< Back to Current Version

Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit

Changes from December 20, 2013 to March 24, 2014

This page shows textual changes in the document between the two versions indicated in the dates above. Textual matter removed in the later version is indicated with red strikethrough and textual matter added in the later version is indicated with blue.


Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit James K. Jackson Specialist in International Trade and Finance December 23, 2013March 24, 2014 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov RL33274 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Summary The U.S. merchandise trade deficit is a part of the overall U.S. balance of payments, a summary statement of all economic transactions between the residents of the United States and the rest of the world, during a given period of time. Some Members of Congress and other observers have grown concerned over the magnitude of the U.S. merchandise trade deficit and the associated increase in U.S. dollar-denominated assets owned by foreigners. International trade recovered from the global financial crisis of 2008-2009 and the subsequent slowdown in global economic activity that reduced global trade flows and, consequently, reduced the size of the U.S. trade deficit. Now, however, U.S. exporters face new challenges with economies in Europe and Asia confronting increased risks of a second phase of slow growth. This report provides an overview of the U.S. balance of payments, an explanation of the broader role of capital flows in the U.S. economy, an explanation of how the country finances its trade deficit or a trade surplus, and the implications for Congress and the country of the large inflows of capital from abroad. The major observations indicate that • Foreign private investors increased their net purchases of U.S. Treasury securities in 2013 by nearly 30% over the amount they purchases in 2012. During the same period, foreign private investors reduced their net purchases of U.S. corporate stocks, but increased their net purchases of corporate bonds, likely reflecting the growth in corporate profits. During 2013, foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasury securities fell by almost half from the amount purchased in 2012. The purchases of U.S. Treasury securities in 2012, although at a slower rate than in 2011 after rising sharply in 2010 in response to financial requirements in home markets and continued uncertainty associated with disruptions in global financial markets. During the same period, foreign private investors increased their purchases of U.S. corporate stocks, but reduced their purchases of corporate bonds, reflecting the growth experienced in the values of U.S. corporate stocks. During 2012, foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasury securities more than doubled over the amount purchased in 2011. The inflow of capital from abroad supplements domestic sources of capital and likely likely allows the United States to maintain its current level of economic activity at at interest rates that are below the level they likely would be without the capital inflows. • Foreign official and private acquisitions of dollar-denominated assets likely will generate a stream of returns to overseas investors that would have stayed in the U.S. economy and supplemented other domestic sources of capital had the assets not been acquired by foreign investors. Congressional Research Service Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Contents Background ...................................................................................................................................... 1 Capital Flows and the Dollar ........................................................................................................... 1 The U.S. Balance of Payments ........................................................................................................ 34 The U.S. Net International Investment Position ............................................................................ 10 Implications ................................................................................................................................... 15 Figures Figure 1. Foreign Private and Official Purchases of U.S. Treasury Securities, 1997-20122013 ............. 7 Figure 2. Net Inflows of Private and Official Sources of Capital, 1997-20122013................................. 8 Figure 3. Foreign Official and Private Investment Positions in the United States, 1994-2012.................................................................................................. 14 Figure 4. U.S. and Foreign Investment Position, By Major Component, 2012 ............................. 15 Tables Table 1. Selected Indicators of the Size of the Global Capital Markets, 2012 ................................ 2 Table 2. U.S. International Transactions, Selected Accounts........................................................... 4 Table 3. Summary of the Net Balances by Major Accounts in the U.S. Balance of Payments..... of Payments .................................................................................................................................. 6 Table 4. Net Foreign Purchases of Long-Term U.S. Securities ....................................................... 98 Table 5. U.S. Net International Investment Position...................................................................... 11 Contacts Author Contact Information........................................................................................................... 16 Congressional Research Service Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Background By standard convention, the balance of payments accounts are based on a double-entry bookkeeping system. As a result, each transaction that is entered into the accounts as a credit must have a corresponding debit and vice versa. This means that a surplus or deficit in one part of the accounts necessarily will be offset by a deficit or surplus, respectively, in another account so that, overall, the accounts are in balance. This convention also means that a deficit in one account, such as the merchandise trade account, is not necessarily the same as a debt.1 The trade deficit can become a debt equivalent depending on how the deficit is financed and the expectations of those who hold the offsetting dollar-denominated U.S. assets. The balance of payments accounts are divided into three main sections: the current account, which includes the exports and imports of goods and services and personal and government transfer payments; the capital account, which includes such capital transfers as international debt forgiveness; and the financial