< Back to Current Version

Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms

Changes from August 13, 2021 to March 22, 2023

This page shows textual changes in the document between the two versions indicated in the dates above. Textual matter removed in the later version is indicated with red strikethrough and textual matter added in the later version is indicated with blue.


The Big Tech Antitrust Bills
June 23, 2021
Over the past decade, Facebook, Google, Amazon, and Apple have revolutionized the digital
economy. Many people now use the products and services of these “Big Tech” firms on a daily
Jay B. Sykes
basis. Facebook boasts more than two billion monthly active users. Google licenses the world’s
Legislative Attorney
most popular mobile operating system and runs a search engine that processes three-and-a-half

billion searches a day. Amazon operates the largest online marketplace, a massive logistics
network, and a leading cloud-computing company. Apple has popularized the smart phone to
For a copy of the full report,
such a degree that consumers have grown accustomed to carrying supercomputers in their
please call 7-5700 or visit
pockets.
www.crs.gov.
While the Big Tech firms have plainly made important technological breakthroughs, their business practices have attracted
scrutiny from antitrust regulators and some Members of Congress. In October 2020, the House Committee on the Judiciary’s
Subcommittee on Antitrust, Commercial and Administrative Law concluded a 16-month investigation of these practices,
which culminated in a 450-page report recommending a range of measures to address the firms’ allegedly anticompetitive
conduct.
Many of those measures have now taken legislative form. In June 2021, the House Committee on the Judiciary ordered to be
reported a series of antitrust bills directed at Big Tech. The legislative package represents the most comprehensive effort to
date to tackle competition issues in the digital economy. This report reviews the bills by outlining the issues they are meant to
address, discussing their approaches to those issues, situating the bills within current antitrust law, and describing the
principal policy arguments made by their supporters and opponents.
H.R. 3816, the American Innovation and Choice Online Act, responds to a variety of allegations leveled againstAntitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms March 22, 2023 Antitrust has become a hot topic. After decades evolving in technocratic obscurity, competition policy now commands the attention of lawmakers, academics, and the general public. Jay B. Sykes Legislative Attorney One of the driving forces behind this trend has been the rise of a handful of large technology firms: Facebook (now Meta Platforms), Google, Amazon, and Apple. While these “Big Tech” companies have revolutionized the daily lives of billions, they also are accused of obtaining and solidifying dominant positions through anticompetitive conduct. Meta is currently defending a Federal Trade Commission (FTC) lawsuit that seeks to unwind its acquisitions of the photo-sharing service Instagram and the messaging app WhatsApp. Google is embroiled in litigation with the Department of Justice (DOJ), state attorneys general, and private plaintiffs over alleged exclusionary conduct related to its search engine, app distribution on Android mobile devices, and its digital-advertising businesses. Amazon has faced lawsuits challenging pricing restrictions it imposes on third-party merchants. Some commentators have also alleged that the company has engaged in anticompetitive tying, predatory pricing, and unfair self-preferencing. Several of Apple’s practices have attracted scrutiny, including the firm’s restrictions on the distribution of iOS apps, its use of competitively sensitive information derived from third-party app developers, and its treatment of its proprietary apps. Litigation challenging the iPhone maker’s app-distribution restrictions is currently pending before the Ninth Circuit. Some lawmakers have also expressed concern about the large number of acquisitions that the Big Tech the Big Tech
firms over the past decade. The bill’s core concern is that Facebook, Google, Amazon, and Apple have leveraged dominance
of their core markets to disadvantage competitors in related markets. “Self-preferencing”—whereby a dominant platform like
Google Search boosts Google’s own products (e.g., Google Shopping, Google Travel, Google Maps)—is a paradigmatic
example. H.R. 3816 would address concerns regarding this type of behavior by prohibiting the Big Tech firms from engaging
in specified forms of “discriminatory conduct.” Supporters of such measures seek to cabin the Big Tech firms’ market power
to their principal lines of business. Opponents contend that many of the prohibited practices are competitively benign, and
that the flexible standards employed by existing antitrust doctrine are preferable to rigid ex ante regulation.
H.R. 3825, the Ending Platform Monopolies Act, responds to the same set of concerns as H.R. 3816. However, instead of
imposing non-discrimination rules, the bill would require structural separation: Big Tech firms could not operate in multiple
lines of business when doing so would create various conflicts of interest. For example, Amazon could not both operate a
marketplace and sell its own private-label products on that marketplace. Likewise, Google could not offer both Google
Search and various vertical search engines. The bill’s proponents argue that structural separation responds to the same
general problem as non-discrimination rules, but is easier to administer. Opponents contend that prohibiting the Big Tech
firms from entering adjacent markets would harm innovation and—counterintuitively—entrench their power.
H.R. 3826, the Platform Competition and Opportunity Act, is directed at mergers and acquisitions. The legislation would
prohibit the Big Tech firms from acquiring competitors or potential competitors. The bill also would shift the burden of proof
to the Big Tech firms to show by clear and convincing evidence that their proposed acquisitions would not enhance their
power in their core markets. Supporters of the bill claim that Facebook, Google, Amazon, and Apple have solidified their
dominance by acquiring rivals and potential rivals rather than competing with them. Opponents argue that the legislation
would dampen startup investment by eliminating the prospect of being acquired by a Big Tech firm.
H.R. 3849, the Augmenting Compatibility and Competition by Enabling Service Switching (ACCESS) Act, tackles the
“network effects” and “switching costs” that give Big Tech firms powerful incumbency advantages. Markets exhibit network
effects when the utility of a product increases as it gains more users. For example, many people prefer Facebook to smaller
social networks because their family members and friends are more likely to use Facebook. Switching costs insulate the Big
Tech firms when a dominant platform’s users face strong disincentives to abandon the platform for its competitors. H.R.
3849 would address these entry barriers with interoperability and data-portability mandates. The bill’s proponents contend
that these measures are necessary to mitigate the structural characteristics that cause tech markets to “tip” in favor of a single
firm. Opponents have raised concerns about security, privacy, and the technical challenges of implementing such
requirements.
Congressional Research Service


link to page 5 link to page 5 link to page 5 link to page 6 link to page 7 link to page 9 link to page 10 link to page 11 link to page 11 link to page 12 link to page 12 link to page 12 link to page 12 link to page 14 link to page 14 link to page 14 link to page 15 link to page 16 link to page 16 link to page 17 link to page 17 link to page 17 link to page 18 link to page 18 link to page 19 link to page 19 link to page 20 The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

Contents
Non-Discrimination Requirements: H.R. 3816, American Innovation and Choice Online
Act ................................................................................................................................................ 2
The Issue ................................................................................................................................... 2
The Legislation.......................................................................................................................... 3
Effect on Current Law ............................................................................................................... 4
The Arguments For.................................................................................................................... 6
The Arguments Against ............................................................................................................. 7
Structural Separation: H.R. 3825, Ending Platform Monopolies Act.............................................. 8
The Issue ................................................................................................................................... 8
The Legislation.......................................................................................................................... 9
Effect on Current Law ............................................................................................................... 9
The Arguments For.................................................................................................................... 9
The Arguments Against ............................................................................................................. 9

Mergers and Acquisitions: H.R. 3826, Platform Competition and Opportunity Act ...................... 11
The Issue .................................................................................................................................. 11
The Legislation......................................................................................................................... 11
Effect on Current Law ............................................................................................................. 12
The Arguments For.................................................................................................................. 13
The Arguments Against ........................................................................................................... 13

Interoperability and Data Portability: H.R. 3849, Augmenting Compatibility and
Competition by Enabling Service Switching (ACCESS) Act .................................................... 14
The Issue ................................................................................................................................. 14
The Legislation........................................................................................................................ 15
Effect on Current Law ............................................................................................................. 15
The Arguments For.................................................................................................................. 16
The Arguments Against ........................................................................................................... 16


Contacts
Author Information ........................................................................................................................ 17

Congressional Research Service


The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

n the 1970s and 1980s, antitrust law experienced a revolution. The insurgents shared certain
general commitments: that antitrust had become overly interventionist; that economic
reasoning should play a more central role in antitrust decision-making; and that the
I maximization of consumer welfare—not the protection of small businesses or the
elimination of concentrated economic power—was the only legitimate goal of competition
policy. This collection of ideas came to be called the “Chicago School” of antitrust analysis,
owing to many of its proponents’ affiliation with the University of Chicago.1 While the
movement’s prescriptions were not imported wholesale into the case law, its core tenets proved
enormously influential in shaping the direction of antitrust doctrine in the courts.2
Now, an antitrust counter-revolution may be brewing in Congress, where a growing chorus of
lawmakers has argued that America has a monopoly problem.3 Much of this concern has focused
on a handful of massive technology companies. In October 2020, the House Committee on the
Judiciary’s Subcommittee on Antitrust, Commercial and Administrative Law (House Antitrust
Subcommittee) concluded a 16-month investigation into the market power of four of the largest
tech platforms: Facebook, Google, Amazon, and Apple. The inquiry culminated in a 450-page
report recommending a slew of measures to rein in the alleged abuses of these “Big Tech” firms.4
In June 2021, many of those measures took legislative form, as Members of the Judiciary
Committee released four bills directed at Big Tech.5 The legislative package—which the
Committee later approved and ordered to be reported with amendments to the full House—
represents the most comprehensive effort to date to tackle competition issues in the digital
economy. This report reviews the four bills by outlining the issues they are meant to address,
discussing their approaches to those issues, situating the bills within current antitrust law, and
describing the principal arguments made by their supporters and opponents.

1 Richard A. Posner, The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 925 (1979).
2 For a critical assessment, see HOW THE CHICAGO SCHOOL OVERSHOT THE MARK: THE EFFECT OF CONSERVATIVE
ECONOMIC ANALYSIS ON U.S. ANTITRUST (Robert Pitofsky ed., 2008). For a largely sympathetic account, see Joshua D.
Wright, Overshot the Mark? A Simple Explanation of the Chicago School’s Influence on Antitrust, Geo. Mason L. &
Econ. Research Paper No. 09-23 (Mar. 31, 2009).
3 See, e.g., JOSH HAWLEY, THE TYRANNY OF BIG TECH (2021); AMY KLOBUCHAR, ANTITRUST: TAKING ON MONOPOLY
POWER FROM THE GILDED AGE TO THE DIGITAL AGE (2021).
4 INVESTIGATION OF COMPETITION IN DIGITAL MARKETS, MAJORITY STAFF REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS, SUBCOMM.
ON ANTITRUST, COM. AND ADMIN. L. OF THE H. COMM. ON THE JUDICIARY, 116TH CONG. (2020) [hereinafter “HOUSE
ANTITRUST SUBCOMM. REPORT”]. This report lists the Big Tech firms in the same order as the Subcommittee’s report
and will retain that order throughout.
5 Congressman David Cicilline, House Lawmakers Release Anti-Monopoly Agenda for “A Stronger Online Economy:
Opportunity, Innovation, Choice,” (June 11, 2021), https://cicilline.house.gov/press-release/house-lawmakers-release-
anti-monopoly-agenda-stronger-online-economy-opportunity. The Committee’s legislative package also included two
bills that are not specifically directed at the Big Tech firms. H.R. 3460, the State Antitrust Enforcement Venue Act of
2021, would exempt antitrust actions filed by state attorneys general from consolidation before the Judicial Panel on
Multidistrict Litigation. H.R. 3460, 117th Cong. (2021). H.R. 3843, the Merger Filing Fee Modernization Act, would
raise filing fees for large mergers, cut them for small mergers, and increase funding for the Department of Justice’s
Antitrust Division and the Federal Trade Commission. H.R. 3843, 117th Cong. (2021). This report omits further
discussion of these bills to focus on the legislation that specifically targets Big Tech firms.
Congressional Research Service
1

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

Non-Discrimination Requirements: H.R. 3816,
American Innovation and Choice Online Act

The Issue
H.R. 3816, the American Innovation and Choice Online Act, responds to a range of allegations
leveled against the Big Tech firms over the past decade, some of which are the subject of pending
antitrust litigation.6 An exhaustive review of these claims is beyond the scope of this report; a
sampling offers a general sense of the terrain.
 Facebook has been accused of imposing anticompetitive limitations on access to
“Facebook Platform”—a set of tools that enable app developers to access
Facebook data and create apps that interoperate with Facebook.7 In a recently
dismissed lawsuit, the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) argued that Facebook
Platform has become key infrastructure for app developers, giving Facebook
significant power over the trajectories of promising new apps. The Commission
alleged that Facebook abused that power by denying access to Facebook
Platform to developers whose apps competed with Facebook products.8
 Google has been accused of conditioning mobile-device manufacturers’ access to
its Google Play app store on manufacturers’ pre-installation of Google Search,
thereby leveraging Google’s power in the app-store market to disadvantage
competitors in the search market.9 The tech giant has also allegedly given
preferential placement to its own vertical search engines (e.g., Google Travel,
Google Maps) in general search results, using its power in general search to
disadvantage vertical rivals (e.g., Expedia, MapQuest).10

6 During the House Judiciary Committee’s markup process, an amendment changed H.R. 3816’s short title from the
“American Choice and Innovation Online Act” to the “American Innovation and Choice Online Act.” See Amendment
in the Nature of a Substitute to H.R. 3816 Offered by Mr. Nadler of New York, Markups, H.R. 3843, the Merger Filing
Fee Modernization Act of 2021, et al., H. COMM. ON THE JUDICIARY, 117TH CONG. (June 21, 2021),
https://docs.house.gov/meetings/JU/JU00/20210623/112818/BILLS-117-HR3816-N000002-Amdt-5.pdf.
This report analyzes and cites the Big Tech antitrust bills that the House Judiciary Committee approved and ordered to
be reported to the full House of Representatives, including amendments made during the Committee’s markup. For a
compilation of those amendments, see Markups, H.R. 3843, the Merger Filing Fee Modernization Act of 2021, et al.,
H. COMM. ON THE JUDICIARY, 117TH CONG. (June 23, 2021),
https://judiciary.house.gov/calendar/eventsingle.aspx?EventID=4601. As of the publication of this report, the bills have
not been reported to the House floor. Therefore, the committee amendments to the bills have not been published as new
bill versions by the Government Publishing Office or made available on congress.gov.
7 “Apps” are software programs that enable users of mobile devices to engage in specific tasks, like sending messages,
taking photos, ordering food, or arranging transportation. See Apple Inc. v. Pepper, 139 S. Ct. 1514, 1518 (2019).
8 Complaint for Injunctive and Other Equitable Relief, FTC v. Facebook, No. 1:20-cv-03590 ¶¶ 22-26 (D.D.C. Jan. 13,
2021); see also HOUSE ANTITRUST SUBCOMM. REPORT, supra note 4, at 166-70.
9 Complaint, United States v. Google LLC, No. 1:20-cv-03010 ¶¶ 72-77 (D.D.C. Oct. 20, 2020); HOUSE ANTITRUST
SUBCOMM. REPORT, supra note 4, at 213.
10 HOUSE ANTITRUST SUBCOMM. REPORT, supra note 4, at 187-92; Brody Mullins, Rolfe Winkler & Brent Kendall,
Inside the U.S. Antitrust Probe of Google, WALL ST. J. (Mar. 19, 2015), https://www.wsj.com/articles/inside-the-u-s-
antitrust-probe-of-google-1426793274. “Vertical” search engines like Expedia and MapQuest are search engines
dedicated to specific types of online content (e.g., travel, maps). More generally, the Big Tech firms’ “vertical” rivals
are companies that compete with Facebook, Google, Amazon, or Apple in markets that are related to or depend upon
those firms’ main platform businesses.
Congressional Research Service
2

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

 Amazon has allegedly:
 ranked its own private-label products higher than more popular
competitors in product search results;11
 used merchant data to identify profitable new lines of business for its
private-label products;12
 required merchants to purchase ads and use Amazon fulfillment services
to receive prominent placement in search results;13 and
 prohibited merchants from offering products on its marketplace that they
sell elsewhere at lower prices.14
 Apple is embroiled in litigation targeting its requirement that purchases within
iPhone apps use Apple’s payment system—a practice that allegedly allows Apple
to extract monopolistic rents from app developers.15 The iPhone maker has also
faced charges that it preferentially ranks its own apps over more popular and
highly rated competitors in its app store.16
The Legislation
H.R. 3816 aims to prohibit Big Tech firms from engaging in much—if not all—of this behavior.17
The legislation would prohibit operators of “covered platforms” from engaging in various forms
of “discriminatory conduct.”18 “Covered platforms” are defined to include platforms that:
 have at least 50 million U.S.-based monthly active users or 100,000 U.S.-based
monthly active business users;
 are owned or controlled by firms with net annual sales or market capitalizations
greater than $600 billion; and
 are “critical trading partner[s]” for the sale or provision of any product or service
offered on or directly related to the platforms.19
The bill’s drafters reportedly maintain that only Facebook, Google, Amazon, and Apple meet all
three criteria.20

11 Dana Mattioli, Amazon Changed Search Algorithms in Ways That Boost Its Own Products, WALL ST. J. (Sept. 16,
2019), https://www.wsj.com/articles/amazon-changed-search-algorithm-in-ways-that-boost-its-own-products-
11568645345.
12 HOUSE ANTITRUST SUBCOMM. REPORT, supra note 4, at 274-82.
13 Id. at 287-92.
14 Id. at 295-97.
15 See Motion for Temporary Restraining Order, Epic Games, Inc. v. Apple Inc., No. 3:20-cv-05640 (N.D. Cal. Aug.
17, 2020).
16 Jack Nicas & Keith Collins, How Apple’s Apps Topped Rivals in the App Store It Controls, N.Y. TIMES (Sept. 9,
2019), https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2019/09/09/technology/apple-app-store-competition.html.
17 H.R. 3816, 117th Cong. (2021).
18 Id. § 2.
19 Id. § 2(g)(4).
20 Dana Mattioli & Ryan Tracy, House Bills Seek to Break Up Amazon and Other Big Tech Companies, WALL ST. J.
(June 11, 2021), https://www.wsj.com/articles/amazon-other-tech-giants-could-be-forced-to-shed-assets-under-house-
bill-11623423248.
Congressional Research Service
3

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

The legislation lists 13 forms of prohibited discriminatory conduct. Among other things, the bill
would prohibit operators of covered platforms from:
 advantaging their own products or services over those of other business users
(commonly called “self-preferencing”);21
 restricting business users from accessing a covered platform or its software on
the same terms as the platform operator’s own businesses;22
 conditioning access to or preferred placement within a covered platform on the
use of other products or services offered by the platform operator;23
 using data obtained from business users or their customers to support the
platform operator’s own products or services;24
 restricting or impeding business users from providing links to facilitate off-
platform business;25 and
 interfering with or restricting business users’ pricing of their goods or services.26
After amendments from the markup process, the bill offers the Big Tech platforms three
affirmative defenses. First, the bill offers an affirmative defense to covered platform operators
that establish by clear and convincing evidence that their conduct would not harm the competitive
process.27 Second, an affirmative defense is available to defendants that prove by clear and
convincing evidence that their conduct was necessary to prevent a violation of law or protect user
privacy, provided that certain other requirements are met.28 Third, the bill allows the Big Tech
firms to avoid liability if they show by clear and convincing evidence that their conduct increases
consumer welfare.29
Effect on Current Law
H.R. 3816 would move significantly beyond existing monopolization doctrine. Under current law,
monopolization is a two-element offense: plaintiffs must establish that a defendant (1) has
monopoly power, and (2) engaged in exclusionary conduct.30 The first element—monopoly
power—typically turns on factors like a defendant’s market share and entry barriers shielding the
defendant from would-be competitors.31 The second element—exclusionary conduct—involves a
burden-shifting framework. Under that framework, monopolization plaintiffs must first make a
prima facie case that the defendant’s conduct had anticompetitive effects. If a plaintiff makes this

21 H.R. 3816, 117th Cong. § 2(a)(1).
22 Id. § 2(b)(1).
23 Id. § 2(b)(2).
24 Id. § 2(b)(3).
25 Id. § 2(b)(6).
26 Id. § 2(b)(8).
27 Id. § 2(c)(1).
28 Id. § 2(c)(2).
29 Id. § 2(c)(3); see also Amendment to the Amendment in the Nature of a Substitute to H.R. 3816, Offered by Mr.
Bentz of Oregon, Markups, H.R. 3843, the Merger Filing Fee Modernization Act of 2021, et al., H. COMM. ON THE
JUDICIARY, 117TH CONG. (June 24, 2021), https://docs.house.gov/meetings/JU/JU00/20210623/112818/BILLS-117-
HR3816-B000668-Amdt-5.pdf.
30 United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966).
31 See, e.g., Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm Inc., 501 F.3d 297, 307 (3d Cir. 2007).
Congressional Research Service
4

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

showing, the burden shifts to the defendant to rebut the plaintiff’s evidence or proffer a
procompetitive justification for its conduct. If the defendant fails at this stage, the plaintiff
prevails. However, if the defendant succeeds, the burden shifts back to the plaintiff to show that
the anticompetitive harms of the challenged conduct outweigh the procompetitive benefits.32
H.R. 3816 would adopt a separate, ostensibly more plaintiff-friendly regulatory regime for the
Big Tech firms. Under that regime, plaintiffs challenging discriminatory conduct would not need
to show that the Big Tech firms possess monopoly power—a task that can require extensive
discovery and expert testimony. In place of that requirement, plaintiffs would face the far more
straightforward task of demonstrating that a defendant satisfies the three criteria necessary to
qualify as a “covered platform.”33
The changes to the exclusionary-conduct burden-shifting framework are also considerable. Here,
the bill’s new regulatory regime would dispense with the fact-intensive weighing of competitive
effects embodied in current monopolization law. In place of that analysis, the bill prohibits the
specified categories of discriminatory conduct.
H.R. 3816 offers the Big Tech firms various affirmative defenses (e.g., for conduct that increases
consumer welfare).34 However, these defenses set a high evidentiary bar—clear and convincing
evidence—that would likely be difficult to meet.35 In all but the rarest of cases, judicial analysis
of the bill’s defenses would probably be significantly truncated relative to current law, which
does not impose heightened evidentiary burdens on defendants seeking to rebut a prima facie case
of competitive harm.
While these changes to the doctrine appear straightforward, H.R. 3816 has already generated
interpretive controversies. Commentators have debated whether Section 2(a)(1) of the bill—
which prohibits platform operators from advantaging their own products—would prevent Google
and Apple from pre-installing their own apps on devices that use their operating systems (Android
and iOS).36 University of Chicago Law Professor Randy Picker has argued that Section 2(a)(1)
seems to prohibit such pre-installation.37 In contrast, the economist Hal Singer has disputed that
reading of the legislation. Singer contends that Section 2(b)(5) of the bill—which bars the Big
Tech firms from restricting or impeding the uninstallation of pre-installed apps—suggests that the
legislation both contemplates and tolerates pre-installation.38 Picker and Singer have also
expressed different views on whether Section 2(a)(3) of the bill—which prohibits the Big Tech
platforms from discriminating among similarly situated business users—would require Google

32 United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 58-59 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
33 H.R. 3816, 117th Cong. § 2(g)(4) (2021).
34 Id. § 2(c)(1)(A).
35 The “clear and convincing evidence” standard is an intermediate evidentiary burden that lies between
“preponderance of the evidence” (the typical burden in civil litigation) and “beyond a reasonable doubt” (the
paradigmatic criminal standard). The Supreme Court has explained that the burden is met when the evidence
supporting a contention makes the contention “highly probable.” Colorado v. New Mexico, 467 U.S. 310, 316 (1984).
While courts ordinarily resist efforts at quantification, one large survey of judges found that 75-percent probability was
the mean, median, and mode figure capturing the “clear and convincing evidence” standard. C.M.A. McCauliff,
Burdens of Proof: Degrees of Belief, Quanta of Evidence, or Constitutional Guarantees?, 35 VAND. L. REV. 1293,
1328-29 (1982).
36 H.R. 3816, 117th Cong. § 2(a)(1) (2021).
37 Randy Picker, The House’s Recent Spate of Antitrust Bills Would Change Big Tech as We Know It, PROMARKET
(June 29, 2021), https://promarket.org/2021/06/29/house-antitrust-bills-big-tech-apple-preinstallation/.
38 Hal Singer, Rep. Cicilline’s Bill Would Offer a Lifeline to Independent App Developers, PROMARKET (July 2, 2021),
https://promarket.org/2021/07/02/antitrust-self-preferencing-preinstallation-app-developers-apple/.
Congressional Research Service
5

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

and Apple to pre-install every app in a given category if they pre-install any apps within that
category.39

Comparing Legislation: S. 225, the Competition and Antitrust Law Enforcement
Reform Act of 2021 (CALERA)
The House Antitrust Subcommittee’s legislative package is not the only significant antitrust legislation in the 117th
Congress. In February 2021, Senator Amy Klobuchar introduced a bil that would make notable changes to
monopolization doctrine and several other elements of antitrust law. As relevant here, S. 225, the Competition
and Antitrust Law Enforcement Reform Act of 2021 (CALERA), would:

Amend the Clayton Antitrust Act to prohibit “exclusionary conduct that presents an appreciable risk of
harming competition.” S. 225, 117th Cong. § 9 (2021);

Define “exclusionary conduct” to include behavior that “materially disadvantages” actual or potential
competitors or “tends to foreclose or limit the ability or incentive” of actual or potential competitors to
compete. Id.;

Adopt a presumption that exclusionary conduct “presents an appreciable risk of harming competition” if it is
undertaken by a firm with a market share greater than 50% or a firm that otherwise possesses “significant
market power.” Id.;

Provide that defendants can rebut this presumption by establishing by a preponderance of the evidence that
their exclusionary conduct does not present an appreciable risk of harming competition. Id.; and

Eliminate several defendant-friendly requirements in the monopolization case law, including limitations on
plaintiffs’ ability to prevail in refusal-to-deal litigation, predatory-pricing claims, and cases involving two-sided
markets. Id.
These changes to monopolization law would be both broader and narrower than H.R. 3816’s prohibitions.
CALERA is broader than H.R. 3816 insofar as it would subject a larger number of firms and a wider range of
behavior to heightened antitrust scrutiny. While H.R. 3816 is limited to “covered platforms” (the Big Tech firms),
S. 225’s conduct-related presumption would extend to all firms that possess “significant market power.” Likewise,
while H.R. 3816 would prohibit only specified forms of discriminatory behavior, S. 225 would extend to any
“exclusionary conduct.”
However, CALERA’s substantive changes to monopolization law would be more modest than H.R. 3816’s non-
discrimination requirements for the Big Tech firms. While CALERA would allow defendants to rebut the relevant
presumption of competitive harm by a preponderance of the evidence, H.R. 3816’s affirmative defenses employ
the more demanding clear-and-convincing-evidence standard.
The Arguments For
H.R. 3816 targets a diverse range of conduct raising a variety of competition issues. There is
nevertheless a clear unifying theme. The bill’s drafters appear to be principally concerned with
the Big Tech firms’ use of market power in their core business lines to disadvantage competitors
in related markets. When dominant platforms preference their own offerings in search rankings,
for example, they make it more difficult for their vertical competitors to compete with those
offerings. Likewise, when a platform uses data derived from business users to compete with those
users, the platform operates with a significant competitive advantage. Similarly, when a powerful
incumbent conditions the availability of its core services on a customer’s use of its related
services, competition in the market for those related services suffers.40

39 See notes 37-38 supra.
40 For a leading academic discussion of these types of competitive harm, see Lina M. Khan, The Separation of
Platforms and Commerce
, 119 COLUM. L. REV. 973 (2019). The article’s author, Lina Kahn, took office as Chair of the
FTC on June 15, 2021. Lina Khan Sworn in as Chair of the FTC, FED. TRADE COMM’N (June 15, 2021),
https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/2021/06/lina-khan-sworn-chair-ftc.
Congressional Research Service
6

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

The Arguments Against
Opponents of non-discrimination requirements have offered two general types of objections to
measures like H.R. 3816. First, some commentators have challenged the claim that the conduct
the bill prohibits is anticompetitive. For example, some commentators have argued that platform
self-preferencing is generally a procompetitive effort to enhance users’ experience.41 Similarly,
Amazon’s use of merchant data to identify profitable new lines of business may very well
increase output in certain product markets.42 Apple has also defended the rules governing
participation in its app store as necessary to preserve the technical integrity of the iPhone
ecosystem.43
Beyond arguments about specific practices, the bill’s opponents have contended that the flexible,
fact-intensive framework employed by current antitrust law is preferable to ex ante regulation.44
Many of these arguments appeal to the “error costs” of categorical prohibitions. The Chicago
School placed error costs at the center of antitrust scholarship, maintaining that the harms of
“false positives” condemning procompetitive conduct usually outweigh those of “false negatives”
allowing anticompetitive behavior to proceed.45 This theoretical framework led to a general
preference for flexible standards over bright-line rules in monopolization cases.46 The debate over
H.R. 3816 is in part a dispute over whether this evolution has rendered antitrust law ill-equipped
to grapple with the Big Tech firms’ dominance.
The participants in this debate are not writing on a blank slate. There is a massive literature on the
choice between rules and standards that this report cannot comprehensively catalogue.47
Nevertheless, some of the key themes are worth noting. General standards afford decision-makers
greater ability to discriminate between harmful and benign conduct than bright-line rules.
However, enforcing broad standards is usually far costlier than applying clear rules, and high
enforcement costs can result in under-deterrence of anticompetitive conduct.48 Case-by-case
adjudication is also arguably less democratic than the legislative and administrative procedures

41 See, e.g., D. Bruce Hoffman & Garrett D. Shinn, Self-Preferencing and Antitrust: Harmful Solutions for an
Improbable Problem
, COMPETITION POLICY INT’L ANTITRUST CHRONICLE 5-8 (June 2021); Sam Bowman & Geoffrey
Manne, Platform Self-Preferencing Can Be Good for Consumers and Even Competitors, TRUTH ON THE MARKET (Mar.
4, 2021), https://truthonthemarket.com/2021/03/04/platform-self-preferencing-can-be-good-for-consumers-and-even-
competitors/.
42 See Sam Bowman, Amazon’s Tightrope: Balancing Innovation and Competition on Amazon’s Marketplace, TRUTH
ON THE MARKET (Apr. 27, 2020), https://truthonthemarket.com/2020/04/27/amazons-tightrope-balancing-innovation-
and-competition-on-amazons-marketplace/ (arguing that the competitive effects of Amazon’s use of merchant data
likely vary based on the nature of the product at issue).
43 Opposition to Motion for a Temporary Restraining Order, Epic Games, Inc. v. Apple Inc., No. 3:20-cv-05640 at 29
(N.D. Cal. Aug. 21, 2020).
44 See, e.g., Joint Submission of Antitrust Economists, Legal Scholars, and Practitioners to the House Judiciary
Committee on the State of Antitrust Law and Implications for Protecting Competition in Digital Markets, INT’L CTR.
FOR L. AND ECON. 3 (May 15, 2020), https://laweconcenter.org/wp-
content/uploads/2020/05/house_joint_antitrust_letter_20200514.pdf.
45 Frank H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1, 2-3 (1984). In brief, Chicago School theorists
argued that the harms of monopoly are largely self-correcting because monopoly prices eventually attract the entry of
new firms, whereas inefficient legal rules are far “stickier.” See id. For a contrary view, see Jonathan B. Baker, Taking
the Error Out of “Error Cost” Analysis: What’s Wrong With Antitrust’s Right
, 80 ANTITRUST L.J. 1 (2015).
46 See, e.g., Daniel A. Crane, Rules Versus Standards in Antitrust Adjudication, 64 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 49 (2007).
47 For a prominent account of the choice between rules and standards, see Louis Kaplow, Rules Versus Standards: An
Economic Analysis
, 42 DUKE L.J. 557 (1992).
48 See Rohit Chopra & Lina M. Khan, The Case for “Unfair Methods of Competition” Rulemaking, 87 U. CHI. L. REV.
357, 361-62 (2020) (arguing that the high costs of antitrust litigation undermine effective enforcement).
Congressional Research Service
7

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

that accompany rule development.49 Finally, rules can provide industry participants with more
legal clarity than open-ended standards.50 The bottom line is that H.R. 3816 wades into a familiar
debate that has occupied antitrust scholars and students of economic regulation more generally.51

A Note on Self-Preferencing
Self-preferencing—whereby a tech platform vertically integrates and gives its downstream products certain
advantages over competitors—is among the core concerns of H.R. 3816 and H.R. 3825. The practice has
provoked a lively debate. Critics have argued that when dominant platforms favor their own products, they can
leverage their power in their core markets to foreclose competition in adjacent markets. See, e.g., Daniel A.
Hanley, How Self-Preferencing Can Violate Section 2 of the Sherman Act, COMPETITION POLICY INT’L ANTITRUST
CHRONICLE 4 (June 2021). The European Commission invoked this theory of harm in 2017 when it fined Google
€2.42 bil ion for giving its own comparison-shopping service more prominent placement than rival services in its
search results. See Case AT.39740 – Google Search (Shopping), Summary of Commission Decision, EUROPEAN
COMM’N (June 27, 2017). A group of state attorneys general is also suing Google based on claims that the tech
giant’s advertising server (which manages advertising inventories for large publishers) unlawful y favors Google’s
advertising exchange (which matches publishers with advertisers). Complaint, State of Texas, et al. v. Google LLC,
No. 4:20-cv-00957 ¶¶ 118-24 (E.D. Tex. Dec. 16, 2020).
Self-preferencing also has its proponents. Big Tech’s defenders have argued that the simplest explanation for self-
preferencing is that it makes platforms more attractive to consumers. See, e.g., Hoffman & Shinn, supra note 41, at
5-7. Under this theory, Amazon sells its own private-label products and gives them conspicuous placement
primarily so that customers can buy inexpensive generic items—not because its private-label business is highly
profitable on a standalone basis. See Mattioli, supra note 10 (noting Amazon’s assertion that its private-label
business represents only “about 1% of its retail sales”). Likewise, Google’s supporters have argued that the
company’s placement of a Google Maps box at the top of certain search results enhances users’ experience by
prominently highlighting valuable information. See Todd, infra note 61, at 526-27; Bowman & Manne, supra note 41.
While different types of self-preferencing raise different issues, there is something of a meta-argument here. In
brief, the practice’s defenders maintain that Big Tech firms vertically integrate and self-preference only when the
gains from doing so outweigh any losses from degradation of the quality of their main platform businesses. Skeptics
of ex ante regulation argue that this calculus is usually a reasonable proxy for overall welfare, and that existing
monopolization doctrine can address those instances in which it is not. See Hoffman & Shinn, supra note 41, at 7-9;
see also Michael Salinger, Self-Preferencing, in REPORT ON THE DIGITAL ECONOMY, GEO. MASON U. GLOBAL ANTITRUST
INST. (2020). For a contrary view, see Edward Iacobucci & Francesco Ducci, The Google Search Case in Europe: Tying
and the Single Monopoly Profit Theorem in Two-Sided Markets
, 47 EUROPEAN J. OF L. AND ECON. 15 (2019).
Structural Separation: H.R. 3825, Ending Platform
Monopolies Act

The Issue
H.R. 3825, the Ending Platform Monopolies Act, is directed at some of the concerns mentioned
above in connection with H.R. 3816.52 Both bills respond to allegations that the Big Tech firms
have leveraged dominance of their core markets to disadvantage rivals in related markets.

