The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Seventeen of the European Union's 27 member states share an economic and monetary union (EMU) with the euro as a single currency. These countries are effectively referred to as the Eurozone. What has become known as the Eurozone crisis began in early 2010 when financial markets were shaken by heightened concerns that the fiscal positions of a number of Eurozone countries, beginning with Greece, were unsustainable. This report provides background information and analysis on the future of the Eurozone in six parts, including discussions on the origins and design challenges of the Eurozone, proposals to define the Eurozone crisis, possible scenarios for the future of the Eurozone, and the implications of the Eurozone crisis for U.S. economic and political interests.


The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests
Raymond J. Ahearn, Coordinator
Specialist in International Trade and Finance
James K. Jackson
Specialist in International Trade and Finance
Derek E. Mix
Analyst in European Affairs
Rebecca M. Nelson
Analyst in International Trade and Finance
January 17, 2012
Congressional Research Service
7-5700
www.crs.gov
R41411
CRS Report for Congress
Pr
epared for Members and Committees of Congress

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Summary
Seventeen of the European Union’s 27 member states share an economic and monetary union
(EMU) with the euro as a single currency. Based on a gross domestic product (GDP) and global
trade and investment shares comparable to those of the United States, these countries (collectively
referred to as the Eurozone) are a major player in the world economy and can affect U.S.
economic and political interests in significant ways. Given its economic and political heft, the
evolution and future direction of the Eurozone is of major interest to Congress, particularly
committees with oversight responsibilities for U.S. international economic and foreign policies.
Uncertainty about the future of the Eurozone began in early 2010 as a result of the onset of a
sovereign debt crisis in Greece. Subsequently, concerns spread that Ireland, Portugal, Spain, and
Italy also lacked sustainable fiscal positions. Fearing possible defaults, markets began demanding
substantially higher interest rates for their bonds. The debt problems of these countries, while
varying from case to case, now constitute a serious risk to the European banking system, the
viability of the euro, and the European integration process. Anemic growth in the Eurozone with a
mild recession forecast for 2012 is compounding the debt and banking problems. Standard &
Poor’s downgrade of the credit ratings of France, Italy, and seven other European countries on
January 13, 2012, served as an additional reminder that the crisis is far from over.
One important cause of the crisis stems from flaws in the architecture of the currency union,
including the fact that the EMU provides for a common central bank (the European Central Bank
or ECB), and thus a common monetary policy, but leaves fiscal policy up to the member
countries. Weak enforcement of fiscal discipline, over time, facilitated rising public debts in some
of the countries. Locked into the euro, individual members cannot inflate their way out of large
public debt or devalue their currency to make their exports more competitive.
In response, European leaders and institutions have combined measures to ease the debt crisis
with financial assistance packages for Greece, Ireland, and Portugal. The most highly indebted
Eurozone members have been forced to cut government spending and programs and to raise taxes
to improve their fiscal positions. A financial assistance facility, the European Financial Stability
Facility, has been created to help stabilize the crisis. The ECB has made large purchases of these
countries’ public debt in order to calm markets, and in December 2011 provided a huge infusion
of credit into the banking system. But many observers are now calling for more fundamental
solutions, such as the issuance of Eurobonds, along with other institutional reforms that could
provide a stronger fiscal foundation to the monetary union.
The reforms, if implemented, could strengthen the foundation of the Eurozone and bolster
confidence in the euro. At the same time, a number of factors could weaken or perhaps even
undermine the sustainability of the Eurozone. Public support in fiscally sound Eurozone
countries, such as Germany, Finland, and the Netherlands, for resource transfers to highly
indebted countries is weak. If the Eurozone survives largely in its current form or strengthens, the
impact on U.S. interests is likely to be minimal. However, if Greece or any other Eurozone
member were to default on its debt, it could lead to another wave of credit freeze-ups and
instability in the European banking sector that weakens a slow growing U.S. economy. Longer
term, if the Eurozone were to break up in a way that undermines the functioning of Europe’s
single market, or resurrects national divisions, the impact on U.S. economic and political interests
could be deeper and more damaging.
Congressional Research Service

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Contents
Introduction...................................................................................................................................... 1
Background on the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) ........................................................... 3
Origins, Rationale, and Economic Significance........................................................................ 4
Key Provisions of the EMU....................................................................................................... 5
Design Challenges ..................................................................................................................... 7
Economic Imbalances and Adjustment Mechanisms within the Eurozone ..................................... 8
Imbalances within the Eurozone................................................................................................ 9
Adjustment Mechanisms ......................................................................................................... 11
Eurozone Crisis Measures and Reform Proposals ......................................................................... 13
Financial Assistance to Greece, Portugal, and Ireland ............................................................ 13
New EU Financing Facilities................................................................................................... 14
European Financial Stability Mechanism.......................................................................... 15
European Financial Stability Facility ................................................................................ 15
European Central Bank Response ..................................................................................... 16
Economic Governance Reforms.............................................................................................. 17
Fiscal Policy Reforms ....................................................................................................... 17
Economic Growth Policies................................................................................................ 17
Possible Scenarios for the Future of the Eurozone ........................................................................ 18
Scenario 1. The Eurozone Breaks Apart.................................................................................. 18
Exit by One or More Southern European Countries ......................................................... 19
Exit by One or More Northern European Countries ......................................................... 19
Scenario 2. The Eurozone Survives......................................................................................... 20
Scenario 3. The Eurozone Becomes More Integrated ............................................................. 21
Implications for U.S. Interests ....................................................................................................... 22
Economic Implications............................................................................................................ 22
U.S. Policy Options ................................................................................................................. 23
Political Implications............................................................................................................... 24
Concluding Observations............................................................................................................... 24

Figures
Figure 1. Economic Trends in the Eurozone.................................................................................. 10
Figure 2. Selected European Current Account Balances ............................................................... 12

Tables
Table 1. EU-IMF Assistance for Greece, Ireland, and Portugal .................................................... 14
Table 2. Glossary of Terms ............................................................................................................ 27

Congressional Research Service

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Contacts
Author Contact Information........................................................................................................... 28
Acknowledgments ......................................................................................................................... 28

Congressional Research Service

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Introduction
What has become known as the Eurozone crisis began in early 2010 when financial markets were
shaken by heightened concerns that the fiscal positions of a number of Eurozone countries,
beginning with Greece, were unsustainable. Fears that a possible Greek default could spread to
other Eurozone countries, particularly Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain, were exacerbated by
revelations of banking sector weaknesses and a delayed policy response from European leaders
and institutions. After extended negotiations, European leaders and the International Monetary
Fund (IMF) agreed in May 2010 to provide funding for a €110 billion (about $158 billion) loan
facility for Greece and a broader stabilization fund for other euro area countries should they
require loans.1 Both loan packages were backstopped by various forms of assistance from the
U.S. Federal Reserve Board (FRB) and the IMF.2 The Greek bail-out was followed in December
2010 by a €67.5 billion (about $97 billion) rescue package for Ireland, and a €78 billion (about
$112 billion) loan for Portugal in May 2011. In July 2011, a second financial assistance package
totaling €109 billion (about $157 billion) was agreed to for Greece.3 In the most recent EU
summit on December 8-9, 2011, EU leaders announced a number of new policy measures,
including a fiscal compact and extension of bilateral lines of credit from European countries to
the IMF, to address the Eurozone crisis.4
These policy responses, resulting from nearly 15 “crisis summits” over the past two years have
contained but not resolved the crisis. Standard & Poor’s downgrade of the credit ratings of
France, Italy, and seven other Eurozone members on January 13, 2012, was based, in part, on the
view that European leaders are moving too slowly to strengthen the monetary union as the region
heads into its second recession in three years.5 The same day suspension of negotiations between
Greece and its creditors (commercial banks and other private holders of Greek debt) on accepting
large losses to make its debt more manageable only added to the concern that the crisis is far from
over.6

1 Germany was widely criticized, including by U.S. officials, for waiting several months after the onset of the Greek
crisis in February 2010 before agreeing to loan facilities for Greece and other Eurozone member states. German
reluctance is thought to have stemmed primarily from strong domestic opposition to the proposed relief packages.
Many Germans consider Greece’s problems to be a consequence of Greek government profligacy and, as such, see
Greece as a burden on the German taxpayer. In light of this opposition, German Chancellor Merkel insisted that the
Greek government commit to significant austerity measures before giving her support to a European assistance
package. Nevertheless, the significant German public opposition to assisting Greece and establishing the loan facilities
suggests that the German government could have a difficult time winning support for future monetary transfers to other
Eurozone countries. This could present a significant challenge as European leaders engage in ongoing efforts to contain
the crisis and shore up the banking sector.
2 The United States is the largest financial contributor to the IMF, and some Members of Congress have expressed
reservations about the IMF loan to Greece. In response to the IMF loan to Greece, Congress included provisions in the
financial regulatory legislation (P.L. 111-203) to protect IMF resources.
3 Implementation of the package is pending negotiations with Greece about meeting the imposed conditions. For
elaboration and analysis of the Greek debt crisis, see CRS Report R41167, Greece’s Debt Crisis: Overview, Policy
Responses, and Implications
, coordinated by Rebecca M. Nelson.
4 Statement by the Euro Area Heads of State or Government, December 9, 2011,
http://www.consilium.europa.eu.uedocs/cms_Dat/docs/pressdata/en/ec/126658.pdf.
5 Liz Alderman and Rachel Donadio, “Debt Ratings Cut for 9 Countries Amid Euro Woes,” New York Times, January
14, 2012. The other countries downgraded were Austria, Slovenia, Slovakia, Spain, Malta, Cyprus, and Portugal.
6 Nelson D. Schwartz, “Euro Woes Could Revive Bout of Market Volatility,” New York Times, January 16, 2012.
Congressional Research Service
1

