Legal Sidebar
The FTC’s Competition Rulemaking
Authority
Updated January 11, 2023
On January 5, 2023, the Federal Trade Commission (FTC)
proposed a rule that would prohibit
noncompete clauses in employment contracts. The proposal relies on the FTC’s putative authority to issue
rules defining “unfair methods of competition” (UMC) under
Sections 5 a
nd 6(g) of the Federal Trade
Commission Act (FTC Act). Other
antitrust rules may
be forthcoming.
Such efforts implicate three unsettled questions. First, does the FTC Act provide the FTC with substantive
UMC rulemaking authority? Second, if the statute does so, what is the scope of that authority? Third, is
rulemaking an appropriate vehicle for implementing antitrust policy?
This Legal Sidebar provides an overview of these questions. A separate Sidebar discusses the FTC’s
proposed noncompete rule.
Does the FTC Have Substantive UMC Rulemaking
Authority?
Antitrust enforcement has traditionally proceeded via adjudication rather than rulemaking. In recent years,
however, som
e commentators have argued for th
e expansion of the enforcement toolkit
, contending that
the FTC should activate its dormant competition rulemaking authority.
The existence of this authority is unsettled. While there is case law holding that the FTC possesses UMC
rulemaking authority, analysts have debated whether courts would reach the same conclusion if presented
with that issue today.
For the foundation of its UMC rulemaking power, the FTC ha
s pointed to the broad language of
Section 6(g) of the FTC Act, which empowers the agency to issue rules “for the purpose of carrying out”
the statute. Becaus
e Section 5 of the FTC Act prohibits “unfair methods of competition,” the Commission
contends, Section 6(g) provides it with the authority to prescribe rules identifying practices that fall within
that category.
Congressional Research Service
https://crsreports.congress.gov
LSB10635
CRS Legal Sidebar
Prepared for Members and
Committees of Congress
Congressional Research Service
2
This position has support in the case law. In its 1973 decision in
National Petroleum Refiners Association
v. FTC, the D.C. Circuit held that Section 6(g) authorizes the FTC to promulgate substantive Section 5
rules defining “unfair or deceptive acts or practices” (UDAP) and UMC.
Two years later, Congress responded to
National Petroleum Refiners in t
he Magnuson-Moss Act, which
established special procedures for the FTC’s UDAP rulemakings under a
new Section 18 of the FTC Act. Magnuson-Moss did not, however, purport to alter the FTC’s UMC rulemaking authority. Th
e statute
contains a provision disclaiming an intent to “affect any authority of the Commission to prescribe rules
(including interpretive rules), and general statements of policy, with respect to unfair methods of
competition in or affecting commerce.”
While Magnuson-Moss did not by its terms affect the FTC’s UMC rulemaking authority, the Commission
has not made extensive use of that power. The FTC has promulgated one substantive antitrust rule—a
1968 regulation (preceding Magnuson-Moss) that involved price discrimination in the men’s clothing
industry, which the agency never enforced an
d later repealed.
Some commentators have argued that the absence of a robust historical pedigree for UMC rules—along
with several principles of statutory construction—suggest that the FTC does not have substantive UMC
rulemaking authority.
First, some observer
s contend that the D.C. Circuit’s decision in
National Petroleum Refiners employed
an interpretive approach that would likely have little traction today. There, a trade association challenging
the FTC’s rulemaking authority invoked a canon of construction under which the expression of one thing
implies the exclusion of others. In particular, the gr
oup argued that Section 5’s identification of
adjudication as the means of implementing the provision’s prohibitions should be read as precluding the
availability of other enforcement tools like rulemaking. The D.C. Circuit was not persuade
d, remarking
that the relevant maxim was “increasingly considered unreliable.” Some commentators, however, have
suggested that courts may give the canon more weight today. Others hav
e argued that modern courts
would likewise place greater emphasis on the fact that the FTC had disclaimed substantive rulemaking
authority for much of its history—a detail that the D.C. Circuit did not
regard as significant.
Second, skeptics of the FTC’s UMC rulemaking authority hav
e emphasized another principle under
which courts presume that Congress does not alter the “fundamental details” of a regulatory scheme in
“vague terms or ancillary provisions”—the so-called “elephants in mouseholes” canon. They argue that
Section 6(g)—which is located in a section of the FTC Act involving the FTC’s investigative powers—is
such a provision. As a result, these commentator
s contend, Section 6(g) is best read as granting the FTC
limited ministerial rulemaking powers, rather than broad substantive authority to prohibit specific
categories of conduct.
Such an interpretation may deriv
e further support from the fact that the FTC Act does not provide any
penalties for violations of rules adopted under Section 6(g). This type of
structural argument and the
“elephants in mouseholes” canon played a role in the Supreme Court’s recent decision in
AMG Capital
Management, LLC v. FTC, where the Court unanimously rejected the FTC’s long-standing interpretation
of some of its remedial authority.