49 See generally Harry First & Spencer Weber Waller, Antitrust’s Democracy Deficit, 81 FORDHAM L. REV. 2543
(2013).
50 See Chopra & Khan, supra note 48, at 358.
51 For an overview of the relative virtues and vices of regulation, adjudication, and administration as tools of
competition policy, see DANIEL A. CRANE, THE INSTITUTIONAL STRUCTURE OF ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 93-108
(2011).
52 H.R. 3825, 117th Cong. (2021).
Congressional Research Service
8

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

The Legislation
While H.R. 3825 and H.R. 3816 are motivated by the same general issue, they address that issue
in different ways. As discussed, H.R. 3816 would prohibit the Big Tech firms from engaging in
various forms of “discriminatory conduct.” In contrast, H.R. 3825 would require structural
separation
. Under the bill, operators of “covered platforms”53 could not:
 use their platforms to sell or provide other products or services;
 require business users to utilize a product or service as a condition of accessing
or receiving preferred placement on their platforms; or
 operate both a covered platform and another “line of business” if doing so would
create a “conflict of interest” by giving the platform operator the incentive and
ability to advantage its own offerings on the platform.54
Effect on Current Law
H.R. 3825 is a major departure from current antitrust doctrine. While courts theoretically have the
power to order structural separation in monopolization cases, it is difficult for plaintiffs to obtain
such sweeping relief in all but the most extraordinary circumstances.55 The bill is instead a form
of sector-specific competition regulation, similar to the regimes governing banking and
(historically) railroads—two other industries in which entry into adjacent markets has been
viewed as creating irremediable conflicts of interest.56
The Arguments For
The arguments for H.R. 3825 mirror those for H.R. 3816. However, structural separation may
have administrability advantages over non-discrimination requirements, as commentators have
argued that the latter are costlier to enforce.57 Rules demanding that tech platforms accord equal
treatment to vertical rivals may be particularly complicated to administer, requiring regulators and
courts to establish some baseline level of “neutral” treatment and probe the inner workings of the
platforms’ algorithms. Advocates of structural separation contend that it is better to “break up”
Big Tech than rely on overburdened regulators and generalist judges to parse such details.58
The Arguments Against
Big Tech’s defenders argue that the firms’ entry into new markets is almost always
procompetitive.59 Facebook, Google, Amazon, and Apple have access to deep pools of retained

53 The bill would apply to the same “covered platforms” as H.R. 3816. Id. § 5(4).
54 Id. § 2(a)-(b).
55 See Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust and Platform Monopoly, 130 YALE L.J. 1901, 1957 (2021) (explaining that, aside
from merger enforcement, most antitrust relief is nonstructural).
56 See Khan, supra note 40, at 1037-43.
57 See, e.g., HOUSE ANTITRUST SUBCOMM. REPORT, supra note 4, at 381 (noting this possible advantage of structural
separation).
58 But see Hal Singer, Inside Tech’s “Kill Zone”: How to Deal With the Threat to Edge Innovation Posed by Multi-
Sided Platforms
, PROMARKET (Nov. 21, 2018), https://promarket.org/2018/11/21/inside-tech-kill-zone/ (defending non-
discrimination requirements over structural separation on the grounds that the latter is a “messy undertaking,” because
drawing boundaries around tech platforms “is not straightforward”).
59 See, e.g., Invited Statement of Geoffrey A. Manne on House Judiciary Investigation Into Competition in Digital
Congressional Research Service
9

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

earnings that they can plow into innovative new lines of business. Under a separation regime,
Google could not have used those resources to develop products like Google Chrome and Google
Maps. Likewise, Amazon may have to exit the “streaming wars” by divesting Prime Video.60 A
rule prohibiting the Big Tech firms from entering adjacent markets may also destroy well-
recognized efficiencies that typically accompany vertical integration.61 Structural separation could
even entrench the Big Tech firms’ power by preventing them from entering each other’s core
markets. Apple could not develop a search engine to challenge Google,62 nor could Amazon build
a video-sharing service to challenge YouTube.63
These objections need not be decisive. Congress could consider a structural-separation regime
that would allow a designated regulator to approve a dominant platform’s entry into adjacent
markets in limited circumstances (i.e., when a market is dominated by another platform
monopolist, or when efficiencies clearly favor integration). Moreover, the Big Tech firms’
financial resources would not simply disappear under an exception-free separation regime. If
Facebook, Google, Amazon, and Apple retain large amounts of cash that they cannot deploy on
new projects or acquisitions, they would likely face pressure to return that money to shareholders,
who could then channel it to other innovative companies.64 The debate over structural separation
may therefore turn on arguments about the desirability of “decentralized” innovation spread
among a large number of firms, as opposed to “centralized” innovation concentrated in a handful
of resource-rich tech companies.65
These debates over efficiencies and innovation sometimes intersect with difficult conceptual
issues facing proponents of structural separation. In some separation regimes, there are clearly
defined boundaries between product markets. For example, it is relatively uncontroversial that
railroads and commodity producers operate in different lines of business.66 However, technology
markets often lack similarly crisp borders.67 For instance, Apple produces the iOS operating
system for mobile devices and a range of related features, including a voice assistant (Siri), a
camera, a calculator, a calendar, an alarm, a photos app, a weather app, a news app, and a
payment system (Apple Pay).68 It is unclear which of these additional features qualifies as a “line
of business” distinct from Apple’s iOS platform within the meaning of H.R. 3825. (The

Markets: Correcting Common Misperceptions About the State of Antitrust Law and Enforcement, INT’L CTR. FOR L.
AND ECON. 7-8, 24-27 (Apr. 17, 2020), https://laweconcenter.org/wp-
content/uploads/2020/04/Manne_statement_house_antitrust_20200417_FINAL3-POST.pdf.
60 See Sam Bowman, Breaking Down the House Democrats’ Forthcoming Competition Bills, TRUTH ON THE MARKET
(June 10, 2021), https://truthonthemarket.com/2021/06/10/breaking-down-house-democrats-forthcoming-competition-
bills/.
61 Patrick F. Todd, Digital Platforms and the Leverage Problem, 98 NEB. L. REV. 486, 539 (2019).
62 See Tim Bradshaw & Patrick McGee, Apple Develops Alternative to Google Search, FIN. TIMES (Oct. 28, 2020),
https://www.ft.com/content/fd311801-e863-41fe-82cf-3d98c4c47e26.
63 See Amazon Video Direct Poses Challenge to YouTube, BBC (May 10, 2016),
https://www.bbc.com/news/technology-36259782.
64 See, e.g., Erin McCarthy, Icahn Letter Pushes Apple to Buy Back More Shares, WALL ST. J. (Oct. 9, 2014),
https://www.wsj.com/articles/icahn-pushes-apple-to-buy-back-more-stock-
1412860351#:~:text=Activist%20investor%20Carl%20C.,Executive%20Tim%20Cook%2C%20which%20Mr.
65 Khan, supra note 40, at 1085-86 (noting the possible costs and tradeoffs of structural separation and recognizing this
distinction).
66 See Pub. L. No. 59-337 § 1, 34 Stat. 584, 585 (1906).
67 See Todd, supra note 61, at 535-37; Singer, supra note 58.
68 Darren Orf, A Brief History of iOS, GIZMODO (June 7, 2016), https://gizmodo.com/a-brief-history-of-ios-
1780790760.
Congressional Research Service
10

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

legislation does not define that term.)69 Moreover, technology markets are not static; the Big Tech
firms continually release updated versions of their platforms with new features that could
theoretically be provided by third parties. A prohibition of integration into separate “lines of
business” may chill this type of innovation to the detriment of consumers.
Mergers and Acquisitions: H.R. 3826, Platform
Competition and Opportunity Act

The Issue
H.R. 3826, the Platform Competition and Opportunity Act, is directed at mergers and
acquisitions—another means by which the Big Tech firms have allegedly maintained and
extended their power.70 The House Antitrust Subcommittee’s October 2020 report found that the
Big Tech firms had acquired hundreds of companies over the prior decade.71 Prominent examples
include Facebook’s acquisitions of Instagram and WhatsApp; Amazon’s acquisitions of IMDb,
Audible, and Zappos; Google’s acquisitions of YouTube, DoubleClick, and Waze; and Apple’s
acquisition of Shazam.72 According to Big Tech’s critics, many of the firms’ deals have allowed
them to solidify their dominance by acquiring competitors and potential rivals.73 The
Subcommittee’s report also alleges that the tech giants acquired some of these firms for the
purpose of shutting them down or discontinuing their main services—a phenomenon that has
been dubbed the “killer acquisition.”74 To address these concerns, the report recommends
legislation that would shift the burden of proof to dominant platforms to show that their proposed
transactions are in the public interest.75
The Legislation
H.R. 3826 takes up the Subcommittee’s recommendation. The bill would prohibit “covered
platform operators”—defined to mean operators of the same “covered platforms” subject to the
bills discussed above—from acquiring other firms unless platform operators can demonstrate by
clear and convincing evidence that:
 the target firm does not compete with the platform operator;
 the target firm is not a “nascent or potential” competitor of the platform operator;
 the acquisition would not enhance the platform operator’s market position for
services related to its existing platform; and

69 H.R. 3825, 117th Cong. § 2 (2021).
70 H.R. 3826, 117th Cong. (2021).
71 HOUSE ANTITRUST SUBCOMM. REPORT, supra note 4, at 406-50.
72 See id.
73 See, e.g., Gilad Edelman, Why the FTC Wants to Revisit Hundreds of Deals by Big Tech, WIRED (Feb. 12, 2020),
https://www.wired.com/story/ftc-special-order-review-big-tech-killer-acquisitions/; JOHN KWOKA, CONTROLLING
MERGERS AND MARKET POWER: A PROGRAM FOR REVIVING ANTITRUST IN AMERICA 109-17 (2020); Diana Moss, The
Record of Weak U.S. Merger Enforcement in Big Tech
, AM. ANTITRUST INST. (July 8, 2019),
https://www.antitrustinstitute.org/wp-content/uploads/2019/07/Merger-Enforcement_Big-Tech_7.8.19.pdf.
74 HOUSE ANTITRUST SUBCOMM. REPORT, supra note 4, at 38.
75 Id. at 387-88.
Congressional Research Service
11

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

 the acquisition would not enhance the platform operator’s “ability to maintain its
market position” for services related to its existing platform.76
As amended, the bill would also provide an exception to its general prohibition for transactions
involving target companies valued at less than $50 million.77
Effect on Current Law
Under current law, mergers and acquisitions are governed by Section 7 of the Clayton Act, which
prohibits deals that may “substantially lessen” competition.78 Courts typically evaluate merger
cases using a burden-shifting framework that resembles the standards employed in
monopolization litigation. Under this framework, the plaintiff bears the initial burden of showing
that a proposed transaction will have anticompetitive effects. If the plaintiff succeeds, the burden
shifts to the defendant to rebut the plaintiff’s case or produce evidence of the deal’s
procompetitive benefits. If the defendant fails at this stage, the plaintiff prevails. However, if the
defendant succeeds, the burden shifts back to the plaintiff to show that the acquisition’s
anticompetitive harms outweigh its procompetitive benefits.79
Courts have also developed special tests for evaluating mergers between potential competitors—
firms that do not compete when an acquisition is proposed, but may otherwise compete in the
future.80 The nuances of this doctrine are outside the scope of this report. For present purposes, it
suffices to note that the courts have generally imposed heavy evidentiary burdens on plaintiffs
challenging mergers involving potential rivals.81
H.R. 3826 would significantly alter these legal standards for the Big Tech firms. The bill would
prohibit Facebook, Google, Amazon, and Apple from engaging in mergers or acquisitions unless
they can show by clear and convincing evidence that their deals would not fall into any of the
specified categories.82 The legislation’s prohibition of acquisitions of potential competitors is
particularly significant, given current law’s deferential posture toward those transactions. While
the Big Tech firms could theoretically press ahead with deals that fall outside of the prohibited
categories, the legislation’s demanding evidentiary requirements may create disincentives for
acquisitions that arguably straddle the boundaries of those provisions.83


76 H.R. 3826, 117th Cong. § 2(a)-(b) (2021).
77 See Amendment to the Amendment in the Nature of a Substitute to H.R. 3826 Offered by Ms. Ross of North
Carolina, Markups, H.R. 3843, the Merger Filing Fee Modernization Act of 2021, et al., H. COMM. ON THE JUDICIARY,
117TH CONG. (June 24, 2021), https://docs.house.gov/meetings/JU/JU00/20210623/112818/BILLS-117-HR3826-
R000305-Amdt-1.pdf.
78 15 U.S.C. § 18. Under current law, firms must submit information about mergers and acquisitions exceeding certain
size thresholds to the Department of Justice and the FTC for review before consummating their transactions. 15 U.S.C.
§ 18a. H.R. 3826 would not alter this requirement.
79 See, e.g., St. Alphonsus Med. Ctr.-Nampa Inc. v. St. Luke’s Health Sys., Ltd., 778 F.3d 775, 783 (9th Cir. 2015).
80 See, e.g., United States v. Marine Bancorporation, Inc., 418 U.S. 602 (1974).
81 See generally Darren Bush & Salvatore Massa, Rethinking Potential Competition Doctrine, 2004 WIS. L. REV. 1035
(2004).
82 H.R. 3826, 117th Cong. § 2(b).
83 See note 35 supra.
Congressional Research Service
12

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

Comparing Legislation: S. 225, the Competition and Antitrust Law Enforcement
Reform Act of 2021 (CALERA), and S. 1074, the Trust-Busting for the Twenty-First
Century Act
H.R. 3826 is not the only significant merger legislation in the 117th Congress. In addition to the changes to
monopolization law discussed above, Senator Klobuchar’s CALERA legislation would amend the Clayton Act to
prohibit mergers that “create an appreciable risk of materially lessening competition.” S. 225, 117th Cong. § 4
(2021). The bil would also shift the burden of proof from the government to the merging party for certain
mergers involving potential rivals, significant increases in market concentration, or firms that exceed specified size
thresholds. Id. In these circumstances, the merging party would bear the burden of showing by a preponderance of
the evidence that its proposed transaction would not violate the amended Clayton Act standard. Id.
These changes would be both broader and narrower than those in H.R. 3826. CALERA is broader than H.R. 3826
insofar as it would apply to a wider range of mergers. While H.R. 3826 is limited to deals involving “covered
platform operators,” CALERA would alter the legal standard governing all mergers and adopt generally applicable
presumptions.
CALERA’s substantive changes are more modest than those in H.R. 3826. H.R. 3826 would prohibit the Big Tech
firms from acquiring rivals and potential rivals, while CALERA would merely alter the legal standard and (in many
cases) the burden of proof for such transactions. Moreover, H.R. 3826 would require the Big Tech firms to
establish by clear and convincing evidence that their proposed mergers do not fall within four prohibited categories.
In contrast, if CALERA became law and a Big Tech merger triggered its presumption of il egality, the Big Tech firm
could rebut that presumption by showing by a preponderance of the evidence that the transaction would not violate
the amended Clayton Act standard.
Senator Josh Hawley has introduced legislation that would make more sweeping changes to the merger laws
governing Big Tech firms than either CALERA or H.R. 3826. S. 1074, the Trust-Busting for the Twenty-First
Century Act, would prohibit firms with market capitalizations exceeding $100 bil ion—a category that comfortably
includes all of the Big Tech firms—from engaging in mergers that “may . . . lessen competition in any way.” S. 1074,
117th Cong. § 3 (2021). Senator Hawley’s office has characterized this language as functionally equivalent to a
categorical ban on mergers involving firms larger than the relevant threshold. See Senator Hawley Introduces The
“Trust-Busting for the Twenty-First Century Act”: A Plan to Bust Up Anti-Competitive Big Businesses
, OFFICE OF SEN. JOSH
HAWLEY (Apr. 12, 2021), https://www.hawley.senate.gov/senator-hawley-introduces-trust-busting-twenty-first-
century-act-plan-bust-anti-competitive-big.
The Arguments For
As discussed, supporters of H.R. 3826 contend that the Big Tech firms have preserved and
extended their monopoly power by acquiring competitors and potential competitors.84
Commentators have placed some of the blame for these transactions on the permissive legal
standards that courts have developed over the past several decades, especially the doctrine
governing acquisitions of potential competitors.85 By prohibiting the Big Tech firms from
engaging in such acquisitions and other types of potentially anticompetitive transactions, the bill
would address one of the major problems identified by Big Tech’s critics.
The Arguments Against
Big Tech’s defenders have responded to this line of argument by appealing to the incentive effects
of potential acquisitions. According to one narrative, the prospect of being acquired by a Big Tech
firm induces entrepreneurs and their venture-capital (VC) backers to enter tech markets. The
possibility of an acquisition thus arguably mitigates the so-called VC “kill zone,” in which
investors are reluctant to commit capital to areas dominated by the Big Four.86 Some

84 See notes 73-75 supra.
85 See note 73 supra.
86 Biz Carson, DOJ Lawyers Ask Startup Investors About Big Tech’s “Kill Zones, PROTOCOL (Feb. 12, 2020),
Congressional Research Service
13

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

commentators have argued that, by eliminating the option of being bought out by Big Tech,
measures like H.R. 3826 may dampen startup investment.87 Debate over the bill may therefore
require Congress to weigh the possible costs of these “barriers to exit” against the benefits of
blocking anticompetitive transactions.
Interoperability and Data Portability: H.R. 3849,
Augmenting Compatibility and Competition by
Enabling Service Switching (ACCESS) Act

The Issue
H.R. 3849, the Augmenting Compatibility and Competition by Enabling Service Switching
(ACCESS) Act, is directed at the “network effects” and “switching costs” that give dominant tech
platforms powerful incumbency advantages.88 Markets exhibit network effects when a product’s
utility depends on the number of people who use it. The idea is intuitive: people want to use
Facebook—as opposed to a smaller social network—because their friends and family are on
Facebook. Likewise, advertisers want to run ads on Facebook—as opposed to a smaller social
network—because Facebook allows them to advertise to a larger number of users. The same basic
reasoning applies to Google Search, Amazon Marketplace, and Apple’s App Store. These network
effects create significant entry barriers that deter startups from competing with the tech giants.89
Even when consumers prefer a smaller competitor over a Big Tech firm, they may face
“switching costs” when deciding whether to make a change. Commentators have argued that
certain digital markets exhibit high switching costs, causing user “lock-in” and creating another
barrier deterring entry by prospective rivals.90 For example, users who abandon Facebook for
another social network must leave behind large amounts of data (e.g., friends, messages, “likes”)
that enhance their user experience.
The combination of powerful network effects and high switching costs makes many digital
markets prone to “tipping” in favor of one or two large companies, leading to a form of “winner-
take-all” economics in which Big Tech firms are shielded from competition after they have
assumed dominant positions.91

https://www.protocol.com/doj-antitrust-venture-capital-workshop.
87 See, e.g., Jeff Farrah, Restrictions on Acquisitions Would Stifle the US Startup Ecosystem, Not Rein In Big Tech,
TECHCRUNCH (May 19, 2021), https://techcrunch.com/2021/05/19/restrictions-on-acquisitions-would-stifle-the-us-
startup-ecosystem-not-rein-in-big-tech/; Sam Bowman, Cracking Down on Mergers Would Leave Us All Worse Off,
THE HILL (Mar. 12, 2021), https://thehill.com/blogs/congress-blog/politics/542880-cracking-down-on-mergers-would-
leave-us-all-worse-off.
88 H.R. 3849, 117th Cong. (2021).
89 See, e.g., HOUSE ANTITRUST SUBCOMM. REPORT, supra note 4, at 39-40; Stigler Committee on Digital Platforms,
Final Report, U. CHI. BOOTH SCH. OF BUS., STIGLER CTR. FOR THE STUDY OF THE ECONOMY AND THE STATE 38-39
(2019) [hereinafter “STIGLER REPORT”].
90 See, e.g., HOUSE ANTITRUST SUBCOMM. REPORT, supra note 4, at 41-42.
91 STIGLER REPORT, supra note 89, at 34-36. For an argument that the Big Tech firms face meaningful competitive
pressures despite operating in “tipped” markets, see generally NICOLAS PETIT, BIG TECH AND THE DIGITAL ECONOMY:
THE MOLIGOPOLY SCENARIO (2020).
Congressional Research Service
14

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

The Legislation
H.R. 3849 addresses these issues with two sets of requirements: interoperability and data
portability. The interoperability mandate would require Big Tech firms to make their products and
services compatible with those offered by competitors.92 The bill directs the FTC to develop
standards fleshing out the content of these obligations, and requires firms that interconnect with
covered platforms to take “reasonable steps” to avoid introducing security risks to the platforms’
information systems.93 While the exact contours of this regime would vary from platform to
platform, one can make some educated guesses about what it would entail. Facebook, for
example, may have to develop tools that allow its users to communicate with users of rival social
networks. Similarly, Apple may have to make its app store compatible with third-party payment
systems.
The data-portability mandate shares a similar structure. The legislation would require the Big
Tech firms to enable users to transfer their data to competitors, authorize the FTC to develop
data-portability standards, and impose certain security requirements on companies that receive
ported data.94 While the precise content of platforms’ obligations would depend on the FTC’s
implementation of the bill, the general idea is simple. Facebook, for example, would likely have
to allow users to transfer their data (e.g., friends, messages, “likes”) to competing social
networks.
Effect on Current Law
Interoperability and data-portability requirements are forms of what antitrust law has traditionally
called “duties to deal” with rivals. While companies are generally free to choose their
counterparties, antitrust duties to deal can arise in several circumstances. First, regulators have
imposed such duties as remedies for certain types of antitrust violations.95 Second, monopolists
may have duties to deal when they control an “essential facility” that cannot reasonably be
duplicated.96 Finally, in Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., the Supreme Court
held that monopolists can be liable for terminating profitable courses of dealing with rivals absent
a valid business justification.97
This body of case law is not a promising vehicle for imposing interoperability and data-portability
requirements on the Big Tech firms. For a court to impose such requirements as remedies, a
plaintiff would have to establish substantive antitrust violations for which interoperability or data
portability is an appropriate form of redress. While the Justice Department’s 2002 consent decree
with Microsoft contained a prominent example of an interoperability mandate,98 it is unclear
whether any of the Big Tech firms’ conduct would prompt a court to order a similar remedy.
This uncertainty is partially attributable to the courts’ significant narrowing of substantive refusal-
to-deal liability. The essential-facilities case law exemplifies this trend, as lower federal courts

92 H.R. 3849, 117th Cong. § 4. The bill’s requirements would apply to the same “covered platforms” as the legislation
discussed above. Id. § 5(6).
93 Id. § 4.
94 Id. § 3.
95 See, e.g., United States v. Microsoft, 231 F. Supp. 2d 144, 190-92 (D.D.C. 2002).
96 See, e.g., Otter Tail Power Co. v. United States, 410 U.S. 366 (1973); United States v. Terminal R.R. Ass’n, 224 U.S.
383 (1912); MCI Comm’cns Corp. v. AT&T Co., 708 F.2d 1081 (7th Cir. 1983).
97 472 U.S. 585 (1985).
98 Microsoft, 231 F. Supp. 2d at 190-92.
Congressional Research Service
15

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

have become increasingly sparing in applying that doctrine.99 The Supreme Court has also
contributed to this tapering. In Verizon Communications, Inc. v. Trinko, the Court referred to the
essential-facilities doctrine as a creation of the lower courts, while declining to either recognize or
repudiate it.100 Commentators have described this treatment of the essential-facilities case law as
inflicting “death by dicta”101 and wondered whether the doctrine is now a “dead letter.”102 Trinko
also cabined refusal-to-deal liability more generally by characterizing Aspen Skiing as “at or near
the outer boundary” of monopolization law.103 Accordingly, current antitrust doctrine does not
offer an attractive means of imposing interoperability or data portability on Big Tech firms that do
not already offer those options.104 H.R. 3849 seeks to plug this alleged gap with a regulatory fix.
The Arguments For
As noted, H.R. 3849’s interoperability requirements are directed at the network effects that
insulate Big Tech firms from competition. The bill represents an attempt to shift those network
effects from individual firms to the market as a whole, leveling the playing field for smaller
rivals.105 Here, the bill borrows a regulatory tool that has played an important role in
telecommunications law, where carriers must allow rivals to interconnect with their facilities and
equipment.106 The legislation’s data-portability requirement would address a different entry
barrier by attempting to reduce the switching costs facing users of Big Tech platforms.107 Again,
telecom regulation imposes an analogous mandate, requiring phone carriers to allow customers to
keep their phone numbers when they switch to rival services.108 Together, interoperability and
data portability would arguably mitigate the structural characteristics that cause certain tech
markets to “tip” in favor of a single dominant firm.
The Arguments Against
The traditional arguments against interoperability and data portability appeal to worries about
security, privacy, technical challenges, and innovation harms. “Closed systems” like Apple’s iOS
arguably have certain security advantages over their open rivals, which interoperability could

99 Spencer Weber Waller & Brett Frischmann, Revitalizing the Essential Facilities Doctrine, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 1, 7
(2008).
100 540 U.S. 398, 411-12 (2004).
101 Waller & Frischmann, supra note 99, at 3.
102 Lina M. Khan, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox, 126 YALE L.J. 710, 801 (2017).
103 540 U.S. at 409. In applying Trinko, lower courts have coalesced around a three-part test for refusal-to-deal liability.
Under that test, a plaintiff bringing a refusal-to-deal claim must show that the defendant-monopolist (1) terminated a
profitable course of dealing with a competitor, (2) continued to sell the relevant product or service to other similarly
situated customers, and (3) was willing to forsake short-term profits for an anticompetitive end, rather than a legitimate
business purpose. See FTC v. Qualcomm Inc., 969 F.3d 974, 993-94 (9th Cir. 2020); Novell, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp.,
731 F.3d 1064, 1074-76 (10th Cir. 2013) (Gorsuch, J.).
104 In June 2021, a federal district court dismissed the FTC’s allegations that Facebook’s restrictions on access to
Facebook Platform constituted unlawful refusals to deal. Memorandum Opinion, FTC v. Facebook, Inc., 1:20-cv-03590
at 39-50 (D.D.C. June 28, 2021).
105 See, e.g., Michael Kades & Fiona Scott Morton, Interoperability as a Competition Remedy for Digital Networks,
WASH. CTR. FOR EQUITABLE GROWTH (Sept. 23, 2020).
106 47 U.S.C. § 251(a).
107 See, e.g., Josh Constine, Friend Portability Is the Must-Have Facebook Regulation, TECHCRUNCH (May 12, 2019),
https://techcrunch.com/2019/05/12/friends-wherever/.
108 47 U.S.C. § 251(b)(2).
Congressional Research Service
16

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills

diminish or eliminate.109 Privacy is also a concern. Often, a platform user’s data is co-mingled
with the data of other users. For example, multiple users might be “tagged” in a photo on
Facebook, and messages typically include information about their senders and recipients.
Allowing users to port such data from a Big Tech firm to another platform without the consent of
other parties would have important privacy implications.110 Interoperability and data-portability
mandates would also likely be complicated to develop and enforce.111 The Telecommunications
Act of 1996—which contains perhaps the most prominent example of an interoperability
requirement—prompted over a decade of litigation that included multiple trips to the Supreme
Court.112 H.R. 3849’s critics have cited this experience as a reason to be skeptical of the
government’s capacity to craft and administer technically complex interoperability regulations
without getting bogged down in litigation.113 In addition, opponents of expansive refusal-to-deal
liability have argued that duties to deal inappropriately privilege static competition (price
competition among sellers of undifferentiated products or services) over dynamic competition
(innovation via the development of new products and services).114 Some commentators have
argued that interoperability would reduce dynamic competition by inducing firms that
interoperate with the Big Tech platforms to eschew significant investments in innovation because
of their need to maintain interoperability. Instead of making such investments, firms that
interoperate may confine themselves to narrower competition focused on repackaging the
services already offered by Big Tech.115