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Some analysts believe that European leaders need to provide more financial resources to defend
countries such as Italy and Spain against contagion, provide more liquidity to under-capitalized
European banks, enact stricter rules to prevent governments from overspending, and provide
more debt relief to the insolvent Greek government. Other observers emphasize that the Eurozone
is institutionally flawed and that efforts to fix this flaw with more rigid rules will not work. This
argument is that a monetary union without a fiscal union is unstable and that only common fiscal
institutions, such as joint debt issuance and a pooling of budgetary resources, can ensure the
Eurozone’s survival.
European policymakers have, in fact, focused on the need to address flaws in the architecture of
the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) of the European Union (EU).7 Most observers believe
that reform of the currency union is needed in order to bolster the euro and avoid another fiscal
crisis triggered by public debt and government deficits. How the members of the Eurozone
address this overriding challenge to bolster the viability and stability of the currency union has
added significance. Unlike in countries such as Argentina or Mexico, where currency crises did
not bring into question the existence or survival of the state, the euro bears weight in terms of
Europe’s political aspirations for an “ever closer union.” As viewed by German Chancellor
Angela Merkel, “the currency union is ... a question, no more or less, of the preservation of the
European idea ... for if the euro fails, Europe fails.”8
A broad range of views exists on the future of the Eurozone. Some academics and journalists
maintain that fears about the long-term viability of the Eurozone are exaggerated. The most
optimistic, in fact, see the crisis as an opportunity to advance the idea of an “ever closer union”
by pursuing greater economic integration and joint coordination of fiscal policy on the European
level. Other observers maintain that a potential break-up of the currency union, in part or in
whole, cannot be ruled out, particularly given the difficulties a number of member governments
are having in servicing their debt. While such a development would not necessarily lead to the
demise of the European Union, most observers agree that a break-up would be destabilizing. A
middle-ground perspective holds that Europe has the option to muddle through the crisis by
introducing a combination of liquidity facilities and reforms that will lower fiscal deficits and
raise economic growth in financially troubled member states.9
The Obama Administration, Federal Reserve (Fed), and Congress have been actively engaged in
monitoring and working towards an orderly resolution of the Eurozone crisis. President Obama
and Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner reportedly have been in close contact with European
leaders, urging them to take decisive action to resolve the crisis. The Federal Reserve on
September 15, 2011 reactivated dollar loans or liquidity swap lines with the ECB in an effort to

7 A total of 17 states (Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy,
Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, Portugal, Slovakia, Spain, and Slovenia) of the 27-member European Union (EU)
participate in an economic and monetary union (EMU) with the euro as the single currency. The other members of the
EU are Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Denmark, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, Sweden, and the United
Kingdom. All 27 members take part in the “economic union” through various forms of policy coordination, a single
market, and single external trade policy, but 17 members have taken economic integration a step further, to the EMU.
Denmark and the United Kingdom were granted special opt-outs of the currency union and are legally exempt from
joining unless their governments decide otherwise, either by parliamentary vote or referendum. Sweden has gained a
de-facto opt-out through the use of various legal provisions. The other 7 members of the EU who joined after 2004
have committed or are expected to adopt the euro as soon as they meet certain economic policy targets.
8 Ben Hall and Quentin Peel, “Adrift Amid a Rift,” Financial Times, June 24, 2010.
9 Jacob Funk Kirkegaard, “How Europe Can Muddle Through Its Crisis,” Peterson Institute for International
Economics,
December 2010.
Congressional Research Service
2

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

ensure that European banks do not incur any temporary shortages of liquidity.10 The 112th
Congress has held five hearings to date on various aspects of the crisis and its implications for the
United States.11
A major U.S. concern is that a sovereign default by Greece or another member of the Eurozone
or the collapse of a major European financial institution, could ignite a wave of credit freeze-ups
that would spillover to U.S. and global financial markets and serve as a major shock to the U.S.
stock market and economy. An additional U.S. concern is that the slowing Eurozone economy,
along with a depreciating euro, will adversely affect U.S exports and earnings of U.S.
companies.12
This report provides background information and analysis on the future of the Eurozone in six
parts:
• the first part discusses the origins, rationale, economic significance, key
provisions, and design challenges of the Eurozone;
• the second section describes how persistent economic imbalances are underlying
causes of the Eurozone crisis and analyzes how the imbalances are related to
inadequate adjustment mechanisms within the EMU;
• the third section focuses on proposals to defuse the Eurozone crisis and
strengthen the framework of the currency union;
• the fourth section examines three possible scenarios for the future of the
Eurozone: (1) the Eurozone breaks apart, (2) the Eurozone survives, and (3) the
Eurozone becomes more integrated;
• the fifth section assesses the implications of the Eurozone crisis for U.S.
economic and political interests; and
• a sixth and final section offers concluding observations.
Background on the Economic and Monetary Union
(EMU)

EMU officially stands for Economic and Monetary Union, but it also commonly referred to as the
European Monetary Union. EMU is the agreement among participating countries of the European
Union to adopt a single currency, the euro, and a common monetary policy set by a common
central bank, the ECB.

10 Neil Irwin and Michael Birnbaum, “Fed Move to Steer Dollars to Banks in the Euro Zone,” Washington Post,
September 16, 2011.
11 Senate Banking, Security and International Trade and Finance Subcommittee, September 22, 2011; House Financial
Services, International Monetary Policy and Trade, October 25, 2011; Foreign Affairs, Europe, and Eurasia
Subcommittee, October 27, 2011; Senate Foreign Relations, European Subcommittee, November 2, 2011; and House
Oversight Subcommittee on TARP, Financial Services, and Bailouts of Public and Private Programs, December 15,
2011.
12 Conrad De Aenlle, “That Bright Light May Be Deceiving,” New York Times, January 8, 2012.
Congressional Research Service
3

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Origins, Rationale, and Economic Significance
The origins of EMU are closely linked with the international monetary system established after
World War II.13 As part of the post-war reconstruction efforts, countries returned to a gold
standard and created a fixed, but adjustable, system of international exchange rates based on a
fixed exchange rate between the U.S. dollar and the price of gold. The goal was to provide
international monetary stability, facilitate trade, and prevent the competitive devaluations,
unstable exchange rates, and protectionist trade policies of the interwar years. While European
leaders had begun the process of economic integration immediately following World War II,
consideration of monetary union did not begin in earnest until the international monetary anchor
provided by the dollar-gold standard collapsed in 1971 and a new wave of currency instability
emerged amidst divergent national policy responses to several 1970s economic shocks, including
the oil crisis.
In 1979, the nine member countries of the European Economic Community (EEC) created the
European Monetary System (EMS). The EMS introduced fixed but adjustable exchange rates
among participating countries’ currencies in order to keep fluctuations of their exchange rates
within acceptable bands. In 1988, the European Commission, then led by Jacques Delors, chaired
a committee which proposed a three-stage plan to reach full economic union. The plan included
the establishment of a European central bank and a single currency that would replace national
currencies.
The EMU officially began on January 1, 1999, when 11 EU members pegged their currencies at a
fixed exchange rate in preparation for adoption of a common currency, the euro. Participating
countries have a common central bank, the European Central Bank (ECB), and by extension a
common monetary policy. Fiscal policy, or decisions about spending and taxation were left to the
individual member states, subject to the 1997 Stability and Growth Pact.
The primary rationale for the EMU was to provide momentum for political union, a long-standing
goal of many European policymakers. Germany and France, Europe’s largest economies, played
the lead role in establishing the EMU, but they have not always agreed on the management and
direction of the single currency. Most observers believe that Germany’s initial support for
monetary union was motivated more by political than economic interests—former Chancellor
Helmut Kohl saw the currency union as an important way to anchor Germany securely in a united
Europe. French leaders, on the other hand, are thought to have viewed the currency union as a key
step to increasing French influence within Europe. Each country subsequently had different
priorities in guiding the development of the monetary union. Germany has insisted that the
Eurozone be anchored in a culture of tight money, low inflation policy, and fiscal discipline.
Accordingly, the ECB’s overriding commitment to price stability is thought to reflect German
preferences. For its part, France has pushed for more flexibility in European monetary policy and
for more political control over the inflation-fighting ECB.14
Although political goals were the driving force in the move towards monetary union, discussions
of EMU also focused heavily on its economic costs and benefits. Generally, European monetary

13 For more information, see Harold James, International Monetary Cooperation Since Breton Woods (Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1996).
14 Katina Borsch, “Germany, The Euro and Politics of the Bail-out,” Centre for European Reform, Briefing Note, June
2010.
Congressional Research Service
4

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

union was expected to make Europe’s economy more efficient, thereby raising the living
standards of Europe. For example, it would eliminate the transaction costs of changing one
currency into another, which would benefit both consumers and producers. Additional economic
benefits included lowering the cost of trading goods by removing exchange rate risk and currency
conversion fees and by facilitating price comparisons of goods and services across national
borders. Cost savings that arise from greater competition also induce direct investment from non-
Eurozone countries as foreign firms attempt to locate facilities within the Eurozone area to access
a larger market. Proponents of the EMU also wanted the euro to become one of the reserve
currencies of international finance, alongside the dollar and the yen.15
The now 17 members of the Eurozone have considerable economic heft. Comprising some 320
million people, the gross domestic product (GDP) of the entire Eurozone area was $12.2 trillion
in 2010,16 or about 19% of world GDP. By comparison, the GDP of the United States in 2010 was
slightly larger at $14.6 trillion. Within the Eurozone, economic weight is heavily concentrated in
a few large countries. More than 76% of the Eurozone’s total GDP is accounted for by just four
countries (Germany, France, Italy, and Spain). In contrast, the Eurozone’s five smallest countries
(in decreasing size: Slovakia, Slovenia, Luxembourg, Cyprus, and Malta) accounted for less than
2% of the Eurozone’s overall GDP in the same year.
The Eurozone is also a major player in the world economy. As a whole, it accounted for 29% of
total world exports; 28% of world imports; and 23% of world net inflows of foreign direct
investment (FDI) in 2010.17 The United States also has a strong bilateral economic relationship
with the Eurozone.18 With respect to merchandise trade, U.S. exports to Eurozone members
totaled $176.7 billion in 2010, representing 14% of total U.S. exports of goods. Likewise, the
value of U.S. imports of goods from the Eurozone in 2010 was $242.7 billion, or 13% of total
U.S. imports.19 In terms of capital flows, U.S. investors on net repatriated $180.6 billion dollars
from the Eurozone in 2010.20
Key Provisions of the EMU
The blueprint for the EMU was formalized in provisions of the 1992 Maastricht Treaty, the
founding document of the present-day European Union. The Treaty established the conditions, or
“convergence criteria,” that countries are required to meet before they join the EMU.21 By