account, which includes official transactions in financial assets and private transactions in financial assets and direct investment in businesses and real estate. In these accounts, exports are recorded as a positive amount even though they represent an outflow of goods and services from the economy, because they represent a credit for which there is a specific obligation of repayment. Similarly, although imports represent an inflow of goods and services to the economy, they are recorded as a negative amount, because they represent a debt that must be repaid. When the basic structure of the balance of payments was established, merchandise trade transactions dominated the accounts. Financial transactions recorded in the capital accounts generally reflected the payments and receipts of funds that corresponded to the importing and exporting of goods and services. As a result, the capital accounts generally represented “accommodating” transactions, or financial transactions associated directly with the buying and selling of goods and services. During this early period, exchange rates between currencies were fixed, and private capital flows, such as foreign investment, were heavily regulated so that nearly all international flows of funds were associated with merchandise trade transactions and with some limited government transactions. Since the 1970s, however, private capital flows have grown markedly as countries have liberalized their rules governing overseas investing and as nations have adopted a system of floating exchange rates, where the rates are set by market forces. Floating exchange rates have spurred demand for the dollar. The dollar also is sought for investment purposes as it has become a vehicle itself for investment and speculation and it serves as a major trade invoicing currency. This means that the balance of payments record not only the accommodating flows of capital which correspond to imports and exports of goods and services, but also autonomous flows of capital that are induced by a broad range of economic factors that are unrelated directly to the trading of merchandise goods. Capital Flows and the Dollar Liberalized capital flows and floating exchange rates have greatly expanded the amount of autonomous capital flows between countries. These capital transactions are undertaken in 1 For additional information about the causes of the U.S. trade deficit, see CRS Report RL31032, The U.S. Trade Deficit: Causes, Consequences, and Policy Options, by Craig K. Elwell. Congressional Research Service 1 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit response to commercial incentives or political considerations that are independent of the overall balance of payments or of particular accounts. As a result of these transactions, national economies have become more closely linked, the process some refer to as “globalization.” The data in Table 1 provide selected indicators of the relative sizes of the various capital markets in 1 For additional information about the causes of the U.S. trade deficit, see CRS Report RL31032, The U.S. Trade Deficit: Causes, Consequences, and Policy Options, by Craig K. Elwell. Congressional Research Service 1 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit various countries and regions and the relative importance of international foreign exchange markets. In 2012, these markets amounted to over $800 trillion, or more than 3050 times the size of the U.S. economy. Worldwide, foreign exchange and interest rate derivatives, which are the most widely used hedges against movements in currencies, were valued at $557 trillion in 2012, more than twice the size of the combined total of all public and private bonds, equities, and bank assets. For the United States, such derivatives total more than three times as much as all U.S. bonds, equities, and bank assets. Table 1. Selected Indicators of the Size of the Global Capital Markets, 2012 (billions of dollars) Bonds, Equities, and Bank Assets Exchange Market Derivatives Gross Domestic Product (GDP) Total Official Reserves Total Stock Market Capitalization Debt Securities Bank Assets World $72,216.4 $11,403.5 $268,585.2 $52,494.9 $99,134.2 European Union 15,514.8 498.0 82,217.5 9,732.2 Euro Area 12,199.5 332.5 57,789.6 United Kingdom 2,476.7 88.6 United States 16,244.6 Japan Emerging markets Total $72,216.4 $11,403.5 European Union 15,514.8 Euro Area World United Kingdom United States Japan Emerging markets Stock Market Capitalization Debt Securities $268,585.2 $52,494.9 498.0 82,217.5 12,199.5 332.5 2,476.7 Exchange Market Derivatives OTC Foreign Exchange Derivatives OTC Interest Rate Derivatives Bank Assets Total $99,134.2 $116,956.1 $557,061 $67,358 $489,703 9,732.2 29,456.8 43,028.8 NA NA NA 57,789.6 5,492.1 21,983.1 30,314.4 211,160 23,797 187,363 88.6 19,991.0 3,415.7 5,778.2 10,717.9 50,069 7,823 42,244 16,244.6 139.1 67,068.6 16,855.6 35,155.0 15,058.0 206,276 57,600 148,676 5,960.3 1,227.1 32,397.0 3,638.6 14,592.4 14,166.1 68,923 14,111 54,812 26,975.0 7,384.2 50,666.0 11,196.3 10,870.7 28,599.0 NA NA NA Source: Global Financial Stability Report, International Monetary Fund, October 2013. Statistical Appendix, Table 1; Quarterly Review, Bank for International Settlements, December, 2013, Tables 20b and 21b. Note: “Total derivatives” does not include equity and commodity-linked derivatives. Another aspect of capital mobility and capital inflows is the impact such capital flows have on the international exchange value of the dollar. Demand for U.S. assets, such as financial securities, translates into demand for the dollar, since U.S. securities are denominated in dollars. As demand for the dollar rises or falls according to overall demand for dollar-denominated assets, the value of the dollar changes. These exchange rate changes, in turn, have secondary effects on the prices of U.S. and foreign goods, which tend to alter the U.S. trade balance. At times, foreign governments intervene in international capital markets to acquire the dollar directly or to acquire Treasury securities in order to strengthen the value of the dollar against particular currencies. In addition, various central banks moved aggressively following the Asian financial crisis in the 1990s to bolster their holdings of dollars in order to use the dollars to support their currencies should the need arise. Congressional Research Service 2 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit The dollar is also heavily traded in financial markets around the globe and, at times, plays the role of a global currency. Disruptions in this role have important implications for the United States and for the smooth functioning of the international financial system. During the decade preceding the recent global financial crisis, banks and