Author Information

Jay B. Sykes

Legislative Attorney


109 Hanno F. Kaiser, Are “Closed Systems” an Antitrust Problem?, 7 COMPETITION POLICY INT’L 91, 100 (2011).
110 Peter firms have engaged in over the past decade. In particular, they have worried about the possibility that some of these transactions eliminated sources of potential or nascent competition. Many of these concerns have prompted calls for legal reform. Some commentators have argued that ex post adjudication is ill-equipped to grapple with competition issues in platform markets that have tipped in favor of a single dominant firm. Other critiques of the existing framework focus on specific doctrinal rules or the alleged shortcomings of the consumer-welfare standard—a general normative benchmark that has heavily influenced current law. For their part, defenders of antitrust adjudication have emphasized the differences between the Big Tech firms. This heterogeneity, they contend, counsels in favor of the fact-specific approach employed by current law and against categorical regulatory treatment. Supporters of the consumer-welfare standard argue that it provides a principled and coherent decision-making framework, in contrast to alternative regimes that would embrace more amorphous goals. While some reform proposals would adopt special competition regulations for large tech platforms, others would work within existing antitrust law by adjusting burdens of proof and changing certain doctrinal requirements. The regulatory route raises questions of policy design—namely, how to scope the relevant regulations and select an appropriate regulator to administer them. On the issue of scope, two general models have emerged. One would allow a regulator to designate covered platforms that offer specified services and meet certain quantitative and qualitative criteria. Designated firms would then be subject to the same set of special competition regulations. The other approach is more targeted and would apply special regulations to individual markets. With respect to the selection of a regulator, commentators have proposed giving new authorities to the DOJ and/or FTC, creating a new branch within either of those agencies, or establishing a standalone digital-platform regulator. As a substantive matter, proposals to reform the competition laws governing Big Tech firms fall into five categories: (1) ex ante conduct rules, (2) structural separation and line-of-business restrictions, (3) special merger rules, (4) interoperability and data-portability mandates, and (5) changes to general antitrust doctrine. Congressional Research Service link to page 6 link to page 6 link to page 7 link to page 7 link to page 8 link to page 14 link to page 14 link to page 15 link to page 17 link to page 19 link to page 20 link to page 20 link to page 21 link to page 22 link to page 23 link to page 25 link to page 28 link to page 30 link to page 30 link to page 31 link to page 34 link to page 34 link to page 35 link to page 37 link to page 38 link to page 39 link to page 39 link to page 41 link to page 44 link to page 44 link to page 49 link to page 49 link to page 50 link to page 50 link to page 50 link to page 54 link to page 55 link to page 56 link to page 56 link to page 57 link to page 57 link to page 59 link to page 59 link to page 62 link to page 63 link to page 65 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Contents Antitrust Law: The Basics ............................................................................................................... 2 Restraints of Trade .................................................................................................................... 2 Monopolization ......................................................................................................................... 3 Monopoly Power ................................................................................................................. 3 Exclusionary Conduct ......................................................................................................... 4 Mergers & Acquisitions .......................................................................................................... 10 Horizontal and Vertical Mergers ....................................................................................... 10 Conglomerate Mergers ....................................................................................................... 11 The Goals of Antitrust ............................................................................................................. 13 The Big Tech Firms: A Summary of Selected Antitrust Allegations ............................................. 15 Meta Platforms ........................................................................................................................ 16 Allegations of Market Power ............................................................................................ 16 Allegations of Anticompetitive Conduct........................................................................... 17 Google ..................................................................................................................................... 18 Online Search .................................................................................................................... 19 Mobile Operating Systems and App Distribution ............................................................. 21 Digital Advertising ............................................................................................................ 24 Amazon ................................................................................................................................... 26 Allegations of Market Power ............................................................................................ 26 Allegations of Anticompetitive Conduct........................................................................... 27 Apple ....................................................................................................................................... 30 Allegations of Market Power ............................................................................................ 30 Allegations of Anticompetitive Conduct........................................................................... 31 Big Tech Mergers and Acquisitions ........................................................................................ 33 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech: General Issues ............................................................................ 34 Is Existing Antitrust Law Insufficient? ................................................................................... 35 Market Structure and the Efficacy of Ex Post Adjudication ............................................. 35 Substantive Antitrust Doctrine .......................................................................................... 37 Scoping Reform Proposals ...................................................................................................... 40 The Designated-Platform Approach.................................................................................. 40 Market-Specific Regulation .............................................................................................. 45 Choice of Enforcers ................................................................................................................. 45 Reform Proposals .......................................................................................................................... 46 Ex Ante Conduct Rules ............................................................................................................ 46 Self-Preferencing / Non-Discrimination Rules ................................................................. 46 Tying ................................................................................................................................. 50 Interoperability and Data Access ...................................................................................... 51 Use of Nonpublic User Data ............................................................................................. 52 Most-Favored-Nation and Anti-Steering Policies ............................................................. 52 App Preinstallation............................................................................................................ 53 Structural Separation and Line-of-Business Restrictions ........................................................ 53 Mergers & Acquisitions .......................................................................................................... 55 Substantive Merger Law ................................................................................................... 55 The Merger Review Process ............................................................................................. 58 Interoperability & Data Portability ......................................................................................... 59 Changes to General Antitrust .................................................................................................. 61 Congressional Research Service link to page 66 link to page 67 link to page 69 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Exclusionary Conduct ....................................................................................................... 62 Mergers ............................................................................................................................. 63 Contacts Author Information ........................................................................................................................ 65 Congressional Research Service link to page 5 link to page 19 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms n 2012, a prominent scholar lamented the diminished significance of antitrust in the United States.1 Although there was once a flourishing antitrust movement, he argued, the subject appeared to attract little interest from lawmakers, academics, and the public.2 Political I candidates rarely mentioned competition issues, opinion polls reflected indifference toward economic concentration, and the enforcement agencies seemed to operate with a narrow understanding of antitrust’s scope.3 Since then, things have changed—dramatically. In the past several years, antitrust has resurfaced as an issue of both popular and political concern.4 The White House has issued an executive order outlining a “whole-of-government” approach to competition policy;5 advocates of reform have been appointed to lead the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and the Department of Justice’s (DOJ’s) Antitrust Division;6 and Congress has considered a suite of proposals to overhaul various aspects of antitrust doctrine.7 In the words of one commentator, antitrust now “stands at its most fluid and negotiable moment in a generation.”8 The subject has not had such political salience, another contends, since 1912.9 Interest in reform has been wide-ranging: “[e]verything is up for grabs, and nothing is free of scrutiny.”10 One of the driving forces behind this trend has been the rise of a handful of large technology firms: Facebook (now Meta Platforms), Google, Amazon, and Apple. In 2020, a House subcommittee released a detailed report (the HJC Report) concluding that the four companies had obtained and solidified dominant positions through anticompetitive conduct.11 These “Big Tech” firms have also faced antitrust lawsuits from regulators and private plaintiffs, both in the United States and abroad.12 This report provides an overview of antitrust issues involving the four Big Tech firms and related proposals for legislative reform. It is divided into four parts. First, the report provides an introduction to basic antitrust principles. Second, it reviews selected antitrust allegations against 1 Maurice E. Stucke, Reconsidering Antitrust’s Goals, 53 B.C. L. REV. 551, 553 (2012). 2 Id. at 553-56. 3 Id. 4 Daniel A. Crane, Antitrust’s Unconventional Politics, 104 VA. L. REV. ONLINE 118, 118-21 (2018). 5 Exec. Order No. 14,036, Promoting Competition in the American Economy, 86 Fed. Reg. 36,987, 36,989 (July 14, 2021). 6 Brent Kendall, Senate Confirms Jonathan Kanter as Justice Department Antitrust Chief, WALL ST. J. (Nov. 16, 2021), https://www.wsj.com/articles/senate-confirms-jonathan-kanter-as-justice-department-antitrust-chief-11637104400; David McCabe & Cecilia Kang, Biden Names Lina Khan, a Big-Tech Critic, as F.T.C. Chair, N.Y. TIMES (June 15, 2021), https://www.nytimes.com/2021/06/15/technology/lina-khan-ftc.html. 7 See, e.g., Prohibiting Anticompetitive Mergers Act of 2022, S. 3847, 117th Cong. (2022); Platform Competition and Opportunity Act, S. 3197, 117th Cong. (2021); American Innovation and Choice Online Act, S. 2992, 117th Cong. (2021); Trust-Busting for the Twenty-First Century Act, S. 1074, 117th Cong. (2021); Competition and Antitrust Law Enforcement Reform Act of 2021, S. 225, 117th Cong. (2021); Ending Platform Monopolies Act, H.R. 3825, 117th Cong. (2021). 8 Crane, supra note 4, at 118. 9 Carl Shapiro, Antitrust in a Time of Populism, 61 INT’L J. INDUS. ORG. 714, 715 (2018). 10 ALAN J. DEVLIN, REFORMING ANTITRUST 265 (2021). 11 INVESTIGATION OF COMPETITION IN DIGITAL MARKETS, MAJORITY STAFF REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS, SUBCOMM. ON ANTITRUST, COMMERCIAL AND ADMIN. L. OF THE H. COMM. ON THE JUDICIARY 12-17 (2020) [hereinafter “HJC REPORT”]. This report lists the Big Tech firms in the same order as the subcommittee’s report. 12 See infra “The Big Tech Firms: A Summary of Selected Antitrust Allegations.” Congressional Research Service 1 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms the Big Tech companies. Third, it discusses conceptual issues with proposals to reform the competition laws governing Big Tech. Fourth, the report analyzes the substance of specific categories of reform proposals. Antitrust Law: The Basics The antitrust laws aim to protect economic competition by prohibiting unreasonable restraints of trade,13 exclusionary conduct by dominant firms,14 and mergers and acquisitions that may “substantially” lessen competition or “tend to create a monopoly.”15 The following subsections provide a high-level overview of antitrust doctrine to lay the groundwork for later discussions of competition issues in tech markets and proposals for legal reform. Restraints of Trade Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits “every” contract or conspiracy “in restraint of trade.”16 Despite this categorical language, the Supreme Court has interpreted Section 1 to bar only unreasonable restraints of trade that harm competition.17 Applying this general standard, the Court has identified some types of agreements that are so likely to be anticompetitive that they are deemed per se illegal, meaning courts need not inquire into their effects in individual cases.18 Restraints in this category include agreements among competitors (“horizontal” agreements) to fix prices,19 divide markets,20 and restrain output.21 While some types of agreements are per se illegal under Section 1, most restraints are evaluated using a standard called the “rule of reason.”22 Under the rule of reason, courts conduct fact-specific assessments of a defendant’s market power and the details of a challenged agreement to determine a restraint’s competitive effects.23 This inquiry typically proceeds via a three-step burden-shifting framework. In that framework, the plaintiff has the initial burden to prove that the challenged restraint has a substantial anticompetitive effect.24 If the plaintiff does so, the burden shifts to the defendant to show a procompetitive justification for the restraint.25 If the defendant makes this showing, the burden 13 15 U.S.C. § 1. 14 Id. § 2. 15 Id. § 18. 16 Id. § 1. 17 Texaco Inc. v. Dagher, 547 U.S. 1, 5 (2006). 18 Id. 19 United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 218 (1940). 20 N. Pac. R.R. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5 (1958). 21 NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 100 (1984). 22 Ohio v. Am. Express Co. (Amex), 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2283-84 (2018). 23 Id. at 2284. The Supreme Court has explained that a firm has market power if it has the ability to price above competitive levels, Bd. of Regents, 468 U.S. at 109 n.38, or the power to constrain market output to raise prices, Fortner Enters. v. U.S. Steel Corp., 394 U.S. 495, 503 (1969). 24 Amex, 138 S. Ct. at 2284. 25 Id. Congressional Research Service 2 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms shifts back to the plaintiff to demonstrate that the relevant procompetitive benefits could be reasonably achieved through less anticompetitive means.26 Some courts have also added a fourth step in which they balance a restraint’s anticompetitive and procompetitive effects.27 Monopolization While Section 1 of the Sherman Act governs agreements between firms, Section 2 prohibits dominant companies from engaging in unilateral anticompetitive conduct. In the statutory parlance, Section 2 makes it unlawful to “monopolize” commerce.28 The monopolization offense has two elements: 1. the possession of monopoly power; and 2. “the willful acquisition or maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historical accident.”29 The second element is often referred to as “exclusionary” or “anticompetitive” conduct.30 Monopoly Power The Supreme Court has explained that a firm possesses monopoly power if it has the ability to “control prices or exclude competition.”31 Although that standard is similar to many descriptions of market power,32 the Court has clarified that monopoly power under Section 2 of the Sherman Act requires “something greater” than market power under Section 1.33 Lower courts have thus concluded that monopoly power entails a large degree of market power.34 Some courts have held that monopoly power can be established through direct evidence of supra-competitive prices and restricted output.35 However, this type of direct proof is rarely available.36 As a result, courts typically evaluate allegations of monopoly power by examining a 26 Id. 27 See, e.g., Bhan v. NME Hosps., Inc., 929 F.2d 1404, 1413 (9th Cir. 1991) (acknowledging a possible fourth step); see also Michael A. Carrier, The Rule of Reason: An Empirical Update for the 21st Century, 16 GEO. MASON L. REV. 827, 827 (2009) (concluding that courts reached a fourth “balancing” step in four percent of rule-of-reason cases decided between 1977 and 1999). The FTC and some lower courts have also employed an intermediate “quick look” framework to evaluate restraints that are similar to per se unlawful conduct but exhibit features warranting additional analysis. See Herbert Hovenkamp, The Rule of Reason, 70 FLA. L. REV. 81, 122-31 (2018) [hereinafter “Hovenkamp, The Rule of Reason”]. Different courts have described quick-look analysis in different ways, but the basic idea is that some types of restraints can be condemned without the full rule-of-reason inquiry. Id. at 122-23. 28 15 U.S.C. § 2. 29 United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966). 30 See, e.g., EINER ELHAUGE, UNITED STATES ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS 211 (3d ed. 2018). 31 United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 391 (1956). 32 See, e.g., Fortner Enters. v. U.S. Steel Corp., 394 U.S. 495, 503 (1969) (defining market power as “the ability of a single seller to raise price and restrict output”). 33 Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 481 (1992). 34 See, e.g., Bacchus Indus., Inc. v. Arvin Indus., Inc., 939 F.2d 887, 894 (10th Cir. 1991); Deauville Corp. v. Federated Dep’t Stores, Inc., 756 F.2d 1183, 1192 n.6 (5th Cir. 1985). 35 Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm Inc., 501 F.3d 297, 307 (3d Cir. 2007); PepsiCo, Inc. v. Coca-Cola Co., 315 F.3d 101, 107 (2d Cir. 2002) (per curiam); Conwood Co. v. U.S. Tobacco Co., 290 F.3d 768, 783 n.2 (6th Cir. 2002). 36 United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 51 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (per curiam). Congressional Research Service 3 link to page 7 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms market’s structure—in particular, whether a defendant occupies a dominant market share and is protected by entry barriers.37 These inquiries require a plaintiff to define the boundaries of the relevant product market—an exercise that turns on the range of items that are “reasonably interchangeable” with the product at issue.38 The key conceptual issue with market definition is whether buyer substitution to other items would limit a monopolist in an alleged market from raising prices significantly above competitive levels.39 If buyer substitution would constrain even a firm with a dominant share of an alleged market from raising prices significantly, the relevant legal test prescribes that the market must be expanded until buyer substitution of other items would not offer such a constraint.40 Courts have relied on a variety of factors in defining markets, including functional similarities and differences between separate items, cross-elasticities of demand (i.e., the extent to which the quantity demanded of one item changes in response to price changes for another item), price differences, price discrimination, and price trends.41 Once a market has been defined, courts usually look to a defendant’s share of that market to assess claims of monopoly power.42 The case law has not identified a definitive point at which monopoly power can be inferred, but courts typically require monopolization plaintiffs to prove that the defendant occupies a market share of 70 percent or more.43 To establish monopoly power, plaintiffs must also show that a defendant’s dominant position is likely to be durable—for example, with evidence of significant entry barriers.44 Entry barriers may include legal and regulatory requirements, control of an essential resource, entrenched buyer preferences, and economies of scale.45 In some digital markets, entry barriers may also emerge from network effects (whereby a product’s utility increases as it gains more users) and significant switching costs (high costs that users of a product would face in switching to a substitute).46 Exclusionary Conduct As noted, the second element of a monopolization claim is exclusionary conduct. The Supreme Court has described this element as involving “the willful acquisition or maintenance of [monopoly] power as distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historical accident.”47 37 Id. 38 United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 395 (1956). 39 ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 240. 40 Id. at 241. 41 MARKET POWER HANDBOOK: COMPETITION LAW AND ECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS, AM. BAR ASS’N 62-74 (2d ed. 2012). 42 See, e.g., U.S. Anchor Mfg., Inc. v. Rule Indus., Inc., 7 F.3d 986, 999 (11th Cir. 1993). 43 U.S. DEP’T OF JUST., COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY: SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT UNDER SECTION 2 OF THE SHERMAN ACT 21 (2008) (withdrawn May 11, 2009) [hereinafter “DOJ MONOPOLIZATION REPORT”] (collecting cases). 44 See, e.g., Lenox MacLaren Surgical Corp. v. Medtronic, Inc., 762 F.3d 1114, 1123-25 (10th Cir. 2014); W. Parcel Express v. United Parcel Serv. of Am., Inc., 190 F.3d 974, 975 (9th Cir. 1999). 45 Rebel Oil Co., Inc. v. Atlantic Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1439 (9th Cir. 1995). 46 FTC v. Facebook, Inc., 581 F. Supp. 3d 34, 51 (D.D.C. 2022). 47 United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966). Congressional Research Service 4 link to page 8 link to page 8 link to page 7 link to page 7 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms As a general standard, many have found that description unhelpful. Businesses often “willfully” try to obtain monopoly status by developing superior products and by deploying business acumen.48 The Court’s dichotomy thus offers little clarity on how to distinguish exclusionary conduct from legitimate competition on the merits. While academics have made several attempts to develop an alternative general standard,49 courts have not decisively embraced any of them.50 Instead, the doctrine contains a variety of tests that govern specific categories of conduct,51 along with a burden-shifting framework that is similar to the usual rule-of-reason inquiry in Section 1 cases.52 The following subsections review the standards governing particular types of conduct by dominant firms. Predatory Pricing Some monopolization cases involve allegations that a defendant aggressively cut prices in an attempt to exclude rivals from the market—a practice commonly known as predatory pricing.53 Under the Supreme Court’s Brooke Group test, plaintiffs must make two showings to prevail on a predatory-pricing claim.54 First, plaintiffs must show that the defendant’s prices fell below an appropriate measure of its costs.55 Second, plaintiffs must establish a “dangerous probability” that the defendant will recoup its investment in below-cost prices by raising prices upon the elimination of competitors.56 These requirements have proven difficult to satisfy. Since the Brooke Group decision, predatory-pricing claims have rarely made it past summary judgment.57 The Court has defended the restrictiveness of the relevant criteria by arguing that successful predatory pricing is rare and by emphasizing the need to avoid deterring procompetitive price cutting.58 Refusals to Deal Another category of potentially exclusionary conduct involves refusals to deal with rivals. For example, a dominant firm might control key infrastructure or technology that its competitors need 48 Many commentators have made this point. For one example, see Daniel Francis, Making Sense of Monopolization, 84 ANTITRUST L.J. 779, 779-80 (2022). 49 For an overview, see CHRISTOPHER SAGERS, ANTITRUST 205-08 (3d ed. 2021); DOJ MONOPOLIZATION REPORT, supra note 43, at 33-47. 50 DOJ MONOPOLIZATION REPORT, supra note 43, at 33. 51 Id. at 49-141; ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 277-355. 52 Viamedia, Inc. v. Comcast Corp., 951 F.3d 429, 463-64 (7th Cir. 2020); United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 58-59 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (per curiam). 53 ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 277. 54 Brooke Grp. Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 222-24 (1993). 55 Id. at 222. 56 Id. at 224. 57 Lina M. Khan, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox, 126 YALE L.J. 710, 730 & n.107 (2017) [hereinafter “Khan, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox”]. 58 Brooke Grp., 509 U.S. at 226. Congressional Research Service 5 link to page 9 link to page 7 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms to effectively compete, in which case a denial of access to the relevant property may harm competition.59 The Supreme Court has held that monopolists have a duty to deal with rivals only in a narrow set of circumstances. In Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., the Court affirmed Section 2 liability because the only plausible motivation for a monopolist’s refusal to deal was a desire to drive its competitor out of business.60 In that case, the defendant’s refusal was not motivated by efficiency concerns and instead represented a sacrifice of short-term profits to eliminate a rival.61 In its 2004 decision in Verizon Communications Inc. v. Trinko, however, the Court characterized its holding in Aspen Skiing as lying “at or near the outer boundary” of Section 2 liability.62 In rejecting a refusal-to-deal claim, Trinko distinguished Aspen Skiing on the grounds that the monopolist in the latter decision had terminated “a voluntary (and thus presumably profitable) course of dealing,” which suggested a willingness to sacrifice short-term profits for an anticompetitive end.63 The Court also emphasized that the monopolist in Aspen Skiing refused to deal with its rival even if compensated at the prices it charged to other customers, which “revealed a distinctly anticompetitive bent.”64 Based on these decisions, some lower courts have concluded that refusal-to-deal plaintiffs must establish that a defendant’s refusal entailed a sacrifice of short-term profits for an exclusionary purpose.65 Some courts have also required plaintiffs to establish this type of profit sacrifice with proof that the defendant terminated a voluntary course of dealing.66 Many circuit courts have also accepted a specific theory of refusal-to-deal liability called the “essential facilities” doctrine, which the Supreme Court has declined to either recognize or repudiate.67 To establish liability under the essential-facilities doctrine, plaintiffs must establish: 1. the control of an “essential facility” by a monopolist; 2. an inability to “practically or reasonably” duplicate the facility; 3. the denial of the use of the facility to a competitor; and 4. the feasibility of providing access to the facility.68 While that doctrine remains on the books as a formal matter,69 two commentators have described the Supreme Court’s treatment of it as inflicting “death by dicta.”70 Its viability thus remains uncertain. 59 SAGERS, supra note 49, at 219. 60 Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 608-11 (1985). 61 See id. 62 540 U.S. 398, 409 (2004). 63 Id. 64 Id. 65 E.g., Novell, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp., 731 F.3d 1064, 1075 (10th Cir. 2013) (Gorsuch, J.); Covad Commc’ns Co. v. Bell Atl. Corp., 398 F.3d 666, 675 (D.C. Cir. 2005); but see Viamedia Inc. v. Comcast Corp., 951 F.3d 429, 462 (7th Cir. 2020) (concluding that profit sacrifice is relevant but not always dispositive for refusal-to-deal liability). 66 E.g., Novell, 731 F.3d at 1075. 67 Trinko, 540 U.S. at 410-11. 68 MCI Commc’ns Corp. v. AT&T Co., 708 F.2d 1081, 1132-33 (7th Cir. 1983). 69 See ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 353 n.91 (collecting circuit court decisions recognizing the doctrine). 70 Brett Frischmann & Spencer Weber Waller, Revitalizing Essential Facilities, 75 ANTITRUST L.J. 1, 3 (2008); see also Congressional Research Service 6 link to page 9 link to page 10 link to page 7 link to page 10 link to page 7 link to page 11 link to page 7 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Tying Tying arrangements are vertical restraints of trade that can be challenged under several provisions of the antitrust laws, including Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act.71 Tying involves a refusal to sell one product (the tying product) unless buyers also purchase another product (the tied product) from the seller.72 The traditional concern with tying arrangements is that they may allow a firm with market power for the tying product to harm competition in and even monopolize the tied product market.73 Tying may also help a dominant firm preserve a monopoly in the tying market by eliminating potential rivals that may enter via the tied market.74 Possible redeeming efficiencies of tying include reputation protection and economies of production or distribution. For example, tying may dissuade consumers from using an inferior substitute to the tied product with the tying product, thereby mitigating the risk of reputational damage to a seller’s brand.75 Producing and selling different products together may also reduce production, marketing, and distribution costs.76 In addition, tying arrangements may encourage investment by allowing a firm to convert fixed costs into variable costs. For example, a franchisor might sell a franchise for less than its market value but employ a tying arrangement to secure overcharges on goods distributed through the franchise.77 This type of arrangement might encourage investment by decreasing a franchisee’s upfront costs.78 Contractual tying arrangements are governed by what is often called a rule of quasi-per-se illegality, though some have described that label as a misnomer.79 While different circuit courts HERBERT HOVENKAMP, FEDERAL ANTITRUST POLICY: THE LAW OF COMPETITION AND ITS PRACTICE 337 (4th ed. 2011) (concluding that “[n]ot many essential facility claims will survive” post-Trinko); Khan, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox, supra note 57, at 801 (noting that commentators have wondered whether the essential-facilities doctrine is now “a dead letter”). 71 HOVENKAMP, supra note 70, at 435. 72 ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 409. 73 CHIARA FUMAGALLI, MASSIMO MOTTA & CLAUDIO CALCAGNO, EXCLUSIONARY PRACTICES: THE ECONOMICS OF MONOPOLISATION AND ABUSE OF DOMINANCE 352 (2018). For a discussion of the Chicago School’s influential critique of this “leverage” theory of harm and responses to that critique, see id. at 363-99. 74 Id. at 386-88. For additional theories of harm involving tying, see HOVENKAMP, supra note 70, at 436. 75 ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 419. 76 FUMAGALLI, et al., supra note 73, at 353. 77 Erik Hovenkamp & Herbert J. Hovenkamp, Tying Arrangements and Antitrust Harm, 52 ARIZ. L. REV. 925, 964 (2010). 78 Id. Some commentators have argued that “variable proportion ties”—whereby consumers purchase a durable tying product (e.g., a printer) and amounts of the tied product (e.g., ink) that vary with their use of the tying product—may also increase welfare in certain circumstances. Id. at 951-52. Firms may use variable proportion ties to lower the price for the tying product while raising the price of the tied product, benefitting low-volume users and harming high-volume users. Id. Net welfare effects may thus depend on the number of consumers who would not have purchased the tying product absent the price reduction. Id. Some commentators have analogized certain conduct in tech markets to variable proportion ties. For example, some have argued that restrictions on app distribution may allow Apple to cut iPhone prices, meaning high-intensity app users effectively subsidize low-intensity users. Thomas A. Lambert, Addressing Big Tech’s Market Power: A Comparative Institutional Analysis, 75 SMU L. REV. 73, 104 & n.182 (2022). For an argument that variable proportion ties are typically welfare-reducing, see Einer Elhauge, Rehabilitating Jefferson Parish: Why Ties Without a Substantial Foreclosure Share Should Not Be Per Se Legal, 80 ANTITRUST L.J. 463, 476-86 (2016). 79 See, e.g., ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 420-21. Congressional Research Service 7 link to page 10 link to page 8 link to page 10 link to page 7 link to page 8 link to page 10 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms have adopted different formulations of the relevant legal test, many of the inquiries are similar.80 One commentator has summarized the doctrine as establishing the following requirements for a tying claim: 1. The defendant offered two distinct products; 2. The defendant conditioned the sale of one product (the tying product) on the purchase of the other product (the tied product); 3. The defendant possessed sufficient economic power in the tying product market to coerce purchasers into acceptance of the tied product; and 4. The defendant’s conduct affected a “not insubstantial” amount of interstate commerce in the tied product.81 Some courts have also required plaintiffs to demonstrate that a tying arrangement had anticompetitive effects in the tied product market.82 Although the above test governs most contractual tying arrangements, different standards have been applied to so-called technological ties, whereby a firm physically integrates separate products or designs its products in a way that makes them difficult to use with those offered by other firms.83 In its 2001 decision in United States v. Microsoft, for example, the D.C. Circuit held that a technological tie involving a computer operating system and a web browser was governed by the rule of reason, rather than the traditional rule of quasi-per-se illegality.84 Several other courts have taken a permissive approach to product-design decisions and accepted arguments that challenged technological ties represented procompetitive quality improvements.85 Exclusive Dealing Like tying, exclusive-dealing arrangements are vertical restraints that can be challenged under both Section 1 and Section 2 of the Sherman Act.86 Exclusive dealing occurs when a firm limits the freedom of buyers or sellers to deal with other companies.87 For example, a seller might offer widgets on the condition that purchasers obtain all of their widgets from the seller.88 80 HOVENKAMP, supra note 70, at 435 (explaining that “[i]n operation the tests are similar,” but that some courts have combined elements that other courts recognize as separate requirements). 81 Id. 82 E.g., Kaufman v. Time Warner, 836 F.3d 137, 141 (2d Cir. 2016); Amey, Inc. v. Gulf Abstract & Title Inc., 758 F.2d 1486, 1503 (11th Cir. 1985); Driskill v. Dallas Cowboys Football Club, Inc., 498 F.2d 321, 323 (5th Cir. 1974). 83 DOJ MONOPOLIZATION REPORT, supra note 43, at 33. 84 253 F.3d 34, 89-90 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (per curiam). 85 See John M. Newman, Anticompetitive Product Design in the New Economy, 39 FLA. ST. U. L. REV. 681, 714-23 (2012) (summarizing the case law). 86 HOVENKAMP, supra note 70, at 478. Exclusive-dealing agreements can also be challenged under Section 3 of the Clayton Act. 15 U.S.C. § 14. Some courts and commentators have suggested that analysis of such agreements may vary based on which provision is invoked. See, e.g., United States v. Dentsply Int’l, Inc., 399 F.3d 181, 197 (3d Cir. 2005) (concluding that findings in favor of the defendant under Section 1 of the Sherman Act and Section 3 of the Clayton Act did not preclude Section 2 liability for exclusive dealing); ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 371 n.1 (explaining that “some modern courts appear to treat Clayton Act § 3 claims more generously at the margins”). However, the precise differences between the relevant inquiries are not entirely clear. DOJ MONOPOLIZATION REPORT, supra note 43, at 132. 87 HOVENKAMP, supra note 70, at 478. 88 Id. Congressional Research Service 8 link to page 7 link to page 11 link to page 10 link to page 7 link to page 9 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms These types of restrictions may raise antitrust concerns if they foreclose enough of the market to deter entry or deny rivals the ability to achieve scale economies.89 Exclusive dealing may also raise rivals’ costs by limiting them to inferior inputs or distribution channels.90 Procompetitive justifications for exclusive dealing include the inducement of relationship-specific investments,91 mitigation of uncertainty about future sales,92 and the encouragement of more intense competition for distribution, which may result in lower consumer prices.93 In evaluating exclusive-dealing restrictions, courts ordinarily assess the extent of foreclosure, the duration of the restrictions, and any business justifications for the restrictions.94 Although there are exceptions, modern courts have tended to require foreclosure of roughly 40 percent of the market before condemning exclusive dealing.95 Monopoly Leveraging A firm’s possession of monopoly power has traditionally given rise to concerns that the firm may use that power to gain a competitive advantage in another market. For many years, the federal courts split over whether Section 2 precluded this type of “monopoly leveraging” in cases where a defendant utilized its monopoly power to harm competition in—but not reasonably threaten to monopolize—a second market. Elhauge, supra note 30, at 357-58 nn.97-98 (col ecting cases). In 2004, the Supreme Court rejected one type of leveraging claim, remarking that a lower court had erred to the extent that it dispensed with the requirement that a plaintiff relying on a leveraging theory establish that the defendant had a “dangerous probability” of monopolizing a second market. Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. L. Offs. of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 410 n.4 (2004) (citation omitted). The Court thus rejected the proposition that a defendant could violate Section 2 merely by gaining an unfair advantage in a second market. In its Microsoft decision, however, the D.C. Circuit endorsed what some commentators have called a “defensive leveraging” or “monopoly maintenance” theory. See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 67 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (per curiam); Robin Cooper Feldman, Defensive Leveraging in Antitrust, 87 GEO. L.J. 2079 (1999). While “offensive leveraging” involves a defendant’s use of monopoly power in one market to extract additional profits from another market, “defensive leveraging” involves the use of monopoly power to gain an advantage in another market so as to prevent erosion of a primary monopoly. See Feldman, Defensive Leveraging, 87 GEO. L.J. at 2080. In Microsoft, for example, the D.C. Circuit concluded that Microsoft had leveraged its operating-system monopoly into the market for web browsers so as to protect its operating-system monopoly. Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 64. Specifically, Microsoft imposed several restrictions related to its Windows operating system that were designed to reduce the usage of rival web browsers, which threatened to supplant Windows as platforms for software development. Id. at 60. The D.C. Circuit held that some of this conduct constituted unlawful monopolization. Id. at 64. Accordingly, under current monopolization law, an “offensive leveraging” theory requires proof that a defendant’s conduct raised a “dangerous probability” of monopolizing a second market; simply gaining an unfair advantage in another market is not sufficient. Trinko, 540 U.S. at 410 n.4. By contrast, “defensive leveraging”—whereby a monopolist’s leveraging of its monopoly power into a second market helps preserve its primary monopoly—may be a viable theory of harm, even without proof that the defendant threatens to monopolize the second market. See Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 64, 80-84. 89 FUMAGALLI, et al., supra note 73, at 239-62. 90 HOVENKAMP, supra note 70, at 479-80. 91 ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 375. 92 Id. at 374. 93 Benjamin Klein & Kevin M. Murphy, Exclusive Dealing Intensifies Competition for Distribution, 75 ANTITRUST L.J. 433 (2008). 94 Barry Wright Corp. v. ITT Grinnell Corp., 724 F.2d 227, 236 (1st Cir. 1983) (Breyer, J.). 95 SAGERS, supra note 49, at 173 (collecting cases). Congressional Research Service 9 link to page 7 link to page 9 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Mergers & Acquisitions The antitrust laws also place limitations on mergers and acquisitions.96 Section 7 of the Clayton Act prohibits mergers whose effect “may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly.”97 Though less common, Section 2 of the Sherman Act can also been used to challenge mergers that help a firm acquire or maintain monopoly power.98 Analysis of mergers varies based on the relationship between the merging parties—specifically, based on whether a merger is horizontal, vertical, or conglomerate. Horizontal and Vertical Mergers Like horizontal restraints of trade, horizontal mergers involve firms that compete in the same market.99 These types of deals raise two primary types of concerns. First, horizontal mergers may have unilateral anticompetitive effects—that is, they may allow the merged firm to raise prices and reduce output irrespective of the conduct of other firms.100 Second, horizontal mergers may produce coordinated anticompetitive effects by creating market structures that facilitate collusion or oligopoly pricing.101 In contrast, vertical mergers involve firms at different stages of the same chain of supply or distribution.102 These transactions receive less exacting scrutiny than horizontal mergers, because they do not eliminate direct competitors and often generate efficiencies.103 The primary concern with vertical mergers is the possibility that such transactions may foreclose sources of supply or distribution previously available to rivals.104 For example, a vertical merger might give the merged entity the incentive and ability to charge rivals higher prices for inputs or raise rivals’ costs of distribution.105 At the extreme, a merged firm may refuse to deal with rivals altogether. Without meaningful alternative sources of supply or distribution, the merged firm’s rivals may face competitive difficulties. Foreclosure may also raise entry barriers by requiring a firm’s prospective competitors to enter at two levels of the market rather than one.106 Vertical mergers may also raise concerns if they give a firm access to competitively sensitive information about rivals or facilitate collusion by allowing the merged entity to monitor compliance with tacit pricing agreements.107 96 For ease of discussion, this report will refer to both mergers and acquisitions as “mergers.” 97 15 U.S.C. § 18. 98 United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 576 (1966); Fraser v. Major League Soccer, LLC, 284 F.3d 47, 61 (1st Cir. 2002); BRFHH Shreveport, LLC v. Willis Knighton Med. Ctr., 176 F. Supp. 3d 606, 619 (W.D. La. 2016). 99 ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 705. 100 DEP’T OF JUST. & FED. TRADE COMM’N, HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES § 6 (2010) [hereinafter “HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES”]. 101 Id. § 7. 102 SAGERS, supra note 49, at 293. 103 DANIEL A. CRANE, ANTITRUST 164 (2014). 104 DEP’T OF JUST. & FED. TRADE COMM’N, VERTICAL MERGER GUIDELINES § 4 (2020) [hereinafter “VERTICAL MERGER GUIDELINES”]. 105 Id. 106 Id. 107 Id. §§ 4-5. Congressional Research Service 10 link to page 14 link to page 14 link to page 7 link to page 9 link to page 7 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms In litigation challenging horizontal and vertical mergers, the plaintiff bears the initial burden of establishing a prima facie case that a merger will substantially lessen competition in the relevant market.108 In horizontal-merger cases, plaintiffs can discharge this burden by establishing that a merger would lead to undue levels of market concentration.109 Vertical-merger doctrine does not offer plaintiffs a similar shortcut, because vertical mergers do not result in immediate changes in market share.110 Instead, plaintiffs challenging vertical mergers must make a fact-specific showing that a transaction is likely to be anticompetitive.111 While the case law on vertical mergers is thin, this prima facie case will often involve the concerns discussed above: foreclosure, raising rivals’ costs, and access to competitively sensitive information.112 If a merger plaintiff carries its initial burden, then the defendant must present evidence that the prima facie case inaccurately predicts the merger’s competitive effects or discredit the evidence underlying that case.113 For example, a defendant in a horizontal-merger case might argue that the plaintiff’s proposed market is poorly defined, that the entry of other firms will discipline its pricing power, or that the merger will create efficiencies that offset any anticompetitive effects.114 In a vertical-merger case, a defendant may contend that it lacks incentives to foreclose rivals, that rivals have adequate alternative sources of supply or distribution, or that the merger would produce efficiencies (e.g., by eliminating double marginalization).115 Upon rebuttal of a prima facie case, the burden of producing further evidence of anticompetitive harm shifts back to the plaintiff and merges with the burden of persuasion.116 Conglomerate Mergers Conglomerate mergers are mergers that are neither horizontal nor vertical.117 Challenges to such mergers are rare.118 One theory of harm in conglomerate cases, however, is particularly relevant to tech markets: the elimination of potential competition. Mergers between potential competitors can raise two types of concerns. First, if the perception that a potential competitor may enter a market constrains a firm’s pre-merger pricing behavior, then allowing the firm to acquire the potential competitor eliminates that constraint.119 In the 108 United States v. AT&T, Inc., 916 F.3d 1029, 1032 (D.C. Cir. 2019) (vertical merger); United States v. Baker Hughes, Inc., 908 F.2d 981, 982-83 (D.C. Cir. 1990) (horizontal merger). 109 See, e.g., FTC v. H.J. Heinz Co., 246 F.3d 708, 715 (D.C. Cir. 2001). 110 AT&T, 916 F.3d at 1032. 111 Id. 112 VERTICAL MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 104, at § 4. 113 United States v. Anthem, 855 F.3d 345, 349 (D.C. Cir. 2017). 114 Herbert J. Hovenkamp & Carl Shapiro, Horizontal Mergers, Market Structure, and Burdens of Proof, 127 YALE L.J. 1996, 1997 (2018). 115 VERTICAL MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 104, at §§ 4, 6. By allowing a downstream firm to access inputs at cost instead of paying a markup, vertical mergers may eliminate the “double marginalization” that occurs when two firms within a supply chain each mark-up their prices. Id. § 6. The elimination of double marginalization is a key procompetitive benefit that is often cited in defense of vertical mergers. See id. 116 Baker Hughes, 908 F.2d at 983. 117 ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 811. 118 Id. at 812; SAGERS, supra note 49, at 321. 