97-1053 E
Updated October 12, 1999
CRS Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
The Proposed Tobacco Settlement: Who Pays for
the Health Costs of Smoking?
(name redacted)
Senior Specialist in Economic Policy
Government and Finance Division
Summary
One of the issues raised in the consideration of tobacco settlements is the
compensation of various parties that might pursue lawsuits to recover the health costs
of smoking. These parties include states whose settlements now total $26 billion over
26 years, the federal government which has filed suit against the industry, and
individuals. Popular estimates of the annual medical costs of smoking range around $50
billion, with the states accounting for slightly under $4 billion, individuals about $10
billion and the remainder paid for by the federal government and private entities. Some
recent estimates have reported higher costs. A more complete accounting of the health
costs of smoking not only increases the size of the costs, but also reallocates costs — and
implies net financial benefits for some parties. Governments save on the costs of old-age
medical care, social security, and nursing home care due to the earlier death of smokers.
(This result does not mean that it is desirable that people die early; it means that in
determining financial cost, if that is the justification for a payment, a correct measure of
the loss will only be calculated if these effects are included.) Smoking has apparently
brought financial gain to both the federal and state governments, especially when tobacco
taxes are taken into account. In general, smokers do not appear to currently impose net
financial costs on the rest of society. The tobacco settlement will increase the transfer of
resources from the smoking to the nonsmoking public. (This report will be updated
periodically.)
Introduction
Part of the objective of the proposed tobacco settlement is to compensate various
parties who might pursue lawsuits. Indeed, the settling of potential lawsuits is a major
reason for the agreement by the tobacco companies to the plan. An important public
policy concern is whether the financial claims are justified and, in addition, whether certain
programs run by the federal government might be justified in receiving a share of benefits.
These economic issues are treated in this paper. (See CRS Issue Brief 98022 for other
Congressional Research Service ˜
The Library of Congress
CRS-2
issues that drive the formulation of public policy on tobacco, including public health
concerns, particularly underage smoking, that are not discussed in this report.)
A proposed settlement was negotiated in June, 1997 between state attorneys general,
plaintiff’s lawyers, public health advocates, and cigarette manufacturers’ representatives.
The initial plan for dividing $15 billion in fully phased in annual payments was: a $5 billion
fund to settle individual lawsuits; $5 billion to reimburse states for Medicaid costs; and
$5 billion for funding certain spending programs.1 Some of the tobacco legislation
subsequently proposed, including the plan agreed to by the Senate Commerce Committee
(S. 1415), does not specify exactly how the money was to be spent. (Other tobacco bills
include S. 1343/H.R. 2764, S. 1491/H.R. 3027, S.1530 and S. 1638). The states
ultimately settled, through individual suits and the Master Settlement Agreement, for $246
billion to be paid over 26 years. The federal government has also filed suit, on September
22, 1999, to recover health related costs.
The first section of this paper reports the popularly cited estimates of the health costs
of smoking. The next section discusses a more comprehensive measure of these costs.
For each set of estimates, the report makes some rough allocations of the amount paid by
the federal government, state governments, private third parties, and smokers themselves.
The final section of the report discusses some uncertainties surrounding these estimates.
The Rice Estimates
The most popularly cited number for the annual cost of smoking is the $50 billion
estimate made by Dorothy Rice and her colleagues. That number is used in publications
of the Center for Disease Control (CDC).2 This amount measures the estimated additional
medical cost attributable to smoking related diseases in 1993 dollars, based on estimates
of smoking attributable risk (what share of each disease is due to smoking). The editors
add that this $50 billion amount translates into approximately $2.06 per pack. The study
also indicates the shares paid by various groups: 21% by smokers, 33.4% by private
insurance, 20.4% by medicare, 10.2% by medicaid, 9.5% by other federal programs, 3.2%
by other state programs, and 2.2% by other. Total medicaid costs are thus about $5 billion.
Recently, a new study by some of the same researchers resulted in a considerably larger
estimate of the Medicaid cost–$12.9 billion–for the same year (and using the same data
set).3
States pay a bit over 40% of medicaid; if “other” is allocated to the same third-party
category as private insurance, we can estimate the following approximate amounts of the
1 Reported in “Smokers Would Pay Bills for Previous Generations,”
Washington Post, June 21,
1997.