other financial institutions expanded their global balance sheets from $10 trillion in 2000 to $34 trillion in 2007. These assets were comprised Congressional Research Service 2 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit primarily of dollar-denominated claims on non-bank entities, including retail and corporate lending, loans to hedge funds, and holdings of structured finance products based on U.S. mortgages and other underlying assets. As the crisis unfolded, the short-term dollar funding markets served as a major conduit through which financial distress was transmitted across financial markets and national borders, according to analysts with the Bank for International Settlements (BIS).2 When these short-term dollar funding markets collapsed in the early stages of the crises, the U.S. Federal Reserve had to engage in extraordinary measures, including a vast system of currency swap arrangements with central banks around the world, to supply nearly $300 billion. After initially expanding the then-existing reciprocal currency arrangements (swap lines) with the European Central Bank, the Bank of England, the Swiss National Bank, and the Bank of Japan, the Federal Reserve made an unprecedented announcement in October 2008 that it would provide swap lines to “accommodate whatever quantity of U.S. dollar funding is necessary” to stem the dollar shortage.3 At the same time, the U.S. Treasury announced a money market guarantee program to stop the withdrawal of funds from the money markets and to offset the withdrawals by providing public funds. The prominent role of the dollar means that the exchange value of the dollar often acts as a mechanism for transmitting economic and political news and events across national borders. While such a role helps facilitate a broad range of international economic and financial activities, it also means that the dollar’s exchange value can vary greatly on a daily or weekly basis as it is buffeted by international events. A triennial survey of the world’s leading central banks conducted by the Bank for International Settlements in April 2013 indicates that the daily trading of foreign currencies through traditional foreign exchange markets4 totaled $5.3 trillion, up 35% from the $4.0 trillion reported in the previous survey conducted in 2010. In addition to the traditional foreign exchange market, the over-the-counter (OTC)5 foreign exchange derivatives market reported that daily turnover of interest rate and non-traditional foreign exchange derivatives contracts reached $2.7 trillion in April 2013. The combined amount of $8.0 trillion for daily foreign exchange trading in the traditional and OTC markets is more than threefour times the annual amount of U.S. exports of goods and services. The data also indicate that 87.0% of the global foreign exchange turnover in April 2013 was in U.S. dollars, slightly higher lower than the 84.9% share reported in a similar survey conducted in 2010.6 The U.S. Balance of Payments Table 2 presents a summary of the major accounts in the U.S. balance of payments over the last seven quarters. The data indicate that in 2011 and 2012 the U.S. current account, or the balance of 2 McGuire, Patrick, and Gotz von Peter, “The US Dollar Shortage in Global Banking and the International Policy Response,” BIS Working Paper No. 291, the Bank For International Settlements, October 2009; McGuire, Patrick, and Goetz von Peter, “The U.S. Dollar Shortage in Global Banking,” BIS Quarterly Review, March 2009. 3 Ibid., p. 76. 4 Traditional foreign exchange markets are organized exchanges which trade primarily in foreign exchange futures and options contracts where the terms and condition of the contracts are standardized. 5 The over-the-counter foreign exchange derivatives market is an informal market consisting of dealers who customtailor agreements to meet the specific needs regarding maturity, payments intervals or other terms that allow the contracts to meet specific requirements for risk. 6 Rime, Dagfinn, and Andreas Schrimpf, The Anatomy of the Global FX Market Through the Lens of the 2013 Triennial Survey, Quarterly Review, Bank for International Settlements, December 2013. Congressional Research Service 3 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit The U.S. Balance of Payments Table 2 presents a summary of the major accounts in the U.S. balance of payments over the four quarters of 2013. The data indicate that in 2011, 2012, and 2013 the U.S. current account, or the balance of exports and imports of goods, services and transfers, was in deficit, or the United States imported more more goods and services than it exported. On a quarterly basis, the deficit in the current account has varied from quarter to quarter, although remaining negative, reflecting a broad range of economic activities. According to the balance of payments accounts, the United States experienced deficits in the merchandise trade goods accounts through the most recent seven quarters from the first quarter of 2012 to the third quarter of four quarters of 2013 in the range of $9581 billion to $121105 billion and a surplus in the services accounts during the seven quarters same period in the range of about $4658 billion. In the income accounts, which represent inflows of income on U.S. assets abroad relative to outflows of income earned on U.S. assets owned by foreigners, the net balance of the accounts was in surplus throughout the seven-quarter period. Table 2. U.S. International Transactions, Selected Accounts (billions of dollars) 2012 2013 2013 2011 2012 2013 I II III IV I II III $-81 Current account Balance on current account $-458 $-440 $-121 $-111 $-107 $-102379 $-105 $-97 $-95 Balance on goods and services -557 -535 -143 -135 -129 -127475 -123 -118 -121 Balance on goods -744 -741 -194 -186704 -179 -182176 -179 -176 -179172 Exports 1,496 1,561 388 392 391 3901,590 391 395 398 405 Imports -2,240 -2,303 -581 -5782,294 -570 -573 -570 -570 -576576 -577 Balance on services 187 207 51 51 50 55 57229 57 58 58 58 Exports 617 649 160 162 161 166682 167 170 171 174 Imports -430 -443 -110 -111 -111 -111453 -110 -112 -113 -116 Balance on income 233 224 55 57 55 57229 51 56 60 64 Income Receipts 761 776 194 193 192 197789 192 195 197 206 Income Payments -528 -552 -139 -136 -138 -140560 -141 -139 -137 -142 Unilateral current transfers -134 -130 -33133 -33 -32 -32 -3334 -34 -3432 -1 7 0 0 0 8 0 0 0 Balance on financial account 552 439 264 18 28 129 40 66 67 U.S.