< Back to Current Version

Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit

Changes from June 22, 2010 to March 7, 2011

This page shows textual changes in the document between the two versions indicated in the dates above. Textual matter removed in the later version is indicated with red strikethrough and textual matter added in the later version is indicated with blue.


Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit James K. Jackson Specialist in International Trade and Finance June 22, 2010March 7, 2011 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov RL33274 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Summary The U.S. merchandise trade deficit is a part of the overall U.S. balance of payments, a summary statement of all economic transactions between the residents of the United States and the rest of the world, during a given period of time. Some Members of Congress and other observers have grown concerned over the magnitude of the U.S. merchandise trade deficit and the associated increase in U.S. dollar-denominated assets owned by foreigners. The recentInternational trade has begun to recover somewhat from the slowdown in global economic activity has reduced in 2008-2009 that reduced global trade flows and, consequently, reduced the size of the U.S. trade deficit. This report provides an overview of the U.S. balance of payments, an explanation of the broader role of capital flows in the U.S. economy, an explanation of how the country finances its trade deficit or a trade surplus, and the implications for Congress and the country of the large inflows of capital from abroad. The major observations indicate that • Foreign officialprivate investors sharply increased their purchases of U.S. Treasury securities in 2010 after declining in 2009 in response to uncertainty associated with disruptions in global financial markets. During the same period, foreign private official investors sharply reduced their purchases of U.S. corporate stocks and bonds compared with 2008in 2010 from the more rapid pace set in 2009. • The inflow of capital from abroad supplements domestic sources of capital and likely allows the United States to maintain its current level of economic activity at interest rates that are below the level they likely would be without the capital inflows. • Foreign official and private acquisitions of dollar-denominated assets likely will generate a stream of returns to overseas investors that would have stayed in the U.S. economy and supplemented other domestic sources of capital had the assets not been acquired by foreign investors. Congressional Research Service Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Contents Background ................................................................................................................................1 Capital Flows and the Dollar ............................. Error! Bookmark not defined. Capital Flows and the Dollar ..........................................................................1 Error! Bookmark not defined. The U.S. Balance of Payments ....................................................................................................4 The U.S. Net International Investment Position ......................................................................... 10 Implications .................................... Error! Bookmark not defined. The U.S. Net International Investment Position ........................... Error! Bookmark not defined. Implications .......................................................................................... 15 Error! Bookmark not defined. Figures Figure 1. Foreign Private and Official Purchases of U.S. Treasury Securities, 1997-2009.............72009Error! Bookmark not defin Figure 2. Net Inflows of Private and Official Sources of Capital, 1997-2009................................8 Figure 3. Foreign Official and Private Investment Positions in the United States, 1994-2008..................................2009Error! Bookmark not defined. Figure 3. Foreign Official and Private Investment Positions in the United States, 1994-2008............................................................ 14 Error! Bookmark not defined. Figure 4. U.S. and Foreign Investment Position, By Major Component, 2008............................ 15 Tables Table 1. Selected Indicators of the Size of the Global Capital Markets, 2008 ...............................2 Table 2. U.S. International Transactions, Selected Accounts ........................................................42008Error! Bookmark not defined. Tables Table 1. Selected Indicators of the Size of the Global Capital Markets, 2009Error! Bookmark not defined. Table 2. U.S. International Transactions, Selected Accounts ........ Error! Bookmark not defined. Table 3. Summary of the Net Balances by Major Accounts in the U.S. Balance of Payments .................................................................................................................................6 Error! Bookmark not defined. Table 4. Net Foreign Purchases of Long-Term U.S. Securities .....................................................8 Table 5. U.S. Net International Investment Position................................................................... 11 Contacts Author Contact Information ............................. Error! Bookmark not defined. Table 5. U.S. Net International Investment Position..................... Error! Bookmark not defined. Contacts Author Contact Information ......................................................................... 16 Error! Bookmark not defined. Congressional Research Service Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Background By standard convention, the balance of payments accounts are based on a double-entry bookkeeping system. As a result, each transaction that is entered into the accounts as a credit must have a corresponding debit and vice versa. This means that a surplus or deficit in one part of the accounts necessarily will be offset by a deficit or surplus, respectively, in another account so that, overall, the accounts are in balance. This convention also means that a deficit in one account, such as the merchandise trade account, is not necessarily the same as a debt.1 The trade deficit can become a debt equivalent depending on how the deficit is financed and the expectations of those who hold the offsetting dollar-denominated U.S. assets. The balance of payments accounts are divided into three main sections: the current account, which includes the exports and imports of goods and services and personal and government transfer payments; the capital account, which includes such capital transfers as international debt forgiveness; and the financial account, which includes official transactions in financial assets and private transactions in financial assets and direct investment in businesses and real estate. When the basic structure of the balance of payments was established, merchandise trade transactions dominated the accounts. Financial transactions recorded in the capital accounts generally reflected the payments and receipts of funds that corresponded to the importing and exporting of goods and services. As a result, the capital accounts generally represented “accommodating” transactions, or financial transactions associated directly with the buying and selling of goods and services. During this early period, exchange rates between currencies were fixed, and private capital flows, such as foreign investment, were heavily regulated so that nearly all international flows of funds were associated with merchandise trade transactions and with some limited government transactions. Since the 1970s, however, private capital flows have grown markedly as countries have liberalized their rules governing overseas investing and as nations have adopted a system of floating exchange rates, where the rates are set by market forces. Floating exchange rates have spurred demand for the dollar. The dollar also is sought for investment purposes as it has become a vehicle itself for investment and speculation and it serves as a major trade invoicing currency. This means that the balance of payments record not only the accommodating flows of capital which correspond to imports and exports of goods and services, but also autonomous flows of capital that are induced by a broad range of economic factors that are unrelated directly to the trading of merchandise goods. Capital Flows and the Dollar Liberalized capital flows and floating exchange rates have greatly expanded the amount of autonomous capital flows between countries. These capital transactions are undertaken in response to commercial incentives or political considerations that are independent of the overall balance of payments or of particular accounts. As a result of these transactions, national economies have become more closely linked, the process some refer to as “globalization.” The data in Table 1 provide selected indicators of the relative sizes of the various capital markets in 1 For additional information about the causes of the U.S. trade deficit, see CRS Report RL31032, The U.S. Trade Deficit: Causes, Consequences, and CuresPolicy Options, by Craig K. Elwell. Congressional Research Service 1 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit various countries and regions and the relative importance of international foreign exchange markets. In 20082009, these markets amounted to nearlyover $700 trillion, or more than 30 times the size of of the U.S. economy. Worldwide, foreign exchange and interest rate derivatives, which are the most most widely used hedges against movements in currencies, were valued at $431500 trillion in 2008, 50% larger than2009, twice the size of the combined total of all public and private bonds, equities, and bank assets. For the the United States, such derivatives total nearly three times as much as all U.S. bonds, equities, and and bank assets. Table 1. Selected