15 For further background on the economic costs and benefits of monetary union with a focus on the EMU, see Paul De
Grauwe, Economics of Monetary Union (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009).
16 World Bank’s World Development Indicators database. Data in current US$.
17 World Bank’s World Development Indicators database. Data in current US$.
18 For more on the bilateral economic relationship between the United States and the EU, see CRS Report RL30608,
EU-U.S. Economic Ties: Framework, Scope, and Magnitude, by William H. Cooper.
19 Cost-in-freight data.
20 U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, http://www.bea.gov.
21 To participate in the initial formation of the EMU, each member had to meet the following five convergence criteria
by 1998: (1) national legislation governing the country's financial system had to be compatible with the treaty
provisions controlling the European System of Central Banks; (2) a rate of inflation within 1.5% of the rates in the
three participating countries with the lowest rates; (3) reduction of its government deficits to below 3% of its gross
national product; (4) currency exchange rates within the limits defined by the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) (an
intermediary step toward a single currency that attempted to stabilize exchange rates by fixing rates through variable
bands) for at least two years; and (5)interest rates within 2% of the rates in the three participating countries with the
lowest rates.
Congressional Research Service
5

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

requiring the members to adhere to similar economic policies, the convergence criteria are meant
to promote more balanced economic growth and development among the various members of the
Eurozone. This, in turn, was thought to make it easier for diverse economies to share a single
currency.

EU Treaties
The Treaty on European Union (TEU or the Maastricht Treaty) is the founding document of the modern European
Union. Together, the TEU and the 1957 Treaty establishing the European Economic Community (also known as the
Rome Treaty or the EEC Treaty, and recently re-named the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, or
TFEU) define the objectives and principles of the EU and set out the EU’s institutional architecture and organizational
rules. The Lisbon Treaty, which entered into force in December 2009, is the most recent treaty amending these
documents.
Consolidated versions of the TEU and the TFEU are available in the Official Journal of the European Union, March 30,
2010, available at: http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:C:2010:083:FULL:EN:PDF
As an integral part of the EMU, a European Central Bank (ECB) was established to set monetary
policy independent of any political influence. The ECB together with the central banks of all the
members of the European Union form the European System of Central Banks, or ESCB, which is
charged by statute with maintaining price stability as its primary objective. The formulation of
price stability as a primary ESCB objective, compared to the U.S. Federal Reserve’s multiple
mandates of price stability, full employment, and moderate long-term interest rates, was a German
pre-condition for sacrificing the Deutsche mark.22
There was no provision in the Maastricht Treaty to allow the ECB to act as a lender of last resort
to Eurozone members in the case of a financial crisis. According to the EMU’s design, each
member must finance its deficits by itself. A “no-bail-out” clause explicitly stipulates that neither
the European Union nor any member state is liable for or can assume the debts of any other
member state.23 However, EU financial assistance is allowed in case of “severe difficulties caused
by natural disasters or exceptional occurrences beyond the control of a member state.”24
For the mutual assurance and stability of the currency, all members are constrained in their ability
to adopt independent fiscal policies by the Protocol on Excessive Deficit Procedure (EDP) and
the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP). The EDP is a procedure under which member states are

22 Paul De Grouse, Economics of Monetary Union.
23 Article 125 TFEU is often referred to as the EU’s “no-bailout” clause. It states:
The Union shall not be liable for or assume the commitments of central governments, regional,
local or other public authorities, other bodies governed by public law, or public undertakings of any
Member State, without prejudice to mutual financial guarantees for the joint execution of a specific
project. A Member State shall not be liable for or assume the commitments of central governments,
regional, local or other public authorities, other bodies governed by public law, or public
undertakings of another Member State, without prejudice to mutual financial guarantees for the
joint execution of a specific project.
24European leaders drew reference to these exceptions (Article 122(2) TFEU) in crafting new crisis management
facilities. They explicitly based the bailout actions on the grounds that the debt crisis endangered the solvency of entire
states and posed a serious threat to the euro and financial stability of the monetary union. For a contrary view that the
euro was endangered by the crisis, see Hans-Werner Sinn, “Rescuing Europe,” CWSifo Forum, Volume 1, August
2010. Sinn argues that the bailout was engineered primarily to protect French, and to a lesser extent, German banks.
Congressional Research Service
6

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

obliged to avoid excessive deficits in national budgets.25 The SGP, agreed to in 1997, was
intended to deepen multilateral surveillance and “speed up and clarify” implementation of the
EDP.26
Soon after the SGP took effect in 1999, EU members began criticizing the rules-based approach
of the Pact for being too stringent and they questioned whether the rules could be enforced. In
2003, the weaknesses of the Pact were exposed when the European Council voted against
applying the punitive procedures under the EDP to France and Germany, which had experienced
rising levels of government debt. Some EU members argued that the Pact focused too heavily on
the rules-based percentage guidelines without regard for the circumstances under which a
government’s level of debt or its deficit spending may rise, for instance as a result of a temporary
increase in government spending to counter an economic downturn.27
In 2005, the EU members adopted a number of changes to the SGP. These changes made
enforcement more flexible to take into account the economic conditions of the member states, and
other factors. For example, the modified Pact provides for each EU member to develop its own
medium-term objectives to bring its deficit spending and its debt level into compliance based on
the unique economic conditions of each member. The changes also allow EU members to avoid
the corrective measures in cases where their annual fiscal deficit exceeds 3% of GDP, if they can
demonstrate that the deficit is caused by “exceptional and temporary” circumstances.
Design Challenges
From the start of the euro area, various academics and policymakers argued that a single currency
for many different economies would face numerous challenges and some even argued that it was
bound to fail. According to these critics, a big weakness of the project was the lack of a common
fiscal policy to support it. This, in turn reflected the fact that it was a currency with a central bank
but without a government that has taxation and spending authority. The creation of the euro also
meant that members of the Eurozone lost their ability to use monetary and exchange rate policy
tools as a way to respond to changes in economic conditions.28
The loss of monetary and exchange rate tools, combined with a lack of a common fiscal policy,
creates vulnerabilities and tensions because members of the Eurozone are constrained in how they
respond to economic shocks such as a recession. Countries are different and in a recession are
likely to experience different unemployment rates. In a currency union, the central bank will set a
common interest rate that may end up too high for the high unemployment country (resulting in

25 The Protocol on Excessive Deficit Procedure established a mechanism for countries to meet the specific guidelines
that are applied under Article 104 of the Maastricht Treaty. Under this protocol, EU members are expected to have an
annual budget deficit no greater than 3% of GDP at market prices and government debt no more than an amount
equivalent to 60% of GDP.
26 The Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) is an agreement by European Union members to conduct their fiscal policy in a
manner that facilitates and maintains the EMU. The Pact is based on Articles 99 and 104 of the Maastricht Treaty, and
related decisions. It consists of (1) a political commitment by all parties involved in the SGP to the full and timely
implementation of the budget surveillance process; (2) regular surveillance aimed at preventing budget deficits from
going above the 3% reference value; and (3) corrective elements which require member states to take immediate action
when the 3% reference value is breached or face the imposition of sanctions.
27 Beetsma, Roel M.W.J., and Xavier Debrun, Implementing the Stability and Growth Pact: Enforcement and
Procedural Flexibility
, IMF Working Paper WP/05/59, International Monetary Fund, March 2005.
28 Martin Feldstein, “The Euro’s Fundamental Flaws,” The International Economy, Spring 2010, p. 11.
Congressional Research Service
7

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

lost employment and output), and too low for the low unemployment country (resulting in excess
spending and consumption), exacerbating the business cycle in both countries.
Despite these costs, joining a currency union may be advantageous as long as there are
adjustment mechanisms that ensure that the benefits of membership such as lower transaction
costs and exchange rate certainty exceed the costs. These adjustment mechanisms, in the absence
of a common federal budget and robust transfer mechanisms from countries experiencing booms
to the countries experiencing recessions, include labor and capital mobility and wage and price
flexibility. For example, the unemployment disparities could be reduced if workers from a
country with high unemployment relocated to the one with low unemployment. Or, relative labor
costs could fall in the high unemployment country to attract investment and create new jobs. In
the absence of viable adjustment mechanisms, there are likely to be strains and tensions within a
currency union.29
The functioning of the dollar in the U.S. economy, despite major differences among its 50 states,
is facilitated by adjustment mechanisms that are either absent or deficient in the Eurozone. For
example, U.S. unemployed workers move much more freely from Maine to Minnesota than do
European unemployed workers from Spain to Slovenia because of factors such as language or
common regulations. Prices of basic consumer durables vary little among the U.S. states but can
be substantial among the members of the Eurozone. And the federal government in Washington
collects roughly two-thirds of all taxes and provides net fiscal transfers to states with temporarily
falling incomes. No such substantial fiscal transfers occur in the Eurozone.30
Just as critical as the lack of a common federal budget to transfer resources from countries
experiencing booms to countries experiencing recessions, the single currency can weaken the
market signals that would otherwise warn a member that its fiscal deficits were becoming
excessive. When a country with an excessive deficit needs to raise taxes and cut government
spending, as is the case in many Eurozone countries now, the resulting contraction in output and
employment cannot be moderated by a devaluation that increases exports and decreases imports.
These shortcomings or design flaws inherent in the architecture of the currency union played a
role in the sovereign debt crisis that hit Greece and several other Eurozone members in early 2010
and are discussed in the next section.
Economic Imbalances and Adjustment Mechanisms
within the Eurozone

At the time of the euro’s launch in 1999, a number of economists predicted that the monetary
union would not survive because of shortcomings in its architecture. This section describes (1)
the persistent economic imbalances that are at the heart of the current crisis; and (2) how the
imbalances are related to the institutional constraints of the monetary union itself, particularly the
lack of adequate adjustment mechanisms that can bridge the gap in competitiveness between the
Eurozone’s wealthy northern countries and the more spendthrift periphery.