-owned assets abroad, net increase / outflow (-) -456 -97 94 192 -267 -116 -229 -106 -74 U.S. official reserve assets, net -16 -4 -1 -3 -1 1 -1 0 1 U.S. Government assets, net -104 85 51 17 15 2 0 3 1 U.S. private assets, net -333 -178 44 179 -281 -119 -228 -110 -76 Foreign-owned assets in the U.S. net increase / inflow (+) 969 544 177 -176 301 242 266 168 148 Current account Capital account Capital account transactions Financial account Congressional Research Service 4 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit 2012 2013 2011 2012 I II III IV I II III Foreign official assets, net 254 394 144 57 108 84 127 -7 69 U.S. Treasury Securities 170 433 143 96 101 93 119 -12 16 Foreign private assets, net 715 150 33 -234 193 158 139 175 80 U.S. Treasury Securities 188 156 65 -5 63 34 51 -6 63 Financial derivatives 35 -7 -7 2 -5 3 4 4 -7 Statistical discrepancy -93 -6 -143 93 79 -35 65 31 28 Source: Scott, Sarah P., U.S. International Transactions: Third Quarter 2013, BEA Release, December 17, 20130 0 552 439 351 40 66 67 174 -456 -97 -553 -229 -106 -74 -149 -16 -4 3 -1 0 1 3 -104 85 2 0 3 1 -1 -114 Capital account Capital account transactions Financial account Balance on financial account U.S.-owned assets abroad, net increase / outflow (-) U.S. official reserve assets, net U.S. Government assets, net Congressional Research Service 4 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit 2013 2011 2012 2013 I II III IV U.S. private assets, net -333 -178 -558 -228 -110 -76 -151 Foreign-owned assets in the U.S. net increase / inflow (+) 969 544 906 266 168 148 325 Foreign official assets, net 254 394 284 127 -7 69 97 U.S. Treasury Securities 170 433 236 119 -12 16 115 Foreign private assets, net 715 150 622 139 175 80 228 U.S. Treasury Securities 188 156 202 51 -6 63 93 35 -7 -2 4 4 -7 -3 -93 -6 28 65 31 28 -93 Financial derivatives Statistical discrepancy Source: Scott, Sarah P., U.S. International Transactions: Fourth Quarter and Year 2013, BEA Release, March 9, 2014. Note: By convention, an increase in U.S.-owned assets abroad is represented in the financial accounts by an outflow, or a negative sign (-), and an increase in foreign-owned assets in the U.S. by an inflow, or a positive sign (+). The data also indicate that the U.S. financial accounts were in surplus throughout the period, because they represent the opposite and offsetting transactions to the deficits in the current account. Indeed, the accounting of the balance of payments is such that the surplus in the financial accounts is equivalent to the deficit in the combined balance in the capital account, the statistical discrepancy, and the balance on the current account. The balance in the financial accounts represents the difference between the capital outflows associated with U.S. investments abroad, which are recorded as a negative value, and the capital inflows associated with foreign investment in the United States, which are recorded as a positive value. This investment is a combination of both private and official investments, or investments by private individuals and institutions and investments by governments and governmental institutions, respectively. The balance on the financial account in 20122013 fell 20%sharply from that recorded in 2011 due to a drop in both U.S. financial outflows and foreign financial inflows2012 due to a 10-fold drop in the value of cross-border financial derivatives. Foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasury securities more than doubled in 2012 from the value purchased in 2011. Over the past seven quarters, foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasury securities peaked in the first quarter of 2012. Private foreign purchases of Treasury securities dropped by 17% in 2012, compared with 2011 Treasury securities also dropped by almost half in 2013 from that recorded in 2012, falling from $433 billion in 2012 to $236 billion in 2013. The data in Table 2 also indicate that in 20122013, U.S. private capital outflows were greater than official outflows. ForeignSimilarly, foreign private capital inflows, which fellhad fallen sharply in 2012 compared with 2011, were overshadowed by large foreign official capital inflows, marking almost a doubling in foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasury securities. Another way of viewing the data is presented in Table 3 which compared with 2011, quadrupled in 2013 to $633 billion from the $150 billion in private foreign inflows in 2012, primarily as a result of an increase in direct investment and a net investment in Treasury securities over 2012, and a large turn-around from outflows to inflows in banks account holdings. Another way of viewing the balance of payments data is presented in Table 3, which shows the net amount of the flows in the major accounts, or the difference between the inflows and outflows. In 20122013 for instance, total net capital inflows representing the net balance on the current account, the capital account, and the statistical discrepancy, were a negative $439351 billion, which was equivalent to the $439351 billion recorded in the financial accounts. The 20122013 values represent a decrease from the net amount recorded in 2011 2012. These totals, however, are subject to periodic revisions. Congressional Research Service 5 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Table 3. Summary of the Net Balances by Major Accounts in the U.S. Balance of Payments (billions of dollars) 2005 20062006 Total Net Capital Inflows 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Total Net Capital Inflows -$7012013 -$809 -$664 -$578 -$231 -$438 -$552 -$439 Total Net Goods -791$-351 -847 -831 -835 -511 -650 -744 -741 -704 Total Net Services 76 87 130 136 127 151 187 207 229 Total Net Income 72 48 91 152 124 178 233 224 Total Net Transfers -106229 -91 -116 -122 -122 -128 -134 -130 -133 Total Net Capital Account 11 -4 -2 6 0 0 -1 7 0 Statistical Discrepancy 37 -2 65 85 151 12 -93 -6 Total Net Financial Account $70128 $809 $664 $578 $231 $458 $552 $439 $351 Total Net Official 279 496 459 16 969 404 134 475 289 Total Net Private 422 284 199 594 -783 20 382 -28 Direct Investment 7664 -2 -123 -23 -160 -95 -179 -222 -166 Portfolio Investment 331 260 306 193 -241 300 -10 208 -142 Other Private (Banks) 14 26 16 424 -383 -185 571 -15 373 Financial Derivatives 0 30 6 -33 45 14 35 -7 -2 Total Net Goods Total Net Transfers Total Net Financial Account Direct Investment Source: Data developed by CRS from data published by the Department of Commerce. Commerce Department data indicate that foreign private purchases of Treasury securities turned negative between 1999 and 2001, in 2006, and again in 2009 as foreign private investors experienced net sales of Treasury securities, as indicated in Figure 1. In 2002, foreign private investors returned to acquiring Treasury securities, but the amount they acquired remained relatively level at $100 billion per year from 2002 to 2005. In contrast, foreign official net acquisitions of Treasury securities trended slightly upward between 2000 and 2002, but such net acquisitions more