Indicators of the Size of the Global Capital Markets, 20082009 (billions of dollars) Exchange Market Derivatives Bonds, Equities, and Bank Assets Gross Domestic Product (GDP) Total Official Reserves World 61,218.7 7,389.7 European Union 17,134.2 Euro Area $57,843.4 $8,543.8 European Union 15,373.1 Euro Area World United Kingdom United States Japan Emerging markets Stock Market Capitalization Debt Securities 221,494.0 33,513.1 296.2 87,354.8 13,631.0 185.5 2,684.2 OTC Foreign Exchange Derivatives OTC Interest Rate Derivatives Bank Assets Total 83,268.7 104,712.3 430, 96.0 44,200.0 385,896.0 7,269.1 29,041.3 51,044.4 N.A. N.A. N.A. 65,036,2 4,991.0 23,700.1 36,345.0 155,134.0 9,049.0 146,085.0 44.3 10,564.8 1,868.2 3,967.6 12,729.0 28,264.0 4,732.0 23,532.0 14,441.4 66.6 56,313.7 11,737.6 30,571.3 14,004.8 166,974.0 37,076.0 129,898.0 4,887.0 1,009.4 25,082.6 3,209.0 11,454.3 10,419.3 61,526.0 4,075.0 57,451.0 18,941.9 4,838.2 28,896.5 5,960.0 6,207.0 16,729.5 N.A. N.A. N.A. Market Capitalization Debt Securities $232,240.8 $47,789.9 404.7 85,277.1 12,478.1 282.8 2,178.9 OTC Foreign Exchange Derivatives OTC Interest Rate Derivatives Bank Assets Total $92,082.4 $92,969.5 $498,989.0 $49,196.0 $449,793.0 10,013.4 33,556.0 41,707.7 NA NA NA 62,887.9 6,576.1 27,239.5 29,072.4 196,091.0 20,364.0 175,727.0 55.7 18,217.0 2,796.4 4,712.3 10,708.3 40,185.0 5,929.0 34,256.0 14,119.1 119.7 60,892.3 15,077.3 31,652.0 14,163.0 194,279.0 40,921.0 153,358.0 5,068.9 1,022.2 24,163.5 3,395.6 11,920.9 8,846.9 65,091.0 11,238.0 53,853.0 17,962.0 5,523.0 33,477.1 9,909.8 7,618.9 15,948.3 NA NA NA Total Source: Global Financial Stability Report, International Monetary Fund, AprilOctober 2010. Statistical Appendix, Table 3Tables 3, 4, and 5. Note: Total derivatives does not include equity and commodity-linked derivatives. Another aspect of capital mobility and capital inflows is the impact such capital flows have on the international exchange value of the dollar. Demand for U.S. assets, such as financial securities, translates into demand for the dollar, since U.S. securities are denominated in dollars. As demand for the dollar rises or falls according to overall demand for dollar-denominated assets, the value of the dollar changes. These exchange rate changes, in turn, have secondary effects on the prices of U.S. and foreign goods, which tend to alter the U.S. trade balance. At times, foreign governments intervene in international capital markets to acquire the dollar directly or to acquire Treasury securities in order to strengthen the value of the dollar against particular currencies. In addition, various central banks moved aggressively following the Asian financial crisis in the 1990s to bolster their holdings of dollars in order to use the dollars to support their currencies should the need arise. The dollar is also heavily traded in financial markets around the globe and, at times, plays the role of a global currency. Disruptions in this role have important implications for the United States and for the smooth functioning of the international financial system. During the decade preceding the recent global financial crisis, banks and other financial institutions expanded their global Congressional Research Service 2 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit balance sheets from $10 trillion in 2000 to $34 trillion in 2007. These assets were comprised Congressional Research Service 2 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit primarily of dollar-denominated claims on non-bank entities, including retail and corporate lending, loans to hedge funds, and holdings of structured finance products based on U.S. mortgages and other underlying assets. As the crisis unfolded, the short-term dollar funding markets served as a major conduit through which financial distress was transmitted across financial markets and national borders, according to analysts with the Bank for International Settlements (BIS). 2 When these short-term dollar funding markets collapsed in the early stages of the crises, the U.S. Federal Reserve had to engage in extraordinary measures, including a vast system of currency swap arrangements with central banks around the world, to supply nearly $300 billion. After initially expanding the then-existing reciprocal currency arrangements (swap lines) with the European Central Bank, the Bank of England, the Swiss National Bank, and the Bank of Japan, the Federal Reserve made an unprecedented announcement in October 2008 that it would provide swap lines to “accommodate whatever quantity of U.S. dollar funding is necessary” to stem the dollar shortage. 