119 ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 811. Congressional Research Service 11 link to page 9 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms doctrine, this concern is known as the elimination of “perceived potential competition.”120 Second, if a potential competitor actually would have entered the relevant market, then a merger would eliminate actual future competition, irrespective of whether the potential competitor constrained pre-merger behavior.121 This concern is called the elimination of “actual potential competition.”122 The Supreme Court has held that the elimination of perceived potential competition may render a merger unlawful, but has not expressly recognized the elimination of actual potential competition as a viable theory of harm.123 The Court has identified several requirements for a perceived-potential-competition claim. A plaintiff bringing such a claim must show that:  the relevant market is highly concentrated;  the potential competitor has the “characteristics, capabilities, and economic incentive to render it a perceived potential de novo entrant”; and  the potential competitor “in fact tempered oligopolistic behavior” by market participants.124 While the Court has declined to resolve the validity of the actual-potential-competition doctrine, it has explained that plaintiffs relying on that theory must establish that:  the relevant market is highly concentrated;  the potential competitor has “feasible means” of entry other than through the merger; and  the potential competitor’s entry offers a “substantial likelihood” of deconcentrating the market or producing other significant procompetitive effects.125 Lower courts have taken different approaches to actual-potential-competition claims. While the Eighth Circuit has accepted the theory,126 other courts have declined to resolve its viability.127 Lower courts are also divided on the evidentiary requirements in actual-potential-competition cases. Some courts require plaintiffs to show that an actual potential competitor “probably” would have entered the relevant market or use some variation of that language.128 Others have required a 120 Id. 121 Id. 122 Id. Arguably, the elimination of potential competition is a horizontal theory of harm, because it involves the claim that a potential competitor would likely enter the acquirer’s market or that the acquirer perceives the potential competitor as being likely to enter its market. SAGERS, supra note 49, at 321 n.45. As discussed above, however, challenges based on these theories are evaluated under different standards than challenges to other types of horizontal mergers. 123 United States v. Marine Bancorporation, Inc., 418 U.S. 602, 624-25 (1974). 124 Id. 125 Id. at 633. 126 Yamaha Motor Co. v. FTC, 657 F.2d 971, 977 (8th Cir. 1981). 127 Fraser v. Major League Soccer, LLC, 284 F.3d 47, 61 (1st Cir. 2002); Tenneco, Inc. v. FTC, 689 F.2d 346, 355 (2d Cir. 1982); FTC v. Atl. Richfield Co., 549 F.2d 289, 294 (4th Cir. 1977). 128 FTC v. Steris Corp., 133 F. Supp. 3d 962, 978 (N.D. Ohio 2015); see also Yamaha Motor, 657 F.2d at 977 (“probably”); Tenneco, 689 F.2d at 355 (“would likely”). Congressional Research Service 12 link to page 5 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms “reasonable probability” of entry129—a standard that one court has construed as more demanding than a mere “probability” or “more likely than not” test.130 Another court has demanded “clear proof” of entry but for the merger.131 Some courts have further required that the potential competitor be one of only a few potential entrants.132 The Goals of Antitrust As the above discussion makes clear, the text of the antitrust laws is very general. The operative phrases of the core statutes—“restraint of trade,” “monopolize,” and “substantially . . . lessen competition”—are generic and undefined. One commentator has observed that “[n]owhere else in the United States code are so few words used to regulate so much.”133 Many scholars also agree that the relevant legislative history offers little guidance as to the content of the key statutory prohibitions.134 The courts have responded to this indeterminacy by treating the antitrust laws as common-law statutes that vest the judiciary with broad powers to shape competition policy in response to new economic learning and conditions.135 In addition to giving judges the power to craft specific doctrinal rules, the flexibility of the antitrust laws leaves courts with a need to identify a normative benchmark to guide decision-making.136 The relevant lodestar has changed in the course of antitrust history. For much of the 20th century, courts interpreted the antitrust laws as serving various goals, including the dispersion of economic power, the protection of small businesses, the preservation of open markets and economic liberty, the elimination of concentrated political power, and the minimization of wealth transfers from consumers and producers to large firms.137 129 Mercantile Tex. Corp. v. Bd. of Govs. of the Fed. Res. Sys., 638 F.2d 1255, 1268-69 (5th Cir. 1981); United States v. Siemens Corp., 621 F.2d 499, 506 (2d Cir. 1980). 130 Mercantile Tex. Corp., 638 F.2d at 1268-69; see also Order Denying Plaintiff’s Motion for Preliminary Injunction at 41, FTC v. Meta Platforms Inc., No. 5:22-cv-04325 (N.D. Cal. Jan. 31, 2023) (adopting the “reasonable probability” standard, as clarified by the Fifth Circuit to mean “a likelihood noticeably greater than fifty percent”). 131 Atlantic Richfield Co., 549 F.2d at 300. 132 E.g., Mercantile Tex. Corp., 638 F.2d at 1267. 133 Herbert Hovenkamp, The Text of the Antitrust Laws 3 (U. Penn. Inst. for L. & Econ. Rsch. Paper No. 23-01, 2023), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4277914. 134 Daniel A. Crane, Antitrust Antitextualism, 96 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 1205, 1206 n.2 (2021); see also United States v. Tans-Mo. Freight Ass’n, 166 U.S. 290, 318 (1897) (“Looking simply at the history of the [Sherman] bill from the time it was introduced in the senate until it was finally passed, it would be impossible to say what were the views of a majority of the members of each house in relation to the meaning of the act. . . . All that can be determined from the debates and reports is that various members had various views, and we are left to determine the meaning of this act, as we determine the meaning of other acts, from the language used therein.”). 135 See, e.g., Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 899 (2007) (“From the beginning the Court has treated the Sherman Act as a common-law statute. . . . Just as the common law adapts to modern understanding and greater experience, so too does the Sherman Act’s prohibition on ‘restraint[s] of trade’ evolve to meet the dynamics of present economic conditions.”) (brackets in original); Nat’l Soc’y of Pro. Eng’rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 688 (1978) (explaining that Congress “expected the courts to give shape to [the Sherman Act’s] broad mandate by drawing on common-law tradition”). 136 See, e.g., ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF 50 (1978) (“[A]ntitrust policy cannot be made rational until we are able to give a firm answer to one question: What is the point of the law—what are its goals? Everything else follows from the answer we give. . . . Only when the issue of goals has been settled is it possible to frame a coherent body of substantive antitrust rules.”); Stucke, supra note 1, at 557 (making a similar point). 137 See, e.g., Stucke, supra note 1, at 560-62; Eleanor M. Fox, Modernization of Antitrust: A New Equilibrium, 66 Congressional Research Service 13 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms In a 1945 monopolization case, for example, Judge Learned Hand remarked that “great industrial consolidations are inherently undesirable, regardless of their economic results,” noting that one of the purposes of the Sherman Act was to “put an end to great aggregations of capital because of the helplessness of the individual before them.”138 The Supreme Court embraced similar views during the relevant period. In a 1962 merger decision, it explained that the Clayton Act was intended “to promote competition through the protection of viable, small, locally owned business,” even if “occasional higher costs and prices might result from the maintenance of fragmented industries and markets.”139 Applying these principles, mid-century courts condemned a wide range of practices as per se Sherman Act violations,140 took a skeptical approach to vertical integration,141 and blocked horizontal mergers that would be unlikely to draw the attention of regulators today.142 In the 1970s and 1980s, things began to change. During that time, courts abandoned small business protectionism and the socio-political effects of concentrated economic power as salient considerations in antitrust decision-making.143 In place of the mid-century “multiple goals” approach, the concept of consumer welfare came to occupy a central place in antitrust doctrine,144 though its precise meaning and accuracy as a descriptive principle remain contested.145 CORNELL L. REV. 1140, 1182 (1981). 138 United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416, 428 (2d Cir. 1945). 139 Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 344 (1962). 140 E.g., United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596 (1972) (joint venture involving territorial restraints); Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145 (1968) (maximum resale price maintenance); United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365 (1967) (vertical territorial restraints). 141 E.g., Brown Shoe Co., 370 U.S. at 332-34. 142 E.g., United States v. Von’s Grocery Co., 384 U.S. 270 (1966) (blocking a merger that would have resulted in the merged firm occupying a 7.5 percent market share in an unconcentrated market). 143 See, e.g., Joshua D. Wright & Douglas H. Ginsburg, The Goals of Antitrust: Welfare Trumps Choice, 81 FORDHAM L. REV. 2405, 2405-06 (2013). 144 Since the 1970s, the Supreme Court has repeatedly described the antitrust laws as being principally concerned with the protection of consumers. See NCAA v. Alston, 141 S. Ct. 2141, 2151 (2021); Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2284 (2018); Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 886 (2007); Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., 549 U.S. 312, 324 (2007); Brooke Grp. Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 224 (1993); Jefferson Par. Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 15 (1984); NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 107 (1984); Reiter v. Sonotone Corp., 442 U.S. 330, 343 (1979); see also John B. Kirkwood & Robert H. Lande, The Fundamental Goal of Antitrust: Protecting Consumers, Not Increasing Efficiency, 84 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 191, 219-24 (2008) (collecting lower court cases embracing the consumer-welfare standard); ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMM’N, REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS 35 (Apr. 2007) (“For the last few decades courts, agencies, and antitrust practitioners have recognized consumer welfare as the unifying goal of antitrust law.”). 145 There are several issues here. First, Robert Bork used the term “consumer welfare” to refer to a total-welfare standard that allows producer gains to offset consumer losses, while many commentators instead use the term “consumer welfare” to mean consumer surplus. See, e.g., Barak Y. Orbach, The Antitrust Consumer Welfare Paradox, 7 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 133, 142-49 (2010). Both versions of the “consumer welfare” standard have supporters. See Roger D. Blair & D. Daniel Sokol, Welfare Standards in U.S. and E.U. Antitrust Enforcement, 81 FORDHAM L. REV. 2497 (2013) (favoring a total-welfare standard); Steven C. Salop, Question: What Is the Real and Proper Antitrust Welfare Standard? Answer: The True Consumer Welfare Standard, 22 LOY. CONSUMER L. REV. 336 (2010) (favoring a consumer-surplus standard). Second, the extent to which the consumer-welfare standard recognizes harms that sellers suffer from anticompetitive conduct remains the subject of ongoing discussion. See, e.g., Herbert J. Hovenkamp, Is Antitrust’s Consumer Welfare Principle Imperiled?, 45 J. CORP. L. 101, 113-15 (2019); C. Scott Hemphill & Nancy L. Rose, Mergers That Harm Sellers, 127 YALE L.J. 2078 (2018). Third, some commentators have argued that the consumer-welfare standard does not represent an accurate description of current antitrust doctrine for other reasons. Congressional Research Service 14 link to page 5 link to page 14 link to page 9 link to page 9 link to page 41 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Since the consumer-welfare revolution, courts have pared back some of the more interventionist elements of mid-century antitrust. For example, the Supreme Court has overturned several decisions establishing per se Section 1 liability for certain categories of conduct146 and established restrictive standards for various types of monopolization claims.147 In a similar vein, lower courts and the antitrust agencies have de-emphasized structural merger analysis in favor of more detailed inquiries into the competitive effects of individual transactions.148 These shifts have generated controversy.149 The chair of the FTC and the Assistant Attorney General for the DOJ’s Antitrust Division have both criticized the consumer-welfare standard and advocated replacing it with a focus on the “competitive process.”150 In academic work, the FTC’s chair has specifically emphasized the consumer-welfare standard’s alleged shortcomings with respect to large technology platforms.151 Other commentators have criticized several applications of the consumer-welfare standard as unduly permissive, but have defended the standard itself.152 These issues are discussed in greater detail later in this report.153 The Big Tech Firms: A Summary of Selected Antitrust Allegations The Big Tech firms have achieved tremendous financial success. As of the publication of this report, the combined market capitalization of Meta, Alphabet (Google’s parent), Amazon, and Apple is more than $5 trillion—a figure that exceeds the value of most national equity markets.154 E.g., Gregory J. Werden, Antitrust’s Rule of Reason: Only Competition Matters, 79 ANTITRUST L.J. 713, 713, 743 (2014) (arguing that “the rule of reason focuses solely on how a challenged restraint affects the competitive process,” and that antitrust protects consumer welfare by protecting the “competitive process”); see also DEVLIN, supra note 10, at 254-68 (contending that the consumer-welfare standard is descriptively inaccurate in several respects). 146 Leegin, 551 U.S. 877 (minimum resale price maintenance); State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3 (1997) (maximum resale price maintenance); Cont’l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977) (vertical territorial restraints). 147 Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc’ns, Inc., 555 U.S. 438 (2009) (price squeezes); Weyerhaeuser, 549 U.S. 312 (predatory buying); Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. L. Offs. of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004) (refusals to deal); Brooke Grp., 509 U.S. 209 (predatory pricing). 148 See, e.g., United States v. Baker Hughes, Inc., 908 F.2d 981 (D.C. Cir. 1990); HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 100, at § 5.3. 149 For a collection of essays—many of them critical—on various aspects of these changes in antitrust theory and doctrine, see HOW THE CHICAGO SCHOOL OVERSHOT THE MARK: THE EFFECT OF CONSERVATIVE ECONOMIC ANALYSIS ON U.S. ANTITRUST (Robert Pitofsky ed. 2008). For a sympathetic account, see Elyse Dorsey, et al., Consumer Welfare & the Rule of Law: The Case Against the New Populist Antitrust Movement, 47 PEPPERDINE L. REV. 861 (2020). 150 Khan, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox, supra note 57, at 744-46; Assistant Att’y Gen. Jonathan Kanter Delivers Remarks at New York City Bar Association’s Milton Handler Lecture (May 18, 2022), https://www.justice.gov/opa/speech/assistant-attorney-general-jonathan-kanter-delivers-remarks-new-york-city-bar-association. 151 Khan, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox, supra note 57, at 716-17. 152 See, e.g., The Consumer Welfare Standard in Antitrust: Outdated or a Harbor in a Sea of Doubt?: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Competition & Consumer Rights of the S. Comm. on the Judiciary, (2017) (testimony of Diana Moss, President, Am. Antitrust Inst.), https://www.judiciary.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/12-13-17%20Moss%20Testimony.pdf [hereinafter “Moss Testimony”]; id. (statement of Carl Shapiro, Professor, Haas School of Business at Univ. of Cal. at Berkeley), https://www.judiciary.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/12-13-17%20Shapiro%20Testimony.pdf [hereinafter “Shapiro Testimony”]. 153 See infra “Substantive Antitrust Doctrine.” 154 See Largest Companies by Market Cap, COMPANIESMARKETCAP (last visited Mar. 15, 2023), https://companiesmarketcap.com/; Largest Stock Exchange Operators Worldwide as of October 2022, By Market Congressional Research Service 15 link to page 5 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms While some have emphasized the quality of the firms’ offerings as the primary driver of their ascent,155 others have alleged that Big Tech has obtained and cemented monopoly power through anticompetitive conduct.156 This section of the report reviews selected antitrust allegations against the Big Tech firms. Meta Platforms Meta describes itself as a company that builds technology that “helps people connect, find communities, and grow businesses.”157 More specifically, Meta offers a “family of apps” related to social networking and messaging.158 This family of apps consists of:  Facebook (a social network);  Instagram (a photo-sharing platform);  Messenger (a messaging app for Facebook users); and  WhatsApp (a messaging app).159 In October 2022, Meta reported that Facebook had 1.98 billion daily active users and 2.96 billion monthly active users.160 The company’s family of apps reportedly features 2.93 billion daily active people and 3.71 billion monthly active people.161 Allegations of Market Power Some observers have argued that Meta possesses significant market power in the market for social networking.162 The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) shares that view. In an ongoing monopolization lawsuit, the Commission has alleged that Meta has held monopoly power in the market for “personal social networking services” (PSNS) since at least 2011.163 To support such Capitalization of Listed Companies, STATISTA (Jan. 2023), https://www.statista.com/statistics/270126/largest-stock-exchange-operators-by-market-capitalization-of-listed-companies/; Market Capitalization of Listed Domestic Companies, THE WORLD BANK (last visited Mar. 15, 2023), https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/CM.MKT.LCAP.CD. 155 E.g., Investigation into the State of Competition in Digital Markets, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial, & Admin. L. of H. Comm. on the Judiciary (May 11, 2020) (statement of Randal C. Picker, James Parker Distinguished Service Prof. of Law, The Univ. of Chi. L. Sch. at 34), https://picker.uchicago.edu/PickerHouseStatement.100.pdf. 156 E.g., HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 12-17. 157 Meta Platforms, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10-K) at 7 (Feb. 3, 2022). 158 Id. Meta also produces augmented and virtual reality products via its Reality Labs division. See Eric Rosenbaum, Why Reality Labs Will Keep Spending Billions Even as Meta Makes the Biggest Cuts in Its History, CNBC (Nov. 17, 2022), https://www.cnbc.com/2022/11/17/why-reality-labs-will-keep-losing-billions-even-as-meta-makes-big-cuts.html. 159 Meta Platforms, Inc., Annual Report at 7. 160 Meta Platforms, Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10-Q) at 33 (Oct. 27, 2022). 161 Id. 162 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 133; ONLINE PLATFORMS AND DIGITAL ADVERTISING: MARKET STUDY FINAL REPORT, U.K. COMPETITION & MKTS AUTHORITY 146 (July 1, 2020), https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/media/5fa557668fa8f5788db46efc/Final_report_Digital_ALT_TEXT.pdf [hereinafter “CMA REPORT”]; Fiona M. Scott Morton & David C. Dinielli, Roadmap for an Antitrust Case Against Facebook, OMIDYAR NETWORK 11-15 (June 2020), https://www.omidyar.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/06/Roadmap-for-an-Antitrust-Case-Against-Facebook.pdf; DIGITAL PLATFORMS INQUIRY: FINAL REPORT, AUSTRALIAN COMPETITION & CONSUMER COMM’N 9 (June 2019), https://www.accc.gov.au/system/files/Digital%20platforms%20inquiry%20-%20final%20report.pdf [hereinafter “ACCC REPORT”]. 163 Substitute Amended Complaint for Injunctive and Other Equitable Relief ¶ 164, FTC v. Facebook, Inc., No. Congressional Research Service 16 link to page 5 link to page 20 link to page 20 link to page 21 link to page 21 link to page 5 link to page 5 link to page 20 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms claims, Meta’s critics have argued that the firm has persistently maintained a large market share and benefited from substantial entry barriers, including powerful network effects and high switching costs.164 Others disagree. Meta has argued that it operates in a “dynamic, intensely competitive” industry in which there are many substitutes for its services.165 In its litigation with the FTC, the firm has criticized the Commission’s alleged PSNS market as unduly narrow insofar as it excludes rivals like YouTube, TikTok, LinkedIn, and Twitter.166 Meta and some commentators have also rejected the notion that entry barriers have caused the market to decisively tip in Meta’s favor.167 For example, observers have highlighted the ability of differentiated firms like TikTok and Snapchat to rapidly gain scale despite Meta’s ostensible network advantages.168 Allegations of Anticompetitive Conduct In addition to facing allegations of monopoly power, Meta has been accused of engaging in anticompetitive conduct. The FTC’s lawsuit contends that Meta has maintained its dominant position through its 2012 acquisition of Instagram and its 2014 acquisition of WhatsApp.169 The Commission argues that Meta’s Instagram purchase allowed it to neutralize a rapidly growing competitive threat, giving the firm control over what became two of the most popular social networks in the world.170 Similarly, the FTC contends that Meta’s acquisition of WhatsApp preserved its monopoly by preventing WhatsApp from entering the PSNS market.171 Besides targeting Meta’s major acquisitions, the FTC and some commentators have criticized the company’s treatment of software developers.172 These allegations involve access to Facebook Platform—an initiative whereby Meta encouraged developers to create apps that interoperate with Facebook.173 As part of this initiative, Meta provided software developers with application programming interfaces (APIs) and other tools that allowed them to access certain Facebook data 1:20-cv-03590 (D.D.C. Sept. 8, 2021). 164 Id. ¶ 212; HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 136-47; Scott Morton & Dinielli, supra note 162, at 11; ACCC REPORT, supra note 162, at 58. The FTC and some commentators have also attempted to establish that Meta has monopoly power with direct evidence, arguing that the firm has degraded the quality of its products without losing significant numbers of users. Substitute Amended Complaint ¶¶ 205-09, FTC v. Facebook, Inc., No. 1:20-cv-03590 (D.D.C. Sept. 8, 2021); Dina Srinivasan, The Antitrust Case Against Facebook: A Monopolist’s Journey Towards Pervasive Surveillance in Spite of Consumer’s Preference for Privacy, 16 BERKELEY BUS. L.J. 39 (2019). 165 Memorandum in Support of Facebook, Inc.’s Motion to Dismiss FTC’s Complaint at 11, FTC v. Facebook, Inc., No. 1:20-cv-03590 (D.D.C. Mar. 10, 2021). 166 Memorandum in Support of Facebook, Inc.’s Motion to Dismiss FTC’s Complaint at 10, FTC v. Facebook, Inc., No. 1:20-cv-03590 (D.D.C. Oct. 4, 2021). 167 Id. at 13-16; Herbert J. Hovenkamp, Selling Antitrust, 73 HASTINGS L.J. 1621, 1623 (2022) [hereinafter “Hovenkamp, Selling Antitrust”]; Jay Ezrielev & Genaro Marquez, Interoperability: The Wrong Prescription for Platform Competition, COMPETITION POLICY INT’L ANTITRUST CHRON. 8, 13-14 (June 2021). 168 Hovenkamp, Selling Antitrust, supra note 167, at 1623; Ezrielev & Marquez, supra note 167, at 8. 169 Substitute Amended Complaint ¶¶ 77-129, FTC v. Facebook, Inc., No. 1:20-cv-03590 (D.D.C. Sept. 8, 2021); see also HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 150-60 (arguing that Meta’s Instagram and WhatsApp acquisitions harmed competition). 170 Substitute Amended Complaint ¶¶ 80-106, FTC v. Facebook, Inc., No. 1:20-cv-03590 (D.D.C. Sept. 8, 2021). 171 Id. ¶¶ 107-29. 172 Id. ¶¶ 130-163; HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 166-70; Scott Morton & Dinielli, supra note 162, at 24-25. 173 Substitute Amended Complaint ¶¶ 25-42, FTC v. Facebook, Inc., No. 1:20-cv-03590 (D.D.C. Sept. 8, 2021). Congressional Research Service 17 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms and functionalities.174 According to the FTC, Facebook Platform ultimately became key infrastructure for app developers because of Facebook’s large user base.175 The Commission’s lawsuit alleges that Meta used its control over this key infrastructure to preserve its social networking monopoly. In particular, the FTC claims that Meta required developers that participated in Facebook Platform to refrain from creating apps that would compete with Facebook products.176 In doing so, Meta allegedly suppressed potential competitive threats.177 Meta has denied engaging in anticompetitive conduct. The company has argued that its Instagram acquisition was procompetitive because the transaction allowed Meta to invest significant resources and expertise in developing Instagram, thereby hastening the small firm’s growth.178 Meta has also defended its WhatsApp purchase, arguing that the FTC has failed to present evidence that WhatsApp would have likely entered social networking absent the acquisition.179 Finally, Meta has argued that its policies governing access to Facebook Platform—which it has since revised—were lawful under duty-to-deal doctrine.180 As of the publication of this report, the FTC’s monopolization case against Meta is in discovery, a pre-trial stage of litigation in which the parties develop evidence that can be used at trial. Although the district court rejected the agency’s initial complaint for failing to plausibly allege monopoly power,181 the court ultimately allowed the case to proceed after concluding that the Commission’s amended complaint was sufficiently plausible to survive a motion to dismiss.182 Google Google is a ubiquitous presence in the digital economy. The firm began as an internet search company, and is now also a major player in digital advertising, mobile operating systems, app distribution, digital maps, email, and web browsing.183 The following subsections discuss antitrust allegations involving Google’s conduct related to online search, mobile operating systems and app distribution, and digital advertising. 174 Id. 175 Id. ¶ 131. 176 Id. ¶ 133. 177 Id. ¶ 134. 178 Memorandum in Support of Facebook, Inc.’s Motion to Dismiss FTC’s Complaint at 29-30, FTC v. Facebook, Inc., No. 1:20-cv-03590 (D.D.C. Oct. 4, 2021). 179 Id. at 24. 180 Id. at 35. 181 FTC v. Facebook, Inc., 560 F. Supp. 3d 1, 4 (D.D.C. 2021). 182 FTC v. Facebook, Inc., 581 F. Supp. 3d 34, 43-52 (D.D.C. 2022). While the district court has allowed the FTC’s challenge to Meta’s Instagram and WhatsApp acquisitions to proceed, it has rejected the agency’s claims involving access to Facebook Platform. Id. at 57-59. In rejecting the latter claims, the court concluded that Meta had no general duty to allow potential rivals to access Facebook Platform. Id. at 58-59. Although the court indicated that specific refusals may be actionable, it held that the refusals alleged by the FTC could not justify injunctive relief because they occurred in 2013 and were not ongoing. Id. 183 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 174. Congressional Research Service 18 link to page 20 link to page 5 link to page 20 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Online Search Allegations of Market Power Some commentators have argued that Google has significant market power in the market for general online search.184 The DOJ agrees. In a pending monopolization lawsuit, the DOJ contends that Google has monopoly power in the market for “general search services” based on an alleged market share of 88 percent and the presence of substantial entry barriers, including economies of scale.185 For its part, Google has claimed that it operates in a “highly competitive environment” and faces a “vast array of competitors.”186 The company also argues that, for particular search queries, it competes against a range of firms—such as Amazon, eBay, and Yelp—that would not fall within a market for general search services.187 Allegations of Anticompetitive Conduct Search Distribution The DOJ’s monopolization lawsuit contends that Google has maintained its search monopoly through various exclusionary agreements with firms that control search distribution.188 In particular, the DOJ alleges that Google pays mobile device manufacturers, wireless carriers, and browser developers to secure default status for its general search engine.189 Additionally, the company—which also controls the Android mobile operating system—allegedly conditions the availability of some “must-have” Google apps and APIs for Android devices on manufacturers’ agreements to preinstall certain apps that use Google Search as their default search engine.190 Through such agreements and its control of the Chrome browser, the DOJ argues, Google “effectively owns or controls search distribution channels accounting for roughly 80 percent of general search queries in the United States.”191 By locking up these distribution channels, Google has allegedly prevented rivals from gaining the scale necessary to serve as effective competitors.192 184 CMA REPORT, supra note 162, at 73; HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 176-82; ACCC REPORT, supra note 162, at 58; Google Search (Shopping) (Case AT.39740), Commission Decision ¶ 271 (June 27, 2017), https://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/dec_docs/39740/39740_14996_3.pdf [hereinafter “EC Google Shopping Decision”]. 185 Amended Complaint ¶¶ 92-96, United States v. Google LLC, No. 1:20-cv-03010 (D.D.C. Jan. 15, 2021). 186 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 179. 187 Id. 188 Amended Complaint ¶ 4, United States v. Google LLC, No. 1:20-cv-03010 (D.D.C. Jan. 15, 2021). A group of state attorneys general has also brought a similar monopolization case challenging Google’s conduct in search markets. Complaint, State of Colorado, et al. v. Google, LLC, No. 1:20-cv-03715 (D.D.C. Dec. 17, 2020). 189 Amended Complaint ¶ 4, United States v. Google LLC, No. 1:20-cv-03010 (D.D.C. Jan. 15, 2021). 190 Id. ¶¶ 72-77. 191 Id. ¶ 5. 192 Id. ¶ 8. In July 2018, the European Commission fined Google €4.34 billion for requiring device manufacturers to pre-install the Google Search app and Chrome browser as a condition of licensing the Google Play app store; paying device manufacturers and mobile network operators to exclusively pre-install the Google Search app on their devices; and preventing device manufacturers that pre-install certain Google apps from selling devices that run versions of Android that Google had not approved. See Press Release, Euro. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Fines Google €4.34 Billion for Illegal Practices Regarding Android Mobile Devices to Strengthen Dominance of Google’s Search Engine Congressional Research Service 19 link to page 5 link to page 23 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Google has denied the DOJ’s allegations. The company argues that its agreements with browser developers do not preclude developers from integrating or promoting other search engines.193 Google also contends that, even if the agreements required exclusivity, they are the result of lawful, customer-instigated “competition for the contract” that the firm has won because of the superiority of its search engine.194 Similarly, Google has argued that its agreements with mobile device manufacturers and wireless carriers do not preclude its counterparties from preinstalling rival apps.195 The company also claims that the agreements would not result in substantial foreclosure of search distribution channels even if they did require exclusivity.196 As of the publication of this report, Google’s motion for summary judgment is pending before the district court.197 Self-Preferencing Commentators and some foreign regulators have also argued that Google has leveraged its dominance in general search to favor its own vertical offerings. For example, the HJC Report concluded that Google has adjusted its search algorithms to automatically elevate some of Google’s vertical services, like its video-sharing platform YouTube, in search results.198 This type of self-preferencing prompted the European Commission—which enforces European Union competition law—to fine Google €2.42 billion in 2017 for giving prominent placement to its comparison-shopping service and demoting rival services in search results.199 The FTC investigated similar allegations of self-preferencing involving Google Search in 2012, but concluded that it had not found sufficient evidence of an antitrust violation.200 The agency determined that Google’s favorable placement of its own verticals could plausibly be viewed as an improvement in the quality of Google’s search product.201 The Commission also did not find sufficient evidence that Google had manipulated its search algorithms to unfairly disadvantage rival vertical websites.202 (July 18, 2018), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IP_18_4581 [hereinafter “EC Android Case”]. 193 Defendant’s Memorandum of Points and Authorities in Support of its Motion for Summary Judgment at 28-31, United States v. Google LLC, No. 1:20-cv-03010 (D.D.C. Jan. 11, 2023). 194 Id. at 35-38. 195 Id. at 39-40. 196 Id. at 40-41. 197 Dave Simpson, Google Seeks Win in Default Search Engine Antitrust Suits, LAW360 (Jan. 11, 2023), https://www.law360.com/articles/1564958. 198 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 187-92. 199 EC Google Shopping Decision, supra note 184. 200 Statement of the Federal Trade Commission Regarding Google’s Search Practices, In the Matter of Google Inc., No. 111-0163 (FTC Jan. 3, 2013). 201 Id. at 3. 202 Id. Congressional Research Service 20 link to page 5 link to page 5 link to page 23 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Mobile Operating Systems and App Distribution Allegations of Market Power Mobile Operating Systems In addition to operating a major search engine, Google controls Android—a leading mobile operating system. Android and Apple’s iOS represent the two dominant mobile operating systems, together accounting for 99 percent of the market.203 Because Apple does not license iOS to other device manufacturers, Android by itself occupies a very large share of the market for licensable mobile operating systems—by some estimates, 99 percent of that market.204 Some commentators have argued that the market for licensable mobile operating systems is the relevant one for antitrust purposes, based on factors like high switching costs.205 Private plaintiffs and (in a separate case) a group of state attorneys general have argued that Google has monopoly power in this market based on the company’s dominant market share and the presence of substantial entry barriers, such as network effects and research and development costs.206 Google denies such allegations, arguing that consumers “can and do switch and multi-home among and between mobile and nonmobile ecosystems, including between Android and iOS.”207 Mobile App Distribution Litigants have also contended that, through its Google Play Store, Google has market power in certain markets related to mobile-app distribution. Some plaintiffs have defined the relevant antitrust market as consisting of the distribution of apps to Android users.208 They allege that Google has monopoly power in this market based on the Play Store’s market share of more than 90 percent, strong network effects, high switching costs, and Google’s ability to charge a 30 percent commission on apps purchased through the Play Store.209 Some plaintiffs have also argued in the alternative that Google has market power in a broader market for mobile app distribution—that is, a market not limited to Android users.210 A group of 203 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 100-02. 204 First Amended Complaint ¶ 7, State of Utah et al. v. Google LLC, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 1, 2021); see also Second Amended Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶¶ 16, 55, Epic Games, Inc. v. Google LLC, No. 3:20-cv-05671 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 17, 2022) (alleging a market share of “over 95%”). 205 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 102. In a 2018 enforcement action, the European Commission concluded that competition from Apple does not sufficiently constrain Google for similar reasons. EC Android Case, supra note 192. 206 Second Amended Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶¶ 55-64, Epic Games, Inc. v. Google LLC, No. 3:20-cv-05671 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 17, 2022); First Amended Complaint ¶¶ 44-58, State of Utah et al. v. Google LLC, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 1, 2021). 207 Defendants’ Answers and Defenses to State of Utah et al. First Amended Complaint ¶ 55-56, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 15, 2021); see also Defendants’ Answer, Defenses, and Counterclaims to Epic Games, Inc.’s Second Amended Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶¶ 55, 57, No. 3:20-cv-05671 (N.D. Cal. Dec. 1, 2022). 208 Second Amended Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶¶ 68-72, Epic Games, Inc. v. Google LLC, No. 3:20-cv-05671 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 17, 2022); First Amended Complaint ¶¶ 63-73, State of Utah et al. v. Google LLC, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 1, 2021). 209 Second Amended Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶¶ 75-88, Epic Games, Inc. v. Google LLC, No. 3:20-cv-05671 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 17, 2022); First Amended Complaint ¶¶ 76-78, State of Utah et al. v. Google LLC, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 1, 2021). 210 Second Amended Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶ 73, Epic Games, Inc. v. Google LLC, No. 3:20-cv-05671 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 17, 2022); First Amended Complaint ¶¶ 79-81, State of Utah et al. v. Google LLC, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 1, 2021). Congressional Research Service 21 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms state attorneys general, for example, has argued that Google occupies a sizeable share of this market, enjoys large profit margins, and benefits from formidable entry barriers.211 Google rejects these claims. It contends that consumers can use different platforms to access apps and that “Apple and Google compete vigorously in the mobile operating system environment on multiple dimensions, including innovation, price, privacy, and security.”212 In-App Payment Processing Plaintiffs have further claimed that Google has monopoly power in a market for in-app payment (IAP) processing for Android apps.213 They have based this claim on the Google Play Store’s large share of the market for Android app distribution and Google’s requirement that software developers using the Play Store also use Google’s IAP processor.214 As discussed, for many transactions, Google charges a 30 percent commission for IAP processing—a rate that is considerably higher than those charged by other electronic payment processors.215 Google has denied possessing monopoly power related to IAP processing.216 Allegations of Anticompetitive Conduct Mobile App Distribution Google has also been accused of engaging in a variety of anticompetitive activities involving app distribution. First, Google has allegedly imposed technical barriers that make it difficult for consumers to download Android apps from sources other than the Google Play Store—a practice commonly known as “sideloading.”217 In particular, litigants have claimed that sideloading Android apps 211 First Amended Complaint ¶¶ 79-81, State of Utah et al. v. Google LLC, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 1, 2021). The state attorneys general allege that Google’s share of this market in the United States exceeds 30 percent, while its share of the global market (excluding China) is approximately 53 percent by revenue. Id. ¶ 80. 212 Defendants’ Answers, Defenses, and Counterclaims to Epic Games, Inc.’s Second Amended Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶ 80, No. 3:20-cv-05671 (N.D. Cal. Dec. 1, 2022). 213 Second Amended Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶¶ 158-60, Epic Games, Inc. v. Google LLC, No. 3:20-cv-05671 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 17, 2022); First Amended Complaint ¶¶ 182-86, State of Utah et al. v. Google LLC, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 1, 2021). 214 Second Amended Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶¶ 158-60, Epic Games, Inc. v. Google LLC, No. 3:20-cv-05671 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 17, 2022); First Amended Complaint ¶¶ 182-86, State of Utah et al. v. Google LLC, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 1, 2021). 215 Second Amended Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶ 160, Epic Games, Inc. v. Google LLC, No. 3:20-cv-05671 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 17, 2022). In March 2021, Google announced plans to lower its commissions from 30 percent to 15 percent for the first $1 million in revenue that developers earn using Google’s billing system. Manish Singh, Google Play Drops Commissions to 15% from 30%, Following Apple’s Move Last Year, TECHCRUNCH (Mar. 16, 2021), https://techcrunch.com/2021/03/16/google-play-drops-commissions-to-15-from-30-following-apples-move-last-year/. 216 Defendants’ Answers, Defenses, and Counterclaims to Epic Games, Inc.’s Second Amended Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶ 158, No. 3:20-cv-05671 (N.D. Cal. Dec. 1, 2022); Defendants’ Answers and Defenses to State of Utah et al. First Amended Complaint ¶ 182, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 15, 2021). 217 First Amended Complaint ¶¶ 83-95, State of Utah et al. v. Google LLC, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 1, 2021). Congressional Research Service 22 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms entails a complicated process that includes several security warnings discouraging such actions.218 Google has also been accused of making it unnecessarily difficult to update sideloaded apps.219 Second, Google has allegedly barred software developers from distributing competing app stores through the Google Play Store.220 Third, Google has allegedly required mobile device manufacturers that license Android and certain other key Google services to preinstall the Google Play Store on their devices.221 Plaintiffs have argued that this preinstallation requirement harms competition by giving the Play Store an advantage over other app stores.222 Fourth, Google has allegedly required device manufacturers that offer the Google Play Store and other “must-have” Google services to refrain from selling devices that run “Android forks”—modified versions of Android that Google has not approved.223 Plaintiffs argue that these restrictions have stifled the development of alternative versions of Android that would be free from some of the restrictions on app distribution discussed above.224 Fifth, Google has allegedly entered into revenue-sharing agreements that deter device manufacturers from developing competing app stores.225 In particular, the challenged agreements give device manufacturers a share of Google’s advertising and Play Store revenue from the devices they sell in exchange for a commitment to refrain from competing against the Play Store.226 Google has either denied engaging in the relevant conduct or rejected the contention that such conduct is anticompetitive.227 In-App Payment Processing Plaintiffs have also accused Google of engaging in anticompetitive conduct in the market for Android IAP processing. They have alleged that Google’s requirement that developers using the Play Store also use Google’s IAP processor represents an unlawful tying arrangement.228 218 Id. 219 Id. ¶ 96. 220 Id. ¶¶ 107-10. 221 Id. ¶¶ 124-25. 222 Id. ¶ 125. 223 Id. ¶¶ 105-06. 224 Id. 225 Id. ¶¶ 130-35. 226 Id. 227 Defendants’ Answers and Defenses to State of Utah et al. First Amended Complaint ¶¶ 83-89, 96, 105-110, 124-25, 130-35, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 15, 2021). 228 Second Amended Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶¶ 161-66, Epic Games, Inc. v. Google LLC, No. 3:20-cv-05671 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 17, 2022); First Amended Complaint ¶¶ 162-67, State of Utah et al. v. Google LLC, No. 3:21-cv-05227 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 1, 2021). Congressional Research Service 23 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Digital Advertising Allegations of Market Power In addition to its search and app-distribution activities, Google is a major force in digital display advertising markets. In those markets, online ad publishers—like news websites—sell advertising space through exchanges.229 Those ad exchanges conduct automated auctions in which advertisers can bid for ad space.230 Intermediaries facilitate this process for both publishers and advertisers. Large publishers manage their ad inventory using a type of software known as an ad server, which interfaces with ad exchanges on behalf of publishers.231 On the other side of the market, advertisers employ ad-buying tools, which connect them with ad exchanges and allow them to purchase ad space.232 Google operates in several segments of these markets via an ad exchange, a publisher ad server, and ad-buying tools for advertisers.233 The DOJ and (in a separate lawsuit) a group of state attorneys general (state AGs) have argued that Google has monopoly power in multiple ad-tech markets. In January 2023, the DOJ filed a complaint alleging that Google has monopoly power in the markets for publisher ad servers,234 ad exchanges,235 and advertiser ad networks.236 In a separate case, a group of state AGs has alleged that Google has monopoly power in the markets for ad exchanges, ad servers, and ad-buying tools for small advertisers.237 The state AGs also contend that Google has monopoly power or a dangerous probability of acquiring monopoly power in the market for ad-buying tools for large advertisers.238 In September 2022, a federal district court concluded that the state AGs’ allegations involving monopoly power were sufficiently plausible to survive a motion to dismiss.239 229 Opinion and Order at 3, In re Google Digital Advertising Antitrust Litigation, No. 21-md-3010 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 13, 2022). 230 Id. 231 Id. at 4. 232 Id. at 10-11. 233 Id. at 6-12. 234 Complaint ¶ 285, United States v. Google LLC, No. 1:23-cv-00108 (E.D. Va. Jan. 24, 2023). 235 Id. ¶ 296. 236 Id. ¶ 301. 237 Opinion and Order at 7-8, 11, In re Google Digital Advertising Antitrust Litigation, No. 21-md-3010 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 13, 2022). 238 Id. at 11. 239 Id. at 19, 34-35. Google has denied possessing monopoly power in the ad-exchange market, but its motion to dismiss did not challenge the other allegations of monopoly power. Id. at 5-6. In response to the DOJ’s lawsuit, Google published a blog post in which it argued that competition in online ad markets is “increasing,” citing the growing ad businesses of Microsoft, Amazon, Apple, TikTok, and several specialized ad-tech companies. Dan Taylor, DOJ’s Lawsuit Ignores the Enormous Competition in the Online Advertising Industry, GOOGLE (Jan. 24, 2023), https://blog.google/outreach-initiatives/public-policy/doj-ad-tech-lawsuit-response/. Congressional Research Service 24 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Allegations of Anticompetitive Conduct The DOJ and state AG lawsuits contend that Google has engaged in a range of anticompetitive practices in several digital-advertising markets, allowing it to obtain and cement a dominant position across the ad-tech stack. The DOJ’s lawsuit claims that, in the early 2000s, Google’s ad-buying tools occupied a dominant position on the advertiser side of the ad-tech market.240 Then, in 2008, Google acquired a firm called DoubleClick, which operated a leading publisher ad server and a nascent ad exchange.241 After the DoubleClick acquisition, the DOJ contends, Google leveraged its position across the ad-tech chain to benefit its own properties. Among other things, the DOJ alleges that Google made demand from its ad-buying tools available only through its ad exchange.242 Google also allegedly required publishers to use its ad server to receive real-time bids from its ad exchange.243 The state AG ad-tech lawsuit makes similar allegations.244 In September 2022, a federal district court held that the state AGs had plausibly alleged tying claims under Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act based on their assertion that Google had coerced publishers into using its ad server as a condition of receiving live bids from its ad exchange.245 The DOJ and state AG lawsuits also target a program used by Google’s ad server that allegedly gave Google’s ad exchange advantages over rival exchanges.246 Another set of accusations involves programs under which Google allegedly manipulated bids from its advertiser clients in ways that advantaged its ad exchange and publisher ad server.247 The September 2022 district court decision in the state AG lawsuit concluded that the allegations of anticompetitive harm from these activities were sufficiently plausible to survive a motion to dismiss.248 The Google ad-tech lawsuits are complex and a full discussion of the relevant claims is beyond the scope of this report. Most of the allegations nevertheless implicate a recurring theme in 240 Complaint ¶¶ 11-13, United States v. Google LLC, No. 1:23-cv-00108 (E.D. Va. Jan. 24, 2023). 241 Id. ¶ 16. The FTC declined to challenge Google’s DoubleClick acquisition at the time. Press Release, Fed. Trade Comn’n, Federal Trade Commission Closes Google/DoubleClick Investigation (Dec. 20, 2007), https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/news/press-releases/2007/12/federal-trade-commission-closes-googledoubleclick-investigation. 242 Complaint ¶ 89, United States v. Google LLC, No. 1:23-cv-00108 (E.D. Va. Jan. 24, 2023). 243 Id. ¶ 104. According to the DOJ’s complaint, publishers could use Google’s ad exchange without using its ad server by selling ad space based on historical—rather than real-time—prices. Id. The DOJ contends, however, that this was not an attractive option because the resulting prices were often considerably lower than those received from real-time bids. Id. 244 Opinion and Order at 18, In re Google Digital Advertising Antitrust Litigation, No. 21-md-3010 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 13, 2022). 245 Id. at 16-20, 77-78. 