than doubled over the 2002 to 2004 period, rising to $273 billion in 2004. In 2005, though, official purchases of Treasury securities plummeted to $112 billion and were less than private purchases of $132 billion. In 2006, private foreign investors again reduced their net holdings of Treasury securities. This action was offset by a large increase in the acquisitions of Treasury securities by foreign governments, directed at least in part to slow the decline in the international exchange value of the dollar. In 2009, foreign private investors sold off $15 billion in Treasury securities, down sharply from the $197 billion they accumulated in 2008. Foreign governments, however, increased their net purchases of Treasury securities in 2009, which rose from $478 billion in 2008 to $570 billion in 2009. Foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasury securities exceeded foreign private purchases in 2010 and in 2012, falling just shy of such private purchases in 2011. In 2012, 2012, and in 2013. In 2013, foreign official purchases of treasury securities rosefell to $434236 billion, outpacing but still outpaced foreign private purchases of $156 $202 billion. Over the 2001-20122013 period, net foreign official purchases of treasury securities were more than twice as large as net foreign private purchases. Congressional Research Service 6 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Figure 1. Foreign Private and Official Purchases of U.S.Treasury Securities, 1997-20122013 Source: Department of Commerce. As the data in Table 3 indicate, a deficit in the net capital inflow account is financed by an offsetting net inflow in the financial account. One striking feature of the financial flows over the 2005-20122006-2013 period is the way the composition of the balances in the net financial account has changed. Net private and net official capital inflows have changed abruptly since the period prior to 2002, when private inflows were greater than official inflows, as indicated in Figure 2. In 2004, 2006, 2007, 2009, 2010, 2012, and 2013and 2012 net official inflows exceeded net private inflows. In contrast, U.S. U.S. private capital flows shifted from a net outflow of $1.4 trillion in 2007 to a net inflow of $867 billion in 2008, reflecting the financial turmoil during that period. Net private outflows by U.S. citizens, however, resumed in the 2009 to 20122013 period. During the same period, U.S. official outflows increased from $22 billion in 2007 to $530 billion in 2008. Since then, official outflows have vacillated between net outflows and net inflows, reflecting the unsettled nature of financial markets following the 2008-2009 financial crisis. In contrast, foreign Foreign private inflows of capital dropped from $1.6 trillion in 2007 to $123 billion in 2008. During the same2009-2013 period, foreign official inflows increased slightly from $481 billion in 2007 to $555 billion in 2008. As a result of these changes, net official flows, or the combination of U.S. and foreign officials flows dropped from a net outflow of $458 billion 2007 to a net outflow of $20 billion in 2008. In addition, net as U.S. firms and others brought capital back to the United States. In addition, net private flows increased from a net inflow of $152 billion in 2007 to a net inflow of $743 billion in 2008. In 2012, net official inflows rose to $475 billion from $134 billion recorded in 2011, while net private inflows dropped to a negative $28 billion from a positive $382 billion in 2011 billion in 2011. In 2013, net official inflows dropped to $298 billion, while net private inflows recorded a net inflow of $64. Congressional Research Service 7 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Figure 2. Net Inflows of Private and Official Sources of Capital, 1997-20122013 Source: Department of Commerce. The data in Table 4 show the total net accumulation of long-term U.S. securities, or the amount of securities purchased less those that were sold, by foreign private and official sources from 2005-20122006-2013. The data indicate that in 2008, the net foreign private accumulation of U.S. securities dropped by three-fourths from that recorded in 2007 as foreign private investors withdrew funds from the U.S. during the financial crisis. In 2009, however, total foreign private and official purchases of U.S. securities rebounded from a negative $186.5 billion in 2008 to a positive $51 billion in 2009 and $414increased to reach $485 billion, propelled primarily by net foreign official purchases. Total foreign purchases of U.S. securities grew to reach $573 billion in 2010, reflecting increased net purchases of U.S. corporate stocks and U.S. Treasury securities. Such foreign continued to grow in 2012 to reach $726 billion, before falling in 2013 to $435 billion. Similarly, total private purchases of Treasury securities dropped in 2011 and 2012, but rebounded somewhat in 2013, in 2012, reaching $ 355205 billion. In 20122013, private foreign investors increased their holdings of U.S. decreased their net purchases of U.S. corporate stock, while reducing their holdingsincreasing their net purchases of corporate bonds. Investors in Europe reduced theirnearly doubled their net purchases of Treasury securities in 2013 from the amount they purchased in 2011, although investors in Asia increased their purchases in 2012 compared with 2011. Congressional Research Service 8 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit amount they purchased in 2012. Table 4. Net Foreign Purchases of Long-Term U.S. Securities (billions of dollars) 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Total private and official net purchases of U.S. securities $875.72013 $1,099.1 $989.6 $236.3 $484.8 $573.2 $412.9 $726.4 $435.1 Total private purchases 598.3 611.4 644.8 -186.5 51.1 414.5 92.4 354.8 249.4 Corporate stocks 88.3 139.7 230.5 57.5 163.4 139.2 60.9 173.3 Europe 44.0-71.0 Europe 92.6 90.5 -2.1 79.6 81.3 -13.8 55.3 1.2 United Kingdom 21.2 73.2 67.9 28.4 33.3 35.0 9.1 25.9 Canada 21.0-2.9 Total private and official net purchases of U.S. securities Congressional Research Service 8 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Canada 12.6 9.8 6.7 9.5 17.3 20.9 52.4 41.9 Caribbean financial centers 14.8 34.4 95.4 1.7 34.2 23.0 40.3 33.3 Latin America -0.4-29.0 1.8 1.1 3.5 5.2 4.9 2.0 14.6 Asia 8.7 -4.7 Asia -2.2 27.9 50.7 31.4 11.0 8.6 11.8 -71.6 Of which: Japan -0.1 -1.2 -5.6 21.8 20.6 11.6 7.4 -8.4 Africa 0.3-59.4 0.0 -0.4 -4.7 -0.8 -0.4 0.9 0.4 Corporate bonds 312.30.5 Corporate bonds 517.8 383.7 -51.4 -117.3 -24.5 -106.3 -33.2 Europe 199.8177.3 Europe 332.1 225.9 -80.4 -105.7 -64.5 -123.5 -46.2 United Kingdom 144.7133.4 United Kingdom 203.6 130.5 -46.3 -56.1 -30.7 -59.0 -55.3 Canada 1.9-7.8 7.9 12.4 -2.0 -0.1 9.8 -2.1 4.0 Caribbean