link to page 2 link to page 2
INSIGHTi
The Federal Reserve’s Revised Monetary
Policy Strategy Statement
September 10, 2020
After a two-year
Review of Monetary Policy Strategy, Tools, and Communications, t
he Federal Reserve
(Fed) announced on August 27, 2020,
revisions to its Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary
Policy Strategy. This statement, initially published in 2012, explains the Fed’s monetary policy strategy
for achieving it
s statutory mandate of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term
interest rates.
The original statement had two key features. First, it set a long-run inflation goal of 2%, the first time the
Fed formally specified a numerical goal. Second, it asserted that a similar numerical goal could not be set
for maximum employment because of uncertainty surrounding full employment. The 2020 revision
retains both features.
Overall, the 2012 statement was concise and did not provide details on how the Fed would react to
specific economic situations. The 2020 statement is more detailed, and it marks a shift on how monetary
policy will respond to inflation and unemployment in light of recent macroeconomi
c developments.
Specifically, since the 2007-2009 financial crisis, t
he federal funds rate has been
close to zero (see
Figure
1), and inflation has been mostly below 2% and relatively unresponsive to changes in the unemployment
rate. Because the Fed cannot reduce rates below zero, it
s primary challenge since the crisis has been to
provide adequate monetary stimulus to achieve its mandate. The 2020 statement articulates a strategy to
provide greater stimulus.
Congressional Research Service
https://crsreports.congress.gov
IN11499
CRS INSIGHT
Prepared for Members and
Committees of Congress
link to page 3
Congressional Research Service
2
Figure 1. Federal Funds Rate
1980-2020
Source: Federal Reserve.
The revision departs from an earlier strategy, adopted in response to excessively high inflation from the
late 1960s to the 1980s, to preemptively increase interest rates when unemployment was viewed as too
low. This view was based on the
“Phillips Curve” relationship that inflation would rise when
unemployment fell, and vice versa. The 2020 statement acknowledges that this relationship has been
weak in recent decades. As shown in
Figure 2, over the past 20 years, inflation has remained around 1%-
2% every year, whether unemployment was very high or very low.
The statutory mandate does not specify how the Fed should weigh inflation and employment goals. The
revised statement drops language about taking a “balanced approach” toward achieving those goals, and
argues that monetary policy should only be used in response to unemployment being too high, but not
when it is too low
. According to the Fed’s Vice Chair, a “low unemployment rate by itself ... will not,
under our new framework, be a sufficient trigger for policy action.” In discussing the statement
, Fed
officials have stressed t
he long-term benefits of “hot” labor markets for “groups that are most vulnerable
to employment fluctuations,” such as minority workers.
link to page 4
Congressional Research Service
3
Figure 2. Phillips Curve
2000-2019
Source: CRS calculations based on data fro
m Bureau of Economic Analysis and
Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Note: Each point represents the unemployment and inflation rates for a year between 2000 and 2019.
The 2020 revision also adopts a more aggressive stance toward persistently low inflation. Whereas the
Fed’s main concern in earlier decades was that inflation might be too high, the Fed’s preferred measure of
inflation has run below 2% in 91 out of 103 months since it adopted the 2% goal in 2012 (se
e Figure 3).
As a result, the Fed is concerned that too-low inflation will feed into expectations, causing it to become
self-perpetuating. In response, the 2020 statement explained that the Fed would aim t
o make up for
periods of inflation below 2% with periods of inflation above 2%, so that inflation would average 2%
over time. Although the 2012 statement did not rule this strategy out, neither did it describe how such a
development would be tackled.
Congressional Research Service
4
Figure 3. Inflation
2012-2020
Source: CRS calculations based on
Bureau of Economic Analysis data
The 2020 statement also notes t
he importance of maintaining financial stability to achieving its mandate. Whereas previous decades featured only fleeting and isolated incidents of financial instability
, financial
stability concerns have been central in the 2007-2009 financial crisis and the current pandemic.
Policy Considerations
Overall, the revised statement can be viewed as a more “dovish” approach to monetary policy—less
concerned about inflation and the risks of unemployment being too low, and more concerned about
providing adequate stimulus. Although some observers have described these changes as a major shift in
policy, it could be argued that
monetary policy decisions have reflected this thinking for some time. In
recent decades, the Fed has not raised preemptively rates when unemployment was high—for example,
1994 was the last time it raised rates when unemployment was above 6%. The Fed reduced interest rates
in the second half of 2019 when unemployment was below 4%—below the Fed’s ow
n longer-run
estimate of unemployment. Likewise, the Fed directly intervened in financial markets with significant
resources in bot
h 2008 and 2020 to restore financial stability, which it justified in terms of its mandate.
With unemployment in double digits when the statement was revised, inflation is arguably a less pressing
concern. A potential drawback to the new statement is that because it is more specific to current concerns,
arguably it could be less useful and possibly unhelpful if future economic conditions change (if inflation
became high or became more sensitive to unemployment again in the future, for example). In that case,
the statement could be revised again. But if it is believed that the statement makes monetary policy more
effective by committing the Fed to a future course of action, t
hen commitment to the strategy matters for
economic outcomes.
Another concern some have is that the new policy is more complicated, and some argue that
simple
policies are more effective and more robust than complicated ones in the face of uncertainty. For example,
the new pledge to follow low inflation periods with periods when inflation exceeds 2% may lead to
confusion among the public about what interest rate path the Fed will pursue and how high inflation will
get. The grounding of low inflation expectations since the 1990s has be
en viewed by many as one of the
Congressional Research Service
5
Fed’s major successes, and this new policy might muddy the waters. Another challenge to the success of
makeup strategies has been the Fed’s inability to get inflation to reach its 2% target since 2012. If its
policies have not reached 2% inflation, what policy could successfully deliver inflation above 2%?
Author Information
Marc Labonte
Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
Disclaimer
This document was prepared by the Congressional Research Service (CRS). CRS serves as nonpartisan shared staff
to congressional committees and Members of Congress. It operates solely at the behest of and under the direction of
Congress. Information in a CRS Report should not be relied upon for purposes other than public understanding of
information that has been provided by CRS to Members of Congress in connection with CRS’s institutional role.
CRS Reports, as a work of the United States Government, are not subject to copyright protection in the United
States. Any CRS Report may be reproduced and distributed in its entirety without permission from CRS. However,
as a CRS Report may include copyrighted images or material from a third party, you may need to obtain the
permission of the copyright holder if you wish to copy or otherwise use copyrighted material.
IN11499 · VERSION 1 · NEW