246 Complaint ¶¶ 21, 120-25, United States v. Google LLC, No. 1:23-cv-00108 (E.D. Va. Jan. 24, 2023); Opinion and Order at 44-50, In re Google Digital Advertising Antitrust Litigation, No. 21-md-3010 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 13, 2022). 247 Complaint ¶¶ 24, 139, 161-62, United States v. Google LLC, No. 1:23-cv-00108 (E.D. Va. Jan. 24, 2023); Opinion and Order at 50-55, In re Google Digital Advertising Antitrust Litigation, No. 21-md-3010 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 13, 2022). 248 Opinion and Order at 44-55, In re Google Digital Advertising Antitrust Litigation, No. 21-md-3010 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 13, 2022). Congressional Research Service 25 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms discussions of antitrust and Big Tech firms: the leveraging of economic power to obtain and solidify dominance across different markets.249 Google maintains that its conduct is permissible under antitrust doctrine governing refusals to deal, product design, and tying.250 Amazon Like Google, Amazon has expanded its remit over time. The company began as an online bookseller, but now operates a leading e-commerce marketplace, a major cloud-computing platform, a logistics network, and a television and film studio.251 The discussion below focuses principally on the company’s e-commerce activities. Allegations of Market Power The HJC Report concluded that Amazon “has significant and durable market power in the U.S. online retail market.”252 While the report acknowledged a wide range of estimates of Amazon’s share of that market, it determined that estimates “at about 50% or higher are more credible than lower estimates of 30-40%.”253 The report also characterized Amazon as the “dominant online marketplace,” noting that the firm reportedly controls “about 65% to 70% of all U.S. online marketplace sales.”254 Based on interviews and other material, the report concluded that Amazon has monopoly power over “most” third-party sellers on its e-commerce marketplace and “many” of its suppliers, in addition to significant market power over consumers.255 Such power is unlikely to erode, the report argued, because of network effects, switching costs, and the difficulty that rivals would face in developing a comparable logistics network.256 The Attorney General for the District of Columbia (D.C. AG) made similar allegations in a 2021 lawsuit brought under District of Columbia law.257 The D.C. AG lawsuit claimed that Amazon had monopoly power among online marketplaces based on an alleged market share of 50%-70%, the company’s ability to dictate certain terms to third-party sellers, and entry barriers like network effects, data advantages, and extensive logistics capabilities.258 249 See generally Patrick F. Todd, Digital Platforms and the Leverage Problem, 98 NEB. L. REV. 486 (2019). 250 Reply Memorandum of Law in Further Support of Google LLC’s Motion to Dismiss Counts I through IV of State Plaintiffs’ Third Amended Complaint at 16-30, In re Google Digital Advertising Antitrust Litigation, No. 21-md-3010 (S.D.N.Y. May 5, 2022). 251 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 247. 252 Id. at 254. 253 Id. 254 Id. at 255. 255 Id. at 257, 259. 256 Id. at 260. 257 First Amended Complaint, District of Columbia v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2021-CA-001775 (D.C. Super. Ct. Sept. 10, 2021). 258 Id. ¶¶ 85-86. During an investigation that began in November 2020, the European Commission preliminarily concluded that Amazon occupied a dominant position in certain European markets for the provision of online marketplace services to third-party sellers. Press Release, Euro. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Accepts Commitments by Amazon Barring it From Using Marketplace Seller Data, and Ensuring Equal Access to Buy Box and Prime (Dec. 20, 2022), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/ip_22_7777 [hereinafter “Amazon EC Congressional Research Service 26 link to page 5 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Amazon rejected those allegations, arguing that it competes in a broader market that includes physical retail stores.259 In 2022, the Superior Court of the District of Columbia dismissed the D.C. AG lawsuit on several grounds, including a failure to plausibly allege monopoly power.260 The D.C. AG has appealed that decision.261 Allegations of Anticompetitive Conduct Most-Favored-Nation and Pricing-Parity Clauses The D.C. AG lawsuit discussed above focused on most-favored-nation and pricing-parity clauses in Amazon’s agreements with third-party sellers that use its e-commerce marketplace.262 One iteration of these provisions—which Amazon has discontinued—prohibited third-party sellers from offering their products elsewhere online at prices lower than those the sellers offered on Amazon.263 Under a later version of the relevant policy, Amazon indicated that it may remove or decline to feature products that third-party sellers offered on Amazon at prices significantly higher than those the sellers recently charged in any venue.264 The D.C. AG argued that the latter policy was “effectively identical” to the earlier pricing-parity provision because—in practice—Amazon continued to penalize third-party sellers for any offers undercutting the sellers’ prices on Amazon.265 The HJC Report reached similar conclusions about the relevant policies and contended that they harmed competition among e-commerce marketplaces.266 In 2022, the Superior Court of the District of Columbia dismissed the D.C. AG’s allegations. The court reasoned that the newer Amazon policy did not prohibit third-party sellers from offering lower prices in other venues; that any broader implementation of the policy was not attributable to the agreements themselves; and that the D.C. AG had not plausibly alleged monopoly power, Commitments”]. 259 Defendant Amazon.com, Inc.’s Opposed Motion to Dismiss Plaintiff District of Columbia’s Amended Complaint at 15-16, District of Columbia v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2021-CA-001775 (D.C. Super. Ct. Oct. 25, 2021); see also HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 255 (noting Amazon’s argument that its share of the total retail market is “the most appropriate and relevant” method of estimating its market share). 260 Order at 15-16, District of Columbia v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2021-CA-001775 (D.C. Super. Ct. Aug. 1, 2022). 261 Notice of Appeal, District of Columbia v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2021-CA-001775 (D.C. Super. Ct. Aug. 25, 2022). 262 First Amended Complaint ¶¶ 5-10, District of Columbia v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2021-CA-001775 (D.C. Super. Ct. Sept. 10, 2021). The Attorney General of California has filed a similar lawsuit under California unfair-competition law. See Complaint, The People of the State of California v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. CGC-22-601826 (Cal. Super. Ct. Sept. 15, 2022). For a discussion of the antitrust issues raised by most-favored-nation clauses in online platform markets, see Jonathan B. Baker & Fiona Scott Morton, Antitrust Enforcement Against Platform MFNs, 127 YALE L.J. 2176 (2018). 263 First Amended Complaint ¶¶ 5-8, District of Columbia v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2021-CA-001775 (D.C. Super. Ct. Sept. 10, 2021). 264 Order at 8, District of Columbia v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2021-CA-001775 (D.C. Super. Ct. Aug. 1, 2022). 265 First Amended Complaint ¶ 9, District of Columbia v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2021-CA-001775 (D.C. Super. Ct. Sept. 10, 2021); see also Order at 8-9, District of Columbia v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2021-CA-001775 (D.C. Super. Ct. Aug. 1, 2022). 266 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 295-97. Congressional Research Service 27 link to page 5 link to page 30 link to page 5 link to page 30 link to page 5 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms meaning it could not prevail on a claim alleging unilateral anticompetitive conduct.267 As discussed, the D.C. AG has appealed the Superior Court’s decision.268 Tying The HJC Report and some foreign competition authorities have also taken issue with the link between Amazon’s e-commerce marketplace and its logistics service, Fulfillment by Amazon (FBA).269 According to the report, Amazon effectively requires third-party sellers to use FBA as a condition of participating in Amazon Prime—a subscription service that offers customers fast shipping of eligible products, among other benefits.270 Many third-party sellers also reported their belief that Amazon favors sellers who use FBA in its product search results and in managing its “Buy Box”—the program that determines which sellers “win” particular product sales.271 As a result of these practices, the report contends, many third-party sellers regard use of FBA as essential to success on Amazon’s marketplace.272 Amazon has responded that it provides non-discriminatory access to the Buy Box and that participation in FBA is voluntary.273 Use of Third-Party Seller Data Amazon’s dual role as both a marketplace operator and a seller on its own marketplace has also attracted scrutiny. Critics have contended that this integration generates conflicts of interest, which have led Amazon to leverage control of its marketplace to advantage its own products and services in various ways.274 Some of these allegations involve Amazon’s use of data. The HJC Report and European regulators have accused Amazon of using data generated by third-party sellers on its marketplace to identify and imitate popular products for its private-label business.275 267 Order at 8-9, 15-16, District of Columbia v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2021-CA-001775 (D.C. Super. Ct. Aug. 1, 2022). The D.C. AG lawsuit also included allegations regarding Amazon’s contracts with suppliers, which are not discussed here. 268 Notice of Appeal, District of Columbia v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2021-CA-001775 (D.C. Super. Ct. Aug. 25, 2022). 269 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 287-90; Amazon EC Commitments, supra note 258; Adam Satariano, Amazon is Fined $1.3 Billion in Italy Over Antitrust Violations, N.Y. TIMES (Dec. 9, 2021), https://www.nytimes.com/2021/12/09/business/amazon-italy-fine.html. 270 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 287. While there is a way third-party sellers can become eligible for Prime without using FBA, the HJC Report characterized that option as “entirely impractical” for “most sellers.” Id. 271 Id. at 288-90. 272 Id. at 287-88. 273 Id. at 292. In 2022, the European Commission accepted certain commitments from Amazon to resolve similar concerns. See Amazon EC Commitments, supra note 258. Among other things, Amazon agreed to treat all sellers equally in managing its Buy Box and to allow third-party sellers that participate in Prime to freely choose their logistics and delivery services. Id. 274 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 16; see also Lina M. Khan, The Separation of Platforms and Commerce, 119 COLUM. L. REV. 973, 985-94 (2019) [hereinafter “Khan, Platforms and Commerce”]. 275 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 274-82; Press Release, Euro. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Sends Statement of Objections to Amazon for the Use of Non-Public Independent Seller Data and Opens Second Investigation into its E-Commerce Business Practices (Nov. 10, 2020), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/ip_20_2077. Congressional Research Service 28 link to page 5 link to page 30 link to page 9 link to page 56 link to page 5 link to page 9 link to page 5 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms During congressional testimony in July 2020, Amazon’s founder and former chief executive said that the company has a policy against using seller-specific data to aid its private-label business.276 He indicated, however, that he could not guarantee that this policy had never been violated.277 Amazon reportedly does not have a policy against using aggregated seller data to assist its retail business.278 Commentators have disputed the competitive effects of a platform’s use of user data to enter new markets. Some commentators have argued that Amazon’s entry into new markets forces other sellers to lower their prices—an outcome that antitrust traditionally encourages.279 Others contend that the alleged copying may have longer-term anticompetitive effects by chilling incentives to innovate.280 Self-Preferencing Amazon’s dual role as a marketplace operator and private-label seller has led to a range of other concerns about self-preferencing. For example, a 2016 ProPublica investigation concluded that Amazon designed the ranking algorithm for its marketplace to favor its own offerings and products offered by sellers that use FBA.281 The HJC Report also alleged that Amazon has engaged in other forms of self-preferencing, such as refusing to allow certain competitors to advertise on Amazon’s platform.282 Predatory Pricing Amazon has also been accused of engaging in predatory pricing at various points in its history.283 These allegations have been directed against several aspects of Amazon’s business, including its sale of e-books;284 its sale of diapers and ultimate acquisition of the parent company of Diapers.com;285 and Amazon Prime.286 276 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 277-78. 277 Id. 278 Id. at 278. The European Commission has investigated similar issues. In 2020, the Commission preliminarily concluded that Amazon had relied on aggregated data generated by third-party sellers to support its own retail offerings. See Amazon EC Commitments, supra note 258. In December 2022, the Commission accepted Amazon’s commitment not to use non-public data derived from third-party sellers to assist its private-label business. See id. 279 See, e.g., Francis, supra note 48, at 832; Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust and Platform Monopoly, 130 YALE L.J. 1952, 2015 (2021) [hereinafter “Hovenkamp, Platform Monopoly”]. 280 ARIEL EZRACHI & MAURICE E. STUCKE, HOW BIG-TECH BARONS SMASH INNOVATION—AND HOW TO STRIKE BACK 54-57 (2022). These issues are discussed in greater detail in infra “Use of Nonpublic User Data.” 281 Julia Angwin & Surya Mattu, Amazon Says It Puts Customers First. But Its Pricing Algorithm Doesn’t, PROPUBLICA (Sept. 20, 2016), https://www.propublica.org/article/amazon-says-it-puts-customers-first-but-its-pricing-algorithm-doesnt. 282 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 283-86. 283 See, e.g., Shaoul Sussman, Prime Predator: Amazon and the Rationale of Below Average Variable Cost Pricing Strategies Among Negative-Cash Flow Firms, 7 J. ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 203 (2019). 284 Khan, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox, supra note 57, at 756-68. 285 Id. at 768-74; HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 297-99. 286 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 299-300. Congressional Research Service 29 link to page 9 link to page 34 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms In academic work, the chair of the FTC has argued that Amazon exemplifies the rationality of predatory pricing in markets characterized by strong network effects and extreme scale economies, contrary to the assumptions that underpin current doctrine.287 Other commentators have challenged these allegations.288 In response to the claims involving Diapers.com, for example, some have noted that Amazon has not been accused of occupying a monopolistic share of the market for online diaper sales or diaper sales generally.289 Others have argued that the HJC report failed to produce sufficient evidence to conclude that Amazon prices Prime memberships below cost.290 Apple Apple is the most valuable company in the world.291 The firm designs, manufactures, and sells iPhone smartphones, Mac personal computers, iPad tablets, and several wearables and accessories, in addition to offering a range of related services.292 The discussion below focuses on issues related to the company’s mobile operating system and App Store. Allegations of Market Power As discussed, Apple’s iOS and Google’s Android are the two dominant operating systems for mobile devices in the United States and globally.293 More than half of the mobile devices in the United States run a version or derivation of iOS.294 Apple’s App Store is the only method by which software developers can distribute apps on iOS devices; Apple does not allow iOS users to download other app stores or sideload apps.295 Based on these restrictions, Apple’s market share, and various entry barriers, the HJC Report concluded that Apple has significant and durable market power in markets for mobile operating systems and mobile app stores.296 The report also alleged that Apple has monopoly power over app distribution on iOS devices.297 Epic Games—the developer of the video game Fortnite—has made similar claims in litigation, arguing that Apple has monopoly power in an iOS app distribution market and a market for iOS in-app payment (IAP) processing.298 (Like Google, Apple requires developers to use its IAP 287 Khan, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox, supra note 57, at 753, 786, 791-92. 288 Kristian Stout & Alec Stapp, Is Amazon Guilty of Predatory Pricing?, TRUTH ON THE MARKET (May 7, 2019), https://truthonthemarket.com/2019/05/07/is-amazon-guilty-of-predatory-pricing/; Jeffrey Eisenach, Who Should Antitrust Protect? The Case of Diapers.com, AM. ENTER. INST. (Nov. 5, 2018), https://www.aei.org/technology-and-innovation/who-should-antitrust-protect-the-case-of-diapers-com/. 289 Eisenach, supra note 288. 290 Carl Shapiro, Regulating Big Tech: Factual Foundations and Policy Goals, NETWORK L. REV. (forthcoming Fall 2023), https://www.networklawreview.org/shapiro-big-tech/. 291 Largest Companies by Market Cap, COMPANIESMARKETCAP (last visited Mar. 15, 2023), https://companiesmarketcap.com/. 292 Apple Inc., Annual Report (Form 10-K) at 1-2 (Oct. 28, 2022). 293 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 100-02. 294 Id. at 334. 295 Id. at 335. 296 Id. at 334. 297 Id. at 335. 298 Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶¶ 58, 119, Epic Games, Inc. v. Apple Inc., No. 4:20-cv-05640 (N.D. Cal. Aug. 13, Congressional Research Service 30 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms processor as a condition of accessing its App Store and has charged 30 percent commissions for that service.)299 Apple has denied possessing monopoly power. With respect to software distribution, the company argues that it competes in a market that includes other app stores, the open internet, and physical retail stores.300 In the Epic Games litigation involving video-game distribution, Apple has contended that the relevant antitrust market is a market for video game distribution generally, which includes other app stores, gaming stores for personal computers, gaming stores on game consoles, and cloud-based game streaming services.301 In September 2021, a federal district court concluded in Epic Games that Apple competes in a market for digital mobile gaming transactions, as opposed to a broader market for video-game distribution generally or a narrower market for game distribution on iOS devices.302 The court further determined that Apple possesses market power—but not monopoly power—in this market.303 Epic Games has appealed this decision.304 Allegations of Anticompetitive Conduct Mobile App Distribution and IAP Processing Apple has been accused of engaging in several anticompetitive practices in app markets. One set of allegations focuses on various technical and contractual restrictions that prevent developers from distributing iOS apps outside of the App Store, which allegedly harms competition in markets for app distribution.305 Epic Games has also argued that the requirement that developers using Apple’s App Store also use Apple’s IAP processor constitutes an unlawful tying arrangement.306 A federal district court has rejected these claims. In Epic Games, the court held that the relevant contractual restrictions on app distribution qualified as unilateral rather than concerted conduct.307 Because the court had determined that Apple was not a monopolist, it rejected the plaintiff’s claims involving those restrictions.308 While the court concluded that the challenged restrictions were unilateral and thus not illegal absent monopoly power, it acknowledged certain doctrinal ambiguities involving the distinction 2020). 299 Epic Games, Inc. v. Apple Inc., 559 F. Supp. 3d 898, 923 (N.D. Cal. 2021). In November 2020, Apple reduced its IAP processing fees from 30 percent to 15 percent for developers with less than $1 million in annual net sales on its platform. Kif Leswing, Apple Will Cut App Store Commissions by Half to 15% for Small App Makers, CNBC (Nov. 18, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/11/18/apple-will-cut-app-store-fees-by-half-to-15percent-for-small-developers.html. 300 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 335. 301 Epic Games, Inc., 559 F. Supp. 3d at 972-76. 302 Id. at 921. 303 Id. at 922. 304 Notice of Appeal, Epic Games, Inc. v. Apple Inc., No. 4:20-cv-05640 (N.D. Cal. Sept. 12, 2021). 305 Complaint for Injunctive Relief ¶¶ 64-81, 87-102, Epic Games, Inc. v. Apple Inc., No. 4:20-cv-05640 (N.D. Cal. Aug. 13, 2020). 306 Id. ¶ 129. 307 Epic Games, Inc. v. Apple Inc., 559 F. Supp. 3d 898, 1035 (N.D. Cal. 2021). 308 Id. at 1044. Congressional Research Service 31 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms between unilateral and concerted conduct.309 The court thus proceeded to conduct a competitive-effects analysis of the challenged restrictions notwithstanding its holding that they were unilateral.310 In conducting this analysis under the rule of reason, the court concluded that: 1. Epic Games had established evidence of the restrictions’ anticompetitive effects;311 2. Apple had proffered valid procompetitive justifications for the restrictions based on security concerns, the promotion of interbrand competition, and the protection of intellectual property;312 and 3. Epic Games had not shown that those procompetitive benefits could be achieved through less restrictive means.313 Accordingly, the court held that the contractual restrictions on app distribution did not violate Section 1 of the Sherman Act, even if they amounted to concerted conduct.314 The court went on to reject other Section 1 and Section 2 claims involving app distribution and IAP processing for similar reasons—namely, the plaintiff’s failure to show that various procompetitive benefits could be achieved through less restrictive means or establish monopoly power.315 Finally, the court denied the plaintiff’s tying claim on the grounds that IAP processing does not represent a separate product from app distribution.316 As noted, Epic Games has appealed the district court’s decision.317 The Ninth Circuit heard oral arguments in the appeal in November 2022.318 Self-Preferencing The HJC Report alleged that Apple has taken a variety of steps to preference its own apps and harm rival app developers.319 Among other things, the report accused Apple of injuring competition by pre-installing its own apps on iPhones;320 denying third-party apps access to 309 Id. at 1036. 310 Id. 311 Id. at 1036-38. 312 Id. at 1038-40. 313 Id. at 1040-41. 314 Id. at 1041. 315 Id. at 1041-44. 316 Id. at 1047. While the court rejected the plaintiff’s federal antitrust claims, it concluded that Apple’s anti-steering provisions—which prohibited app developers from including links to external mechanisms for making IAPs—violated California’s unfair-competition law. Id. at 1058. Apple has cross-appealed that aspect of the district court’s decision. Notice of Appeal, Epic Games, Inc. v. Apple Inc., No. 4:20-cv-05640 (N.D. Cal. Oct. 8, 2021). 317 Notice of Appeal, Epic Games, Inc. v. Apple Inc., No. 4:20-cv-05640 (N.D. Cal. Sept. 12, 2021). 318 Paresh Dave, Epic’s ‘Failure of Proof’ in Apple Antitrust Case Questioned by Appeals Panel, REUTERS (Nov. 14, 2022), https://www.reuters.com/legal/fortnite-creator-fight-apple-antitrust-ruling-appeal-hearing-2022-11-14/. 319 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 352. 320 Id. Congressional Research Service 32 link to page 5 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms certain APIs and device functionalities that are available to its own apps;321 favoring its own apps in search results on its App Store;322 and removing rival apps from the App Store.323 Apple has denied giving preferential treatment to its own apps in search rankings and justified removing specific apps from the App Store as efforts to protect user privacy.324 Use of Competitively Sensitive Information Like Amazon, Apple has faced allegations that it uses its access to data generated by dependent businesses to identify and imitate popular offerings.325 In particular, software developers have accused Apple of using competitively sensitive information about popular apps to build competing apps and integrate certain functionalities into iOS.326 Apple has responded to questions regarding such allegations by stating that it does not violate other companies’ intellectual property rights.327 Big Tech Mergers and Acquisitions Some of the allegations discussed above involve Big Tech mergers and acquisitions. As noted, the FTC is currently challenging Facebook’s acquisitions of Instagram and WhatsApp,328 while Google’s acquisition of DoubleClick is a key part of the DOJ’s monopolization lawsuit targeting the company’s ad-tech practices.329 Some policymakers have expressed broader concerns about Big Tech mergers.330 The companies have been active dealmakers: between 2000 and 2019, the four firms engaged in hundreds of mergers and acquisitions.331 Many of these transactions fell below the numerical thresholds that trigger pre-merger review by the antitrust agencies.332 321 Id. at 354. In May 2022, the European Commission preliminarily determined that Apple had violated European Union competition law by limiting rival mobile wallet developers from accessing certain technology that Apple makes available to its own wallet, Apple Pay. See Press Release, Euro. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Sends Statement of Objections to Apple Over Practices Regarding Apple Pay (May 2, 2022), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/ip_22_2764. 322 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 359-61. 323 Id. at 364-67. 324 Id. at 361, 366. 325 Id. at 361-64. 326 Id. at 362. 327 Id. at 363. 328 FTC v. Facebook, Inc., 581 F. Supp. 3d 34 (D.D.C. 2022). 329 Complaint, United States v. Google LLC, No. 1:23-cv-00108 (E.D. Va. Jan. 24, 2023). For a more detailed discussion of mergers and acquisitions in tech markets, see CRS Report R46739, Mergers and Acquisitions in Digital Markets, by Clare Y. Cho. 330 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 387; SUBCOMM. ON ANTITRUST, COM., AND ADMIN. L. OF THE H. COMM. ON THE JUDICIARY, 116TH CONG., THE THIRD WAY: ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT IN BIG TECH 9 (2020) (written by Ken Buck, et al. in response to majority report), https://buck.house.gov/sites/evo-subsites/buck-evo.house.gov/files/wysiwyg_uploaded/Buck%20Report.pdf. 331 Diana L. Moss, The Record of Weak U.S. Merger Enforcement in Big Tech, AM. ANTITRUST INST. 6 (July 8, 2019), https://www.antitrustinstitute.org/wp-content/uploads/2019/07/Merger-Enforcement_Big-Tech_7.8.19.pdf. 332 FED. TRADE COMM’N, NON-HSR REPORTED ACQUISITIONS BY SELECT TECHNOLOGY PLATFORMS, 2010-2019: AN FTC STUDY (Sept. 2021), https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/reports/non-hsr-reported-acquisitions-select-technology-platforms-2010-2019-ftc-study/p201201technologyplatformstudy2021.pdf [hereinafter “FTC Non- Congressional Research Service 33 link to page 59 link to page 5 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 50 link to page 57 link to page 59 link to page 59 link to page 63 link to page 65 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms These deals have prompted some commentators to worry that the Big Tech firms are cementing their dominant positions by acquiring promising potential competitors.333 Transactions involving “nascent” competitors have been a particular point of concern.334 While the concept of a “nascent” competitor has been defined in different ways, it generally refers to an innovative firm whose technology represents a serious yet uncertain future threat to an incumbent.335 Other commentators have raised concerns about the number of Big Tech mergers that fall below the thresholds that trigger premerger review by the DOJ and FTC.336 These issues are discussed in greater detail in “Mergers & Acquisitions” infra.337 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech: General Issues The issues discussed above have prompted calls for policy reform. Some proposals would supplement the antitrust laws with sectoral competition regulations directed at large technology platforms.338 Others would work within the existing antitrust framework by adjusting burdens of proof and changing certain doctrinal rules.339 While the relevant options are varied, they all implicate the threshold question of whether the existing antitrust laws are adequate to address competition issues in the tech sector. Reportable Acquisitions Study”]. 333 JONATHAN B. BAKER, THE ANTITRUST PARADIGM: RESTORING A COMPETITIVE ECONOMY 160-61 (2019); Steven C. Salop, Dominant Digital Platforms: Is Antitrust Up to the Task?, 130 YALE L.J. F. 563, 578-79 (2021); Mark Glick, et al., Big Tech’s Buying Spree and the Failed Ideology of Competition Law, 72 HASTINGS L.J. 465, 468-75 (2021); HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 387; Tim Wu & Stuart A. Thompson, The Roots of Big Tech Run Disturbingly Deep, N.Y. TIMES (June 7, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2019/06/07/opinion/google-facebook-mergers-acquisitions-antitrust.html; STIGLER CTR. FOR THE STUDY OF THE ECON. AND THE STATE, STIGLER COMM. ON DIGITAL PLATFORMS: FINAL REPORT 71-72, 75 n.152 (2019), https://www.chicagobooth.edu/-/media/research/stigler/pdfs/digital-platforms---committee-report---stigler-center.pdf [hereinafter “STIGLER REPORT”]; HM TREASURY, UNLOCKING DIGITAL COMPETITION, REPORT OF THE DIGITAL COMPETITION EXPERT PANEL 40 (2019), https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/785547/unlocking_digital_competition_furman_review_web.pdf [hereinafter “UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT”] 334 A. Douglas Melamed, Mergers Involving Nascent Competition, Stanford L. and Econ. Olin Working Paper No. 566 (Jan. 17, 2022), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4009229; John M. Yun, Are We Dropping the Crystal Ball? Understanding Nascent & Potential Competition in Antitrust, 104 MARQ. L. REV. 613 (2021); C. Scott Hemphill & Tim Wu, Nascent Competitors, 168 U. PA. L. REV. 1879 (2020); OECD, START-UPS, KILLER ACQUISITIONS AND MERGER CONTROL 21-36 (2020), https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/start-ups-killer-acquisitions-and-merger-control-2020.pdf [hereinafter “OECD STARTUP ACQUISITION REPORT”]. 335 Yun, supra note 334, at 626-29; Hemphill & Wu, supra note 334, at 1883. 336 STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 111. 337 The FTC was unsuccessful in its first effort to block a Big Tech merger using a potential-competition theory. In January 2023, a federal district court denied the FTC’s motion for an injunction against Meta’s proposed acquisition of Within Unlimited—the developer of a virtual-reality (VR) fitness app. Order Denying Plaintiff’s Motion for Preliminary Injunction, FTC v. Meta Platforms Inc., No. 5:22-cv-04325 (N.D. Cal. Jan. 31, 2023). In that case, Meta was the putative potential entrant. The FTC alleged that, absent the acquisition, Meta would have organically entered the market for VR fitness apps. Id. at 39. The Commission also offered a perceived-potential-competition argument, contending that the prospect of Meta’s entry exerted competitive pressures on that market. Id. at 60. The district court rejected both theories, concluding that the FTC failed to establish a “reasonable probability” of entry absent the acquisition or that Meta was perceived as a potential competitor. Id. at 59, 62. 338 See infra Ex Ante Conduct Rules,“Structural Separation and Line-of-Business Restrictions,” “Mergers & Acquisitions” & “Interoperability & Data Portability.” 339 See infra “Changes to General Antitrust.” Congressional Research Service 34 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 5 link to page 39 link to page 39 link to page 38 link to page 38 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms The proposals that would supplement antitrust with a new regulatory regime also raise additional questions of policy design—namely, how to scope the relevant regulations and select an appropriate regulator to administer them. This section of the report discusses these general issues in the debate over antitrust reform directed at Big Tech firms. Is Existing Antitrust Law Insufficient? Whether antitrust is ill-equipped to deal with competition issues in the tech industry has been the subject of debate. Reform proponents have alleged that current law is inadequate for two general reasons. First, they argue that ex post adjudication is ill-equipped to address competition concerns raised by the unique structure of certain tech markets.340 Second, they contend that several elements of substantive antitrust doctrine insulate Big Tech firms from liability for specific types of anticompetitive conduct.341 Market Structure and the Efficacy of Ex Post Adjudication As discussed, outside of a narrow set of per se offenses, antitrust is a fact-specific enterprise. Generally, courts employ a case-by-case approach to evaluate claims of anticompetitive behavior.342 Because liability typically depends on case-specific facts rather than the application of bright-line rules, antitrust investigations and litigation are often time-consuming and expensive.343 The open-ended nature of the relevant legal standards can also make it difficult to predict whether particular conduct violates the law, which may undermine enforcement by allowing large firms to profit from anticompetitive conduct and treat potential lawsuits as a cost of doing business.344 Advocates of reform have argued that these features of antitrust adjudication make it ill-suited to deal with tech markets characterized by a unique confluence of structural characteristics, such as strong network effects, economies of scale, economies of scope derived from user data, and consumer tendencies to single home.345 340 See, e.g., OECD, EX ANTE REGULATION AND COMPETITION IN DIGITAL MARKETS 6 (2021), https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/ex-ante-regulation-and-competition-in-digital-markets-2021.pdf [hereinafter “OECD REGULATION REPORT”]; STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 100; UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 333, at 123-24. 341 See, e.g., HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 395-99. 342 William P. Rogerson & Howard Shelanski, Antitrust Enforcement, Regulation, and Digital Platforms, 168 U. PA. L. REV. 1911, 1917-18 (2020). 343 Rohit Chopra & Lina M. Khan, The Case for “Unfair Methods of Competition” Rulemaking, 87 U. CHI. L. REV. 357, 360-62 (2020); Daniel A. Crane, Rules Versus Standards in Antitrust Adjudication, 64 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 49, 83 (2007). 344 Chopra & Khan, supra note 343, at 360-61. 345 OECD REGULATION REPORT, supra note 340, at 9-12; STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 7-8, 99; UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 333, at 5. While many markets have one or more of these features, some commentators have argued that their combination and strength in digital-platform markets raise unique challenges for antitrust enforcers. See, e.g., Michael Kades & Fiona Scott Morton, Interoperability as a Competition Remedy for Digital Networks, WASH. CTR. FOR EQUITABLE GROWTH 7 n.14 (Sept. 23, 2020), https://equitablegrowth.org/working-papers/interoperability-as-a-competition-remedy-for-digital-networks/. Congressional Research Service 35 link to page 33 link to page 39 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 33 link to page 39 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 33 link to page 40 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 50 link to page 39 link to page 63 link to page 33 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms According to some, these characteristics cause certain tech markets to tip in favor of a single dominant firm.346 After an initial period of competition, one company may gain an edge that becomes self-reinforcing. For example, a platform with a large user base and associated data advantages may be the most attractive to new users, generating a positive feedback loop that allows it to grow even larger and thereby become even more attractive.347 Prospective entrants may then face difficulties achieving the scale necessary to compete with the dominant incumbent.348 Big Tech firms may also derive benefits from their roles as gatekeepers for key digital ecosystems, like mobile operating systems, app stores, online marketplaces, and social networks.349 By controlling access to these ecosystems and setting the rules within them, tech platforms can allegedly preserve their dominant positions and leverage those positions to obtain advantages in related markets.350 Some analysts contend that antitrust adjudication is too slow to adequately police markets characterized by these winner-take-all dynamics.351 By the time a market has tipped, they argue, remedies for anticompetitive conduct may be unable to restore meaningful competition.352 These worries have prompted calls for prophylactic rules to supplement case-by-case antitrust adjudication.353 Some proposals would also seek to address structural issues in Big Tech markets by imposing affirmative duties designed to catalyze competition.354 Other commentators have rejected the claim that antitrust is unable to grapple with competition issues involving large digital platforms. Some, for example, dispute the proposition that Big Tech markets have all decisively tipped in favor of a single firm.355 Rather, they contend that the tech 346 EZRACHI & STUCKE, supra note 280, at 10-11; OECD REGULATION REPORT, supra note 340, at 9; STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 34-36; UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 333, at 4. 347 Michael L. Katz & Carl Shapiro, Systems Competition and Network Effects, 8 J. ECON. PERSP. 93, 105-06 (1994). 348 Joseph Farrell & Paul Klemperer, Coordination and Lock-In: Competition with Switching Costs and Network Effects, in 3 HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 1970, 1974 (Mark Armstrong & Robert H. Porter eds., 2007). 349 EZRACHI & STUCKE, supra note 280, at 45-50; Marco Cappai & Giuseppe Colangelo, Taming Digital Gatekeepers: The More Regulatory Approach to Antitrust Law, Stanford-Vienna TTLF Working Paper 9 (Stanford-Vienna TTLF, Working Paper No. 55, 2020). 350 OECD REGULATION REPORT, supra note 340, at 10. 351 Giorgio Monti, The Digital Markets Act—Institutional Design and Suggestions for Improvement 1 (Tilburg L. & Econ. Ctr., Discussion Paper No. 2021-04, 2021); STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 99; UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 333, at 6. 352 EZRACHI & STUCKE, supra note 280, at 173-75; Monti, supra note 351, at 1; STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 99; UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 333, at 6. 353 E.g., STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 100-01; UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 333, at 62-63. Proposals involving ex ante conduct rules for Big Tech firms are discussed in Ex Ante Conduct Rules” infra. 354 E.g., Rogerson & Shelanski, supra note 342, at 1927-30. Proposals involving these types of affirmative obligations are discussed in “Interoperability & Data Portability” infra. 355 E.g., Hovenkamp, Platform Monopoly, supra note 279, at 1978; Joint Submission of Antitrust Economists, Legal Scholars, and Practitioners to the House Judiciary Committee on the State of Antitrust Law and Implications for Protecting Competition in Digital Markets at 3-4 (May 15, 2020), https://gai.gmu.edu/wp-content/uploads/sites/27/2020/05/house_joint_antitrust_letter_20200514.pdf [hereinafter “Antitrust Economist Submission”]; see also NICOLAS PETIT, BIG TECH AND THE DIGITAL ECONOMY: THE MOLIGOPOLY SCENARIO 153-71, 257 (2020) (arguing that Big Tech firms face meaningful competitive pressures even when operating in tipped markets); How Tech’s Defiance of Economic Gravity Came to an Abrupt End, THE ECONOMIST (Dec. 24, 2022), https://www.economist.com/business/2022/12/24/how-techs-defiance-of-economic-gravity-came-to-an-abrupt-end (arguing that some Big Tech firms face “fierce” competition from one another and from new rivals); Ryan Bourne & Rachel Chiu, A Monopoly of What? Big Tech in Today’s Context, CATO INST. (Nov. 3, 2022), https://www.cato.org/commentary/monopoly-what-big-tech- Congressional Research Service 36 link to page 40 link to page 33 link to page 33 link to page 40 link to page 5 link to page 38 link to page 5 link to page 5 link to page 38 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms giants compete in diverse markets characterized by different competitive dynamics.356 While some of those markets may be susceptible to tipping, others arguably retain a competitive fringe or exhibit competition among rivals of comparable size.357 Defenders of the adjudicative model of antitrust enforcement have thus emphasized the heterogeneity of digital-platform markets, which they contend militates against categorical treatment of Big Tech firms and in favor of the existing fact-specific approach.358 Substantive Antitrust Doctrine Support for fact-specific adjudication over regulation does not necessarily entail wholesale endorsement of prevailing antitrust doctrine. Commentators with diverse antitrust ideologies have argued that certain features of substantive antitrust law allow some types of anticompetitive conduct by Big Tech platforms to escape liability. Among other things, they have criticized the doctrine governing unilateral refusals to deal,359 monopoly leveraging,360 predatory pricing,361 and mergers involving potential and “nascent” competitors.362 These topics are discussed in greater detail throughout the remainder of this report. For purposes of this section, the important point is that alleged doctrinal infirmities represent a concern that is distinct from dissatisfaction with adjudication as an enforcement mechanism. A lawmaker’s preferred policy response may vary based on this distinction. As discussed below, some reform todays-context (similar); D. Daniel Sokol & Jingyuan (Mary) Ma, Understanding Online Markets and Antitrust Analysis, 15 NW. J. TECH. & INTELL. PROP. 43, 48-50 (2017) (“Online markets are constantly transforming. Indeed, online markets typically have innovative challengers against incumbents. Challengers may overtake incumbent firms through new ideas and technologies. In such settings, there are low entry barriers.”). 356 PETIT, supra note 355, at 257-58; Hovenkamp, Platform Monopoly, supra note 279, at 1978; Joshua D. Wright & John M. Yun, Platforms in the Spotlight at FTC Hearings, Geo. Mason L. & Econ. Research Paper No. 18-44 at 3 (Nov. 2018), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3280532. 357 Hovenkamp, Platform Monopoly, supra note 279, at 1978. 358 Id.; Antitrust Economist Submission, supra note 355, at 8-9; see also C.D. HOWE INST. COMPETITION POL’Y COUNCIL, DIGITAL PLATFORMS: OVERSIGHT IF NECESSARY, BUT NOT NECESSARILY REGULATION 7-8 (2021), https://www.cdhowe.org/sites/default/files/attachments/other-research/pdf/Communique_2021_0107_CPC.pdf (arguing that general competition law should be the presumptive framework for addressing competition issues in the tech sector and that special competition regulations for digital platforms are likely to overlook important distinctions among heterogeneous business models); ABA ANTITRUST L. SECTION, COMMON ISSUES RELATING TO THE DIGITAL ECONOMY AND COMPETITION, REPORT OF THE INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS AND COMMENTS TASK FORCE ON POSITIONS EXPRESSED BY THE ABA ANTITRUST LAW SECTION BETWEEN 2017 AND 2019, at 5 (2020) [hereinafter “ABA DIGITAL ECONOMY REPORT”] (concluding that antitrust authorities should address competition issues in digital-platform markets on a case-by-case basis using existing tools); Group of Seven (G7), Common Understanding of G7 Competition Authorities on “Competition and the Digital Economy” (June 5, 2019), https://www.autoritedelaconcurrence.fr/sites/default/files/2019-11/g7_common_understanding.pdf (“Because of its flexible analytical framework, fact-based analysis, cross-sector application, and technology-neutral nature, competition law can effectively apply to digital markets and to harmful anticompetitive behaviors in the digital economy.”). 359 Erik Hovenkamp, The Antitrust Duty to Deal in the Age of Big Tech, 131 YALE L.J. 1483, 1525 (2022) [hereinafter “Hovenkamp, Antitrust Duty to Deal”]; HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 397-98; STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 96-97; Sandeep Vaheesan, Reviving an Epithet: A New Way Forward for the Essential Facilities Doctrine, 2010 UTAH L. REV. 911 (2010). 360 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 396. 361 Marshall Steinbaum & Maurice E. Stucke, The Effective Competition Standard: A New Standard for Antitrust, 87 U. CHI. L. REV. 595, 608 (2020); HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 396-97; Aaron S. Edlin, Stopping Above-Cost Predatory Pricing, 111 YALE L.J. 941 (2002). 362 Hemphill & Wu, supra note 334; Kevin A. Bryan & Erik Hovenkamp, Antitrust Limits on Startup Acquisitions, 56 REV. OF INDUS. ORG. 615, 632 (2020); HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 394-95. Congressional Research Service 37 link to page 50 link to page 9 link to page 9 link to page 19 link to page 19 link to page 40 link to page 42 link to page 19 link to page 19 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms proposals target large tech platforms with sectoral regulations that would supplement the antitrust laws, while others would make changes within general antitrust doctrine.363 These debates over specific doctrinal rules take place alongside broader contestation regarding the fundamental goals of antitrust. A group of scholars and policymakers commonly identified as “Neo-Brandeisians” have called for the abandonment of the consumer-welfare standard as a benchmark for antitrust decision-making.364 Members of this movement have argued that a singular focus on consumer welfare has led to lax competition enforcement, which has in turn generated rising economic concentration, growing wealth inequality, and a political system captured by corporate interests.365 Some Neo-Brandeisians have specifically emphasized the consumer-welfare standard’s alleged inadequacy vis-à-vis large tech platforms. In particular, they contend that a focus on short-term price and output effects neglects the ways in which tech platforms forgo immediate profits to establish long-term dominance and then leverage that dominance across business lines.366 Defenders of the consumer-welfare standard fall into two broad camps. Some commentators join the Neo-Brandeisians in arguing that antitrust enforcement has become overly lax, but support the retention of the consumer-welfare standard as a general goal.367 While they object to specific doctrinal developments, these commentators attribute such developments to misapplications of the consumer-welfare standard rather than the standard itself.368 In contrast, others have defended both the consumer-welfare standard and current levels of antitrust enforcement.369 Among other things, supporters of the consumer-welfare standard have argued that many Neo-Brandeisian criticisms are based on an inaccurate view that the standard focuses solely on price to the exclusion of other benefits of competition, like innovation and product quality.370 Abstracting from the merits of the Neo-Brandeisian critique, the possible repudiation of the consumer-welfare standard raises the question of whether an alternative benchmark would replace it. Several options have been proposed. Some critics of the status quo have argued that antitrust should focus on the “competitive process.”371 That phrase has been used for a variety of 363 See infra “Reform Proposals.” 364 See, e.g., TIM WU, THE CURSE OF BIGNESS: ANTITRUST IN THE NEW GILDED AGE 135-38 (2018); Sandeep Vaheesan, The Profound Nonsense of the Consumer Welfare Standard, 64 ANTITRUST BULL. 479 (2019); Khan, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox, supra note 57, at 744-46. The Neo-Brandeisian movement derives its name from Louis Brandeis, a former Associate Justice of the Supreme Court who was also a proponent of vigorous antitrust enforcement and a critic of large corporations. See Lina M. Khan, The New Brandeis Movement: America’s Antimonopoly Debate, 9 J. EURO. COMPETITION L. & PRACTICE 131 (2018). 365 Lina M. Khan & Sandeep Vaheesan, Market Power and Inequality: The Antitrust Counterrevolution and Its Discontents, 11 HARV. L. & POL’Y REV. 235 (2017). 366 Khan, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox, supra note 57, at 747-53, 774-80. 367 See, e.g., Einer Elhauge, Should the Competitive Process Test Replace the Consumer Welfare Standard?, PROMARKET (May 24, 2022), https://www.promarket.org/2022/05/24/should-the-competitive-process-test-replace-the-consumer-welfare-standard/; Moss Testimony, supra note 152; Shapiro Testimony, supra note 152. 368 A. Douglas Melamed, Antitrust Law and Its Critics, 83 ANTITRUST L.J. 269, 274-79 (2020) (discussing several points of disagreement between “conservatives” and “mainstream progressives” working within the consumer-welfare paradigm). 369 See, e.g., Antitrust Economist Submission, supra note 355, at 4-12. 370 Melamed, supra note 368, at 281; Dorsey, et al., supra note 149, at 902; Moss Testimony, supra note 152, at 4. 