Third, some commentators hav
e highlighted th
e major questions doctrine as another possible impediment
to substantive competition rules. Under that doctrine, the Supreme Court has rejected claims of regulatory
authority involving issues of
“vast economic and political significance” when an agency has been unable
to establish
“clear congressional authorization” for the relevant power. The FTC’s critics
argue that the
authority to issue substantive UMC rules would implicate “major questions” and that Section 6(g) does
not constitute the type of clear congressional authorization that would be necessary to implement such
rules.
Congressional Research Service
3
In addition to these statutory arguments, som
e observers hav
e suggested that Section 6(g) may raise
constitutional concerns if interpreted to authorize substantive UMC rulemaking. The alleged infirmity
involves the
non-delegation doctrine, which requires Congress to provide agencies with an
“intelligible
principle” to guide delegations of lawmaking authority. While the Supreme Court has taken a deferential
approach in applying this test
, several Justices have recently
expressed interest in reinvigorating the
doctrine. It remains to be seen whether any future litigation over UMC rules would offer an attractive
vehicle for that effort.
Proponents of UMC rulemaking have offered several responses.
First, som
e commentators hav
e reiterated a point that the D.C. Circuit emphasized in
National Petroleum
Refiners: Section 6(g) of the FTC Act does not identify any limitations on the rulemaking power it
confers. They
argue that the court’s reliance on the plain meaning of the statutory text is consistent with
current interpretive practice.
Second, supporters of UMC rulemaking have denied that some of the canons of statutory construction
discussed above cut against the FTC’s authority. For example, some hav
e questioned whether rulemaking
would in fact alter the “fundamental details” of a statutory scheme in which the FTC can independently
implement Section 5’s prohibition of UMC via adjudication. In other words, it may not be clear that UMC
rulemaking authority is sufficiently elephantine to justify application of the “elephants in mouseholes”
canon.
Third, some commentators hav
e argued that competition rulemaking would not categorically implicate
the types of issues that trigger the major questions doctrine. While some UMC rules might involve issues
of “vast economic and political significance,” they
contend, others might not. As a result, the
major
questions doctrine may play a role in challenges to the scope of the FTC’s UMC rulemaking power, rather
than the threshold question of whether the agency has such authority in the abstract.
Fourth, defenders of the FTC’s UMC rulemaking power hav
e argued that it is unlikely that such authority
violates the non-delegation doctrine’s “intelligible principle” test based on the Supreme Court’s
deferential application of that standard. Likewise, they
suggest that it is doubtful that UMC rules would
categorically violate any replacement test that the Court may adopt, even if the Court might use such a
test to invalidate particular UMC rules.
What Is the Scope of the FTC’s UMC Rulemaking
Authority?
Even if the FTC possesses substantive UMC rulemaking authority, there will likely be questions about the
scope of that power
. Courts hav
e recognized that Section 5 of the FTC Act i
s broader than the Sherman
and Clayton Acts—the other core antitrust statutes. However, the precise scope of Section 5’s extra
coverage—often called the FTC’s “standalone” Section 5 authority—is unsettled.
Courts and the FTC have concluded that, in addition to prohibiting conduct that violates the Sherman or
Clayton Act, Section 5 bars
certain “incipient” antitrust violations that may not have ripened into a
violation of those statutes. Practices in this category hav
e included invitations to collude; certain
distribution arrangements that may mature into an antitrust violation because of specific industry
conditions; and sequences of individually permissible mergers that collectively harm competition. Other
distinctive Section 5 prohibitions may include conduct that violates the “spirit” of the antitrust laws but
falls within a “gap” in their coverage, such as certai
n pricing practices that facilitate tacit collusion.
Congressional Research Service
4
While Section 5 is thus broad, the courts have curtailed some of the FTC’s attempts to extend its reach.
The Commissi
on lost several
standalone Section
5 cases in the 1980s, demonstrating that the judiciary has
cabined the provision even while acknowledging its capaciousness.
These limits may soon be tested again. In November 2022, the FTC released
a policy statement
repudiating it
s previous practice of hewing closely to Sherman and Clayton Act principles in exercising
its Section 5 authority. In place of an exclusive focus on consumer welfare, the November 2022 policy
statement identifies two criteria that the FTC plans to use to determine whether conduct qualifies as a
UMC.
First, the statement
indicates that a UMC “may be coercive, exploitative, collusive, abusive, deceptive,
predatory, or involve the use of economic power of a similar nature,” and “may also be otherwise
restrictive or exclusionary.”
Second, the statement
explains that a UMC “must tend to negatively affect competitive conditions”—for
example, by tending to “foreclose or impair the opportunities of market participants, reduce competition
between rivals, limit choice, or otherwise harm consumers.”