29 Faltin, Dirk, and Katherine Klingensmith, “Eurozone Economics: The Future of the Euro in Jeopardy,” UBS Wealth
Management Research,
July 13, 2010.
30Martin Feldstein, p.12.
Congressional Research Service
8

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Imbalances within the Eurozone
When the euro was introduced, many economists expected that the national economies within the
Eurozone would achieve additional convergence. However, many of the Eurozone economies
have remained quite different or have actually diverged in a number of dimensions since the euro
was introduced over a decade ago. This divergence is generally thought to have occurred between
two groups of countries within the Eurozone: the Northern European countries, including Austria,
Belgium, Germany, Finland, France, Luxembourg, and the Netherlands; and a group of mostly
Southern European countries, including Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain. These latter
five countries are often referred to by the acronym “GIIPS.”
Figure 1 shows average economic trends in these two groups of countries over the past decade.
Prior to the outbreak of the global financial crisis in 2008, the GIIPS experienced higher rates of
economic growth on average than the Northern European countries. However, the GIIPS also
generally experienced faster growth in prices (inflation), including faster growth in the
compensation for workers (adjusted for differences in worker productivity). This resulted in a loss
of industrial competitiveness for the GIIPS and an increase in industrial competitiveness for the
Northern European countries. As a result, the GIIPS on average ran trade deficits, while the
Northern European countries generally ran large trade surpluses. The GIIPS also generally ran
larger government budget deficits (relative to GDP) and accumulated higher levels of government
debt (relative to GDP) than Northern European countries.
Congressional Research Service
9


The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Figure 1. Economic Trends in the Eurozone

Source: GDP growth, inflation, budget, and debt data are from the IMF’s World Economic Outlook database.
Unit labor cost are from the Source OECD database. Trade data is from the World Bank’s World Development
Indicators.
Congressional Research Service
10

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Notes: GIIPS refers to Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain. Northern Eurozone countries include Austria,
Belgium, Germany, Finland, France, Luxembourg, and the Netherlands. Five countries that have joined the Euro
zone in 2007 or later (Cyprus, Estonia, Malta, Slovenia, and Slovakia) are not included. Unweighted averages
used. Growth data is adjusted for inflation (real growth). Trade data are for goods and services. Budget and debt
data are for general government (central, state, and local levels).
Much of the money that the GIIPS borrowed to finance trade and budget deficits came from
banks located in the Eurozone, particularly French and German banks. The exposure of French
and German banks to the GIIPS rose from $357.2 billion in December 1999 to $1.6 trillion in
December 2009, an increase of more than 450%.31 In sum, the net borrowers (the GIIPS) were
being financed by the net savers (Northern European countries).
Adjustment Mechanisms
Differences between the economies of Northern Europe and the GIIPS can be attributed to a
number of factors, including policy choices.32 For example, Germany’s export-led economic
strategy and commitment to wage moderation is often cited as a factor for its low costs of
production and trade surpluses.
However, many have suggested that the imbalances are caused by the institutional arrangements
of the currency union itself and its inadequate adjustment mechanisms. This argument typically
proceeds as follows:33 After the GIIPS adopted the euro, investors viewed these countries as safer
destinations for investment, and the interest rates paid by the GIIPS on their government bonds
fell to the interest rates paid by Northern European countries. As a result, interest rates in the
GIIPS were far too low, leading to distorted investment decisions and ultimately overinvestment
in a number of sectors. As private sector borrowing and demand increased, the GIIPS launched
investment projects to allow growth to take place with less inflation. This, in turn, required
increased borrowing, particularly from banks in Northern European countries, and contributed to
larger government budget deficits.
Capital inflows into the GIIPS fueled domestic demand, leading to high levels of growth, but also
to inflation. Increasing prices in the GIIPS reduced their competitiveness, and consequently,
caused the GIIPS to start running current account deficits (see Figure 2).34 Each year’s current
account deficits added to the public and private aggregate debt of the GIIPS. As part of this
process, the GIIPS accumulated foreign debt which rose close to 80% of GDP.35

31 Bank for International Settlements (BIS), “Consolidated International Claims of BIS Reporting Banks,” Publication
data up to 2009Q4, June 2010, Table 9B: Consolidated Foreign Claims of Reporting Banks - Immediate Borrower
Basis, http://www.bis.org/statistics/consstats.htm. Data includes exposure to the GIIPS governments (sovereigns) and
private sectors.
32 Gilles Saint-Paul, “Is the Euro a Failure?,” VoxEU, May 5, 2010.
33 Uri Dadush and Bennett Stancil, “Europe’s Debt Crisis: More than a Fiscal Problem,” in Paradigm Lost: The Euro in
Crisis
, ed. Uri Dadush and Contributors (Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 2010), pp. 9-15.
34 The current account is the sum of the balance of trade (exports minus imports of goods and services), net factor
income such as interest payments and dividends, and net transfer payments such as foreign aid. Measures to reduce a
current account deficit usually involve increasing exports or decreasing imports. Economists tend to argue that this can
be accomplished most effectively by increasing domestic savings or reducing borrowing of households and
government.
35 Dirk Faltin and Katherine Klingensmith, “Eurozone Economics: The Future of the Euro in Jeopardy,” p. 6.
Congressional Research Service
11


The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Figure 2. Selected European Current Account Balances
Percent of GDP

Source: International Monetary Fund
Meanwhile, most Northern European economies did not face dramatic reductions in their interest
rates upon joining the Eurozone and did not have substantial increases in capital inflows.
Combined with fiscal policies that aimed to contain domestic demand, the Northern European
countries as a result had lower inflation and remained more competitive than their GIIPS
counterparts. Partly due to their relative competitiveness, the Northern European countries were
able to export to the GIIPS and run large current account trade surpluses.36
Some suggest that being in the Eurozone constrained the ability of the GIIPS governments to
respond to growing divergences from the Northern European countries.37 For example, if the
GIIPS countries had not been in the Eurozone, they could have reduced their trade deficits
through currency depreciation. Likewise, the GIIPS countries could have raised interest rates to
slow economic growth in response to a potentially over-heating economy. But as members of the
Eurozone, neither devaluation nor an increase in interest rates is an option.
The GIIPS countries did retain some control over their fiscal policy and could have reined in
government spending or raised taxes in order to curb consumption. Such a policy could have
freed up resources for payments to foreign creditors. However, the low interest rates resulting
from Eurozone membership increased the attractiveness of government deficit spending, and the

36 Given that about 75% of all Eurozone trade constitutes exports of one Eurozone member to another (so-called “intra-
Eurozone trade”), the trade surpluses of one Eurozone country or group of countries are to a large extent matched by
the deficits of others.
37 Gilles Saint-Paul, “Is the Euro a Failure?”, VoxEU, May 5, 2010.
Congressional Research Service
12

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

GIIPS countries generally borrowed, running budget deficits. Alternatively, given that inflation
was twice as high in the GIIPS countries than the EMU average, real interest rates (i.e., nominal
rates minus inflation) were extremely low, thereby discouraging savings and causing private firms
and households to run up debt to finance consumption and housing construction, especially in
Spain and Ireland.38
Given their membership in the Eurozone, the GIIPS are left with using deflation (decreases in
wages, incomes, and prices) in order to reduce their trade deficits. However, deflation may have
little beneficial effect on the foreign debt positions of most of the GIIPS if they all pursue the
same strategy simultaneously. This is because the negative effects on economic growth and
employment could be compounded, weakening the economies of the GIIPS to the point where
their debt-to-GDP ratios continue to rise.39
In sum, the trade imbalances between the Northern countries and GIIPS provide evidence that the
EMU’s internal adjustment mechanisms are not working well. Whatever labor mobility and price
flexibility that exists in the Eurozone, combined with limited fiscal transfers, did not prevent the
accumulation of persistent trade imbalances and the current economic crisis. While improved
labor mobility and price flexibility may be long-term solutions, European leaders and institutions
are now considering a range of proposals to increase fiscal coordination and integration as the
best way to shore-up the EMU’s institutional shortcomings.
Eurozone Crisis Measures and Reform Proposals
Beginning in May 2010, European leaders and institutions adopted an unprecedented package of
emergency measures to halt rising financial market tensions stemming from concern about the
fiscal solvency of Greece and several other Eurozone countries. This section briefly discusses the
crisis measures adopted to defuse the crisis and the reform proposals for economic governance
and economic policies.
Financial Assistance to Greece, Portugal, and Ireland
Current concerns about the sustainability of domestic finances in several Eurozone countries
began in early 2010 when investor sentiment turned against Greece, which had borrowed heavily
in international capital markets over the past decade. Analysts argue that this borrowing was
necessary to support high government spending, weak revenue collection, structural rigidities,
and declining competitiveness.40 Access to capital at low interest rates after adopting the euro and
weak enforcement of EU rules concerning debt and deficit ceilings helped set the stage for the
current sovereign debt crisis.41