2 Medical-Care Expenditures Attributable to Cigarette Smoking— United States, 1993.
Morbidity
and Mortality Weekly Report, vol. 43, No. 26, July 8, 1994. The estimates were made by: J.C.
Bartlett, School of Public Health and L.S. Miller, School of Social Welfare, University of
California—Berkeley; D.P Rice, Institute for Health and Aging, University of California—San
Francisco.
3Leonard S. Miller, Xiulan Zhang, Thomas Novotny, Dorothy P. Rice, and Wendy Max, State
Estimates of Medicaid Expenditures Attributable to Cigarette Smoking, Fiscal Year 1993,
Public
Health Reports, Volume 113, pp. 140-151.
CRS-3
$50 billion: $18.1 billion for the federal government, $3.6 billion for the states, $17.8
billion for private insurance and other, and $10.5 billion for individual smokers. The later
research by Rice, et al. implies costs of over $5 billion for the states.
These calculations are, however, an incomplete accounting of the costs of smoking.
The economic cost of smoking is composed of two parts: the actual costs of producing
the product and the additional costs, largely health related. These additional costs include
not only any excess health costs, but also other costs such as lost productivity and, most
importantly, premature death. Indeed, the same CDC report includes an estimate of
indirect costs associated with morbidity and premature mortality of $6.9 billion and $40.3
billion, also in 1993 dollars, which would approximately double the total cost. The
following section discusses an estimate of this more comprehensive measure of smoking-
related health costs.
The Manning Study
A more complete accounting of the costs of smoking not only increases the size of
the costs, but also reallocates costs — and implies net financial benefits for some parties.
For example, total medical expenditures due to smoking are reduced by offsetting
reductions in costs because of premature death. A person who dies from a smoking
related disease causes an increase in medical cost at that time, but medical costs are
decreased in the future because that person does not suffer the illnesses otherwise suffered
during a longer life. Similarly, smokers who die prematurely lose retirement benefits in
the form of social security, which is a financial saving for the government (since the
smokers are generally alive during the contribution period).
It is important to clarify this point, which has been confused in some press reports.
The fact of savings from government transfers due to premature death does not imply that
there is a social gain from premature death; there is clearly a loss that accrues to the
smoker who is part of society. Nevertheless, in a straight-forward accounting for costs,
the government in its role as provider of certain services will experience financial savings
from premature death, which must be considered in determining how different parties fare
because of smoking. This observation does not mean that it is desirable that people die
early; rather it means that in compensating relevant parties financially, if that is the
justification for a payment, a correct measure of the loss will only be calculated if the
effects of premature death are taken into account. In addition to these health-related
financial costs and savings, there is a transfer from smokers to governments because of the
cigarette taxes.
This report uses estimates by Manning,4 updated and categorized for 1993 by
Viscusi,5 to calculate the effects on third parties (federal, state, and private third-parties
4 Willard G. Manning, Emmett B. Keeler, Joseph P. Newhouse, Elizabeth M. Sloss, Jeffrey
Wasserman.
The Costs of Poor Health Habits, A RAND Study, Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press, 1991.
5 Kip Viscusi. “Cigarette Taxation and the Social Consequences of Smoking,”
Tax Policy and
the Economy, Vol. 9, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1995,
pp. 51-101.
CRS-4
such as insurance companies).6 The original study included the categories of medical
costs, sick days, group life insurance, nursing homes, retirement benefits, effects of fires,
and loss of taxes and contributions to these plans. Viscusi further divides the medical
costs into those incurred under-65 and over-65. By allocating these categories to the
different parties, a rough estimate of the general magnitude of these costs is provided. 7
In the calculations, the federal and state payments and contributions made through the
governments’ role as employers are treated as private. Please note that these estimates are
rough, and could probably be refined considerably.
Manning, et al. discounted payments, with those occurring later in life being valued
less; the purpose of that study was to determine what tax would reflect external costs for
a new smoker. These numbers would not provide a measure of the current cost, although
Viscusi reports an allocation at a 0% discount rate, which would probably be close to how
one would measure these current costs. Using a zero discount rate, each of the external
parties actually benefits from smoking.
