Legal Sidebar
The 2023 Merger Guidelines: Analysis and
Issues for Congress
March 28, 2024
In December 2023, the Department of Justice (DOJ) and Federal Trade Commission (FTC) finalized the
2023 Merger Guidelines (the Guidelines), which outline the agencies’ analytical approach to merger
review. The Guidelines represent a major departure from th
e 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines and the
2020 Vertical Merger Guidelines, signaling a more aggressive approach to merger enforcement. This
Legal Sidebar analyzes the finalized 2023 Guidelines and discusses related considerations for Congress.
The 2023 Merger Guidelines
The DOJ and FTC began efforts to revise previous merger guidelines in January 2022, when they
launched
a public inquiry aimed at “strengthening enforcement against illegal mergers.” As part of that
inquiry, the agencies issued
a request for information on several topics, including the purpose and scope
of merger review; threats to potential and nascent competition; monopsony power and labor markets; and
the unique characteristics of digital markets.
In July 2023, the agencies release
d new draft guidelines for public comment. The draft guidelines
addressed many of the issues from the January 2022 RFI and were summarized in
a previous Legal
Sidebar, which also provided background information on merger law. The finalized Guidelines largely
track the July 2023 draft, with some modifications.
In addition to discussing several topics that were absent from previous guidelines, the finalized
Guidelines appear to evince a broader philosophical shift in merger enforcement that is consistent with
recent enforcement trends and public statements from the leadership of th
e DOJ’s Antitrust Division and
t
he FTC. Some of the key features of the finalized Guidelines—which reflect the agencies’ enforcement
policies but
do not bind courts—are discussed below.
Shift in Emphasis from Market Power to Market Structure. The 2023 Guidelines appear to adopt a
different normative benchmark from previous guidelines.
The “unifying theme” of the 2010 Horizontal
Merger Guidelines (HMGs) was that “mergers should not be permitted to create, enhance, or entrench
market power or to facilitate its exercise.”
The 1992, 1984, and 1982 guidelines contained similar
language. The July 2023 draft guidelines did not include this emphasis on market power
, focusing instead
on the more general notion of harm to “competition.” This change is consistent with the position that
Congressional Research Service
https://crsreports.congress.gov
LSB11138
CRS Legal Sidebar
Prepared for Members and
Committees of Congress
Congressional Research Service
2
antitrust should focus on harms to the “competitive process” rather than economic welfare—a view
advanced by some proponents of antitrust reform. Often, the “competitive process” theory is taken to
denote an emphasis on the intrinsic value of
deconcentrated market structures.
The traditional
criticism of this approach is that it provides little guidance on the resolution of concrete
cases; unless deconcentration always trumps welfare considerations, enforcers and courts need some
standard for deciding which value prevails in specific fact patterns. Several commentators
highlighted this
point in analyzing the draft guidelines
, arguing that the DOJ and FTC did not clearly explain how they
proposed to operationalize the concept of harm to “competition.”
I
n response to this criticism, the finalized Guidelines
included the following language:
Competition is a process of rivalry that incentivizes businesses to offer lower prices, improve wages
and working conditions, enhance quality and resiliency, innovate, and expand choice, among many
other benefits. Mergers that substantially lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly increase,
extend, or entrench market power and deprive the public of these benefits. Mergers can lessen
competition when they diminish competitive constraints, reduce the number or attractiveness of
alternatives available to trading partners, or reduce the intensity with which market participants
compete.
While this clarification references market power, it preserves the July 2023 draft’s primary emphasis on
“competition.” According to the new language, increased market power can
result from mergers that
substantially lessen “competition,” but the focus remains on “competition” as an independent concept. As
discussed below, several parts of the finalized Guidelines suggest that the agencies regard market
structure as a central consideration in analyzing possible harm to “competition.”
This is a meaningful departure from the 2010 HMGs, whi
ch downplayed the significance of structural
factors relative to previous guidelines. To the extent that the new Guidelines prioritize deconcentration
over economic welfare, they also diverge from how courts have construed the Sherman Act, which the
Supreme Court has
characterized as a “consumer welfare prescription.” While the Court has not issued a
merits opinion in a merger case since 19
75, some lower
courts have likewise interpreted the Clayton Act
as focusing primarily on economic welfare. It thus remains to be seen whether courts will follow the DOJ
and FTC in giving market structure independent normative significance.
