Labor Market Tightness and the Economic Recovery, Part 2




INSIGHTi

Labor Market Tightness and the Economic
Recovery, Part 2

October 5, 2021
Recently, many businesses have reportedly complained of labor market “tightness”—workforce shortages
and difficulties in hiring to reduce them. This is surprising to many economists because employment is
still low. If long-lasting, these shortages could hold back the economic recovery and potentially contribute
to inflationary pressures. This Insight, which concludes a previous CRS Insight (Part 1) that analyzes
evidence of potential labor market tightenness, discusses potential causes and the policy implications of
those findings.
Potential Causes
Labor market tightness is likely being caused by a number of factors. As discussed in Part 1, the
Coronavirus Disease 2019 (COVID-19) pandemic caused many people to initially leave the labor force,
and for some, their reasons for leaving remain. Census Bureau data reveal that 3% of adults who were not
working in early September 2021 did so because they were “concerned about getting or spreading the
coronavirus.” Workers who are unwilling to return to their jobs because of health fears are often
concentrated in industries where social distancing is hardest, increasing tightness in those industries.
Another 4% of survey respondents were not working because they were “caring for someone or sick
myself with coronavirus symptoms” (although someone on temporary leave is still part of the labor
force). The unavailability of child or other dependent care or paid caregiving leave caused some parents
of young children and others to be unable to continue working, and the Federal Reserve estimated that
“nonparticipation in the labor force associated with caregiving has increased 0.7 percentage point.”
Individuals who leave the labor force can re-enter at any time, but some types of exits, such as
retirements, are more likely to be permanent. The pandemic led to a wave of extra retirements, which the
Federal Reserve estimated “account for more than one-half of the 1.7 percentage point decline in the
aggregate labor force participation rate (LFPR) over this period.” The LFPR for workers ages 55 and
over, which rose during the previous two recessions, is the lowest this year since 2007.
Unemployment insurance was temporarily enhanced during the pandemic in terms of eligibility, length,
and size of benefits.
Recipients received an additional $600 benefit weekly through July 2020, which
resulted in roughly two-thirds of recipients receiving a larger benefit than their previous wages, and
Congressional Research Service
https://crsreports.congress.gov
IN11771
CRS INSIGHT

Prepared for Members and
Committees of Congress



Congressional Research Service
2
thereafter an additional $300 until September 2021 in some states. Some have posited that these policies
created disincentives to return to work. A few recent studies used the fact that benefits ended at different
times across states to measure the differences in employment outcomes, with mixed results. One study
tracked individuals and found a modest increase in the probability of finding a job by the first week of
August for unemployed individuals in states that withdrew benefits early. Other studies, performed at the
state level, found no significant differences in outcome. As of September 5, 2021, all enhanced
unemployment benefits expired, so their influence on the labor supply will fade.
Restrictions on immigration were implemented in response to the pandemic that may explain the
temporary drop in the growth rate of the immigrant labor force. While net migration flows are small
compared to the overall labor force, even small reductions in available workers can have a significant
effect when markets are tight, especially for specific industries and regions that are heavily reliant on
immigrant labor.
Labor shortages may be less of an overall phenomenon than one specific to certain industries. As
discussed in Part 1, the pandemic caused changes in demand that necessitated job reallocation across
industries. Inter-industry reallocation can be more time-consuming and costly than intra-industry
reallocation, because retraining or relocation is more likely to be necessary. One study suggests inter-
industry reallocation could contribute to elevated unemployment for about three years. Another study
found that much of the reallocation was due to the disproportionate impact of the pandemic on the leisure
and hospitality industry. Future reallocation will depend heavily on the speed of recovery in that industry.
Outside the leisure and hospitality industry, there has not been a significant change in the overall rate of
reallocation.
Hiring employees takes time. According to a LinkedIn study, the median hiring time was over a month
across 15 industries. When a large decline in employment is followed by a large increase in hiring, this
lag may simultaneously lengthen the time of unemployment for many individuals and temporarily
maintain a relatively high level of job openings. With time, this lag will clear, which may lessen perceived
labor shortages.
Policy Implications
Many of the underlying causes of labor market tightness are related to the decline in the LFPR, and
policies that cannot address the specific reasons for the decline may be ineffective. There are a couple of
timing considerations that may be important for policy. First, many of the potential causes of labor market
tightness are pandemic-related and, therefore, are likely to dissipate once the pandemic ends. As such,
policies aimed at ending the pandemic may also help the labor market. Second, the labor market, like
other economic markets, has a theoretical equilibrium: There is an average wage at which labor supply
will meet demand. Rising wages could be a sign that the labor market is moving toward this market-
clearing equilibrium, at which point tightness would dissipate. However, as evidenced by hiring lag times,
it could take time for the labor market to equilibrate on its own.
There are costs to inaction if the labor force remains permanently smaller. The combination of both a low
labor force participation rate and labor market tightness points to challenges in regaining a level of full
employment in line with its pre-pandemic path. If the labor force remained permanently smaller, potential
output would be permanently lower as well, all things equal, perhaps justifying policies aimed at boosting
employment and output (i.e., expansionary fiscal and monetary policy). However, given the current
tightness in the labor market, these types of policies could cause offsetting effects, such as inflation,
which is currently relatively high.



Congressional Research Service
3

Author Information

Marc Labonte
Lida R. Weinstock
Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
Analyst in Macroeconomic Policy





Disclaimer
This document was prepared by the Congressional Research Service (CRS). CRS serves as nonpartisan shared staff
to congressional committees and Members of Congress. It operates solely at the behest of and under the direction of
Congress. Information in a CRS Report should not be relied upon for purposes other than public understanding of
information that has been provided by CRS to Members of Congress in connection with CRS’s institutional role.
CRS Reports, as a work of the United States Government, are not subject to copyright protection in the United
States. Any CRS Report may be reproduced and distributed in its entirety without permission from CRS. However,
as a CRS Report may include copyrighted images or material from a third party, you may need to obtain the
permission of the copyright holder if you wish to copy or otherwise use copyrighted material.

IN11771 · VERSION 1 · NEW