371 E.g., HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 391-92; Tim Wu, The “Protection of the Competitive Process” Standard, (Colum. Pub. L. Research Paper No. 14-612, 2018), https://scholarship.law.columbia.edu/cgi/ Congressional Research Service 38 link to page 9 link to page 5 link to page 41 link to page 42 link to page 42 link to page 41 link to page 42 link to page 19 link to page 43 link to page 42 link to page 50 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms purposes,372 but in this context appears intended to signify a standard that would protect “not just consumers, but also workers, entrepreneurs, independent businesses, open markets, a fair economy, and democratic ideals.”373 In other work, Neo-Brandeisians have advocated a “citizen interest” standard that would “protect consumers from anticompetitive overcharges and small producers from anticompetitive underpayments, preserve open markets, and disperse economic and political power.”374 Proponents of these approaches have argued that they are more normatively attractive than the consumer-welfare standard and better reflect the full range of considerations that originally motivated the antitrust laws.375 Critics have contended that the proposed alternatives embrace vague and often contradictory goals and thus offer little guidance regarding the types of conduct that they would prohibit or allow.376 These debates are not purely academic. As discussed below, some legislative proposals would subject large tech platforms to special conduct rules that incorporate competitive-effects analysis, either as an element of a plaintiff’s case-in-chief or as an affirmative defense.377 The appropriate standard for assessing competitive harm may thus have important practical consequences beyond its significance in current doctrine. Error Costs in Digital Markets Modern antitrust has been heavily influenced by concerns about error costs—the harms that result from decisions prohibiting procompetitive conduct (false positives) or permitting anticompetitive conduct (false negatives). Alan Devlin & Michael Jacobs, Antitrust Error, 52 WM. & MARY L. REV. 75, 78-79 (2010). Antitrust conservatives have offered error-cost arguments favoring limited enforcement. In a 1984 article, Frank Easterbrook—now a federal judge on the Seventh Circuit—argued that false positives are more harmful than false negatives. Frank H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1, 2 (1984). He reasoned that the force of judicial precedent makes false positives difficult to correct, but that monopoly profits eventually induce the entry of new firms, mitigating the costs of false negatives. Id. Several Supreme Court decisions later relied upon this viewcontent.cgi?article=3293&context=faculty_scholarship; Khan, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox, supra note 57, at 745. 372 See Herbert Hovenkamp, The Slogans and Goals of Antitrust Law 51-58 (U. Penn. Inst. for L. & Econ. Research Paper No. 22-33, 2022), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4121866#. 373 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 391; see also Steinbaum & Stucke, supra note 361, at 602 (proposing an “effective competition” standard under which “[a]gencies and courts shall use the preservation of competitive market structures that protect individuals, purchasers, consumers, and producers; preserve opportunities for competitors; promote individual autonomy and well-being; and disperse private power as the principal objective of the federal antitrust laws.”). 374 Khan & Vaheesan, supra note 365, at 276. 375 WU, supra note 364, at 135-38; Steinbaum & Stucke, supra note 361, at 621-23 & n.91; Khan & Vaheesan, supra note 365, at 276. 376 Dorsey, et al., supra note 149, at 879; Joshua D. Wright, et al., Requiem for a Paradox: The Dubious Rise and Inevitable Fall of Hipster Antitrust, 51 ARIZ. ST. L. J. 292, 362-65 (2019); see also Hovenkamp, supra note 372, at 54 (“[A]n antitrust concern articulated as the protection of the competitive process does not give us much help unless we have some background substance to tell us what is intelligent competition policy and what is not.”); Elhauge, supra note 367 (arguing that a “competitive process” standard that lacks any supplemental benchmark “amounts to a conclusory I-know-it-when-I-see-it test”); John M. Newman, Procompetitive Justifications in Antitrust Law, 94 IND. L.J. 501, 514 (2019) (“[T]he actual content of the competitive-process approach remains mercurial, a cipher. The scholarly arguments in favor of it never seem to identify what, exactly, constitutes the ‘competitive process.’”); Daniel A. Crane, Four Questions for the Neo-Brandeisians, COMPETITION POL’Y INT’L ANTITRUST CHRON. 63, 66-67 (Apr. 2018) (“[W]hat would happen in a system that was nominally designed to protect consumers, workers, labor unions, small businesses, new entrants, and existing competitors all at once? Since the interests of those groups are often in conflict, courts and agencies would have to pick their favorites on the fly, without any objective principle to decide among them.”). 377 See infra “Self-Preferencing / Non-Discrimination Rules.” Congressional Research Service 39 link to page 44 link to page 49 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms analysis to justify holdings narrowing various aspects of antitrust doctrine. Herbert J. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Error Costs, U. PA. J. BUS. L. 293, 295-96 (2022) (col ecting cases). Courts and commentators have grappled with error-cost issues in digital markets. In its 2001 decision in United States v. Microsoft Corp., the D.C. Circuit relied on the novelty of platform software products to conclude that the rule of reason—rather than the traditional rule of quasi-per-se il egality—applied to a challenged tying arrangement involving such products. 253 F.3d 34, 89-90 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (per curiam). Other courts and commentators have likewise emphasized the complexity and dynamism of tech markets in arguing for a cautious approach to antitrust intervention. See FTC v. Qualcomm Inc., 969 F.3d 974, 990-91 (9th Cir. 2020); Rachel S. Tennis & Alexander Baier Schwab, Business Model Innovation and Antitrust Law, 29 YALE J. ON REG. 307, 319 (2012). This reasoning is controversial. Some observers have mounted general challenges to the claim that error costs justify permissive antitrust doctrine. See, e.g., Jonathan B. Baker, Taking the Error Out of “Error Cost” Analysis: What’s Wrong with Antitrust’s Right, 80 ANTITRUST L.J. 1, 8-12, 23-25 (2015) (disputing the arguments that markets are self-correcting and that erroneous judicial precedent is more durable than market power). Others have focused their critique on digital markets. For example, John Newman—now the Deputy Director of the FTC’s Bureau of Competition—has argued that false negatives in tech markets are far more common and costly than false positives. John M. Newman, Antitrust in Digital Markets, 72 VAND. L. REV. 1497, 1502 (2019). In particular, Newman contends that the structure of many digital markets insulates incumbents from competitive threats; that digital markets provide incumbents with unique anticompetitive strategies; and that challenged conduct in digital markets typically has few redeeming benefits. Id. at 1503-48. These features, he maintains, justify more vigilant antitrust scrutiny of tech markets, contrary to what he characterizes as the “orthodox” view of error costs. Id. at 1502. These error-cost debates have important implications for the choice between adjudication and regulation as enforcement mechanisms and the appropriate content of antitrust doctrine. Scoping Reform Proposals Reform proposals that would go beyond general antitrust to impose sectoral competition regulations raise additional questions of policy design. Two general models have emerged. One would apply special regulations to digital platforms that offer specified services and meet certain quantitative and qualitative criteria intended to capture platforms with bottleneck power over business users.378 Because proposals in this category involve the designation of covered platforms by regulators, this report refers to this strategy as the “designated-platform approach.”379 The second model is narrower. While the designated-platform approach would apply the same set of regulations to covered firms in a range of markets (e.g., social networking, e-commerce, online search), some legislation would apply only to individual markets.380 This report refers to this strategy as the “market-specific approach.” The subsections below review these two models for sector-specific competition regulation. The Designated-Platform Approach Policymakers in the United States and EU have explored the designated-platform approach. The EU has adopted legislation titled the Digital Markets Act, which applies special regulations to 378 See infra “The Designated-Platform Approach.” 379 As drafted, some of these proposals would apply special regulations to platforms meeting the relevant criteria even if the platforms are not formally designated by a regulator. See, e.g., American Innovation and Choice Online Act, H.R. 3816, 117th Cong. § 2(g)(4) (2021) (Reported Version). Nevertheless, this report adopts the terminology noted above because of the central role that designation would likely have played in the bills’ application. 380 See infra “Market-Specific Regulation.” Congressional Research Service 40 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms designated “gatekeepers.”381 Firms are to be designated as “gatekeepers” if they offer certain “core platform services”—including search engines, app stores, operating systems, advertising services, social networking, and online marketplaces—and meet certain quantitative and qualitative criteria.382 In the United States, several bills in the 117th Congress would have adopted a broadly similar approach.383 Under the bills, “covered platforms” would have included search engines, app stores, operating systems, social networks, and online marketplaces that meet specified quantitative and qualitative criteria.384 The proposals would have empowered the DOJ and FTC to designate a platform offering any of these services as a covered platform based on (1) quantitative thresholds involving market capitalization, annual sales, and active users, and (2) the platform’s status as a “critical trading partner.”385 Different bills would have imposed different types of competition regulations on designated platforms, including rules involving discriminatory conduct against business users,386 vertical integration,387 and mergers.388 Depending on the interpretation of the “critical trading partner” standard, the designation criteria may have encompassed the platforms discussed earlier in this report:  Facebook, Instagram, and WhatsApp (which are controlled by Meta Platforms);  Google Search, Android, the Google Play Store, and some of Google’s ad-tech services;  Amazon Marketplace; and  Apple’s iOS and App Store.389 Certain Microsoft properties and TikTok—a short-form video app controlled by the Chinese firm ByteDance—may also have fallen within the bills’ coverage.390 The designation criteria employed in these proposals raised several issues. Some commentators criticized the use of market capitalization and annual sales as factors that would have determined 381 Press Release, Euro. Comm’n, Digital Markets Act: Rules for Digital Gatekeepers to Ensure Open Markets Enter Into Force (Oct. 31, 2022), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IP_22_6423. 382 Id. 383 American Innovation and Choice Online Act, S. 2992, 117th Cong. § 3(d) (2022) (Reported Version); Platform Competition and Opportunity Act of 2021, S. 3197, 117th Cong. § 4 (2021); ACCESS Act of 2021, H.R. 3849, 117th Cong. § 6 (2021); Platform Competition and Opportunity Act of 2021, H.R. 3826, 117th Cong. § 4 (2021); Ending Platform Monopolies Act, H.R. 3825, 117th Cong. § 6 (2021); H.R. 3816 at § 2(d). 384 See, e.g., S. 2992 § 2(a)(9). 385 See, e.g., id. §§ 2(a)(5), 3(d). 386 S. 2992; H.R. 3816. 387 H.R. 3825. 388 H.R. 3826. Another proposal—which would have imposed interoperability and data-portability obligations on covered platforms—employed the same general designation standards as the other bills, but would have provided for firm-specific standards rather than categorical regulatory treatment of covered firms. H.R. 3849. 389 Leah Nylen, Tech Antitrust Bill Threatens to Break Apple, Google’s Grip on the Internet, BLOOMBERG (July 26, 2022), https://www.bloomberg.com/graphics/2022-tech-antitrust-bill/#xj4y7vzkg. 390 Id. Congressional Research Service 41 link to page 46 link to page 46 link to page 46 link to page 7 link to page 46 link to page 7 link to page 33 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms a firm’s regulatory status.391 Those criteria, they contended, have little relevance for a platform operator’s ability to harm competition, which instead depends on a firm’s market power.392 As discussed, courts typically assess claims of market power by evaluating a firm’s size within a relevant antitrust market—not its absolute size.393 Critics of the designated-platform bills thus argued that the proposals employed arbitrary designation criteria intended to single out a small handful of firms.394 The bills sought to address some of these concerns about arbitrariness with the additional requirement that covered platforms include only “critical trading partners”—a term defined to mean persons with the ability to “restrict or impede” a business user’s access to customers or tools or services needed to effectively serve customers.395 This phrase would have represented a novel addition to the antitrust lexicon. The use of the new “critical trading partner” language instead of the more familiar concept of market power may have been a response to some of the more demanding elements of market-power doctrine. Market definition—which is required if a plaintiff seeks to establish market power via market-share evidence—often involves a costly and time-consuming battle of economic experts.396 The “critical trading partner” terminology may have been motivated in part by a desire to ease these burdens. Some commentators have also lodged theoretical objections to the centrality of market definition in contemporary antitrust.397 Among other things, they have highlighted the limitations of binary market analysis when it comes to differentiated products.398 Products that fall within a relevant 391 Erik Hovenkamp, Proposed Antitrust Reforms in Big Tech: What Do They Mean for Competition and Innovation?, COMPETITION POLICY INT’L ANTITRUST CHRONICLE 15, 22 (July 2022) [hereinafter “Hovenkamp, Proposed Antitrust Reforms”]; AURELIAN PORTUESE, INFO. TECH. & INNOVATION FDN., THE REVISED (BUT UNCORRECTED) VERSION OF THE KLOBUCHAR BILL (2022), https://www2.itif.org/2022-revised-uncorrected-klobuchar-bill.pdf; Comments of the American Bar Association Antitrust Law Section Regarding the American Innovation and Choice Online Act (S. 2992) Before the 117th Congress 8 (Apr. 27, 2022), https://www.americanbar.org/content/dam/aba/administrative/antitrust_law/comments/at-comments/2022/comments-aico-act.pdf [hereinafter “ABA Letter”]. 392 Hovenkamp, Proposed Antitrust Reforms, supra note 391, at 22; PORTUESE, supra note 391; ABA Letter, supra note 391, at 8. 393 ELHAUGE, supra note 30, at 226. 394 E.g., Herbert Hovenkamp, Gatekeeper Competition Policy 18 (U. of Penn., Inst. for L. & Econ., Research Paper No. 23-08, 2023), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4347768 [hereinafter “Hovenkamp, Gatekeeper Competition Policy”] (arguing that the strategy of designating platforms based on size rather than market share suggests an intent to protect the rivals of covered platforms from aggressive competition rather than a desire to protect consumers); PORTUESE, supra note 391. 395 E.g., American Innovation and Choice Online Act, H.R. 3816, 117th Cong. §§ 2(g)(4)(B)(iii), 2(g)(5) (2021) (Reported Version). One of the bills defined the term “critical trading partner” to mean a person with the ability to “restrict or materially impede” a business user’s access to customers or tools needed to effectively serve customers. American Innovation and Choice Online Act, S. 2992, 117th Cong. § 2(a)(6) (2022) (Reported Version) (emphasis added). For a more detailed discussion of the American Innovation and Choice Online Act, see CRS Report R47228, The American Innovation and Choice Online Act, by Jay B. Sykes. 396 See Hovenkamp, The Rule of Reason, supra note 27, at 98-99 (discussing the administrative costs associated with the rule of reason); John E. Lopatka & William H. Page, Economic Authority and the Limits of Expertise in Antitrust Cases, 90 CORNELL L. REV. 617, 659-60 (2005) (noting that modern courts recognize that “market definition requires the sophisticated use of data and theory,” which in turn requires expert testimony). 397 Louis Kaplow, Why (Ever) Define Markets?, 124 HARV. L. REV. 437, 476-79 n.78-79 (2010) (cataloguing academic criticisms of the role that market definition plays under current law). 398 Hovenkamp, Platform Monopoly, supra note 279, at 1961 (“If a market is product-differentiated, any conclusion about market definition is wrong.”); Joseph Farrell & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Evaluation of Horizontal Mergers: An Economic Alternative to Market Definition, 10 B.E. J. OF THEORETICAL ECON. art. 9 at 4 (2010) (“Product Congressional Research Service 42 link to page 33 link to page 5 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms antitrust market, for example, all count as equally effective substitutes for the product at issue; the market-definition paradigm does not consider different rates of substitution among products within a relevant market.399 Similarly, firms deemed to fall outside a relevant market are treated as if they exert no competitive pressure on a defendant.400 Reality is often more nuanced. In markets with differentiated products—like many technology markets—there may be a range of firms that compete with a defendant to various degrees. Singling out a specific market boundary along this type of continuum may thus yield inaccurate assessments of market power.401 Other commentators have expressed narrower concerns about current market-power doctrine. For example, some have argued that the Supreme Court’s 2018 decision in Ohio v. American Express (Amex)402—which adopted special market-definition rules for two-sided transaction platforms—may hamper antitrust enforcement against some tech firms.403 The “critical trading partner” requirement thus appeared to respond to dissatisfaction with existing case law. However, many argued that the requirement’s precise relationship with current doctrine was unclear. The core concern of market definition—the availability of reasonable substitutes—seems relevant to whether a platform has the ability to “restrict or impede” a business user’s access to customers or necessary tools. As a result, some of the considerations that figure in market definition would potentially have played a role in evaluations of the “critical trading partner” requirement. The exact ways in which this inquiry may have differed from traditional market definition accordingly remained uncertain. The literature also reflected different views of the requirement’s stringency. Some commentators argued that the relevant bills were “carefully targeted” because they would have applied only to “critical trading partners.”404 Others contended that the additional criterion would have been unlikely to exclude firms that met the bills’ quantitative thresholds.405 The analytical framework differentiation can make defining the relevant market problematic, notably because products must be ruled ‘in’ or ‘out,’ creating a risk that the outcome of a merger investigation or case may turn on an inevitably artificial line-drawing exercise.”). 399 Hovenkamp, Platform Monopoly, supra note 279, at 1961. 400 Id. 401 See DEVLIN, supra note 10, at 281-84; Franklin M. Fisher, Diagnosing Monopoly, 19 Q. REV. ECON. & BUS. 7, 16 (1979) (“By focusing on whether products are in or out of the market, one converts a necessarily continuous question into a question of yes or no.”). 402 138 S. Ct. 2274 (2018). 403 JAMES BESSEN, THE NEW GOLIATHS: HOW CORPORATIONS USE SOFTWARE TO DOMINATE INDUSTRIES, KILL INNOVATION, AND UNDERMINE REGULATION 157 (2022); Lina Khan, The Supreme Court Case That Could Give Tech Giants More Power, N.Y. TIMES (Mar. 2, 2018), https://www.nytimes.com/2018/03/02/opinion/the-supreme-court-case-that-could-give-tech-giants-more-power.html; but see Tim Wu, The American Express Opinion, the Rule of Reason, and Tech Platforms, 7 J. ANTITRUST ENF’T 117 (2019) (arguing that Amex’s holding is narrow and that the decision is unlikely to impede antitrust enforcement against major tech platforms). 404 Letter from Fiona M. Scott Morton, et al., to Sen. Amy Klobuchar & Sen. Charles Grassley 1 (July 7, 2022), https://som.yale.edu/sites/default/files/2022-07/AICOA-Final-revised.pdf (“[S. 2992’s] approach is carefully targeted in that its prohibitions apply only to platforms deemed ‘critical trading partners’—meaning they have the power to deprive business users of access to customers or access to inputs necessary for those users to run their businesses. The result is that [S. 2992’s] restrictions apply to the platforms whose market positions confer undue gatekeeping power, and no others.”). 405 Monika Schnitzer, et al., International Coherence in Digital Platform Regulation: An Economic Perspective on the US and EU Proposals, YALE TOBIN CTR. FOR ECON. POLICY 9 (Aug. 9, 2021), https://tobin.yale.edu/sites/default/files/Coherence%20in%20Digital%20Platform%20Regulation.pdf; see also Reining in Dominant Digital Platforms: Restoring Competition to Our Digital Markets, Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Competition Policy, Congressional Research Service 43 link to page 5 link to page 5 link to page 39 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms governing assessments of the “critical trading partner” standard would thus have to be fleshed out in practice, if Congress were to enact legislation employing that concept.406 The use of the “critical trading partner” language instead of a market-power requirement is not inherent to the designated-platform approach. In empowering a regulator to designate platforms for special competition regulation, Congress could consider limiting designations to firms that possess market power. In the 117th Congress, S. 1074 would have taken that approach.407 The bill would have imposed special merger rules on “dominant digital firms”—a term defined to mean companies that provide online services and possess “dominant market power” in any market related to such services.408 Under the legislation, the FTC would have been empowered to designate companies as “dominant digital firms” based on their possession of “dominant market power” and several other factors, including network effects, use of exclusivity agreements, and vertical integration.409 In linking platform designation and market power, Congress could address some of the concerns discussed above by dispensing with certain elements of market-power doctrine. For example, Congress could provide that market definition is not necessary to establish market power or abrogate specific decisions like Amex. One general antitrust bill in the 117th Congress would have made both of those changes.410 Besides these issues involving designation criteria, the designated-platform approach implicates the broader question of whether the Big Tech firms (and any other designated firms) are sufficiently similar to warrant categorical regulatory treatment. As discussed, some commentators have argued that Big Tech markets share important structural similarities that justify a consistent regulatory response, while others have emphasized the differences between those markets.411 For proponents of new competition regulations, that issue may be the central question that determines the choice between the designated-platform approach and market-specific regulation. Antitrust and Consumer Rights of the S. Comm. on the Judiciary (Mar. 7, 2023) (testimony of Daniel Francis, Assistant Professor of Law, New York University School of Law at 85), https://www.judiciary.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/2023-03-07%20-%20Testimony%20-%20Francis.pdf [hereinafter “Francis Testimony”] (arguing that the definition of “critical trading partner” in the American Innovation and Choice Online Act was “strikingly broad and vague,” and that it “appears to encompass any business that offers a desirable means of reaching customers for even a single business user”). 406 One commentator has proposed a potentially similar test for identifying dominant platforms without resorting to traditional market-power analysis. The relevant proposal would subject platforms to special competition regulations based on an assessment of their “cost of exclusion”—a concept that measures the costs to an individual or business of being excluded from a platform. HAROLD FELD, ROOSEVELT INST., THE CASE FOR THE DIGITAL PLATFORM ACT: MARKET STRUCTURE AND REGULATION OF DIGITAL PLATFORMS 41-47 (May 8, 2019), https://rooseveltinstitute.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/07/RI-Case-for-the-Digital-Platform-Act-201905.pdf. For a discussion of the mathematics involved in calculating a firm’s “cost of exclusion,” see id. at 43-44. 407 Trust-Busting for the Twenty-First Century Act, S. 1074, 117th Cong. § 4 (2021). 408 Id. 409 Id. 410 Competition and Antitrust Law Enforcement Reform Act of 2021, S. 225, 117th Cong. §§ 9, 13 (2021); see also DEVLIN, supra note 10, at 282 (calling for a reduced role for market definition in antitrust doctrine); HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 399 (arguing that Congress should adopt legislation overriding Amex and providing that market definition is not required to prove an antitrust violation). For a defense of market definition, see Gregory J. Werden, Why (Ever) Define Markets? An Answer to Professor Kaplow, 78 ANTITRUST L.J. 729 (2013). For a defense of the Supreme Court’s Amex decision, see Geoffrey A. Manne, In Defence of the Supreme Court’s “Single Market” Definition in Ohio v. American Express, 7 J. ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 104 (2019). 411 See supra “Market Structure and the Efficacy of Ex Post Adjudication.” Congressional Research Service 44 link to page 50 link to page 28 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Market-Specific Regulation Some proposals for sectoral competition regulation rely on a more targeted strategy than the designated-platform approach. Instead of applying the same set of regulations to designated firms operating across a range of different tech markets, policymakers could adopt regulations tailored to individual markets. In the 117th Congress, lawmakers introduced bills targeting two industries: app stores and digital advertising.412 The Open App Markets Act (OAMA) would have established competition regulations for large app stores.413 Among other things, the legislation would have prohibited operators of covered app stores from tying their app stores to their payment processors, preferencing their own apps in search results, and using nonpublic information derived from third-party apps to compete with those apps.414 The bill’s requirements are discussed in greater detail in “Ex Ante Conduct Rules” infra. The Competition and Transparency in Digital Advertising Act would have imposed structural-separation requirements and conduct rules on certain digital-advertising platforms.415 The legislation would have prohibited firms with more than $20 billion in annual digital-advertising revenue from owning platforms that operate in more than one of the key nodes in the ad-tech supply chain (ad exchanges, sell-side brokerages, and buy-side brokerages).416 It also would have required firms with more than $5 billion in annual digital-advertising revenue to abide by customer-protection rules involving best execution, transparency, and conflicts of interest.417 Choice of Enforcers A new regulatory regime for large tech platforms would require the selection of a regulator. Several options are available. The designated-platform bills discussed above would have empowered the DOJ and FTC to designate firms for special regulation.418 One of those bills—which included interoperability and data-portability mandates—would have granted the FTC rulemaking authority to develop standards implementing the relevant requirements.419 The others would have given enforcement authority to the DOJ and FTC, but did not include explicit grants 412 Competition and Transparency in Digital Advertising Act, S. 4258, 117th Cong. (2022); Open App Markets Act, S. 2710, 117th Cong. (2022) (Reported Version); Competition and Transparency in Digital Advertising Act, H.R. 7839, 117th Cong. (2022); Open App Markets Act, H.R. 7030, 117th Cong. (2022); Open App Markets Act, H.R. 5017, 117th Cong. (2021). 413 S. 2710; H.R. 7030; H.R. 5017. 414 S. 2710 § 3; H.R. 7030 § 3; H.R. 5017 § 3. 415 S. 4258; H.R. 7839. 416 S. 4258 § 2; H.R. 7839 § 2. As discussed in supra “Digital Advertising,” the DOJ has filed a monopolization lawsuit seeking to compel Google to divest some of its ad-tech businesses. 417 S. 4258 § 2; H.R. 7839 § 2. 418 American Innovation and Choice Online Act, S. 2992, 117th Cong. § 3(d) (2022) (Reported Version); Platform Competition and Opportunity Act of 2021, S. 3197, 117th Cong. § 4 (2021); ACCESS Act of 2021, H.R. 3849, 117th Cong. § 6 (2021); Platform Competition and Opportunity Act of 2021, H.R. 3826, 117th Cong. § 4 (2021); Ending Platform Monopolies Act, H.R. 3825, 117th Cong. § 6 (2021); American Innovation and Choice Online Act, H.R. 3816, 117th Cong. § 2(d) (2021) (Reported Version). 419 H.R. 3849 § 6(c). Congressional Research Service 45 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 39 link to page 38 link to page 20 link to page 38 link to page 48 link to page 39 link to page 38 link to page 22 link to page 34 link to page 30 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms of rulemaking power.420 Some of the bills also would have given enforcement authority to state attorneys general.421 Some commentators have endorsed an alternative approach involving the creation of a new specialist regulator for large digital platforms.422 In certain proposals, this regulator would be an entirely new agency,423 while others would establish a new branch with special powers within an existing antitrust authority.424 In the 117th Congress, the Digital Platform Commission Act would have taken the former approach and created a new Federal Digital Platform Commission tasked with regulating “systemically important digital platforms.”425 Reform Proposals With the conceptual ground cleared, this final section of the report discusses the substance of various proposals to reform the competition laws governing Big Tech platforms. The proposals fall into five categories: (1) ex ante conduct rules, (2) structural separation and line-of-business restrictions, (3) special merger rules, (4) interoperability and data-portability mandates, and (5) changes to general antitrust doctrine. Ex Ante Conduct Rules As discussed, some commentators and legislators have advocated the adoption of prophylactic conduct rules for Big Tech platforms, which would supplement general antitrust law.426 This subsection reviews several of these proposals for ex ante competition regulations. Self-Preferencing / Non-Discrimination Rules The ability of large digital platforms to preference their own offerings is a recurring concern in debates over antitrust reform. As discussed, several of the Big Tech firms have been accused of engaging in various forms of self-preferencing. Google has allegedly favored its own verticals in general search results, its own app store and apps through its control of Android, and its own ad-tech businesses through its presence in multiple segments of the ad-tech market.427 Apple has likewise been accused of preferencing its own apps and app store,428 while Amazon has allegedly privileged its own private-label products and products that use its logistics service.429 420 S. 2992; S. 3197; H.R. 3826; H.R. 3825; H.R. 3816. 421 S. 2992 § 2(c)(1)(C); S. 3197 § 5(a)(3); H.R. 3826 § 5(a); H.R. 3816 § 2(h)(1)(C). Some of the bills also would have created private rights of action. S. 3197 § 7; H.R. 3826 § 7; H.R. 3816 § 6. 422 STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 104-06; UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 333, at 8. 423 Rogerson & Shelanski, supra note 342, at 1916; STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 104-06. 424 ACCC Report, supra note 162, at 31; see also UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 333, at 10 (noting both options); FELD, supra note 406, at 188-95 (discussing the advantages and disadvantages of creating a new digital-platform regulator). 425 Digital Platform Commission Act of 2022, S. 4201, 117th Cong. (2022); Digital Platform Commission Act of 2022, H.R. 7858, 117th Cong. (2022). 426 S. 2992; H.R. 3816; OECD REGULATION REPORT, supra note 340, at 9-15; UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 333, at 62-63. 427 See supra “Google.” 428 See supra “Apple.” 429 See supra “Amazon.” Congressional Research Service 46 link to page 30 link to page 51 link to page 41 link to page 9 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms The primary concern with this type of conduct involves monopoly leveraging.430 As discussed, leveraging theories of harm can take two forms. Offensive leveraging occurs when a firm attempts to use monopoly power in a primary market to extract additional profits from a secondary market.431 By contrast, defensive leveraging involves the use of monopoly power to gain an advantage in a secondary market so as to preserve a primary market monopoly—for example, by eliminating competitive threats that might emerge from the secondary market.432 Defensive leveraging may be a viable theory of harm under existing monopolization law.433 Offensive-leveraging claims, however, cannot succeed under Section 2 absent evidence that a defendant had a dangerous probability of monopolizing a secondary market; mere harm to competition in the secondary market is not sufficient.434 For some of the self-preferencing allegations against Big Tech firms, these limitations may preclude monopolization claims.435 It may be unlikely, for example, that Amazon will achieve monopoly power over most of the products that it sells on its marketplace. As a result, it would be difficult to challenge the preferential display of those products under an offensive-leveraging theory.436 This type of alleged favoritism may also be a weak foundation for a defensive-leveraging or monopoly-maintenance case; it is not clear that Amazon’s alleged elevation of inferior products helps it maintain a putative e-commerce monopoly. Similarly, the case law governing unilateral refusals to deal is not an attractive vehicle for challenging platform self-preferencing. A platform operator’s favorable treatment of its own verticals relative to rivals that use its platform is typically less harmful to rivals than an outright refusal of access.437 Because antitrust imposes access duties only in a narrow set of circumstances, many forms of self-preferencing are unlikely to constitute unlawful refusals to deal.438 430 See generally Todd, supra note 249. 431 GIUSEPPE COLANGELO, INT’L CTR. FOR L. & ECON., ANTITRUST UNCHAINED: THE EU’S CASE AGAINST SELF-PREFERENCING (2022), https://laweconcenter.org/resources/antitrust-unchained-the-eus-case-against-self-preferencing/?doing_wp_cron=1675175836.8782548904418945312500. 432 Robin Cooper Feldman, Defensive Leveraging in Antitrust, 87 GEO. L.J. 2079, 2080 (1999); Matthew Levinton, Defensive Leveraging as Monopolization, AM. BAR ASS’N (June 22, 2022), https://www.americanbar.org/groups/antitrust_law/resources/newsletters/defensive-leveraging-as-monopolization. 433 See United States v. Microsoft, 253 F.3d 34, 67 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (per curiam). 434 Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. L. Offs. of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 410 n.4 (2004); see also Levinton, supra note 432. 435 See GREGORY J. WERDEN, THE FOUNDATIONS OF ANTITRUST: EVENTS, IDEAS, AND DOCTRINES 355 (2020) (discussing leveraging claims under U.S. law and concluding that “[s]elf-preferencing by digital platform monopolists will be minimally constrained in the United States unless Congress creates a new regulatory structure for digital platforms”). 436 Herbert J. Hovenkamp, Monopolizing and the Sherman Act 32 (Penn. Carey L. Sch., Research Paper, No. 2769, 2022), https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=3772&context=faculty_scholarship. 437 Hovenkamp, Antitrust Duty to Deal, supra note 359, at 1546. 438 Trinko, 540 U.S. at 409. Refusal-to-deal doctrine is discussed in greater detail in supra “Refusals to Deal.” The essential-facilities doctrine is also unlikely to preclude many forms of platform self-preferencing for a variety of reasons, even if that doctrine remains good law. For an overview of the difficulties facing an essential-facilities challenge to “search bias,” for example, see Marina Lao, Search, Essential Facilities, and the Antitrust Duty to Deal, 11 NW. J. TECH. & INTELL. PROP. 275, 298-304 (2013). Congressional Research Service 47 link to page 39 link to page 39 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms In the 117th Congress, the American Innovation and Choice Online Act (AICOA) would have responded to these doctrinal difficulties by prohibiting covered platform operators from preferencing their own products and services in certain circumstances.439 Different versions of the legislation structured the prohibition differently. The Senate Judiciary Committee reported a version of the AICOA that would have prohibited covered platform operators from preferencing their own products “in a manner that would materially harm competition.”440 The House Judiciary Committee, by contrast, reported a version of the bill that would have prohibited platform self-preferencing but granted defendants certain competition-related affirmative defenses.441 In particular, the reported House bill would have allowed defendants to avoid liability if they established by clear and convincing evidence that their conduct would (1) not harm “the competitive process by restricting or impeding legitimate activity by business users,” or (2) increase “consumer welfare.”442 These competing approaches raise a central issue in the debate over conduct rules for Big Tech platforms: the role of business justifications. As discussed, antitrust has developed a general burden-shifting framework that often allows defendants to rebut a prima facie case of competitive harm by establishing procompetitive justifications for their conduct.443 The opportunity to offer such arguments likely reduces the incidence of false positives.444 One of the primary motivations for ex ante conduct rules, however, is a desire to avoid the delays and expense that accompany this type of fact-intensive analysis.445 The proper framework for evaluating business justifications thus implicates a key trade-off facing proponents of competition regulation. The AICOA’s resolution of that trade-off was not entirely clear. As discussed, different versions of the bill employed different approaches to the issue of competitive harm. The self-preferencing prohibition in the reported Senate bill would have made “material harm to competition” an element of the government’s case-in-chief.446 The reported House bill, by contrast, offered competition-related affirmative defenses subject to a clear-and-convincing-evidence standard.447 That difference might suggest that the reported Senate bill took a more defendant-friendly approach than the reported House bill. Some lawmakers and commentators, however, argued that 439 American Innovation and Choice Online Act, S. 2992, 117th Cong. § 3(a)(1) (2022) (Reported Version); American Innovation and Choice Online Act, H.R. 3816, 117th Cong. § 2(a)(1) (2021) (Reported Version). The OAMA included a more limited prohibition of self-preferencing related to app-store search results. The bill would have prohibited covered firms from “unreasonably preferencing or ranking” their own apps in search results. Open App Markets Act, S. 2710, 117th Cong. § 3(e)(1) (2022) (Reported Version); Open App Markets Act, H.R. 7030, 117th Cong. § 3(e)(1) (2021); Open App Markets Act, H.R. 5017, 117th Cong. § 3(e)(1) (2021). 440 S. 2992 § 3(a)(1). 441 H.R. 3816 §§ 2(a)(1), (c)(1), (c)(3). 442 Id. §§ 2(c)(1), (c)(3). The bills offered separate affirmative defenses related to user privacy, data security, and compliance with other laws. S. 2992 § 3(b)(1); H.R. 3816 § 2(c)(2). The reported Senate version of the bill also provided an affirmative defense related to the maintenance or enhancement of a platform’s “core functionality.” S. 2992 § 3(b)(1)(C). 443 See, e.g., Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2284 (2018) (describing the framework in a Section 1 case); Viamedia, Inc. v. Comcast Corp., 951 F.3d 429, 463-64 (7th Cir. 2020) (describing the framework in a Section 2 case). 444 See, e.g., Crane, supra note 343, at 55. 445 See, e.g., Chopra & Khan, supra note 343, at 360. 446 S. 2992 § 3(a)(1). 447 H.R. 3816 §§ 2(c)(1), (c)(3). Congressional Research Service 48 link to page 46 link to page 46 link to page 53 link to page 46 link to page 53 link to page 47 link to page 46 link to page 9 link to page 47 link to page 17 link to page 41 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms the meaning of the “materially harm competition” standard in the Senate-reported bill was unclear.448 Among other things, they highlighted the novelty of the standard’s materiality language, the absence of a market-power requirement, and the bill’s omission of an explicit consumer-welfare defense.449 Those factors made it difficult to predict the type of framework a court might have adopted in applying the “materially harm competition” standard. In particular, it appeared unclear whether that language was intended to broaden the types of competitive harm that antitrust has traditionally recognized.450 This issue overlapped with questions about the relationship between the “materially harm competition” standard and antitrust’s existing analytical tools. For example, if that standard was intended to implement something similar to traditional rule-of-reason burden shifting—which allows defendants to offer procompetitive justifications for their conduct—then litigation under the AICOA may have been nearly as costly and time-consuming as Sherman Act lawsuits.451 On the other hand, an interpretation of the bill that did not permit consumer-welfare or efficiency justifications would have represented a departure from the prevailing framework for assessing competitive harm.452 If the AICOA had been enacted, courts may have been reluctant to move away from these existing analytical tools without clearer legislative direction. 448 Hovenkamp, Gatekeeper Competition Policy, supra note 394, at 24 (arguing that the meaning of the “materially harm competition” standard was unclear and that “[i]f the AICOA is redrafted, this provision more than any other needs clarification”); A. Douglas Melamed, Why I Think Congress Should Not Enact the American Innovation and Choice Online Act, COMPETITION POLICY INT’L (June 19, 2022), https://www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/why-i-think-congress-should-not-enact-the-american-innovation-and-choice-online-act/ (arguing that the meaning of the “materially harm competition” standard was not clear); ABA Letter, supra note 391, at 5, 9-11 (similar); Transcript of Markup of S. 2992 at 53 (Jan. 20, 2022) (on file with author) [hereinafter “S. 2992 Markup Transcript”] (Sen. Thom Tillis) (“It’s not clear how existing competitor or competition jurisprudence would support or be changed by [S. 2992]. The purpose of competition law is to eliminate harm to consumers not to pick winners and losers. I’m also aware of the spirited debate [over] whether decades of antitrust law based on [the] consumer-welfare standard should be put in the burn pit. I’m open to having [a] separate discussion about potential changes to that standard and I hope that we will. But as it stands in relation to this bill, what standard will enforcers look to[?] What about amendments [that] would insert [the] consumer welfare standard back into the definition of material harm to competition?”). 449 Melamed, supra note 448; ABA Letter, supra note 391, at 6; S. 2992 Markup Transcript, supra note 448, at 53. 450 Francis Testimony, supra note 405, at 55 (“‘[H]arm to competition’ is just not a phrase with a single self-executing meaning. It could be interpreted to mean welfare harm in a manner we would associate with traditional antitrust; or it could be interpreted to mean ‘injury to rivals[.]’”) (emphasis in original); Hovenkamp, Gatekeeper Competition Policy, supra note 394, at 23-24 (“If competition is defined in an economically sensible way to refer to reduced market output and higher prices, then the statute might end up limiting its reach to conduct posing a realistic threat of competitive harm. If it means something else, such as merely injuring a rival or placing it at a disadvantage on that particular platform as opposed to the market as a whole, then it could end up doing a great deal of harm.”). 451 See Francis, supra note 48, at 823-24 (arguing that antitrust rules allowing defendants to offer justifications for challenged conduct would be “unlikely to lighten the adjudicative load much”). Under this reading of the bill, the self-preferencing prohibition still would have modified existing law by substituting the designation criteria discussed earlier in this report for a market-power requirement. The prohibition also would have potentially covered conduct that currently escapes liability because of the limitations on monopoly-leveraging and refusal-to-deal claims discussed in this section. 452 Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2284 (2018); United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 59 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (per curiam); Schnitzer, et al., supra note 405, at 20 (interpreting the AICOA to not allow platforms to defend challenged conduct on efficiency grounds, “as might be possible in a standard antitrust case”). The absence of consumer-welfare and efficiency justifications would, however, be consistent with some conceptions of “competition” that prevailed in earlier periods of antitrust history and with the stated aims of the recent Neo-Brandeisian movement. See supra “The Goals of Antitrust” & “Substantive Antitrust Doctrine.” Congressional Research Service 49 link to page 46 link to page 10 link to page 44 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Given the potential expansiveness of a general self-preferencing prohibition,453 these issues involving competitive harm and business justification would likely represent key questions for any similar legislative efforts.454 Those issues also underscore that the distinction between adjudicative and regulatory approaches to competition issues in the tech sector may be more of a continuum than an either/or question. Unless ex ante rules entail categorical prohibitions based on the form of challenged conduct, the competitive-effects analysis that characterizes modern antitrust adjudication would likely play some role in a new regulatory regime. Tying Besides its self-preferencing prohibition, the AICOA would have barred covered platform operators from tying access to or preferred placement on their platforms to the purchase or use of other products or services.455 The OAMA included a narrower tying provision. The bill would have prohibited covered firms from conditioning access to their app stores on the use of their payment processors.456 As discussed, existing antitrust doctrine prohibits tying in certain circumstances. Under current law, a plaintiff can prevail on a tying claim by showing that: 1. The defendant offered two distinct products; 2. The defendant conditioned the sale of one product (the tying product) on the purchase of the other product (the tied product); 3. The defendant possessed sufficient economic power in the tying product market to coerce purchasers into acceptance of the tied product; and 4. The defendant’s conduct affected a “not insubstantial” amount of interstate commerce in the tied product.457 Some courts have also required plaintiffs to demonstrate that a tying arrangement had anticompetitive effects in the tied product market.458 Unlike this test, neither the AICOA nor the OAMA contained explicit market-power requirements. Instead, as discussed, the AICOA used certain quantitative criteria and a “critical trading partner” standard to identify the platforms that would be subject to its prohibitions.459 The OAMA, in contrast, employed only a quantitative threshold. The bill would have applied to companies that control app stores with more than 50 million U.S. users.460 453 See Hovenkamp, Proposed Antitrust Reforms, supra note 391, at 18 (noting the ubiquity of self-preferencing by vertically integrated firms); Randy Picker, How Would the Big Tech Self-Preferencing Bill Affect Users?, PROMARKET (June 16, 2022), https://www.promarket.org/2022/06/16/how-would-the-big-tech-self-preferencing-bill-affect-users/ (reviewing possible implications of a general self-preferencing prohibition for Big Tech platforms). 454 See D. Daniel Sokol, A Framework for Digital Platform Regulation, 17 COMPETITION L. INT’L 95, 102 (2021) (discussing the role that defenses and competitive-effects analysis may play in a regulatory regime for digital platforms). 455 American Innovation and Choice Online Act, S. 2992, 117th Cong. § 3(a)(5) (2022) (Reported Version); American Innovation and Choice Online Act, H.R. 3816, 117th Cong. § 2(b)(2) (2021) (Reported Version). 456 Open App Markets Act, S. 2710, 117th Cong. § 3(a)(1) (2022) (Reported Version); Open App Markets Act, H.R. 7030, 117th Cong. § 3(a)(1) (2021); Open App Markets Act, H.R. 5017, 117th Cong. § 3(a)(1) (2021). 457 HOVENKAMP, supra note 70, at 435 (summarizing the test employed by most federal circuit courts of appeals). 458 Id. at 435-36. 459 See supra “The Designated-Platform Approach.” 