Concentration Thresholds and the Structural Presumption. In keeping with their heightened attention
to structure, the finalized Guidelines lower the concentration thresholds at which the agencies regard
horizontal mergers (i.e., mergers between competitors) as triggering a presumption of illegality. While the
2010 H
MGs indicated that this “structural presumption” would be triggered by mergers resulting in a
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) exceeding 2,500 and an HHI increase of more than 200, the
2023 Guideline
s lower those levels to a post-merger HHI exceeding 1,800 and an HHI increase of more
than 100. The HHI is calculated by squaring the market share of each firm in the relevant market and
summing the results.
The lowered concentration thresholds in the 2023 Guidelines revert to the levels employed by the
1992 Merger Guidelines. Under these thresholds, the agencies
regard “7-to-6” mergers (i.e., mergers in
markets with seven firms of roughly equal size) as presumptively unlawful. Under the 2010 HMGs, by
contrast, the structural presumption was triggered by a 5-to-4 merger, but not by a 6-to-5 merger.
The 2023 Guidelines als
o provide that the structural presumption is triggered by transactions that would
create a firm with a market share exceeding 30% while increasing the market’s HHI by more than 100.
These triggers for the presumption did not appear in the 2010 HMGs. The 30% figure is derived from the
Supreme Court’s 1963 decision i
n United States v. Philadelphia National Bank. That decision, however,
did not address HHI changes and instead grounded the presumption in a combination of the 30%
threshold and
a “significant” increase in market concentration. The Court did not specify a minimum
value for a “significant” increase in concentration, but the HHI increase in that case was roughly 600. The
Congressional Research Service
3
discrepancy between this figure and the Guidelines’ use of the lower trigger of 100 has prompted some to
question whether the Guidelines’ approach is firmly rooted in existing doctrine.
These additional triggers for the structural presumption are somewhat similar to th
e “Leading Firm
Proviso” from the 1982 Merger Guidelines. That clause indicated that the DOJ was likely to challenge
mergers between a leading firm and any firm with a 1% market share, provided the leading firm had a
market share of at least 35% and was approximately twice as large as the second-largest firm in the
market. The 1992 Merger Guidelines dropped this proviso, but some commentators ha
ve supported the
restoration of a similar principle for firms with a market share of at least 50%.
In addition to expanding the reach of the structural presumption, the 2023 Guidelines do not include two
safe harbors from the 2010 HMGs. While the 2010 H
MGs indicated that the agencies ordinarily would
not challenge mergers involving an HHI increase of less than 100 or mergers resulting in an HHI below
1,500, the 2023 Guidelines do not contain those safe harbors.
Vertical Mergers. Modern analysis of vertical mergers (i.e., mergers between firms in the same supply
chain) has
focused on whether a merged firm would have the ability and incentive to foreclose rivals’
access to inputs or customers. Regulators have assessed incentives to foreclose because foreclosure is not
always a rational strategy; an integrated firm considering whether to deny inputs to rivals must
weigh
anticipated gains from reduced downstream competition against the losses that would accompany lower
sales by its upstream division. While the Guidelines
accept the modern “ability and incentive” framework
as one possible means of demonstrating competitive harm, they al
so indicate that market structures that
merely
allow a merged firm to limit access to a related product may constitute an independently sufficient
basis for blocking a merger.
On this front
, Guideline 6 in the July 2023 draft would have adopted a presumption of illegality for
vertical mergers that produce a foreclosure share exceeding 50%. The finalized Guidelines do not include
Draft Guideline 6, but some of the material from Draft Guideline 6 has been transferred t
o Guideline 5,
which addresses foreclosure more generally. The relevant material in Guideline 5 indicates that, if a
merger would allow a firm to approach or attain monopoly power over a “competitively significant”
related product, “those factors alone are a sufficient basis to demonstrate that the dependent firms do not
have adequate substitutes and the merged firm has the ability to weaken or exclude them by limiting their
access to the related product.” Guideline 5 t
hen states in a footnote that the agencies will “generally infer,
in the absence of countervailing evidence,” that a firm “has or is approaching monopoly power in the
related product if it has a [market] share greater than 50%.”