In this analysis, the federal government saves about $29 billion per year in net health
and retirement costs (accounting for effects on tax payments). These include a saving in
retirement (largely social security benefits) of about $40 billion and in nursing home costs
(largely medicaid) of about $8 billion. Costs include about $7 billion for medical care
under 65 and about $2 billion for medical care over 65; the remaining $10 billion cost is
the loss in contributions to social security and general revenues that fund medicaid. (Note
that medical costs already include offsetting savings for premature death and thus are much
smaller in the aggregate than in the Rice estimates). The federal government also collects
$5.6 billion in cigarette taxes. This calculation implies that smokers (past and present)
currently save the federal government almost $35 billion per year.
State governments also have an overall saving, though smaller, of $2.1 billion. This
saving takes into account the large saving in nursing home costs financed through medicaid
($4.8 billion) which exceeds net medical costs of $1.5 billion. The remaining difference
reflects a cost of $1.8 billion from foregone contributions and a benefit of $0.6 billion in
retirement savings. States also receive about $7.6 billion of cigarette taxes, for a total
annual saving, including cigarette taxes, of almost $10 billion.
6 The Manning study was also used in a CRS study of the proposed cigarette tax increase in 1994.
This paper discusses the literature in this area more extensively and also discusses the potential
magnitude of costs of second-hand smoking. See (name redacted) and (name redacted),
Cigarette Taxes to Fund Health Care Reform, CRS Report 94-214, March 8, 1994.
7 External medical costs (those not paid for by smokers) over 65 are primarily a federal
responsibility because of medicare; the federal government is estimated to account for 83%, the
state 2%, and private insurance 15%. Under-65 medical care is more heavily financed by private
insurance: 51%, with 20% allocated to the state and 29% to the federal government. Nursing
home care is 61% federal, 35% state, and 4% private; pensions are 64% federal, 35% private, and
1% state; contributions to these private and public plans are 56% federal, 10% state, and 34%
private. These ratios were developed by CRS from a variety of sources on health expenditures,
sources of pension income, and taxes.
CRS-5
Private third parties also have savings of $5.4 billion largely because a $22 billion
saving in pensions offsets the net costs smokers impose on employer health plans.8
An alternative way of examining costs is to measure them from a lifetime perspective.
This is the approach taken in the Manning study, which calculated the payment per pack
that would be necessary to cover the net costs to society over an individual smoker’s
lifetime. That calculation is more likely to result in a cost because the savings from
premature death would be discounted more heavily as they occur further in the future. If
one were to impose a tax to cover these costs on a lifetime basis (we use a 5% discount
rate) the tax, multiplied by current sales, would be a refund of $0.5 billion for the federal
government (a subsidy), receipts of $1.1 billion for the states and receipts of $5.4 billion
for private sources. These estimated tax receipts are smaller than current cigarette taxes
of $5.6 billion for the federal government and $7.6 billion for the state government,
suggesting that current taxes are larger than the costs imposed on society. Both costs and
benefits would be increased by about 10% to adjust for 1997 price levels.
Costs are imposed on some segments of society, with or without discount rates (and
benefits are received by others). Private health insurance is one example where a net cost
occurs. One should not necessarily conclude that lump sum payments to these firms is
appropriate, however, since the higher costs were passed on to subscribers, that is, to the
large group of individuals enrolled in private health insurance. Indeed, one could think of
these third party private costs as falling on a broad segment of society, so that it makes
some sense to aggregate these external costs. Once all costs, private, federal, state and
local are combined, whether one discounts or not, the analysis indicates that smokers are
transferring financial benefits to nonsmokers.
The proposed settlement would increase that transfer, because most or perhaps all
of the cost of the settlement payment would fall on smokers,9 but the benefits would go
partly to nonsmokers. Within the group of smokers, there would be a generational
transfer: current and future smokers would pay to compensate existing and perhaps
largely former smokers and their families. Since cigarette taxes are highly regressive, this
plan would have the effect of redistributing income from lower income individuals to
higher income ones, unless receipts are spent in a way to offset these effects.
Caveats and Uncertainties
The Manning study is the only comprehensive study of smoking costs, although there
have been a number of more limited studies focusing largely on medical costs. Some are
similar to the Rice study, and others focus on the lifetime medical costs taking into account
8 All of the above estimates are CRS allocations based on Viscusi’s estimates of per-pack costs,
aggregated by multiplying by number of packs.