financial centers 40.218.0 106.9 61.9 12.1 -7.4 21.4 9.1 5.5 Latin America 7.320.0 9.3 4.7 -13.7 -4.5 3.4 3.4 0.1 Asia 54.4-2.1 Asia 53.7 72.8 32.4 1.6 6.8 11.6 6.8 Japan 25.62.3 Japan 12.2 39.5 21.7 -1.6 0.8 7.1 -2.1 Africa 0.6-5.2 Africa 0.2 -0.4 -0.4 0.1 0.1 0.0 -0.2 Other 8.10.3 Other 7.7 6.4 0.7 -1.3 -1.4 -4.8 -2.7 5.4 U.S. Treasury bonds 147.9 -71.9 39.2 -20.0 49.2 273.6 146.8 157.9 Europe 65.2205.1 Europe -61.9 57.8 -43.5 -38.0 105.0 137.9 75.7 Canada 21.8145.4 Canada 14.7 -1.9 -6.2 19.7 35.9 -18.2 25.6 Caribbean financial centers 44.9-11.8 -10.9 -6.2 2.6 -13.8 22.1 6.7 -14.7 Latin America 10.45.1 -2.1 9.8 -5.0 6.1 0.4 -5.7 1.2 Asia 14.3 -10.7 -20.8 29.3 71.9 111.0 26.2 52.2 Africa 1.762.5 Africa 1.1 1.5 7.0 1.1 5.5 0.1 -1.4 Other 2.50.0 Other -2.1 -1.1 -4.3 2.3 -6.4 -0.2 19.3 -0.5 Federal agency bonds 49.8 25.8 -8.6 -172.6 -44.3 26.2 -9.1 56.7 Congressional Research Service 9 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Europe -11.9-62.0 Europe -8.1 42.3 -17.4 -46.6 1.1 -10.3 12.0 1.8 United Kingdom -1.3 -8.8 70.9 42.4 -30.4 25.0 4.9 -2.0 Canada 12.114.6 9.7 3.0 5.0 1.8 8.1 3.5 1.3 Caribbean financial centers 3.0-0.1 31.3 -21.6 -75.8 7.9 -14.5 2.9 13.7 Latin America 7.1-32.9 3.4 2.8 0.8 0.8 5.0 3.6 -0.5 Asia 40.2-1.4 -10.8 -34.6 -81.4 -3.7 28.7 -8.1 30.8 Japan 15.6-28.0 Japan 2.9 -14.9 -39.0 -1.2 21.7 4.8 23.6 Africa -0.3-50.6 Africa -0.3 -0.6 -2.9 -2.0 -0.9 -0.2 -0.4 Other -0.4 0.6 0.1 -1.0 -2.4 -1.2 -0.4 -0.2 Total official purchases 277.4 487.7 344.8 422.8 433.7 458.7 320.5 371.6 U.S. Treasury bonds 156.9 233.5 76.6 276.2 512.7 506.9 273.5 417.5 Other U.S. Government securities 100.5 219.8 171.5 42.7 -132.6 -88.7 -20.7 -118.5 Corporate bonds 19.1 28.6 51.6 35.0 -2.3 0.8 -5.1 13.9 Corporate stocks 1.0 5.8 45.1 68.9 55.9 39.7 72.8 58.7 Source: Scott, Sarah P., “U.S. International Transactions: Third Quarter 2013, BEA Release, December 17, 2013-0.3 Other 0.6 0.1 -1.0 -2.4 -1.2 -0.4 -0.2 -1.2 Latin America Africa Canada Caribbean financial centers Latin America Caribbean financial centers Latin America Asia Canada Caribbean financial centers Latin America Asia Congressional Research Service 9 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Total official purchases 487.7 344.8 422.8 433.7 458.7 320.5 371.6 185.8 U.S. Treasury bonds 233.5 76.6 276.2 512.7 506.9 273.5 417.5 209.8 Other U.S. Government securities 219.8 171.5 42.7 -132.6 -88.7 -20.7 -118.5 -30.9 Corporate bonds 28.6 51.6 35.0 -2.3 0.8 -5.1 13.9 26.0 Corporate stocks 5.8 45.1 68.9 55.9 39.7 72.8 58.7 -19.2 Source: Scott, Sarah P., “U.S. International Transactions: Fourth Quarter and Year 2013, BEA Release, March 9, 2014. Table 8a. The U.S. Net International Investment Position As indicated above, the data in Table 2 and Table 3 show that the trade deficit is accompanied by an equal capital inflow that represents an accumulation of dollar-denominated assets by foreigners. Some observers have equated the trade deficit and the associated accumulation of foreign-owned dollar-denominated assets as a debt that the U.S. economy owes to foreigners that will have to be repaid. This characterization, however, is not entirely appropriate. The debts owned by foreign investors represents claims on assets, rather than loans where payments on the principle and interest are specified according to a fixed schedule and where failure to meet the repayment schedule can result in the loans being called in and made payable in full. While foreign investors have expectations of a positive return on their dollar-denominated assets, returns, except for Treasury securities, are not guaranteed, but are subject to market forces. An important feature of claims by foreign investors on U.S. assets is that some or all of the profits or returns on the assets can be repatriated to the home country of the foreign investor, thereby reducing the returns that otherwise would remain in the U.S. economy. According to the most commonly accepted approach to the balance of payments, macroeconomic developments in the U.S. economy are the major driving forces behind the magnitudes of capital flows, because the macroeconomic factors determine the overall demand for and supply of capital in the economy. Economists generally conclude that the rise in capital inflows can be attributed to comparatively favorable returns on investments in the United States when adjusted for risk, a surplus of saving in other areas of the world, the well-developed U.S. financial system, the overall stability of the U.S. economy, and the generally held view that U.S. securities, especially Treasury securities, are high quality financial instruments that are low risk. In turn, these net Congressional Research Service 10 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit capital inflows (inflows net of outflows) bridge the gap in the United States between the amount of credit demanded and the domestic supply of funds, likely keeping U.S. interest rates below the level they would have reached without the foreign capital. These capital inflows also allow the United States to spend beyond its means, including financing its trade deficit, because foreigners are willing to lend to the United States in the form of exchanging goods, represented by U.S. imports, for such U.S. assets as stocks, bonds, U.S. Treasury securities, and real estate and U.S. businesses. While this exchange of assets is implicit in the balance of payments, the Department of Commerce explicitly accounts for this broad flow of dollar-denominated assets through the nation’s net international investment position. The U.S. net international investment position represents the accumulated value of U.S.-owned assets abroad and foreign-owned assets in the Congressional Research Service 10 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit United States measured on an annual basis at the end of the calendar year. Some observers refer to the net of this investment position (or the difference between the value of U.S.-owned assets abroad and the value of foreign-owned assets in the United States) as a debt, or indicate that the United States is a net debtor nation, because the value of foreign-owned assets in the United States is greater than the value of U.S.