In support of the 50% trigger, Guideline 5 cites language from the Supreme Court’s 1962 decision in
Brown Shoe Co., Inc. v. United States. There, the Court indicated that a foreclosure share that “approaches
monopoly proportions” would violate both the Clayton Act and the Sherman Act. To the extent that the
Guidelines’ reference to this language in
Brown Shoe is meant to derive a structural presumption from
current doctrine, there are several reasons courts may be skeptical of the Guidelines’ argument.
First, whil
e modern cases continue to cite
Brown Shoe for certain principles related to market definition,
other aspects of the decision have bee
n abandoned. As a result, modern courts may not embrace the
quoted language as authoritative. In a 2023 concurring opinion, for example, one FTC Commissioner
argued that
Brown Shoe’s more general framework for evaluating vertical mergers is no longer good law.
(
A Fifth Circuit decision affirming the FTC’s order in the case declined to resolve whether
Brown Shoe’s
multi-factor approach to vertical deals remains valid.)
Second, the relevant passage from
Brown Shoe may not support the agencies’ position. While the
Guideline
s use the term “foreclosure share” to mean “the share of the related market to which the merged
firm could limit access,” some observer
s read the cited language from
Brown Shoe to require evidence
regarding the likelihood of
actual foreclosure as a result of a defendant’s post-merger conduct.
Congressional Research Service
4
Third, recent vertical merger decisions have not endorsed a structural presumption. In
United States v.
AT&T, t
he district court and t
he D.C. Circuit indicated that there is no structural presumption in
challenges to vertical mergers. (The DO
J stipulated to this proposition before trial.) In July 2023, a
district court
reached the same conclusion in rejecting the FTC’s challenge to Microsoft’s acquisition of
Activision.
Accordingly, as a statement of existing law, the Guidelines’ possible adoption of a structural presumption
for vertical mergers is open to question. Such a presumption may, however, be intended to move the law
in a more restrictive direction. As a matter of policy, this type of presumption also has the support of some
economists.
In addition to potentially adopting a structural presumption for vertical cases, the Guidelines depart from
the 2020 Vertical Merger Guidelines (VMGs) in their treatment of the elimination of double
marginalization (EDM). EDM refers to th
e phenomenon whereby vertical integration may lower prices by
allowing a downstream firm to access inputs at cost rather than paying a markup. The 2020 VMGs
contained extensive discussion of this issue an
d stated that vertical mergers “often” benefit consumers
because of EDM. The July 2023 draft guidelines, in contrast, did not mention EDM. The finalized
Guidelines have added language addressing EDM in a
footnote, which explains that EDM is a “common
rebuttal argument” in vertical cases and that the agencies evaluate EDM arguments under the same
framework used to assess other claims of procompetitive efficiencies. This diminished emphasis on EDM
relative to the 2020 VMGs appears to reflect
skepticism regarding the frequency with which vertical
integration results in merger-specific EDM and t
he pass-through of related benefits to consumers.
Potential Competition. The 2023 Guidelines give more attention to the elimination of potential
competition than the 2010 HMGs.
Guideline 4 references the two categories of potential competition that
have been recognized in the case law: “actual potential competition” and “perceived potential
competition.” The former involves the prospect that a firm may enter the relevant market in the future
absent a merger, while the latter refers to existing competitive pressures that result from the perception
that a firm may enter the market. (The case law on potential competition is discussed in this CRS Report.)
In addressing actual potential competition, the Guidelines
identify “reasonable probability of entry” as the
applicable analytical standard, but do not reduce that phrase to a specific numerical value. Some
courts
have
employed that language and construed it to require a probability of entry that is noticeably greater
than 50%. Others have used different language, demanding evidence that entry was
“likely” or would
“probably” occur. Another has adopted a stricter standard
requiring “clear proof” of entry. Actual potential
competition thus remains an area of considerable doctrinal uncertainty that may receive clarification if the
DOJ and FTC pursue more cases grounded in that theory.