460 S. 2710 § 2(3); H.R. 7030 § 2(3); H.R. 5017 § 2(3). Congressional Research Service 50 link to page 63 link to page 63 link to page 22 link to page 30 link to page 47 link to page 46 link to page 20 link to page 34 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Both bills also would have departed from the tying test employed by some federal courts of appeals that requires proof of anticompetitive effects.461 The AICOA’s tying prohibition would have instead offered defendants certain competition-related affirmative defenses.462 The OAMA’s enforcement would not have involved competitive-effects analysis.463 In addition to ties involving app stores and payment processors, the AICOA’s tying provision potentially would have implicated several of the other practices discussed above, including some of Google’s conduct in ad-tech markets and the link between favorable placement on Amazon’s marketplace and use of Amazon’s logistics service.464 Interoperability and Data Access Other proposals involve the ability of business users to interoperate with and access data they generate on covered platforms. The AICOA, for example, included an interoperability provision that would have prohibited covered platform operators from restricting or impeding the ability of business users to interoperate with features that are available to the operator’s own products or services.465 Among other conduct, the prohibition may have been directed at Facebook’s alleged refusal to allow certain app developers to access Facebook Platform and Apple’s alleged refusal to allow developers to access some APIs and device functionalities that are available to Apple’s apps.466 The OAMA also contained interoperability requirements. The bill would have required covered companies to allow users of their operating systems to install third-party apps and app stores through means other than the covered companies’ app stores.467 It also would have mandated that covered firms provide developers with access to operating-system interfaces, development information, and hardware and software features on terms that are functionally equivalent to those that covered firms offer to their own apps.468 The AICOA’s data-access provision would have prohibited covered platform operators from restricting or impeding a business user from accessing or transferring data generated by the user’s activities on a covered platform.469 Interoperability and data-portability issues are discussed in greater detail in “Interoperability & Data Portability” infra. 461 See, e.g., Kaufman v. Time Warner, 836 F.3d 137, 141 (2d Cir. 2016); Amey, Inc. v. Gulf Abstract & Title Inc., 758 F.2d 1486, 1503 (11th Cir. 1985); Driskill v. Dallas Cowboys Football Club, Inc., 498 F.2d 321, 323 (5th Cir. 1974). 462 American Innovation and Choice Online Act, S. 2992, 117th Cong. § 3(b)(2)(A) (2022) (Reported Version); American Innovation and Choice Online Act, H.R. 3816, 117th Cong. §§ 2(c)(1), (c)(3) (2021) (Reported Version). 463 S. 2710; H.R. 7030; H.R. 5017. 464 See supra “Google” & “Amazon.” The tying provision in the reported Senate version of the AICOA would not have barred ties involving products that are “part of or intrinsic to” a covered platform. S. 2992 § 3(a)(5). Some commentators have argued that this exception was vague and would likely be the subject of litigation. See Francis Testimony, supra note 405, at 68; ABA Letter, supra note 391, at 5-6. 465 S. 2992 § 3(a)(4); H.R. 3816 § 2(b)(1). 466 See supra “Meta Platforms” & “Apple.” 467 S. 2710 § 3(d)(2); H.R. 7030 § 3(d)(2); H.R. 5017 § 3(d)(2). 468 S. 2710 § 3(f); H.R. 7030 § 3(f); H.R. 5017 § 3(f). 469 S. 2992 § 3(a)(7); H.R. 3816 § 2(b)(4). Congressional Research Service 51 link to page 30 link to page 34 link to page 9 link to page 33 link to page 54 link to page 31 link to page 30 link to page 31 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Use of Nonpublic User Data As discussed, some Big Tech firms have been accused of using their access to user data to identify and imitate popular offerings. Amazon, for example, has allegedly used nonpublic user data to find profitable opportunities for its own private-label business.470 Apple has similarly been accused of using competitively sensitive information to replicate fast-growing apps and integrate certain functionalities into iOS.471 Some proposals would prohibit this conduct. Both the AICOA and OAMA included provisions that would have barred covered companies from using nonpublic data from dependent businesses to support their own offerings.472 This type of prohibition has been debated. Some commentators have argued that a platform operator’s imitation of rival products typically increases static efficiency by stimulating competition and lowering prices.473 Others have argued that a ban on the use of nonpublic data by platform operators would boost dynamic efficiency by protecting the incentives of other businesses to innovate.474 Most-Favored-Nation and Anti-Steering Policies Another general category of proposals involves platform restrictions of the activities of business users in other transaction venues. The reported House version of the AICOA would have prohibited covered platform operators from restricting a business user’s pricing of its products or services or its communications on a covered platform regarding other transaction options.475 Similarly, the OAMA would have barred covered companies from restricting developers from communicating with users about “legitimate business offers,” including pricing terms and product or service offerings.476 Some of the pricing restrictions targeted by the House version of the AICOA include most-favored-nation clauses (MFNs), which prohibit a platform’s business users from offering lower prices on rival platforms.477 Platform MFNs may make it difficult for rivals to compete with a dominant platform by charging lower commissions, because such clauses prevent business users from passing along those savings to consumers.478 The primary procompetitive benefit proffered in defense of MFNs involves concerns about free-riding. The basic worry is that, absent an MFN, consumers will use a highly functional platform to search for and compare products, but then make their purchases on a different 470 See supra “Amazon.” 471 See supra “Apple.” 472 S. 2992 § 3(a)(6); H.R. 3816 § 2(b)(3); S. 2710 § 3(c); H.R. 7030 § 3(c); H.R. 5017 § 3(c). 473 Francis, supra note 48, at 832; Hovenkamp, Platform Monopoly, supra note 279, at 2015; Sokol, supra note 454, at 102. 474 Andre Hagiu, Tat-How Teh & Julian Wright, Should Platforms Be Allowed to Sell on Their Own Marketplaces?, 53 RAND. J. ECON. 297, 32 (2022). 475 H.R. 3816 § 2(b)(6), (b)(8). 476 S. 2710 § 3(b); H.R. 7030 § 3(b); H.R. 5017 § 3(b). 477 Baker & Scott Morton, supra note 262, at 2181. As discussed, Amazon has faced a lawsuit challenging its pricing restrictions, though the nature of the relevant policies was disputed. See supra “Amazon.” 478 Baker & Scott Morton, supra note 262, at 2195 n.82. Platform MFNs may also facilitate collusion among sellers on a platform. Id. at 2182. Congressional Research Service 52 link to page 47 link to page 31 link to page 22 link to page 34 link to page 54 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms low-cost platform.479 Under those conditions, platforms may lack incentives to invest in expensive site features like an attractive design or effective comparison tools, even though those features benefit consumers.480 The literature has distinguished between “narrow” platform MFNs (which restrict a seller’s prices only on the seller’s own website) and “wide” platform MFNs (which restrict a seller’s prices on all other platforms).481 Some theoretical analyses have concluded that narrow MFNs are more likely to be procompetitive than wide MFNs.482 The reported House version of the AICOA would have prohibited both narrow and wide platform MFNs.483 Challenged restrictions would have escaped liability, however, if a platform operator established by clear and convincing evidence that its conduct would (1) not harm “the competitive process by restricting or impeding legitimate activity by business users,” or (2) increase “consumer welfare.”484 App Preinstallation The AICOA and OAMA also included provisions prohibiting covered firms from restricting or impeding the uninstallation of preinstalled apps or changing default settings that steer users to a covered firm’s own products or services.485 These prohibitions appeared to be directed at concerns that Google and Apple have leveraged control of their operating systems to favor their own apps and app stores.486 Though the bills did not explicitly prohibit the preinstallation of a covered firm’s proprietary apps, commentators have debated whether such preinstallation would run afoul of the AICOA’s general self-preferencing prohibition.487 Structural Separation and Line-of-Business Restrictions Several of the proposed rules discussed above respond to concerns that Big Tech firms face conflicts of interest when they operate both a digital platform and vertically related businesses that compete with platform users. The proposals sought to address those concerns by prohibiting specific categories of allegedly problematic conduct. One possible downside of this approach involves administrability. 479 Id. at 2183-84. 480 Id. at 2184. 481 Schnitzer, et al., supra note 405, at 18 n.12. 482 Baker & Scott Morton, supra note 262, at 2184 n.23 (citing examples). 483 American Innovation and Choice Online Act, H.R. 3816, 117th Cong. § 2(b)(8) (2021) (Reported Version). 484 Id. §§ 2(c)(1), (c)(3). 485 American Innovation and Choice Online Act, S. 2992, 117th Cong. § 3(a)(8) (2022) (Reported Version); H.R. 3816 § 2(b)(5); Open App Markets Act, S. 2710, 117th Cong. § 3(d)(1), (d)(3) (2022) (Reported Version); Open App Markets Act, H.R. 7030, 117th Cong. § 3(d)(1), (d)(3) (2021); Open App Markets Act, H.R. 5017, 117th Cong. § 3(d)(1), (d)(3) (2021). 486 See supra “Google” & “Apple.” 487 Compare Picker, supra note 453 (arguing that the AICOA’s self-preferencing prohibition may prohibit app preinstallation), with Hal Singer, Rep. Cicilline’s Nondiscrimination Bill Would Offer a Lifeline to Independent App Developers, PROMARKET (July 2, 2021), https://www.promarket.org/2021/07/02/antitrust-self-preferencing-preinstallation-app-developers-apple/ (arguing that the AICOA would not prohibit app preinstallation). Congressional Research Service 53 link to page 5 link to page 32 link to page 9 link to page 5 link to page 32 link to page 32 link to page 56 link to page 30 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms The worry is twofold. First, conduct rules require regulators to continuously monitor the behavior of covered firms.488 Second, as discussed, the availability of affirmative defenses means that rule enforcement may entail some of the same issues of cost and timeliness that have led to dissatisfaction with the existing antitrust framework.489 Based on these potential difficulties, some commentators have argued that structural restrictions have important advantages over behavioral rules.490 Such restrictions can take two general forms. Structural regulation could involve total separation, meaning firms would be prohibited from owning both a covered platform and a business that operates on that platform.491 Alternatively, regulations could mandate partial or functional separation, whereby firms would be required to house a covered platform and vertically related businesses in separate legal entities.492 There is precedent for these types of structural regulations, including in the railroad, banking, and telecommunications industries.493 In the 117th Congress, H.R. 3825 would have adopted a separations regime for covered platform operators.494 The bill would have prohibited covered platform operators from owning, controlling, or having a beneficial interest in a “line of business” that:  utilizes the covered platform for the sale or provision of products or services;  offers a product or service that the covered platform requires business users to purchase or utilize as a condition of accessing or receiving preferred placement on the platform; or  gives rise to a “conflict of interest.”495 The bill would have provided that “conflicts of interest” arise when a platform operator’s ownership or control of another “line of business” creates the incentive and ability for its platform to (1) advantage the platform operator’s products or services over those of competitors, or (2) exclude or disadvantage the products or services of competitors.496 These types of proposals have generated debate. Critics of separation requirements have argued that a platform’s entry into new markets typically benefits consumers.497 For example, by selling its own private-label products on its marketplace, Amazon may offer consumers low-cost 488 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 381; Khan, Platforms and Commerce, supra note 274, at 1036. 489 See, e.g., Francis, supra note 48, at 823-24. 490 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 381; Khan, Platforms and Commerce, supra note 274, at 1036; see also Rory Van Loo, In Defense of Breakups: Administering a “Radical” Remedy, 105 CORNELL L. REV. 1955, 2007 (2020) (arguing that breakups may be preferable to access remedies in certain circumstances). 491 Khan, Platforms and Commerce, supra note 274, at 1052. 492 Id. 493 Id. at 1037-43, 1045-51. 494 Ending Platform Monopolies Act, H.R. 3825, 117th Cong. (2021). 495 Id. § 2(a). 496 Id. § 2(b). In the 117th Congress, S. 1204 would have also imposed structural separation requirements on large online marketplaces, exchanges, and search engines. Bust Up Big Tech Act, S. 1204, 117th Cong. § 2 (2021). 497 Hagiu, et al., supra note 474, at 319; Herbert J. Hovenkamp, The Looming Crisis in Antitrust Economics, 101 B.U. L. REV. 489, 541 (2021) [hereinafter “Hovenkamp, Looming Crisis”]; Giuseppe Colangelo, Evaluating the Case for Regulation of Digital Platforms, in GLOBAL ANTITRUST INSTITUTE REPORT ON THE DIGITAL ECONOMY 905 (2020); Thomas A. Lambert, The Case Against Legislative Reform of U.S. Antitrust Doctrine 21-22 (Univ. of Mo. Sch. of L. Legal Studies, Research Paper No. 2020-13, 2020), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3598601; Todd, supra note 249, at 524-25. Congressional Research Service 54 link to page 58 link to page 30 link to page 30 link to page 39 link to page 32 link to page 32 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms alternatives to established brands.498 Integration into related business lines may also create efficiencies.499 Apple and Google, for instance, may be well-positioned to produce apps and app stores for their respective operating systems, as well as related devices like earphones and smart watches.500 Separation requirements may also face line-drawing difficulties. The boundary between a covered platform and separate services is not always clear.501 For example, Apple produces many apps and functionalities—including a voice assistant (Siri), a camera app, and a payment system (Apple Pay)—that are integrated with its iOS operating system to various degrees.502 Whether these services would qualify as “lines of business” that are distinct from iOS may be uncertain; H.R. 3825 did not define that term. Because tech platforms regularly add new functionalities to their primary services, some observers have argued that an absence of clarity surrounding permissible activities may deter innovation and thereby harm consumers.503 Proponents of separation requirements have acknowledged these criticisms. In response, they have argued that the innovation benefits of an equal playing field would likely outweigh any losses in static efficiency that result from the elimination of a platform operator’s downward pricing pressure in adjacent markets.504 In addition, advocates of separation rules contend that any decreases in platform innovation caused by such rules must be weighed against likely increases in innovation by platform users.505 The arguments in favor of broad separation requirements have thus focused on innovation policy, in addition to the foreclosure concerns that sound in traditional antitrust analysis. Mergers & Acquisitions Substantive Merger Law Other proposals target Big Tech mergers. In the 117th Congress, H.R. 3826 would have prohibited covered platform operators from acquiring other firms unless they could demonstrate by clear and convincing evidence that a target does not:  compete with the platform operator; 498 Hovenkamp, Looming Crisis, supra note 497, at 541 (“Many of the brands that compete with Amazon’s own brands are sold by large firms, often at margins that are significantly higher than Amazon’s margins. . . . Forcibly separating Amazon’s brands from the offerings of these companies will almost certainly reduce downward pricing pressure on these national name brands, resulting in higher prices for consumers.”). 499 See, e.g., Todd, supra note 249, at 514-17. 500 Randy Picker, The House’s Recent Spate of Antitrust Bills Would Change Big Tech as We Know It, PROMARKET (June 29, 2021), https://www.promarket.org/2021/06/29/house-antitrust-bills-big-tech-apple-preinstallation/. 501 Carl Shapiro, Protecting Competition in the American Economy: Merger Control, Tech Titans, Labor Markets, 33 J. ECON. PERSPS. 69, 84 (2019); Hal Singer, Inside Tech’s “Kill Zone”: How to Deal With the Threat to Edge Innovation Posed by Multi-Sided Platforms, PROMARKET (Nov. 21, 2018), https://www.promarket.org/2018/11/21/inside-tech-kill-zone/. 502 Todd, supra note 249, at 536. 503 E.g., Rogerson & Shelanski, supra note 342, at 1934. 504 Khan, Platforms and Commerce, supra note 274, at 1085; see also Feng Zhu & Qihong Liu, Competing with Complementors: An Empirical Look at Amazon.com, 39 STRATEGIC MGMT. J. 2168 (2018) (concluding that, while Amazon’s entry into a new market typically reduces prices, it may also reduce the number of innovative products on Amazon’s marketplace by discouraging participation by third-party sellers). 505 Khan, Platforms and Commerce, supra note 274, at 1085. Congressional Research Service 55 link to page 15 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 38 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms  constitute “nascent or potential competition” for the platform operator;  enhance or increase the platform operator’s market position with respect to products or services offered on or directly related to a covered platform; or  enhance or increase the platform operator’s ability to maintain its market position with respect to products or services offered on or directly related to a covered platform.506 The reported version of the bill included an amendment that would have exempted transactions of less than $50 million from the prohibition.507 For transactions of $50 million or greater, then, the bill would have prohibited Big Tech firms from engaging in horizontal mergers, mergers involving “nascent or potential” competitors, and vertical and conglomerate mergers that enhance, increase, or help maintain their market positions with respect to products or services “offered on or directly related” to a covered platform. As drafted, the bill raised three issues. The first involved the legislation’s prohibition of acquisitions involving “potential” competitors.508 As discussed, antitrust doctrine has recognized two theories of harm in potential-competition cases: the elimination of perceived potential competition and the elimination of actual potential competition.509 Courts have identified prerequisites for both theories.510 The relationship between those prerequisites and H.R. 3826’s requirement that a Big Tech platform show that a target firm is not a “potential” competitor may have generated complex legal questions, if the bill had become law. For example, the bill could have been read to allow platform operators to make such a showing by negating an element of both types of potential-competition claims.511 That is not, however, the only interpretive option; the details surrounding the relevant burden would have had to be fleshed out in practice. That the Supreme Court has recognized only the perceived-potential-competition theory might have complicated this inquiry. The second issue concerned the bill’s prohibition of Big Tech acquisitions involving “nascent” competitors.512 Commentators have offered different definitions of the concept of “nascent” competition.513 In general, however, the term has been used to refer to new technologies with uncertain prospects that nevertheless pose serious threats to an incumbent.514 506 Platform Competition and Opportunity Act of 2021, H.R. 3826, 117th Cong. § 2(b)(2) (2021). The bill would have also excluded certain categories of transactions that are exempt from pre-merger filing requirements for reasons other than their size. Id. § 2(b)(1). 507 Amendment to the Amendment in the Nature of a Substitute to H.R. 3826 Offered by Ms. Ross of North Carolina, Markups, H.R. 3843, the Merger Filing Fee Modernization Act of 2021, et al., H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 117th Cong. (June 24, 2021), https://docs.house.gov/meetings/JU/JU00/20210623/112818/BILLS-117-HR3826-R000305-Amdt-1.pdf. 508 H.R. 3826 § 2(b)(2)(B). 509 See supra “Conglomerate Mergers.” 510 Id. 511 Under the bill, such efforts would be subject to a clear-and-convincing-evidence standard. H.R. 3826 § 2(b). 512 Id. § 2(b)(2)(B). 513 Yun, supra note 334, at 626 (“Amongst antitrust practitioners and scholars, various definitions have emerged for nascent competition”); Hemphill & Wu, supra note 334, at 1881 (“Nascent competition means different things to different people.”). 514 United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 79 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (per curiam); Yun, supra note 334, at 626-27; Hemphill & Wu, supra note 334, at 1886-88; Tracy J. Penfield & Molly Pallman, Looking Ahead: Nascent Competitor Congressional Research Service 56 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 38 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Despite posing such threats, acquisitions of “nascent” competitors may be difficult to challenge under existing law. As discussed, to prevail under an actual-potential-competition theory, a plaintiff must establish a “substantial likelihood” that a target firm would deconcentrate the relevant market or produce other procompetitive benefits.515 In cases involving unproven or developing technology, that burden could prove problematic for a plaintiff. H.R. 3826 was a response to this doctrinal difficulty.516 While the bill thus sought to address an issue that has generated considerable attention, the analytical framework that would govern inquiries into “nascent” competition remains unsettled. There is little case law addressing issues of “nascent” competition in the merger context.517 Accordingly, H.R. 3826 would have leaned on the courts to develop standards for evaluating whether a firm constituted a “nascent” competitor of a covered platform. The third issue raised by H.R. 3826 involved the breadth of the provisions prohibiting mergers that “enhance or increase” a platform operator’s market position or ability to maintain its market position.518 By their terms, these prohibitions did not distinguish between procompetitive mergers and anticompetitive mergers. As drafted, the bill thus appeared to prohibit mergers that “enhance or increase” a Big Tech platform’s market position by improving the quality of its products or services, even when the target company is not a competitor, potential competitor, or nascent competitor of the platform. As a result, H.R. 3826 may have limited Big Tech platforms to in-house development or licensing of complementary technologies; acquisitions of firms that could enhance a platform’s core offerings would have likely been off-limits. S. 1074—another bill in the 117th Congress—would have taken a similarly strict approach toward Big Tech mergers.519 Among other things, S. 1074 would have prohibited companies designated as “dominant digital firms” from engaging in acquisitions valued at more than $1 million.520 Acquisition Challenges in the “TechLash” Era, ANTITRUST SOURCE 2 (June 2020), https://www.americanbar.org/content/dam/aba/publishing/antitrust-magazine-online/2020/june-2020/jun20_penfield_6_17f.pdf. 515 United States v. Marine Bancorporation, Inc., 418 U.S. 602, 633 (1974). 516 There is an ongoing debate within the antitrust community as to whether Section 2 of the Sherman Act provides a more attractive vehicle for challenging acquisitions of nascent competitors than Section 7 of the Clayton Act. Compare Hemphill & Wu, supra note 334, at 1896-1901 (discussing the advantages of Section 2); Melamed, supra note 334, at 6-7 (similar), with Scott Sher, Keith Klovers & John Ceccio, Nascent Competition, Section 2, and the Agencies’ Quixotic Quest to Avoid the Potential Competition Doctrine, ANTITRUST MAGAZINE ONLINE (Aug. 2021), https://www.americanbar.org/content/dam/aba/publishing/antitrust-magazine-online/august-2021/atonline-sher.pdf (arguing that Section 2 is less stringent than Section 7 as applied to mergers); Jonathan Jacobson & Christopher Mufarrige, Acquisitions of “Nascent” Competitors, ANTITRUST SOURCE 5-6 (Aug. 2020), https://www.americanbar.org/content/dam/aba/publishing/antitrust-magazine-online/2020/august-2020/aug20_full_source.pdf (similar). Both approaches remain largely untested. 517 See, e.g., Yun, supra note 334, at 635 (“A considerable downside to bringing a nascent competition case under [Section] 7 is that there are no court precedents for doing so. . . . Consequently, a court would need to develop new conditions and requirements to find a violation, which is certainly a major impediment to applying the nascent competition doctrine in [Section] 7 cases.”). 518 Platform Competition and Opportunity Act of 2021, H.R. 3826, 117th Cong. § 2(b)(2)(C)-(D) (2021). 519 Trust-Busting for the Twenty-First Century Act, S. 1074, 117th Cong. § 4 (2021). 520 Id. Congressional Research Service 57 link to page 38 link to page 20 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 62 link to page 62 link to page 61 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 38 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Other proposals are more limited. Several commentators, for example, have advocated a requirement that Big Tech firms bear the burden of proving that their mergers would not harm competition.521 Abstracting from specific policy options, the debate over special merger rules for Big Tech firms has focused on two general concerns. First, opponents of such rules have argued that Big Tech mergers are typically benign or procompetitive.522 Acquisitions of complementary technologies, for example, may reduce the transaction costs associated with licensing arrangements or allow for more efficient integration with a platform’s offerings.523 Mergers may also stimulate competition among Big Tech firms by giving them an attractive means of entering or expanding within each other’s core markets.524 Second, some have argued that limitations on Big Tech mergers may reduce startup investment by eliminating a popular exit route for venture investors and other entrepreneurs.525 Proponents of special merger rules for tech platforms have responded that the procompetitive benefits of tech mergers are often overstated.526 Merger limitations targeting a handful of prospective acquirers may also leave startup investors with enough viable exit options to mitigate concerns about dampened investment. Some commentators have also suggested that reducing investment in innovations that end up in the hands of dominant incumbents is the intended outcome of the relevant proposals.527 The Merger Review Process Before moving on from mergers, one final topic warrants mention: the Hart-Scott-Rodino (HSR) premerger review process. Under the HSR Act, parties to mergers that exceed certain thresholds must report their transactions to the DOJ and FTC and abide by specified waiting periods before closing.528 This process gives the agencies the opportunity to review proposed mergers for antitrust concerns and seek relief before deals are consummated. Some commentators have expressed concerns about the number of Big Tech mergers that fall below the relevant thresholds and thus evade HSR review.529 In September 2021, the FTC 521 STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 98, 111; ACCC Report, supra note 162, at 109; see also OECD STARTUP ACQUISITION REPORT, supra note 334, at 38-41 (cataloguing various rebuttable-presumption proposals). 522 Samuel Bowman & Sam Dumitriu, Better Together: The Procompetitive Effects of Mergers in Tech, INT’L CTR. FOR L. & ECON. (Oct. 1, 2021), https://laweconcenter.org/resources/better-together-the-procompetitive-effects-of-mergers-in-tech/?doing_wp_cron=1676398306.5821518898010253906250; UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 333, at 101 (concluding that regulators should adopt a “balance of harms” approach to platform mergers instead of a presumption of illegality because “the majority of acquisitions by large digital companies are likely to be either benign or beneficial for consumers”). 523 Bowman & Dumitriu, supra note 522; A. Douglas Melamed & Nicolas Petit, The Misguided Assault on the Consumer Welfare Standard in the Age of Platform Markets, 54 REV. OF INDUS. ORG. 741, 754 (2019). 524 Bowman & Dumitriu, supra note 522. 525 Gary Dushnitsky & D. Daniel Sokol, Mergers, Antitrust, and the Interplay of Entrepreneurial Activity and the Investments That Fund It, 24 VAND. J. OF ENT. & TECH. L. 255 (2022); Jacobson & Mufarrige, supra note 516, at 10; UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 333, at 101. 526 John M. Newman, Antitrust in Digital Markets, 72 VAND. L. REV. 1497, 1541 (2019). 527 Hemphill & Wu, supra note 334, at 1893. 528 15 U.S.C. § 18a. 529 STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 111. Congressional Research Service 58 link to page 37 link to page 5 link to page 41 link to page 5 link to page 38 link to page 38 link to page 5 link to page 38 link to page 39 link to page 21 link to page 63 link to page 63 link to page 39 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms released a report indicating that the four Big Tech firms discussed in this report and Microsoft together engaged in 819 non-reportable deals between 2010 and 2019.530 In response to worries about these transactions, some have supported a blanket HSR filing requirement for Big Tech acquisitions.531 Opponents of such a rule have argued that it would be burdensome and offer few benefits for regulators.532 Interoperability & Data Portability Network effects and switching costs are frequent themes in discussions of Big Tech.533 Some reform proposals seek to address these structural features of certain platform markets by imposing interoperability and data-portability obligations on designated platform operators.534 In broad strokes, interoperability refers to the ability of distinct services to work together and communicate with one another.535 Interoperability can develop organically—as with email and many patent pools—or as a result of a legal mandate.536 Examples in the latter category include the 1996 Telecommunications Act’s requirement that local exchange carriers interconnect with other providers.537 The DOJ’s 2002 monopolization settlement with Microsoft also included an interoperability provision prohibiting Microsoft from excluding other firms’ web browsers from its Windows operating system.538 These types of measures seek to lower the entry barriers associated with networked industries by shifting network effects from individual firms to the market as a whole, thus making them available to nascent and potential competitors of a dominant incumbent.539 Data portability, by contrast, refers to a consumer’s right to move his or her data from one platform to another.540 Telecommunications law again offers an example by granting phone users the right to retain their phone numbers when they change carriers.541 Such requirements decrease the switching costs that might otherwise discourage consumers from taking their business to a more attractive provider.542 530 FTC NON-REPORTABLE ACQUISITIONS STUDY, supra note 332, at 10. 531 HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 388. 532 ABA DIGITAL ECONOMY REPORT, supra note 358, at 16. 533 See, e.g., HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 40-42; STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 38-39, 109; UK DIGITAL COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 333, at 35-36. 534 OECD, DATA PORTABILITY, INTEROPERABILITY AND DIGITAL PLATFORM COMPETITION (2021), https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/data-portability-interoperability-and-digital-platform-competition-2021.pdf [hereinafter “OECD INTEROPERABILITY REPORT”]; HJC REPORT, supra note 11, at 384-86; STIGLER REPORT, supra note 333, at 109-10, 113; see also Kades & Scott Morton, supra note 345 (advocating interoperability remedies in antitrust litigation involving tech platforms). 535 Ezrielev & Marquez, supra note 167, at 9; OECD INTEROPERABILITY REPORT, supra note 534, at 12. 536 Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Interoperability Remedies, 123 COLUM. L. REV. F. 1, 10 (2023) [hereinafter “Hovenkamp, Interoperability Remedies”]. 537 47 U.S.C. § 251(c). 538 United States v. Microsoft Corp., 215 F. Supp. 2d 1 (D.D.C. 2002). For other examples of antitrust cases in which interoperability has been used as a remedy, see Hovenkamp, Interoperability Remedies, supra note 536, at 13 n.74. 539 Kades & Scott Morton, supra note 345, at 41-42; Becky Chao & Ross Schulman, Promoting Platform Interoperability, NEW AM. FDN. 21-22 (May 2020). 540 Michal S. Gal & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Data Standardization, 94 NYU L. REV. 737, 739 (2019). 541 47 U.S.C. § 251(b)(2). 542 Juan Pablo Maicas, et al., Reducing the Level of Switching Costs in Mobile Communications: The Case of Mobile Congressional Research Service 59 link to page 55 link to page 47 link to page 39 link to page 39 link to page 63 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms In the 117th Congress, H.R. 3849 would have imposed interoperability and data-portability duties on designated digital platforms.543 The bill would have directed the FTC to develop standards implementing those duties for individual covered platforms.544 In promulgating standards under the legislation, the FTC would have been advised by technical committees that included representatives of a platform’s competitors, competition and privacy-advocacy organizations, the National Institute of Standards and Technology, and covered platforms.545 The obligations contemplated by H.R. 3849 were potentially broader than those in the AICOA, which were discussed earlier in this report.546 The AICOA’s interoperability provision would have prohibited a covered platform operator from restricting the ability of business users to interoperate with features that are available to the operator’s own products or services.547 Accordingly, the prohibition would have been limited to a platform operator’s unequal treatment of firms that utilize its platform.548 In contrast, H.R. 3849 would have granted the FTC rulemaking authority to impose potentially broader, platform-specific interoperability obligations.549 For a social network like Facebook, an interoperability rule might have included duties to allow users of other networks to “friend” Facebook users and transmit posted content from Facebook to other networks.550 Supporters of interoperability have argued that these types of obligations would catalyze competition by allowing users of upstart social networks to benefit from Facebook’s scale.551 H.R. 3849’s data-portability provision was also potentially broader than the parallel requirement in the AICOA. While the AICOA’s requirement would have applied only to a platform’s business users,552 H.R. 3849’s data-portability obligation would have encompassed individuals who use a covered platform.553 A rule implementing this duty might have required a social network like Facebook to keep a user’s messages, photos, and other content in an accessible format that could be transferred to other platforms.554 Although this type of requirement may have partially overlapped with the ongoing transferability contemplated by H.R. 3849’s interoperability mandate, it could also have Number Portability, 33 TELECOMMS. POL’Y 544 (2009). 543 ACCESS Act of 2021, H.R. 3849, 117th Cong. §§ 3-4 (2021). 544 Id. § 6(c). 545 Id. § 7. 546 See supra “Interoperability and Data Access.” 547 American Innovation and Choice Online Act, S. 2992, 117th Cong. § 3(a)(4) (2022) (Reported Version); American Innovation and Choice Online Act, H.R. 3816, 117th Cong. § 2(b)(1) (2021) (Reported Version). 548 The reported House version of the AICOA also included a broader provision that prohibited covered platform operators from restricting a business user’s ability to interoperate with “any product or service.” H.R. 3816 § 2(b)(9). 549 ACCESS Act of 2021, H.R. 3849, 117th Cong. §§ 4, 6 (2021); see also Schnitzer, et al., supra note 405, at 22 (contrasting the AICOA’s interoperability provision with the “general interoperability requirement” in H.R. 3849). 550 Kades & Scott Morton, supra note 345, at 16; Transcript of Markup of H.R. 3843, the Merger Filing Fee Modernization Act, et al., at 48,832-48,835 (June 23, 2021) (on file with author) [hereinafter “H.R. 3849 Markup Transcript”] (Rep. Mary Gay Scanlon) (“Much like texting allows iPhone owners to communicate with Android owners, so, too, would [H.R. 3849] allow individuals switching to new social media platforms to be able to communicate and interact with their friends and family on Facebook.”). 551 Kades & Scott Morton, supra note 345, at 9. 552 S. 2992 § 3(a)(4); H.R. 3816 § 2(b)(1). 553 H.R. 3849 § 3. 554 Hovenkamp, Interoperability Remedies, supra note 536, at 27. Congressional Research Service 60 link to page 64 link to page 63 link to page 63 link to page 63 link to page 21 link to page 11 link to page 46 link to page 21 link to page 39 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms included categories of data not subject to continuous real-time interoperability for technical or other reasons.555 Data-portability rules may likewise require Amazon to allow retailers on its marketplace to port their customer reviews to rival e-commerce platforms and Apple to permit iPhone users to transfer their message histories to an Android device.556 Objections to interoperability and data-portability mandates take several forms. Some have highlighted the complexity of interoperability requirements, which may pose challenges of implementation and enforcement.557 Others have focused on possible privacy and data-security risks that might accompany both interoperability and data-portability rules.558 H.R. 3849 attempted to address complexity concerns by directing the FTC to establish technical committees to assist with rule development.559 The bill sought to mitigate privacy and data-security risks by imposing data-security requirements on firms that interoperate with or receive ported data from a covered platform.560 Another category of criticism directed at interoperability requirements involves innovation concerns. Some have worried that interoperability may result in homogenized markets as an incumbent’s rivals coalesce around a single set of standards.561 Compelled interoperability also potentially implicates the free-rider problems that motivate narrow duty-to-deal doctrine: by requiring firms to share the fruits of their innovation with competitors, policymakers may dampen incentives to invest in new products.562 Defenders of interoperability have acknowledged this risk, but maintain that interoperating Big Tech platforms would still face incentives to innovate to prevent rivals from gaining a competitive edge.563 Changes to General Antitrust While the proposals discussed above would entail special competition rules for large tech platforms, other options involve changes to general antitrust law. Because general antitrust reform is a vast topic, this report does not attempt an exhaustive overview of the relevant proposals. Instead, it briefly reviews selected bills involving exclusionary conduct and merger law. 555 See id. (arguing that “dynamic” interoperability for social networks might be technically difficult and that the “static” interoperability offered by data portability may thus be a more promising option). 556 H.R. 3849 Markup Transcript, supra note 550, at 4,564-4,568 (Rep. David Cicilline). 557 See, e.g., Hovenkamp, Interoperability Remedies, supra note 536, at 35; Randy Picker, Forcing Interoperability on Tech Platforms Would Be Difficult to Do, PROMARKET (Mar. 11, 2021), https://www.promarket.org/2021/03/11/interoperability-tech-platforms-1996-telecommunications-act/. 558 See, e.g., Laura Alexander & Randy Stutz, Interoperability in Antitrust Law & Competition Policy, COMPETITION POLICY INT’L ANTITRUST CHRON. 31, 36 (June 2021); OECD INTEROPERABILITY REPORT, supra note 534, at 24; Peter Swire & Yianni Lagos, Swire & Yianni Lagos, Why the Right to Data Portability Likely Reduces Consumer Welfare: Antitrust and
Privacy Critiques
Critique, 72 MD. L. REV. 335, , 72 MD. L. REV. 335, 348365-75 (2013). 559 ACCESS Act of 2021, H.R. 3849, 117th Cong. § 6 (2021). 560 Id. §§ 3(b), 4(b). 561 Hovenkamp, Interoperability Remedies, supra note 536, at 35; Ezrielev & Marquez, supra note 167, at 10-11. 562 See, e.g., FUMAGALLI, et al., supra note 73, at 547; ABA Letter, supra note 391, at 14; Ezrielev & Marquez, supra note 167, at 10-11; Howard A. Shelanski, Unilateral Refusals to Deal in Intellectual and Other Property, 76 ANTITRUST L.J. 369, 371 (2009). 563 Kades & Scott Morton, supra note 345, at 26. Congressional Research Service 61 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Exclusionary Conduct S. 225, the Competition and Antitrust Law Enforcement Reform Act (117th Cong.) In the 117th Congress, S. 225 would have made several changes to the legal framework governing exclusionary-conduct claims.564 The bill would have amended the Clayton Act to prohibit “exclusionary conduct that presents an appreciable risk of harming competition.”565 “Exclusionary conduct” would have been defined to mean conduct that (1) “materially disadvantages” an actual or potential competitor, or (2) “tends to foreclose or limit” the ability of an actual or potential competitor to compete.566 S. 225 would have adopted a presumption that exclusionary conduct presents “an appreciable risk of harming competition” if it is undertaken by a firm with a market share of greater than 50 percent or that otherwise has “significant market power” in the relevant market.567 That presumption could be rebutted, however, if a defendant established by a preponderance of the evidence that: 1. “distinct procompetitive benefits of the exclusionary conduct in the relevant market eliminate the risk of harming competition presented by the exclusionary conduct”; 2. another firm has “entered or expanded their presence in the market with the effect of eliminating the risk of harming competition posed by the exclusionary conduct”; or 3. “the exclusionary conduct does not present an appreciable risk of harming competition.”568 The bill would have provided that several of the conduct-specific tests that courts have adopted in Sherman Act cases would not apply to exclusionary-conduct claims under the amended Clayton Act. Among other things, exclusionary-conduct plaintiffs would not have to show:  that a defendant terminated a prior course of dealing,569 which some courts have held is a prerequisite for refusal-to-deal liability under the Sherman Act;570  that the defendant priced its products below its costs or is likely to recoup losses from below-cost pricing,571 which are both requirements for predatory-pricing claims under the Sherman Act;572 or 564 Competition and Antitrust Law Enforcement Reform Act of 2021, S. 225, 117th Cong. §§ 9, 13 (2021). 565 Id. § 9. 566 Id. 567 Id. 568 Id. 569 Id. 570 E.g., Novell, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp., 731 F.3d 1064, 1075 (10th Cir. 2013) (Gorsuch, J.). 571 Competition and Antitrust Law Enforcement Reform Act of 2021, S. 225, 117th Cong. § 9 (2021). 572 Brooke Grp. Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 222-24 (1993). Congressional Research Service 62 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms  that the conduct of a multi-sided platform presents an appreciable risk of harming competition on more than one side of the platform,573 contrary to the rule the Supreme Court adopted for two-sided transaction platforms in Amex.574 S. 225 also would have provided that market definition is not necessary to prove an antitrust violation, except in cases where the applicable statute includes the phrase “relevant market,” “market concentration,” or “market share.”575 S. 1074, the Trust-Busting for the Twenty-First Century Act (117th Cong.) S. 1074—another bill in the 117th Congress—also would have made changes to the standards governing exclusionary-conduct claims.576 The legislation would have provided that, in litigation under Section 1 or Section 2 of the Sherman Act, a defendant that relies upon procompetitive effects to justify its conduct must establish by clear and convincing evidence that: 1. the relevant procompetitive effects “clearly outweigh” any anticompetitive effects; and 2. the defendant “could not obtain substantially similar procompetitive effects through commercially reasonable alternatives that would involve materially lower competitive risks.”577 Like S. 225, the bill would have provided that market definition is not required to prove a violation of Section 1 or Section 2.578 Mergers S. 225, the Competition and Antitrust Law Enforcement Reform Act (117th Cong.) In addition to the exclusionary-conduct provisions discussed above, S. 225 would have modified several aspects of merger law. The bill would have amended Section 7 of the Clayton Act to prohibit mergers that “create an appreciable risk of materially lessening” competition579—a change from the current language that prohibits mergers that may “substantially” lessen competition.580 The term “materially” was defined to mean “more than a de minimis amount.”581 S. 225 also would have shifted the relevant burden of proof to the merging parties in certain circumstances.582 For example, merging parties would have had the burden of proving that their transactions would not “create an appreciable risk of materially lessening” competition in cases where: 573 S. 225 § 9. 574 Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2286-87 (2018). 575 S. 225 § 13(a). 576 Trust-Busting for the Twenty-First Century Act, S. 1074, 117th Cong. § 2 (2021). 577 Id. 578 Id. 579 S. 225 § 4(b)(1). 580 15 U.S.C. § 18. 581 S. 225 § 4(b)(3). 582 Id. Congressional Research Service 63 link to page 59 link to page 14 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms  a merger would lead to a “significant increase in market concentration”;  a firm with a market share greater than 50 percent or that possesses “significant market power” acquires a competitor or a company that has a “reasonable probability” of becoming a competitor;  a transaction is valued at more than $5 billion; or  the acquiring firm has assets, net revenue, or a market capitalization exceeding $100 billion and the transaction is valued at $50 million or more.583 S. 1074, the Trust-Busting for the Twenty-First Century Act (117th Cong.) S. 1074 also included merger restrictions.584 The bill would have prohibited firms with market capitalizations exceeding $100 billion from engaging in mergers whose effect “may be to lessen competition in any way.”585 It also would have explicitly provided that market definition is not necessary to block a merger and that mergers shall not be presumed to be legal on the grounds that the parties are not direct competitors.586 S. 3847, the Prohibiting Anticompetitive Mergers Act (117th Cong.) In the 117th Congress, S. 3847 would have taken a similarly skeptical approach to large mergers. The legislation would have prohibited mergers valued at more than $5 billion, mergers that result in a market share of over 33 percent for sellers or 25 percent for employers, and mergers that would result in specified levels of market concentration.587 S. 3847 also would have made changes to the merger-review process.588 Among other things, the bill would have extended the initial HSR waiting period from 30 days to 120 days and allowed the antitrust agencies to block mergers without obtaining a court order.589 In addition, the bill would have directed the DOJ and FTC to review mergers consummated after January 1, 2000, if they would have qualified as “prohibited mergers” under the categories mentioned above.590 It would have further required the agencies to pursue remedies to restore competition or address the anticompetitive effects of these mergers in specified circumstances.591 583 Id. 584 S. 1074 contained both size-based merger restrictions and merger restrictions that would have applied to companies designated as “dominant digital firms.” Trust-Busting for the Twenty-First Century Act, S. 1074, 117th Cong. §§ 3, 4 (2021). The latter are discussed in supra “Substantive Merger Law.” 585 S. 1074 § 3. 586 Id. 587 Prohibiting Anticompetitive Mergers Act of 2022, S. 3847, 117th Cong. § 3 (2022). The market-concentration prohibition would have barred mergers that would (1) result in a Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) of greater than 1,800, and (2) increase the relevant HHI by more than 100 points. Id. A market with an HHI of 1,800 qualifies as “moderately concentrated” under the current Horizontal Merger Guidelines, but would have been deemed to be “highly concentrated” under the 1992 version of the Guidelines. HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 100, at § 5.3; DEP’T OF JUSTICE AND FED. TRADE COMM’N, 1992 MERGER GUIDELINES § 1.5 (1992). 588 S. 3847 § 4(b). 589 Id. 590 Id. § 6. 591 Id. Congressional Research Service 64 Antitrust Reform and Big Tech Firms Author Information Jay B. Sykes Legislative Attorney (2013).
111 See Randy Picker, Forcing Interoperability on Tech Platforms Would Be Difficult to Do, PROMARKET (Mar. 11,
2021), https://promarket.org/2021/03/11/interoperability-tech-platforms-1996-telecommunications-act/.
112 See Verizon Commc’ns v. FCC, 535 U.S. 467 (2002); AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 525 U.S. 366 (1999).
113 Gus Hurwitz, Digital Duty to Deal, Data Portability, and Interoperability, in REPORT ON THE DIGITAL ECONOMY,
GEO. MASON U. GLOBAL ANTITRUST INST. (2020).
114 See id.; see also CRANE, supra note 51, at 172 (“Economists and antitrust scholars increasingly view static consumer
injuries as far less significant than dynamic injuries.”); JOSEPH SCHUMPETER, CAPITALISM, SOCIALISM, AND DEMOCRACY
84-85 (1942).
115 Hurwitz, supra note 113. For an argument that interoperability can promote dynamic competition, see Brian
Feldman, U.S. v. Microsoft Proved That Antitrust Can Keep Tech Power in Check, N.Y. MAGAZINE (Dec. 12, 2017),
https://nymag.com/intelligencer/2017/12/u-s-v-microsoft-proved-that-antitrust-can-check-tech-power.html.
Congressional Research Service
17