While the policy statement
addresses possible justifications for challenged conduct, it does not contain
detailed affirmative guidance on that topic. Rather, the FTC
notes that there is “limited” case law on
“what, if any, justifications may be cognizable in a standalone Section 5 [UMC] case,” and that “some
courts have declined to consider justifications altogether.” The statement further
explains that, if a party
asserts a justification as an affirmative defense to a Section 5 claim, the FTC “can draw on [its] long
experience evaluating asserted justifications when enforcing Section 5, as well as its review of decided
cases and past enforcement actions.”
Whether the courts will accept the FTC’s conception of its standalone Section 5 authority remains to be
seen. As discussed, the judiciary has limited several of the FTC’s past efforts to extend that power,
leading some commentators t
o characterize the agency’s Section 5 litigation record as “uninspiring.” In
addition, the major questions doctrine may serve as an independent limitation on the FTC’s standalone
Section 5 authority in specific cases.
Should the FTC Issue UMC Rules?
Besides these legal questions, commentators have debated whether rulemaking is an appropriate vehicle
for implementing antitrust policy. Advocates of competition rules have offered several arguments in their
favor.
First, supporters of competition rules hav
e argued that
ex post adjudication moves
too slowly to
effectively address certain issues—for example, the allegedly anticompetitive conduct of large technology
platforms that operate in constantly changing markets. While complex antitrust litigation can take years to
resolve, the FTC may be able to develop and enforce competition rules more expeditiously.
Second, depending on their content, rules may
provide regulated entities with more legal certainty than
some of the open-ended standards that make up antitrust doctrine.
Third, rulemaking may allow for
greater democratic participation in the fashioning of competition policy
than case-by-case adjudication.
Fourth, rules may have technocratic virtues. Many commentators hav
e argued that generalist judges and
lay juries are ill-equipped to analyze the complex economic evidence that plays a central role in
contemporary antitrust litigation. In contrast, expert regulators often develop detailed knowledge of
specific industries and conduct, which they can deploy during the rulemaking process.
Critics of antitrust rules make several arguments in response.
Congressional Research Service
5
First, while rules offer the potential benefits of speed and certainty, those virtues may come with the cost
of
increased error. If UMC rules include bright-line prohibitions, for example, they may condemn
unacceptable amounts of procompetitive conduct. By contrast, if rules simply create presumptions of
illegality that can be rebutted with proof of procompetitive benefits, they lose some of the speed and
certainty advantages that arguably make them an attractive alternative to adjudication.
Second, some commentators hav
e argued that UMC rules present risks of institutional conflict between
the FTC and the Department of Justice—the other federal antitrust enforcer. In particular, they contend
that UMC rules that reach beyond the Sherman and Clayton Acts would create separate standards of
liability that vary between the agencies, raising the possibility of disparate treatment for similarly situated
parties.
Third, some observers have
contended that UMC rulemaking would likely result in “zig-zagging”
regulations that come and go with changes in presidential administration. This phenomenon may
undermine the certainty benefits discussed above. Skeptics of UMC rule
s argue that the FTC’s limited
resources may be better devoted to litigation under existing procedures, which may produce greater
stability than regulation.
Considerations for Congress
Whether the FTC possesses UMC rulemaking authority is primarily a question of statutory interpretation.
Congress could thus try to resolve that question via legislation clarifying the Commission’s powers. To
the extent that Section 5’s broad language raises possible non-delegation issues, Congress could attempt
to address such concerns by providing more specific standards to guide the FTC’s exercise of lawmaking
authority.
Congress could also respond to specific competition rules, should the FTC implement them. History may
be instructive on this point. After the Commission
successfully deployed Section 5 to challeng
e certain
pricing arrangements in the 1930s and 1940s, Congres
s considered several bills to overturn the relevant
decisions, ultimately adopting one of the proposals in 1950. While President Trum
an vetoed the bill,
congressional concerns about the FTC’s policies—which various Members expressed through the
oversight process
—prompted the agency t
o disavow an expansive reading of the relevant doctrine.
Congressional oversight can also be used to encourage more aggressive enforcement efforts. At various
points in its history, the FTC has
responded to congressional calls for more vigorous antitrust policy by
focusing its resources on specific industries of concern. Members of Congress could thus encourage the
FTC to use its putative UMC rulemaking authority to address particular areas of interest.
Author Information
Jay B. Sykes
Legislative Attorney
Disclaimer
Congressional Research Service
6
This document was prepared by the Congressional Research Service (CRS). CRS serves as nonpartisan shared staff
to congressional committees and Members of Congress. It operates solely at the behest of and under the direction of
Congress. Information in a CRS Report should not be relied upon for purposes other than public understanding of
information that has been provided by CRS to Members of Congress in connection with CRS’s institutional role.
CRS Reports, as a work of the United States Government, are not subject to copyright protection in the United
States. Any CRS Report may be reproduced and distributed in its entirety without permission from CRS. However,
as a CRS Report may include copyrighted images or material from a third party, you may need to obtain the
permission of the copyright holder if you wish to copy or otherwise use copyrighted material.
LSB10635 · VERSION 2 · UPDATED