Mergers That Entrench or Extend a Dominant Position. Guideline 6 indicates that mergers may be
illegal if they entrench or extend a dominant position. “Dominance” is a concept i
n European Union
competition law, but does not have an established meaning in U.S. antitrust doctrine. Guideline 6
indicates that the agencies evaluate dominance “based on direct evidence or market shares showing
durable market power.” Th
e July 2023 draft identified a 30% market share as a factor that would justify a
finding of dominance. The finalized Guidelines, however, do not include this clarification, leaving some
uncertainty as to the precise boundaries of “dominance.” Mergers risk entrenching a dominant position,
the agencie
s explain, if they raise barriers to entry or involve the elimination of nascent competitive
threats. The Guidelines also state that a merger risks
extending a dominant position into another market if
the merger would lead a firm to leverage its position by tying or bundling separate products. The material
on the suppression of
nascent competitive threats wades into an evolving area that could prove
particularly significant in technology markets. While some monopolization cases—most notably, the D.C.
Circuit’s
2001 Microsoft decision—have dealt with nascent competition, there is little merger case law on
the issue.
Congressional Research Service
5
Trends Toward Consolidation. Both the July 2023 draft guidelines and the finalized Guidelines discuss
mergers that contribute to a trend toward consolidation. The July 2023 draft
framed such mergers as
implicating a standalone theory of illegality, stating that mergers “should not” further a trend toward
concentration. Relatedly, the draft’s section on procompetitive justification
s indicated that efficiencies are
not cognizable if they accelerate a trend toward concentration or vertical integration. These types of
concerns with consolidation trends wer
e dropped from the merger guidelines in 1982, but continue to
receive some acknowledgment in the case law.
The finalized Guidelines adopt a less restrictive approach toward mergers in consolidating markets than
the July 2023 draft, removing the relevant caveat from the section on procompetitive justifications and
abandoning the proposition that consolidation trends represent a standalone theory of illegality. Instead of
prescribing that mergers “should not” contribute to a trend toward consolidation, Guideline
7 explains
that increasing levels of concentration or integration are “highly relevant” factors in evaluating a merger’s
competitive effects. The change suggests that a trend toward consolidation may help buttress a theory of
harm that is grounded in other parts of the Guidelines, but will not constitute an independently sufficient
basis for challenging a merger.
Multi-Sided Platforms. Guideline 9 addresses mergers involving multi-sided platforms, explaining that
such transactions can implicate competition
between platforms, competition
on platforms, and
competition to
displace a platform. The agencies venture into new legal territory in addressing the second
category—competition on platforms. Here, the Guidelines
indicate that the agencies will “carefully
examine” mergers between a platform operator and a platform participant for possible “conflicts of
interest” that may lead the operator to favor its own products or services over those of other platform
participants. These types of “conflicts of interest” have been the subject of
legislative efforts to reform the
competition laws governing tech platforms. Challenges to mergers based solely on such concerns may,
however, face
difficulties under existing law, and the Guidelines do not cite any legal authorities for the
proposition that possible self-preferencing (as opposed to foreclosure) can render a merger unlawful.
Labor Markets. The Guidelines break new ground vis-á-vis previous guidelines by explicitly addressing
labor markets. Guideline 10
suggests that mergers involving competing employers may often warrant
heightened scrutiny because of the high costs of switching jobs, search frictions, job-specific investments,
geographical limitations on worker mobility, and other factors that contribute to employers’ market power.
These unique features, the agencies contend, mean that competition concerns may arise at lower levels of
concentration in labor markets than they would in product markets. The Guidelines al
so reject the
proposition that downstream benefits in product markets—for example, lower consumer prices—can
justify mergers that harm competition in labor markets. This repudiation of “out-of-market” efficiencies is
consistent with the Supreme Court’s approach to that issue i
n Philadelphia National Bank. Some
commentators, however, ha
ve argued that a normative benchmark focused on consumer or total welfare—
as opposed t
o “trading partner welfare” or the
“competitive process”—would allow for consideration of
downstream efficiencies in cases involvi
ng buyer power. The Guidelines’ discussion of labor markets thus
implicates foundational issues regarding the intended beneficiaries of the antitrust laws and trade-offs
involving those beneficiaries.