38 Dick Faltin and Katherine Klingensmith, “Eurozone Economics: The Future of the Euro In Jeopardy,” p.5.
39 Ibid., p. 8.
40 For more information, see: CRS Report R41167, Greece’s Debt Crisis: Overview, Policy Responses, and
Implications
, coordinated by Rebecca M. Nelson.
41 For more information, see: CRS Report R41838, Sovereign Debt in Advanced Economies: Overview and Issues for
Congress
, by Rebecca M. Nelson.
Congressional Research Service
13

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

To date, Greece, Ireland, and Portugal have received significant financial assistance packages
from the IMF and Euro area and EU fiscal facilities (Table 1). The ECB has also contributed
extensively to European economic stability, actively intervening to support European
governments and banks. Despite this support, concerns increased that the crisis could spread to
the larger European economies, including Italy and Spain. Investor concerns about the likelihood
of default in Greece and the other countries receiving financial assistance, as well as doubts about
the ability of European authorities to agree on sufficient economic reforms, pushed the cost of
issuing European sovereign debt up sharply for most Eurozone members except Germany.42
Table 1. EU-IMF Assistance for Greece, Ireland, and Portugal
European Financial
IMF Financial
Total Financial
Date
Agreed Assistance
Assistance
Assistance
Greece May
2010
€80
billion
€30 billion
€110 billion
(about $104 billion)
(about $39 billion)
(about $143 billion)

Greecea
July 2011
€109 billion
€109
billion
(about €142 billion)
(about €142 billion)
Irelandb
December 2010
€45 billion
€22.5 billion
€67.5 billion
(about $59 billion)
(about $29 billion)
(about $88 billion)

Portugal
May 2011
€52 billion
€26 billion
€78 billion
(about $68 billion)
(about $34 billion)
(about $102 billion)
Source: IMF press releases.
Notes: Figures denominated in euros converted to dol ars using exchange rate on December 15, 2011: €1 =
$1.3019. Figures may not add due to rounding.
a. Pending ratification by participating countries.
b. The headline number used by the IMF and in news reports for Ireland’s total financial assistance package
was €85 billion. This includes €17.5 billion (about $25 billion) from Ireland’s cash reserves and other liquid
assets. Resources used by national authorities in the crisis response are not included in the table above.
New EU Financing Facilities
The primary institutions available for providing emergency financial support to European
governments and financial institutions, in addition to national authorities, are the European
Financial Stabilization Mechanism (EFSM), the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF),
and the ECB. The IMF is also expected to make contributions as well as play a coordinating role,
as it has much expertise in financial surveillance and putting together sovereign debt packages.43

42 Art Patnaude and Mark Brown, "European Funding Costs Hit Record Highs," Wall Street Journal, September 12,
2011.
43 At the December 2011 Summit, leaders extended €200 billion (about $260 billion) in bilateral lines of credit from
European countries to the IMF, leaving open the possibility that other countries outside of Europe could also contribute
to the IMF.
Congressional Research Service
14

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

European Financial Stability Mechanism
The EFSM is a €60 billion supranational EU balance of payments loan facility created in 2010
and available to any EU member country facing financial difficulties. It is similar in design to an
existing €50 billion EU balance of payments facility that can only be drawn on by non-Eurozone
EU member nations.44 Since 2008, Hungary, Latvia, and Romania have borrowed from this
facility as part of joint EU-IMF economic adjustment programs.
Under the EFSM, the European Commission is allowed to raise up to an additional €60 billion on
the international capital market by issuing bonds individually and collectively backed by all 27
EU member states.45 EFSM loans require a qualified majority vote of the Council of the EU. The
borrowing nation would be subject to economic conditionality supervised by the European
Commission, which would decide at regular intervals whether sufficient economic progress has
been made to warrant the continued release of funds. Funds are available immediately and there is
no sunset date for the EFSM. Beginning in January 2011, several bond offerings have been placed
to partially fund the Ireland and Portugal assistance packages.
European Financial Stability Facility
European leaders decided to provide the majority of the initial rescue package, up to €440 billion
(about $573 billion), in a temporary three-year crisis prevention facility, the so-called European
Financial Stability Facility (EFSF), outside of the EU system. The EFSF has been established
under Luxembourg law as a limited liability corporation.46 This allows participating countries to
have greater discretion over the use of the facility’s resources—decisions are made by a board of
directors from participating countries instead of the European Commission—and to limit their
liability to the amount of their individual guarantee. The amount of a country’s guarantee is to be
derived from their respective contributions to the paid-in capital of the ECB.
The EFSF depends on the credit rating of it guarantors to raise funds in capital markets, which it
then lends to weaker members of the Eurozone at a small mark-up. On January 16, 2012,
Standard & Poor’s lowered the fund’s credit rating from triple A to AA+ following earlier
downgrades of France and Austria. As these two countries account for some 40% of the credit
guarantees underlining the EFSF, this action could force the facility to pay higher premiums for
its capital. To date the EFSF has contributed €43.7 billion to Ireland and Portugal and is expected
to contribute another €150 billion to help underwrite a second Greek bail-out.47
The EFSF was expected to be replaced by a permanent lending facility, the European Stability
Mechanism (ESM), after it expires in 2013. At the December 2011 Summit, leaders announced
that this timeline would be accelerated to July 2012 so that it could overlap with the EFSF for a
year. The S&P downgrade of the EFSF could reinforce this effort. The ESM will be comprised of
€80 billion in paid-in capital contributions from Eurozone members, as opposed to the guarantees

44 The current balance of payments facility was created under Article 143 of the Lisbon Treaty, which limits assistance
to “member states with a derogation,” i.e., those outside the Eurozone.
45 Council Regulation (EU) No. 407/2010 of 11 May 2010 establishing a European financial stabilization mechanism.
Official Journal of the European Union, December 5, 2010. L 118/1.
46 Council of the European Union, Press Release, Extraordinary Council Meeting, Economic and Financial Affairs,
Brussels, May 9/10, 2010.
47 Joshua Chaffin and Quentin Peel, “Eurozone Bail-out Fund Hit by Downgrade,” Financial Times, January 17, 2012.
Congressional Research Service
15

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

underlying the EFSF. In theory, this should make the ESM more robust, but this fund still must
clear several legislative hurdles if it is to be up and running by mid-2012. And even then some
analysts believe that for the ESM to be credible in the event larger European countries like Italy
or Spain need to borrow from it, the fund would have to be increased five-fold, from its current
€500 billion ceiling to at least €2.5 trillion.48
European Central Bank Response
Along with the creation of the EFSM and the EFSF, the European Central Bank has implemented
several crisis-response measures to improve European financial stability. Arguably the most
important of these measures is the ECB’s decision to purchase European sovereign debt outright
in the secondary markets. This was a significant policy reversal for the ECB, which had long
viewed interventions in sovereign debt markets as compromising its independence, and a
diversion from its core mandate of price stability. However, as it required several months to
legally establish the EFSM and the EFSF, the ECB was able to provide immediate support
following the worsening of the crisis in early May. The ECB began interventions on May 10,
2010, purchasing €16.5 billion of Eurozone sovereign debt.49 It is believed that the ECB is now
among the largest holders of Greek, Italian, and Portuguese debt. Given a sharp increase in
buying beginning in August 2011, the ECB as of mid-year 2011 held €143 billion of European
sovereign debt.50
In December 2011 the ECB provided unusually flexible liquidity support to Eurozone banks. In
what has been called the biggest infusion of credit ever into the banking system, the ECB
awarded 523 banks with €489 billion euros (about $639 billion) in loans at the average
benchmark interest rate – currently 1 percent—over a three year period. The ECB hopes that the
banks will use the money to help them keep lending to companies and households, and possibly
purchase sovereign debt that is being sold this year. In theory, the banks by borrowing at one
percent could use the money to lend at much higher rates to European governments. But given
ongoing fears of possible defaults, it is unclear whether the banks will consider increasing their
exposure to government bonds as being too risky,51
Other ECB policy measures include the reactivation of temporary liquidity swap lines with the
U.S. Federal Reserve. In addition to the ECB, the Fed re-activated temporary reciprocal currency
agreements, known as swap lines, with the Bank of Canada, the Bank of England, Bank of Japan,
and the Swiss National Bank.52 The swap lines with the Federal Reserve provide foreign central
banks with a source of dollar financing should such immediate liquidity be needed.

48 Willem Buiter, Global Economics View, Europe: Fear and Panic Make Poor Counsellors, Citgroup, August 12,
2011.
49 David Oakley, Peter Garnham, and Ralph Atkin, “ECB reveals €16.5bn bond purchases,” Financial Times, May 17,
2010.
50 Reuters, “ECB's spent 14 bln euros on bonds ahead of Stark exit,” September 12, 2011.
51 David McHugh, “Europe’s Banks Jump at $639B in ECB loans,” USA Today, December 22, 2011.
52 In response to the beginnings of the recent financial crisis, similar swap lines were established in December 2007 and
expired in February 2010. On the re-establishment of these lines, see Federal Reserve, “Federal Reserve, European
Central Bank, Bank of Canada, Bank of England, and Swiss National Bank Announce Reestablishment of Temporary
U.S. Dollar Liquidity Swap Facilities,” http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20100509a.htm and
Federal Reserve, “FOMC Authorizes Re-establishment of Temporary U.S. Dollar Liquidity Swap Arrangement with
the Bank of Japan,” http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20100510a.htm.
Congressional Research Service
16

