping Points”
There is not a general consensus about a “tipping point” at which debt becomes unsustainable.
CBO goes so far as to purposefully not define such a point: “the debt-to-GDP ratio has no
identifiable tipping point because the risk of a crisis is influenced by other factors, including the
long-term budget outlook, near-term borrowing needs, and the health of the economy.”61 The
purest definition of debt sustainability is whether or not a country is able to service its debt
without defaulting. However, as discussed in the “Risks of Persistent Expansionary Fiscal Policy”
section, there can be negative economic consequences of having a large debt apart from fiscal
crisis.

60 CBO, The 2021 Long-Term Budget Outlook, March 2021, p. 2, https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2021-03/56977-
LT BO-2021.pdf.
61 CBO, Federal Debt: A Primer, March 2020, https://www.cbo.gov/publication/56309.
Congressional Research Service

15

Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19

That being said, there are those who have attempted to quantify such a tipping point. In 2010,
economists Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff argued that advanced countries with debt-to-
GDP ratios above 90% had median growth rates about 1% lower and average growth rates about
4% lower than their less indebted counterparts.62 This research was largely put in doubt a few
years later when academics from the University of Massachusetts at Amherst discovered coding
errors in Reinhart and Rogoff’s spreadsheets and unsound statistical methodology.63 Reinhart and
Rogoff maintain the soundness of their conclusions but have admitted to the coding errors.64
Another group of economists published further research in 2013 that countries with debt-to-GDP
ratios above 80% and persistent trade deficits are vulnerable to rapid fiscal deterioration.65 This
research, or that of Reinhart and Rogoff, suggest the United States should already be seeing
detrimental effects due to the size of the debt. As of yet, this appears not to be the case.
More recently, the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City published research about potential
default tipping points for the debt-to-GDP ratio. They researched several different scenarios given
different assumptions about economic conditions and policy. In the baseline scenario, the odds of
default were found to begin increasing dramatical y at a debt-to-GDP ratio of 200% and become
nearly certain around 275%.66 According to this model, the United States does not currently run a
significant risk of being unable to meet its debt obligations.


Author Information

Lida R. Weinstock

Analyst in Macroeconomic Policy


62 Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff, “Growth in a T ime of Debt,” American Economic Review, vol. 100
(May 2010), pp. 573-578.
63 T homas Herndon, Michael Ash, and Robert Pollin, “Does High Public Debt Consistently Stifle Economic Growth?
A Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff,” University of Massachusetts Amherst Political Economy Research Institute,
Working Paper no. 322, April 15, 2013.
64 Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff, “Debt, Growth and the Austerity Debate,” New York Times, April 25,
2013, https://www.nytimes.com/2013/04/26/opinion/debt-growth-and-the-austerity-debate.html?hp&_r=0.
65 David Greenlaw et al., “Crunch T ime: Fiscal Crises and the Role of Monetary Policy,” NBER, Working Paper no.
19297, August 2013.
66 Huixin Bi, Wenyi Shen, and Shu-Chun S. Yang, U.S. Federal Debt Has Increased, but Appears Sustainable for Now,
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, November 16, 2020, https://www.kansascityfed.org/research/economic-bulletin/
us-federal-debt-increased-appears-sustainable/.
Congressional Research Service

16

Federal Deficits, Growing Debt, and the Economy in the Wake of COVID-19



Disclaimer
This document was prepared by the Congressional Research Service (CRS). CRS serves as nonpartisan
shared staff to congressional committees and Members of Congress. It operates solely at the behest of and
under the direction of Congress. Information in a CRS Report should n ot be relied upon for purposes other
than public understanding of information that has been provided by CRS to Members of Congress in
connection with CRS’s institutional role. CRS Reports, as a work of the United States Government, are not
subject to copyright protection in the United States. Any CRS Report may be reproduced and distributed in
its entirety without permission from CRS. However, as a CRS Report may include copyrighted images or
material from a third party, you may need to obtain the permission of the copyright holder if you wish to
copy or otherwise use copyrighted material.

Congressional Research Service
R46729 · VERSION 1 · NEW
17