The Big Tech Antitrust Bills



Disclaimer
This document was prepared by the Congressional Research Service (CRS). CRS serves as nonpartisan This document was prepared by the Congressional Research Service (CRS). CRS serves as nonpartisan
shared staff to congressional committees and Members of Congress. It operates solely at the behest of and shared staff to congressional committees and Members of Congress. It operates solely at the behest of and
under the direction of Congress. Information in a CRS Report should not be relied upon for purposes other under the direction of Congress. Information in a CRS Report should not be relied upon for purposes other
than public understanding of information that has been provided by CRS to Members of Congress in than public understanding of information that has been provided by CRS to Members of Congress in
connection with CRS’s institutional role. CRS Reports, as a work of the United States Government, are not connection with CRS’s institutional role. CRS Reports, as a work of the United States Government, are not
subject to copyright protection in the United States. Any CRS Report may be reproduced and distributed in subject to copyright protection in the United States. Any CRS Report may be reproduced and distributed in
its entirety without permission from CRS. However, as a CRS Report may include copyrighted images or its entirety without permission from CRS. However, as a CRS Report may include copyrighted images or
material from a third party, you may need to obtain the permission of the copyright holder if you wish to material from a third party, you may need to obtain the permission of the copyright holder if you wish to
copy or otherwise use copyrighted material. copy or otherwise use copyrighted material.

Congressional Research Service Congressional Research Service
R46875 R46875 · VERSION 1 · NEW
185 · UPDATED 65