The agencies’ recent enforcement records reflect their new focus on labor markets. In 2022, the DOJ
blocked Penguin Random House’s acquisition of rival book publisher Simon & Schuster based on the
theory that the deal would allow the merged firm to pay lower advances to authors. The FTC has also
challenged Kroger’s proposed acquisition of rival supermarket operator Albertsons based in part on the
transaction’s alleged effects on unionized grocery workers.
Serial Acquisitions. The Guidelines
indicate that, when a merger is part of a series of acquisitions, the
agencies may evaluate the competitive effects of the entire series, rather than focusing only on individual
transactions. This principle may be especially relevant t
o industry “roll-up” strategies and serial
acquisitions by large tech companies. The former—which involve private equity firms or other financial
Congressional Research Service
6
buyers acquiring and then combining multiple small firms within the same industry—have recently
attracted increased scrutiny. In September 2023, the FTC
challenged a private equity firm’s acquisitions
of various anesthesiology practices in Texas under the Sherman Act, the Clayton Act, and the Federal
Trade Commission Act.
Rebuttal Evidence. The Guidelines identify several factors that could rebut evidence of a substantial
lessening of competition, including t
he weak financial position of one of the merging firms (the so-called
“failing firm” defense), the prospect of
entry by other firms, and procompetitive efficiencies. Each of
thes
e factors was al
so present in the 2010 HMGs. In other respects, the Guidelines appear to take a more
restrictive approach to rebuttal evidence than the 2010 HMGs. For example, in explaining that cognizable
efficiencies must be merger-specific, the Guidelines
state that efficiencies will be considered only if they
“could not” be achieved absent a merger. The 2010 HMGs
adopted the less demanding requirement that
credited efficiencies be “unlikely” without a merger. The 2023 Guidelines also do not mention the
possibility that powerful buyers may constrain a merged firm’s market power—a consideration that was
included in the 2010 HMGs and has been recognized
by some courts.
Considerations for Congress
The finalized Guidelines are consistent with the enforcement philosophy that the DOJ’s Antitrust Division
and FTC have adopted under their current leadership. They also highlight some issues—like nascent
competition and multi-sided platforms—that have figured prominently in policy debates but raise
relatively novel issues for merger law.
As discussed, at several points, the Guidelines appear intended to implement a more restrictive approach
to mergers within the antitrust agencies, as opposed to merely synthesizing existing doctrine. Whether the
Guidelines have a broader impact on merger law remains to be seen. The Guidelines are not legally
binding and do not receive judicial deference, but some courts have treated previous guidelines as
persuasive authority.
Congress has the authority to weigh in on either side of these issues. Several
bills in the 117th Congress
would ha
ve tightened merger law with new presumptions a
nd per se rules. Those proposals are discussed
in this CRS Report. Alternatively, Congress may favor a less restrictive approach than the one reflected in
the Guidelines. It could seek to advance such an approach through legislation or its oversight activities.
Author Information
Jay B. Sykes
Legislative Attorney
Disclaimer
This document was prepared by the Congressional Research Service (CRS). CRS serves as nonpartisan shared staff
to congressional committees and Members of Congress. It operates solely at the behest of and under the direction of
Congress. Information in a CRS Report should not be relied upon for purposes other than public understanding of
information that has been provided by CRS to Members of Congress in connection with CRS’s institutional role.
Congressional Research Service
7
CRS Reports, as a work of the United States Government, are not subject to copyright protection in the United
States. Any CRS Report may be reproduced and distributed in its entirety without permission from CRS. However,
as a CRS Report may include copyrighted images or material from a third party, you may need to obtain the
permission of the copyright holder if you wish to copy or otherwise use copyrighted material.
LSB11138 · VERSION 1 · NEW