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Economic Governance Reforms
Crisis response measures have succeeded in calming financial markets, but they are temporary
measures that do not address fundamental weaknesses in the architecture of the EMU. The
temporary measures, however, have provided European leaders with time to consider changes in
the governance of the currency union. Reforms have also focused on developing more effective
means of coordinating national fiscal policies and on promoting faster and more balanced growth.
These are described briefly below.
Fiscal Policy Reforms
As discussed earlier, there have been efforts to reform the framework for European fiscal policy
coordination and enforcement of European fiscal rules. On September 15, 2011, the EU
Parliament approved new rules that provide a limited amount of additional power to EU
authorities in controlling public debt levels of member countries.53 The rules strengthen the SGP
by improving budgetary surveillance of Member countries. If Member countries continue to run
excessive budget deficits, the EC would eventually be able to impose a fine of up 0.1% of GDP.
Countries found to be falsifying their economic statistics could be subject to a fine of 0.2% of
GDP.54
At the December 2011 Summit, leaders announced the creation of a new fiscal compact.55 The
primary focus of the fiscal compact is an agreement that government budgets should be balanced
or in surplus, and that constitutions should be amended to reflect this rule. The United Kingdom
government was the only one of the 27 EU members not to sign on to the compact. At the
Summit, the UK was unable to secure safeguards it desired regarding financial supervision and
regulation, and therefore blocked the compact from taking the form of an amendment to the EU
treaty.
Economic Growth Policies
Important for securing the long-term viability of the EMU is reversing several years of weak
economic growth. Whatever fiscal reforms and surveillance targets are adopted, the Eurozone
economies will find it very difficult to restore public finances and regain competitiveness in the
absence of more rapid economic growth.56
Most economists predict that the Eurozone as whole will incur a minor contraction in 2012 (less
than 1 percent) before it returns to modest growth in 2013. Growth is declining in large part
because fiscal policy is highly contractionary across the Eurozone. Monetary policy, until the last
quarter 2011, was also relatively restrictive, leaving only structural reforms to boost economic
growth.57

53 Claire Davenport, "EU Wins Battle Over National Debt Vetting," Euractiv.com, September 15, 2011.
54 Honor Mahoney, "Deal Reached on EU Economic Governance Laws," euobserver.com, September 15, 2011.
55 The fiscal compact is still a “proposed” compact. The language is being drafted, the content debated, and it will have
to be ratified by all members.
56 Simon Tilford and Philip Whyte, “Why Stricter Rules Threaten the Eurozone,” Centre for European Reform, October
2011.
57 Many Eurozone policymakers argue that fiscal austerity, even if pursued by all member states simultaneously, will
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
17

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

For all Eurozone countries, the ECB and the European Commission have stressed the importance
in their view of pressing forward with difficult structural reforms that have prevented the
completion of the European common market. Removing remaining trade barriers, especially in
the services sector, is viewed by the ECB and the EC as being particularly important for
increasing growth. According to the ECB, only 20% of services provided in the EU have a cross-
border dimension. A full implementation of the European Commission’s services liberalization
proposals could increase EU GDP growth rates by 0.6-1.5 percentage points.58 Other growth
enhancing EU-wide reform efforts include promoting a common energy market and accelerating
the implementation of new digital technologies in accordance with the objectives of the Europe
2020 growth strategy.
Addressing the trade imbalances within the Eurozone may also be important for achieving more
rapid growth. To date the emphasis by the Eurozone leaders has been on dealing with the deficit
countries by exhorting them to pay down debt, increase savings, and live within their means.
While households and firms in deficit countries on the periphery have been spending less and
saving more, there has been little offsetting increase in spending in the mostly northern surplus
countries. With all members of the Eurozone simultaneously trying to save more, aggregate
demand is weakening further across the Eurozone and dampening economic growth.59
Possible Scenarios for the Future of the Eurozone
The current debt crisis has posed the most fundamental challenge to the Eurozone since the euro
was introduced a decade ago and has led to speculation about the future of the Eurozone. Three
scenarios have typically been discussed: (1) the crisis leads to a splintering or break-up of the
Eurozone, with multiple members abandoning the euro; (2) the Eurozone survives the crisis
largely intact; and (3) substantial reforms to the Eurozone architecture are implemented, leading
to greater economic and political integration. Currently, the second scenario appears the most
likely. European leaders are pursuing policy measures to keep the Eurozone intact; stepping up
ECB liquidity support to private Eurozone banks, for example, appears to be stabilizing financial
markets in the short-term. However, many analysts argue that longer-term policy changes under
discussion, including introducing balanced budget amendments in nearly all EU member state
constitutions, will not result in fundamental changes that address the structural problems inherent
in the Eurozone and fall short of creating a full fiscal or political union.
Scenario 1. The Eurozone Breaks Apart
It was once considered unthinkable that countries would leave the Eurozone, but the current debt
crisis has raised the possibility that one or more countries could exit the Eurozone. Exiting the
Eurozone would entail countries abandoning the euro as their national currency, issuing a new

(...continued)
not be contractionary because it will boost consumer and business confidence that government finances are sustainable.
Over time, it is argued that consumption and investment will grow along with the rising confidence.
58 Lorenzo Bini Smaghi, Imbalances and Sustainability in the Euro Area, European Central Bank, Presentation at the
ECB and its Watchers Conference, Frankfurt, July 9, 2010.
59 Simon Tilford and Philip Whyte, “Why Stricter Rules Threaten the Eurozone,” p.24.
Congressional Research Service
18

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

national currency, and allowing the new national currency to appreciate or depreciate against the
euro.
Exit by One or More Southern European Countries
The Eurozone could break apart if multiple Southern European countries decide to leave the
Eurozone, or are pushed out of the Eurozone by Northern European countries. The biggest benefit
to Southern European countries exiting the Eurozone would be new national currencies that are
depreciated against the currency of its major trading partners in northern Europe (the euro). This
would help them regain competitiveness against the northern European countries, leading to an
increase in exports and a decrease in imports. A surge in exports would spur economic growth,
offsetting depressed demand at home due to austerity measures. Additionally, by increasing
exports and lowering imports, Southern European countries would reduce their trade deficits and
the borrowing needed to finance these deficits.
Exiting the Eurozone would involve potentially huge costs for the Southern European economies,
however. First, the debt of Southern European countries is denominated in euros, and leaving the
Eurozone in favor of a depreciated national currency could significantly raise the value of their
debt in terms of national currency. Second, there are technical and legal obstacles to exiting the
euro.60 Legislation would likely be required to issue the new national currency, and all contracts
involving euros would have to be rewritten for the national currency. Numerous electronic
machines involving euros, including computers, ATMs, and vending machines, would have to be
reprogrammed or replaced, and new printing presses would be needed. Third, as investors and
consumers anticipated that the new national currency would depreciate in value against the euro,
massive capital flight from the country could trigger a major financial crisis in the country and
put pressure on other vulnerable European countries. Such a financial crisis could have acute,
negative impacts on short-term economic growth. Fourth, leaving the Eurozone would likely
strain the country’s political relations with other countries in the EU, and could possibly even lead
to the country having to depart from the EU.
Exit by One or More Northern European Countries
Another variant of the Eurozone-breaking-apart scenario is exit by one or more Northern
European countries due to frustration with the current debt crisis.61 When the Eurozone was
created, there was concern among northern Eurozone members, particularly Germany, about the
commitment of the ECB to price stability and the commitment of the Southern European
countries to sustainable debt levels. Northern European countries did not want to be a “fiscal
backstop” for the Southern European countries.62 To address these concerns, the ECB was created
with the primary goal of price stability (compared, for example, to the U.S. Federal Reserve,
which has a dual mandate of price stability and full employment), the legal text establishing the
euro included a “no bail-out” clause, and limits were put in place on the governments’ overall
outstanding debt levels (60% of GDP) and annual budget deficits (3% of GDP).

60 Barry Eichengreen, “The Euro: Love It or Leave It?,” VoxEU, November 17, 2007,
http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/729.
61 Gerard Baker, “Will Germany Leave the Euro?,” The Spectator, June 19, 2010, pp. 14-15.
62 Ibid.
Congressional Research Service
19

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

However, the current debt crisis has thrown these commitments into question. Some have argued
that the ECB’s decision to buy bonds of distressed Eurozone countries represents a loss of
independence for the ECB, and political support in some of the Northern Eurozone countries for
the financial assistance package for the vulnerable Eurozone countries has, at times, been
ambivalent at best. Some have suggested that one or more Northern European countries could
exit the Eurozone in favor of a new national currency. In Germany, four academics have,
unsuccessfully, tried to challenge the constitutionality of Germany’s membership in the Eurozone
in German courts.63
Even if reverting to a new national currency could regain Northern European countries greater
control over their monetary policy and reduce their financial commitments to the Southern
European countries, leaving the Eurozone could be costly. A new national currency for one of the
Northern European countries would likely appreciate against the euro, complicating the export-
led growth strategies that several Northern European countries pursue. The Northern Eurozone
countries would also face the same technical, legal, and political challenges to exiting the euro
that face the Southern Eurozone countries, discussed above. However, some observers believe
that banks in Northern European countries, even with new national currencies, could still accept
debt payments in euros from Southern European countries without posing a risk to their
solvency.64 This scenario would also have significant repercussions for the EU and the future of
European integration.
Scenario 2. The Eurozone Survives
A second possible scenario is that the Eurozone emerges from the crisis largely in its current
form. The status quo in the Eurozone could be maintained if market pressures on vulnerable
Southern European countries are calmed by the magnitude of the ECB liquidity support to
Eurozone banks and bond purchases, financial support from the EFSF and the IMF, austerity
packages in the Southern Eurozone countries, and an orderly restructuring of Greek bonds.
Austerity and structural reforms could also successfully lower prices in Southern European
countries, reducing imbalances within the Eurozone and obviating the need for additional
integration of fiscal policies at the Eurozone level. The new institutional arrangements being
proposed could increase integration among European countries, but fall short of a creating a full
fiscal or political union.
Some have expressed concern that if the Eurozone does emerge from the crisis in its current form,
the underlying problems with the architecture of the Eurozone that led to the current crisis would
not be addressed. Failure to address these issues, including coordination of fiscal policies at the
European level and correction of the imbalances within the Eurozone that developed over the past
decade, may mean that similar crises lie ahead.
The likelihood of this second scenario, that the Eurozone survives in its current form, largely
depends on whether financial markets have confidence in the current crisis response measures.
Specifically, much could depend on whether financial markets have confidence in the soundness
of the reforms implemented or whether markets are left wondering if reforms will lead to more