-owned assets abroad. In fact, the nation’s net international investment position is not a measure of the nation’s indebtedness similar to the debt borrowed by some developing countries, but it is simply an accounting of assets. By year-end 2012, the latest year for which data are available, the overseas assets of U.S. residents totaled $21.0 trillion, while foreigners had acquired about $25.1 trillion in assets in the United States, with direct investment measured at historical cost. As a result, the U.S. net international investment position was about a negative $4.1 trillion in 2012, with direct investment measured at historical cost, as indicated in Table 5. Table 5. U.S. Net International Investment Position (billions of dollars) Type of Investment 2009 2010 2011 2012 With direct investment at current cost $-2,321.8 $-2,473.6 $-3,730.6 $-3,863.9 With direct investment at market value -2,661.3 -2,813.4 -4,510.7 -4,558.7 With direct investment at historical cost -2,503.8 -2,656.2 -3,932.2 -4,081.8 Financial derivatives 126.3 110.4 86.0 57.8 With direct investment at current cost 18,511.7 20,298.4 21,636.2 21,637.6 With direct investment at market value 18,769.4 20,758.3 21,486.9 21,809.4 With direct investment at historical cost 18,000.9 19,782.5 21,057.7 21,013.2 Financial derivatives 3,489.8 3,652.3 4,716.6 3,619.8 U.S. official reserve assets 403.8 488.7 537.0 572.4 U.S. Government assets, other 82.8 75.2 178.9 93.6 With direct investment at current cost 14,535.3 16,082.2 16,203.6 17,351.9 With direct investment at market value 14,793.1 16,542.1 16,054.4 17,523.7 Net international investment position of the United States: U.S.-owned assets abroad: U.S. private assets: Congressional Research Service 11 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Type of Investment 2009 2010 2011 2012With direct investment at historical cost 14,024.5 15,566.3 15,625.2 16,727.5 —At current cost 4,029.5 4,306.8 4,663.1 5,077.8 —At market value 4,287.2 4,766.7 4,513.9 5,249.5 —At historical cost 3,518.7 3,790.9 4,084.7 4,453.3 Foreign securities 5,565.6 6,336.4 6,441.4 7,531.2 —Bonds 1,570.3 1,689.5 1,939.9 2,140.7 —Corporate stocks 3,995.3 4,646.9 4,501.4 5,390.5 U.S. claims by US nonbanking concerns 930.3 874.8 793.0 844.8 U.S. claims reported by US banks930.3 874.8 793.0 844.8 Net international investment position of the United States: Financial derivatives U.S.-owned assets abroad: Financial derivatives U.S. official reserve assets U.S. Government assets, other U.S. private assets: Direct investment abroad: U.S. claims by US nonbanking concerns Congressional Research Service 11 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Type of Investment U.S. claims reported by US banks 2009 2010 2011 2012 4,009.9 4,564.2 4,306.2 3,898.2 With direct investment at current cost 20,833.5 22,772.0 25,366.7 25,501.5 With direct investment at market value 21,430.7 23,571.7 25,997.6 26,368.2 With direct investment at historical cost 20,504.7 22,438.7 24,989.8 25,095.0 Financial derivatives 3,363.4 3,541.9 4,630.5 3,562.0 4,402.8 4,912.7 5,256.4 5,692.4 With direct investment at current cost 13,067.2 14,317.4 15,479.8 16,247.1 With direct investment at market value 13,664.5 15,117.1 16,110.7 17,113.7 With direct investment at historical cost 12,738.4 13,984.0 15,102.9 15,840.6 —At current cost 2,398.2 2,597.7 2,879.5 3,057.3 —At market value 2,995.5 3,397.4 3,510.4 3,924.0 —At historical cost 2,069.4 2,264.4 2,502.6 2,650.8 U.S. Treasury securities 791.0 1,101.8 1,386.3 1,541.6 U.S. other securities 5,319.9 5,934.0 6,151.6 6,904.1 —Corporate and other bonds 2,825.6 2,915.7 2,894.6 3,062.0 —Corporate stocks 2,494.3 3,018.3 3,256.9 3,842.1 U.S. currency 313.8 342.1 397.1 454.2 U.S. liabilities by U.S. nonbanking concerns 706.4 643.6 630.9 656.5 U.S. liabilities reported by U.S. banks 3,537.9 3,698.2 4,034.5 3,633.4 With direct investment at historical cost Direct investment abroad: Foreign-owned assets in the United States: Financial derivatives Foreign official assets in the United States Foreign private assets: Direct investment in the United States: U.S. Treasury securities U.S. liabilities reported by U.S. banks Source: Nguyen, Elena L., The International Investment Position of the United States at the End of the First Quarter 2013 and Yearend 2012, Survey of Current Business, July 2013. p. 14. Foreign investors who acquire U.S. assets do so at their own risk and accept the returns accordingly, unlike the debt owed by developing countries where principle and debt service payments are guaranteed in advance. While foreign investors likely expect positive returns from their dollar-denominated assets, the returns on most of the assets in the international investment Congressional Research Service 12 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit position, except for bonds, are not guaranteed and foreign investors stand to gain or lose on them similar to the way U.S. domestic investors gain or lose. As Table 5 indicates, the investments in the international investment position include such financial assets as corporate stocks and bonds, government securities, and direct investment7 in 7 The United States defines foreign direct investment as the ownership or control, directly or indirectly, by one foreign person (individual, branch, partnership, association, government, etc.) of 10% or more of the voting securities of an incorporated U.S. business enterprise or an equivalent interest in an unincorporated U.S. business enterprise. 15 CFR §806.15 (a)(1). Similarly, the United States defines direct investment abroad as the ownership or control, directly or indirectly, by one person (individual, branch, partnership, association, government, etc.) of 10% or more of the voting securities of an incorporated business enterprise or an equivalent interest in an unincorporated business enterprise. 15 (continued...) Congressional Research Service 12 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit businesses and real estate. The value of these assets, measured on an annual basis, can change as a result of purchases and sales of new or existing assets; changes in the financial value of the assets that arise through appreciation, depreciation, or inflation; changes in the market values of stocks and bonds; or changes in the value of currencies. For instance, by year-end 2012, U.S. private holdings abroad had risen in value from $15.6 trillion to $16.7 trillion, with direct investment valued at historical cost, due in part to an upward revaluation in the values of foreign corporate stocks, reflecting an increase in stock market values. Similarly, the value of foreign owned corporate stocks in the United States rose in value in 2012, pulling up the overall investment position of foreign investors. The Department of Commerce uses three different methods for valuing direct investments that yield roughly comparable estimates for the net position, although the three methods do provide estimates on U.S. direct investment abroad and foreign direct investment that can be considerably different at times.8 The foreign investment position in the United States continues to increase as foreigners acquire additional U.S. assets and as the value of existing assets appreciates. These assets are broadly divided into official and private investments reflecting transactions by governments among