9See
The Proposed Tobacco Settlement: Effects on Prices, Smoking Behavior, and Income
Distribution, by (name r edacted), CRS Report 97-995, Updated February 24, 1998, for a
discussion.
CRS-6
premature death. These studies and the Manning study were also examined in a previous
CRS study; the highlights of this analysis are summarized below.10
The Manning study attributes variations in total lifetime health costs to smoking
status, income, sex, and other attributes using data from an interview survey. This
procedure is a standard one which attempts to control for the influences of nonsmoking
factors on health. Updated to 1995 price levels and discounted at 5%, the result is that the
combined burden imposed by smokers on non-smokers (accounting for premature death)
is 33 cents a pack, well below current cigarette taxes, which are about 50 cents a pack.
The authors report an upper bound health cost estimate by simply comparing smokers to
nonsmokers and obtain a cost of 53 cents a pack; this measure is undoubtedly too high
because smoking is known to be correlated with many other health risk factors. The
authors also provide several estimates that restrict smoking attributable health costs to
those diseases which are generally recognized to be associated with smoking, a procedure
that may help to correct for omitted influences; these estimates lower the cost to non-
smokers to close to zero or even result in savings (again at a 5% discount rate).
The Manning study is now somewhat dated and health effects of smoking may be
affected by a variety of factors which cannot be easily captured in updates. There are also
potential recall errors from survey data, and use of an alternative data source produced
slightly larger costs when discounted (43 cents). There are other external effects beyond
those that derive from the sharing of costs and benefits through social insurance. (The
1994 CRS study discusses many of these effects, although it suggests that one effect
subject to much popular attention, the health cost of passive smoking, is likely to be very
small.) Other studies have found different lifetime profiles of health costs. The results are
quite sensitive to choice of discount rate, as should be apparent from the previous section.
These uncertainties act in some cases to increase and in others to reduce the point
estimates from the Manning study and the base case estimates used in that study represent
a central position.
A recent study not covered in the 1994 CRS report found that, among the Dutch
population, lifetime medical costs of smokers (undiscounted) were smaller than lifetime
medical costs of nonsmokers, suggesting that aggregate medical costs alone (not counting
pension savings) were lower as a result of smoking.11 Such findings are consistent with
a financial savings in medicaid expenditures from smoking, but these results do not
necessarily apply to the United States.
10 (name r edacted) and (name redacted),
Cigarette Taxes to Fund Health Care Reform, CRS
Report 94-214, March 8, 1994. In part, this study discussed the external costs of passive smoking
but found that this effect was uncertain and too small, when translated into dollar costs, to alter
the findings regarding aggregate external costs discussed in the study. Passive smoking has been
also been the subject of another CRS report: (name redacted) and Richard C. Rowberg.
Environmental Tobacco Smoke and Lung Cancer Risk, CRS Report 95-1115 SPR, November 14,
1995. This study did not identify the potential dollar cost of passive smoking risk, but rather
reviewed and assessed the size and relative certainty of the risk.
11Jan J. Barendregt, Luc Bonneux, and Paul J. Van Der Maas, The New England Journal of
Medicine. The Health Care Costs of Smoking,
New England Journal of Medicine, v. 337, No. 15,
October 9, 1997, pp. 1052-1057.
EveryCRSReport.com
The Congressional Research Service (CRS) is a federal legislative branch agency, housed inside the
Library of Congress, charged with providing the United States Congress non-partisan advice on
issues that may come before Congress.
EveryCRSReport.com republishes CRS reports that are available to al Congressional staff. The
reports are not classified, and Members of Congress routinely make individual reports available to
the public.
Prior to our republication, we redacted names, phone numbers and email addresses of analysts
who produced the reports. We also added this page to the report. We have not intentional y made
any other changes to any report published on EveryCRSReport.com.
CRS reports, as a work of the United States government, are not subject to copyright protection in
the United States. Any CRS report may be reproduced and distributed in its entirety without
permission from CRS. However, as a CRS report may include copyrighted images or material from a
third party, you may need to obtain permission of the copyright holder if you wish to copy or
otherwise use copyrighted material.
Information in a CRS report should not be relied upon for purposes other than public
understanding of information that has been provided by CRS to members of Congress in
connection with CRS' institutional role.
EveryCRSReport.com is not a government website and is not affiliated with CRS. We do not claim
copyright on any CRS report we have republished.