63 Wolgang Proissi, “Why Germany Fell Out of Love with Europe,” Brueghel Essay and Lecture Series, July 2020,
pp.15-17.
64At the same time, the value of Northern banks’ euro-denominated assets would still fall relative to their liabilities
denominated in new currency.
Congressional Research Service
20

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

sustainable fiscal positions. In the fall of 2011, the crisis threatened to spread more broadly, but
markets appear to be reassured by increased liquidity support by the ECB to Eurozone banks,
announced in December 2011, and by the steps that Italy and Spain both took to curb deficits.
However, it is unclear how long the ECB will be willing to provide this support, and how long
these policy measures will reassure markets. The January 2012 downgrade by Standard & Poor’s
on the credit ratings of France, Italy, and seven other Eurozone countries underscored that more
decisive and comprehensive responses from EU leaders could be required if the Eurozone is to
continue to survive.
Scenario 3. The Eurozone Becomes More Integrated
A third possible scenario is that substantial reforms to the Eurozone architecture are implemented,
leading to greater economic and political integration. This scenario would entail implementing
reforms to reduce fiscal free-riding and to enhance the ability of the Eurozone to respond to future
crises, if and when they arise. Greater fiscal federalism and a clear mechanism to provide
emergency financial assistance to vulnerable countries would also be a goal. Several proposals, as
discussed in the previous section, are currently being developed and are under consideration that
are intended to accomplish these goals. Most concretely, European leaders have already taken
steps to create a permanent fund to provide financial assistance to Eurozone members, the ECB
has taken on new powers that increase its flexibility to respond to financial crises in the
Eurozone, and the EU has passed new legislation that would introduce significant reforms to
economic governance. As the crisis has continued, EU officials have pushed for more integration.
In December 2011, some EU leaders pledged to pursue tighter fiscal coordination, including
through balanced budget amendments.
However, fiscal policies are an important issue of national sovereignty, and it remains to be seen
whether, or to what extent, national governments in the Eurozone will be willing to concede
control over national budgets to European authorities or implement balanced budget amendments.
Also, given the unpopularity of the financial assistance package for Greece and the broader
support mechanisms for vulnerable Eurozone members with voters in Northern European
countries, it is unclear whether countries will be willing to continue providing financial assistance
to Eurozone members in crisis. Today, the EU budget represents about 1% of EU GDP and
proposals to boost that by even 0.1% have consistently drawn vetoes from several EU members.
Likewise, proposals to create EU-wide bonds (“Eurobonds”) instead of bonds issued by national
governments has been resisted by some EU members, most notably Germany. A recent German
constitutional court decision that prohibits any future guarantees benefitting additional Eurozone
members without the prior approval of the Bundestag may further constrain the German
government from supporting the issuance of Eurobonds.65
While the likelihood of this third scenario—the Eurozone becomes more tightly integrated—has
increased since the start of the crisis, it is by no means assured. As the crisis has unfolded, it has
become clear that small, piecemeal steps by EU officials are not sufficient to calm markets about
the crisis response. Given the public statements by EU leaders about the commitment to avoid
countries leaving the Eurozone, it seems likely that more comprehensive response measures may
be taken if the markets lose confidence in the current policy measures, or if the ECB becomes

65 George Soros, “Does the Euro Have A Future?” The New York Review of Books, October 13, 2011.
Congressional Research Service
21

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

unwilling to intervene in markets. However, political obstacles to implementing measures that
increase fiscal integration in meaningful ways remain formidable.
Implications for U.S. Interests
The Eurozone crisis can affect U.S. economic and political interests in important ways. A major
U.S. concern is that a sovereign default by Greece or other Eurozone member or the failure of a
major European financial institution could reverberate throughout the global economy in much
the same way as the U.S. sub-prime crisis did in 2008. At a time when the U.S. economy is weak,
another wave of credit freeze-ups and instability in the European banking sector could weaken
U.S. financial institutions and nudge the U.S. economy into recession. Slower growth or a
recession in the Eurozone could also adversely affect U.S exports and sales of U.S. companies
operating in Europe and over time adversely affect U.S. GDP growth. While the Obama
Administration, the Federal Reserve, and Congress have been engaged in monitoring and working
towards an orderly resolution of the crisis, U.S. actions that could make a major difference are
limited.
Economic Implications
The U.S. and Eurozone economies play major roles in the world economy and are crucially
important for each other’s prosperity. The two sides combined account for around 40% of world
GDP, 25% of world trade, 60% of world foreign direct investment flows, and 60%-70% of world
banking assets and financial services. They also remain each other’s most important market for
exports of goods and services, and are each other’s primary source for foreign direct investment.
U.S. companies operating in Europe and European companies operating in the United States
employ up to 15 million workers on both sides of the Atlantic.66
Given these strong economic linkages, it is not surprising that the U.S. economy can be
negatively impacted by the Eurozone crisis via both financial and trade linkages. Already there
have been instances where concerns that the crisis is deepening have precipitated extreme
volatility in U.S. stock prices. The unexpected resignation of an influential member of the ECB
on September 9, 2011, for example, reportedly contributed to a 5% drop in European stock
markets and a decline of more than 2% in major U.S. stock indexes.67
The debt problems of Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain constitute a serious risk to the
European banking system—particularly German, French, and British banks, which have close ties
to U.S. banks. There are continuing concerns how these banks would be able to absorb losses on
bonds should one of these countries default or restructure its debt. There are related concerns that
should these banks’ financial positions deteriorate or collapse, they would not be able to make
payments owed to U.S. banks. At the same time, the December 2011 decision by the ECB to

66 CRS Report R41553, International Trade and Finance: Key Policy Issues for the 112th Congress, coordinated by
Raymond J. Ahearn, The Transatlantic Economy 2011, Johns Hopkins Center for Transatlantic Relations, 2011.
67 Jack Ewing and Nicholas Lulish, “A Setback for the Euro Zone: Central Bank Resignation Reveals a Widening Split
on the Debt Crisis,” New York Times, September 10, 2011.
Congressional Research Service
22

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

provide European banks with large amounts of cheap credit for up to three years has eased
concerns of any disorderly winding down of European bank holdings.68
In terms of international trade, the U.S. and Eurozone countries have one of the largest bilateral
relationships in the world. If the Eurozone economy stagnates this year or slips into recession,
demand for U.S. exports and the sales and profits of U.S. multinationals operating in Europe will
be depressed. If the euro begins to depreciate more steeply against the dollar due to slower
growth and loss of confidence in the euro, these adverse impacts on the U.S. economy could be
amplified.69
A stronger dollar/weaker euro would also likely have some effects on U.S.-Eurozone foreign
direct investment flows. Currently, Eurozone countries account for 26% of all U.S. direct
investment abroad and for 44% of all foreign direct investment in the United States.70 Based on
slower growth in Europe, U.S. investors may look towards emerging markets for additional
investments, particularly since profits generated in euros would translate into fewer dollars,
hurting the bottom line of U.S. parent companies. An offsetting factor could be that European
stocks and assets with a weaker euro would look cheaper and more attractive, attracting U.S.
capital to Europe.
Economists tend to be divided on the magnitude of any impacts on the U.S. economy. If the
Eurozone economy contracts only modestly in 2012 (some forecasts are predicting a 0.2% drop in
Eurozone GDP followed by a rebound to 1.0% growth in 2013) the impact on the U.S. economy
is likely to be minimal.
However, the economic impact could be much more substantial if the Eurozone were to plunge
into a deep and prolonged recession or even break-up due to a deepening sovereign debt crisis.
By one estimate, a complete break-up of the Eurozone could lead to a 10% cumulative loss of
output over the first two years.71 Combined with a likely adverse impact on the functioning of the
EU’s single market, U.S. exports of goods and services to Europe (which totaled over $300
billion in 2011) could be significantly reduced.
U.S. Policy Options
Measures that the Obama Administration could consider to help defuse the Eurozone crisis are
limited. The most direct option involves the Federal Reserve Board, which has the authority to
provide foreign central banks with an unlimited amount of dollars for an equivalent amount of
currency. In 2007, 2008, and again in September 2011 the Fed did just this, swapping dollars for
euros in order to provide the ECB with liquidity to calm capital markets. The Fed can also make
short-term loans to commercial banks in distress in order to protect the U.S. financial system.