themselves and transactions among the public. While the foreign official share of the overall amount of capital inflows has grown sharply as indicated in Table 3, the overall foreign official share of foreign-owned assets in the United States has remained relatively modest. As Figure 3 indicates, foreign official asset holdings were valued at about $5.7 trillion in 2012, or about 26% of the total foreign investment position, a share that has rose above 20% in 2008 as foreign official holdings of U.S. Treasury securities rose during the global financial crisis. Official assets include such monetary reserve assets as gold, the reserve position with the International Monetary Fund (IMF), and holdings of foreign currency. An important component of foreign official holdings in the United States is the acquisitions of U.S. Treasury securities by foreign governments. At times, such acquisitions are used by foreign governments, either through coordinated actions or by themselves, to affect the foreign exchange price of the dollar. Foreign currency holdings account for a relatively small share of the total foreign investment position.9 7 The United States defines foreign direct investment as the ownership or control, directly or indirectly, by one foreign person (individual, branch, partnership, association, government, etc.) of 10% or more of the voting securities of an incorporated U.S. business enterprise or an equivalent interest in an unincorporated U.S. business enterprise. 15 CFR §806.15 (a)(1). Similarly, the United States defines direct investment abroad as the ownership or control, directly or indirectly, by one person (individual, branch, partnership, association, government, etc.) of 10% or more of the voting securities of an incorporated business enterprise or an equivalent interest in an unincorporated business enterprise. 15(...continued) CFR §806.15 (a)(1). 8 For additional information, see CRS Report RL32964, The United States as a Net Debtor Nation: Overview of the International Investment Position, by James K. Jackson. 9 For additional information, see CRS Report RL32462, Foreign Investment in U.S. Securities, by James K. Jackson. Congressional Research Service 13 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Figure 3. Foreign Official and Private Investment Positions in the United States, 1994-2012 Source: Department of Commerce. Private asset holdings are comprised primarily of direct investment in businesses and real estate, purchases of publicly traded government securities, and corporate stocks and bonds. As indicated in Figure 4, the composition of U.S. assets abroad and foreign-owned assets in the United States differ in a number of ways. The strength and uniqueness of the U.S. Treasury securities markets make these assets sought after by both official and private foreign investors, whereas U.S. investors hold few foreign government securities. As a result, foreign official assets in the United States far outweigh U.S. official assets abroad. Both foreign private and official investors have been drawn at times to U.S. government securities as a safe haven investment during troubled or unsettled economic conditions. Congressional Research Service 14 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Figure 4. U.S. and Foreign Investment Position, By Major Component, 2012 Source: Department of Commerce. Implications The persistent U.S. trade deficit raises concerns in Congress and elsewhere due to the potential risks such deficits may pose for the long term rate of growth for the economy. In particular, some observers are concerned that foreigner investors’ portfolios will become saturated with dollardenominated assets and foreign investors will become unwilling to accommodate the trade deficit by holding more dollar-denominated assets. The shift in 2004 in the balance of payments toward a larger share of assets being acquired by official sources generated speculation that foreign private investors had indeed reached the point where they were no longer willing to add more dollar-denominated assets to their portfolios. This shift was reversed in 2005, however, as foreign private investments rebounded. Another concern is with the outflow of profits that arise from the dollar-denominated assets owned by foreign investors. This outflow stems from the profits or interest generated by the assets and represent a clear outflow of capital from the economy that otherwise would not occur if the assets were owned by U.S. investors. These capital outflows represent the most tangible cost to the economy of the present mix of economic policies in which foreign capital inflows are needed to fill the gap between the demand for capital in the economy and the domestic supply of capital. Indeed, as the data presented indicate, it is important to consider the underlying cause of the trade deficit. According to the most commonly accepted economic approach, in a world with floating exchange rates and the free flow of large amounts dollars in the world economy and international access to dollar-denominated assets, macroeconomic developments, particularly the demand for and supply of credit in the economy, are the driving forces behind the movements in the dollar’s international exchange rate and, therefore, the price of exports and imports in the economy. As a result, according to this approach, the trade deficit is a reflection of macroeconomic conditions within the domestic economy and an attempt to address the issue of the trade deficit without Congressional Research Service 15 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit addressing the underlying macroeconomic factors in the economy likely would prove to be of limited effectiveness. In addition, the nation’s net international investment position indicates that the largest share of U.S. assets owned by foreigners is held by private investors who acquired the assets for any number of reasons. As a result, the United States is not in debt to foreign investors or to foreign governments similar to some developing countries that run into balance of payments problems, because the United States has not borrowed to finance its trade deficit. Instead the United States has traded assets with foreign investors who are prepared to gain or lose on their investments in the same way private U.S. investors can gain or lose. It is certainly possible that foreign investors, whether they are private or official, could eventually decide to limit their continued acquisition of dollar-denominated assets or even reduce the size of their holdings, but there is no firm evidence that such presently is the case. Author Contact Information James K. Jackson Specialist in International Trade and Finance jjackson@crs.loc.gov, 7-7751 Congressional Research Service 16