68 Steven Mufson, “Ailing EU banks could hamper U.S.,” New York Times, December 23, 2011.
69 Given that a variety of factors such as relative growth rates, differential interest rates, and perceptions of stability can
affect exchange rates, predictions of movements in the dollar/euro rate are difficult to make. During 2011 the euro
depreciated or weakened against the dollar by about 3 percent.
70 U.S. Department of Commerce, Survey of Current Business, various editions.
71 ING Global Economics, “EMU Break-up: Quantifying the Unthinkable,” July 7, 2010.
Congressional Research Service
23

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Some in Congress have voiced opposition to these activities on the grounds that they constitute a
“bailout” of European banks and governments.72
Beyond direct action by the Fed, the Obama Administration is left to exhorting European officials
and U.S. financial institutions to do the right thing. Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner, for
example, has implored European officials to take more forceful actions to deal with the debt
crisis.73 Alternatively, the administration could also encourage countries such as China and Saudi
Arabia to help alleviate the crisis through additional purchases of European debt. Stable European
financial markets and a growing world economy, it can be argued, are strongly in the interests of
these countries as well as the United States.
Political Implications
Over the years, a key U.S. political interest has been a prosperous, peaceful, and stable Europe. In
support of this interest, successive U.S. administrations have supported European efforts at
economic and political integration. U.S. policy on the euro and the EMU has generally been that
if it is good for Europe, it will be good for the United States. For example, on January 4, 1999,
then President Clinton issued the following statement:74
We welcome the launch of the Euro, an historic step that 11 nations have taken toward a
more complete Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). The United States has long
advocated for European integration, and we admire the steady progress that Europe has
demonstrated in taking the often difficult budget decisions that make this union possible. A
strong and stable Europe, with open markets and robust growth, is good for America and
good for the world. A successful economic union that contributes to a dynamic Europe is
clearly in our long-term interests.
Given this history, if the Eurozone emerges from the crisis close to its present form or even
stronger than before, strong U.S.-EU political ties are likely to continue. Only in the possible
scenario of the Eurozone breaking apart are the effects likely to raise questions about the status
quo. Major challenges to political ties could emerge if a break-up of the Eurozone were
accompanied by growing divisions between key European countries, economic and social turmoil
in selected countries, or a return to more nationalistic policies. The Obama Administration, like
previous administrations, believes that a prosperous, secure, and increasingly integrated Europe
that is capable of partnering with the United States in addressing mutual policy challenges is in
the U.S. interest. On the other hand, it might also be argued that if a break-up were to occur, the
United States might have greater influence with individual members of the EU. Those who held
this view might also argue that a break-up could make the EU less of a rival to the United States.
Concluding Observations
The Eurozone crisis has highlighted cracks in the architecture of the currency union. Efforts to
make the currency union more stable and sustainable in the long run represent one of the most
fundamental challenges European leaders have faced in an over 50-year effort to advance political

72 Bruce Stokes, “Above the Fray No More,” National Journal, May 21, 2011.
73 John Fraher and Ian Katz, “Geithner to Prod EU on Crisis Fight, Washington Post, September 14, 2011.
74 Website: http://clinton6.nara.gov/1999/01/1999-01-04-statement-by-the-president-on-the-launch-of-the-euro.html
Congressional Research Service
24

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

and economic integration. The U.S. stake in the outcome of these efforts, given the magnitude of
U.S. economic and political ties with Europe, is considerable.
European proposals to date to reform the currency union center heavily on increasing fiscal
coordination and integration in ways that do not surrender members’ autonomy to make their own
spending and tax decisions to a supra-EU entity. Rather, the proposals seek to strengthen current
Stability and Growth Pact rules, partly through some form of sanctions, and to provide more
policy coordination on budgets and other fiscal matters. Backed by the creation of liquidity
facilities and the continued active involvement of the ECB in crisis management, European
leaders have a limited period of time to calm financial markets and bolster confidence in the
currency union. At the same time, the deepening crisis has prompted much stronger proposals
such as the issuance of Eurobonds and a greater pooling of budgetary resources as a way to
provide a stronger fiscal foundation for the monetary union.
Whether the currently contemplated reforms prove sufficient to ensure the sustainability and
viability of the currency union is unclear. A number of factors and developments could either
bolster or destabilize the currency union.
Factors and developments that could bolster the Eurozone include the following:
• Given that the EMU is largely a political undertaking and a major symbol of
European integration, European leaders and elites may be highly motivated to
keep the EMU intact.
• The proposals adopted to date introduce institutions and policies that represent
somewhat higher levels of integration and commitment to budgetary discipline—
elements that are considered necessary to rebuild market confidence in the euro
for the future.
• The creation of the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) to replace the EFSF
beginning in July 2012 provides a permanent facility to extend bridge loans to
countries that are temporarily shut out of bond markets. In return, debtor
countries have agreed to much stricter membership rules.
• The ECB has demonstrated willingness to help members in fiscal distress by
buying their bonds on secondary markets, and it has acted to provide low-interest
rate (one percent or less) loans to Eurozone banks for three years in order to
ensure their financial stability.
• European and IMF rescue programs put into place for Greece, Ireland, and
Portugal have been conditioned on fiscal and structural reforms of product and
labor markets that are necessary to regain market confidence. Moreover, these
reforms will improve the potential for economic growth and strengthen the euro
in the long run.
• Steps taken to date have prevented contagion from spreading to Italy and Spain,
countries deemed too large to bail-out.
Factors and possible developments that could weaken the sustainability of the currency union in
its current form include the following:
• Solutions adopted to date may not may not keep a lid on bond yields. The result
could make some sovereign defaults and bank failures unavoidable.
Congressional Research Service
25

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

• There appears to be little political support for financing debt by issuing
Eurobonds which would be guaranteed by all Eurozone members. In the long-
run, mutualization of debt may be necessary to generate low risk-free interest
rates that will enable all Eurozone countries time to put their public finances on a
stronger footing.
• The issuance of Eurobonds, in any case, may not prevent debt crises so long as
the current account imbalances within the Eurozone persist. Such imbalances
drain demand and employment from the deficit countries in the periphery, forcing
these governments to run big deficits.
• Even with common bonds and stricter fiscal rules and targets, the public finances
of the Eurozone may not improve markedly in the absence of more vigorous
economic growth. Growth prospects, however, are poor as fiscal policy is highly
contractionary across the Eurozone. Reforms to increase labor mobility and wage
flexibility could boost growth, but these reforms make take years to come to
fruition.
• The fundamental problem of countries at very different levels of development
living with a single monetary policy and a single exchange rate will remain.
Congressional Research Service
26

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Table 2. Glossary of Terms
Term Definition
Broad Economic Policy
The Broad Economic Policy Guidelines (BEPGs) are adopted by the Council as a
Guidelines (BEPG)
reference document guiding the conduct of the whole range of economic
policies in the Member States and the European Union. They play a central role
in the system of economic policy coordination, setting out economic policy
recommendations which give a basis for economic policy in both the Member
States and the EU as a whole in the current year.
Council of the European
The Council of the European Union is the Union’s main decision-making body and
Union (“Council of
enacts legislation based on proposals from the European Commission. Its
Ministers” or “Council”)
meetings are attended by the member state ministers, and is thus the institution
which represents the member states. The Presidency of the Council rotates
among the member states every six months.
Economic and Monetary
Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) is the process of harmonizing the economic
Union (EMU)
and monetary policies of the member states of the European Union with a view
to the introduction of a single currency, the euro.
European Central Bank
Founded on June 30, 1998, the European Central Bank (ECB) is the institution of
(ECB)
the European Union responsible for setting the monetary policy of the 16 EU
member states taking part in the Eurozone. The bank is headquartered in
Frankfurt, Germany.
European Commission (EC)
The European Commission (EC) acts as the EU’s executive branch, and has the
right of legislative initiative. There are 27 Commissioners—one from each
country.
European Council
The European Council brings together the leaders of the member states and the
Commission President. It acts as a strategic guide and driving force for EU
policy.
European Financial Stability
The European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) was set up by the 16 Eurozone
Facility (EFSF)
countries to provide a funding backstop should a euro area Member State find
itself in financial difficulties. The EFSF has the capacity to issue bonds guaranteed
by euro area members for up to € 440 billion in lending to Eurozone countries.
European Financial Stability
The European Financial Stability Mechanism (EFSM) is a new €60 billion
Mechanism (EFSM)
supranational EU balance of payments loan facility available to any EU member
country facing financial difficulties.
The European System of
The European System of Central Banks (ESCB) comprises the European Central
Central Banks (ESCB)
Bank and the national central banks of al EU member states whether they have
adopted the euro or not.
European Union (EU)
The European Union (EU) was established by the Treaty on European Union
(Maastricht, 1992). The project of creating a Union has a long history, and was
first mooted at the European Summit of 1972. The Union is both a political
project and a form of legal organization.
Eurozone
The Eurozone, officially the euro area, is an economic and monetary union (EMU)
of 17 EU members states which have adopted the euro currency as their sole
legal tender. Monetary policy of the zone is the sole responsibility of the
European Central Bank, though there is no common representation, governance
or fiscal policy for the currency union. Some cooperation does, however, take
place through the euro group, which makes political decisions regarding the
Eurozone and the euro.
Excessive Deficit Procedure
The excessive deficit procedure is governed by Article 104 of the Treaty
(EDP)
establishing the European Community, under which member states are obliged
to avoid excessive deficits in national budgets.
Lisbon Treaty
The Lisbon Treaty, the latest institutional reform treaty of the European Union
(EU), went into effect on December 1, 2009. It seeks to give the EU a stronger
Congressional Research Service
27

The Future of the Eurozone and U.S. Interests

Term Definition
and more coherent voice with the creation of a new position, President of the
European Council. It also makes changes to the EU's internal decision-making
mechanisms, and foreign policy apparatus, among other provisions.
Maastricht Treaty
The Treaty of Maastricht, formally, the Treaty on European Union (TEU), was signed
on February 7, 1992 by members of the European Community in Maastricht,
Netherlands. Upon its entry into force on November 1, 1993, it created the
European Union and led to the creation of the single European currency, the
euro.
Sovereign debt
Sovereign debt is a financial liability of a national government.
Stability and Growth Pact
The Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) pertains to the third stage of economic and
(SGP)
monetary union (EMU), which began on January 1,1999. It is intended to ensure
that member states maintain budgetary discipline after the single currency has
been introduced.
Source: Europa Glossary (http://europa.eu/scadplus/glossary/index-en.html).

Author Contact Information

Raymond J. Ahearn, Coordinator
Derek E. Mix
Specialist in International Trade and Finance
Analyst in European Affairs
rahearn@crs.loc.gov, 7-7629
dmix@crs.loc.gov, 7-9116
James K. Jackson
Rebecca M. Nelson
Specialist in International Trade and Finance
Analyst in International Trade and Finance
jjackson@crs.loc.gov, 7-7751
rnelson@crs.loc.gov, 7-6819

Acknowledgments
The authors wish to thank the following CRS colleagues who provided helpful suggestions and comments
on this report: Paul Belkin, Nils Bjorksten, William Cooper, Ian Fergusson, Marc Labonte, Dick Nanto and
Martin Weiss.

Congressional Research Service
28