3 At the same time, the U.S. Treasury announced a money market guarantee program to stop the withdrawal of funds from the money markets and to offset the withdrawals by providing public funds. The prominent role of the dollar means that the exchange value of the dollar often acts as a mechanism for transmitting economic and political news and events across national borders. While such a role helps facilitate a broad range of international economic and financial activities, it also means that the dollar’s exchange value can vary greatly on a daily or weekly basis as it is buffeted by international events. A triennial survey of the world’s leading central banks conducted by the Bank for International Settlements in April 200742010 indicates that the daily trading of foreign currencies through traditional foreign exchange markets5 totals more than $3.2 trillion, up sharply from the $1.9markets4 totals $4.0 trillion, up 20% from the $3.3 trillion reported in the previous survey conducted in 20042007. In addition to the traditional traditional foreign exchange market, the over-the-counter (OTC)65 foreign exchange derivatives market market reported that daily turnover of interest rate and non-traditional foreign exchange derivatives derivatives contracts reached $2.1 trillion in April 20072010. The combined amount of $5.36.1 trillion for daily daily foreign exchange trading in the traditional and OTC markets is more than three times the annual annual amount of U.S. exports of goods and services. The data also indicate that 86.384.9% of the global global foreign exchange turnover isin April 2010 was in U.S. dollars, slightly lower than the 88.7% share reported 85.6% share reported in a similar survey conducted in 2004.7 2 2007.6 2 McGuire, Patrick, and Gotz von Peter, “The US Dollar Shortage in Global Banking and the International Policy Response,” BIS Working Paper No. 291, the Bank For International Settlements, October 2009; McGuire, Patrick, and Goetz von Peter, “The U.S. Dollar Shortage in Global Banking,” BIS Quarterly Review, March 2009. 3 Ibid., p. 76. 4 A similar survey was conducted in April 2010 and is expected to be released in August 2010. 5 Traditional foreign exchange markets are organized exchanges which trade primarily in foreign exchange futures and options contracts where the terms and condition of the contracts are standardized. 65 The over-the-counter foreign exchange derivatives market is an informal market consisting of dealers who customtailor agreements to meet the specific needs regarding maturity, payments intervals or other terms that allow the contracts to meet specific requirements for risk. 76 Triennial Central Bank Survey: Foreign Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity in 20072010. Bank for International Settlement, September 20072010. pp. 1-2. A copy of the report is available at http://www.bis.org/publ/rpfx07rpfx10.pdf Congressional Research Service 3 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit The U.S. Balance of Payments Table 2 presents a summary of the major accounts in the U.S. balance of payments over the last sevenfive quarters. The data indicate that in 2008 and 2009 the U.S. current account, or the balance of exports and imports of goods, services and transfers, was in deficit, or the United States imported more than it exported. On a quarterly basis, the deficit in the current account has risen from the second quarter of 2009 through the first quarter of 2010, reflecting the gains experienced in the U.S. economy. According to the accounts, the increased each quarter since the second quarter of 2009. According to the balance of payments accounts, the United States experienced growingsuccessively higher deficits in the merchandise trade goods accounts in the third and fourth quarters of 2009 and the first quarter of 2010 through the most recent five quarters and a surplus in the services accounts across the entire periodduring the five quarters. In the income accounts, which represent inflows of income on U.S. assets abroad relative to outflows of income earned on U.S. assets owned by foreigners, the net balance of the accounts was in surplus throughout the five-quarter period. Table 2. U.S. International Transactions, Selected Accounts (billions of dollars) 2009 2008 2009 I 2010 II III IV I -$84 -$98 -$101 -$109III 2010 IV I II III Current account Balance on current account -$669 -$378 -$9698 -101 -109 -123 -127 Balance on goods and services -699 -375 -90 -80 -99 -105 -11599 -105 -114 -133 -134 Balance on goods -835 -507 -121 -114 -132 -140 -151132 -140 -151 -170 -171 Exports 1,305 1,068 255 254 269 291 306 316 323 Imports -2,140 -1,575 -376 -368 -401 -431 -457401 -431 -457 -486 -494 Balance on services 136 132 31 33 33 35 3633 35 37 36 37 Exports 534 502 123 124 125 130 133 134 137 Imports -398 -370 -93 -91 -92 -94 -97 Balance on income 578 216 8 15 78 116 131 Income Receipts 797 588 143 142 147 156 16492 -94 -96 -97 -100 Balance on income 152 121 35 35 40 43 41 Income Receipts 797 588 147 156 161 164 166 Income Payments -645 -467 -119 -116 -111 -121 -122 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 6 0 0 0 0 0 0111 -121 -121 -121 -124 Unilateral current transfers -122 -125 -34 -31 -35 -33 -34 6 0 0 0 Balance on financial account 578 216 8 15 78 116 35 31 182 31 U.S.-owned assets abroad, net 156 -140 113 32 -276 -9 -301 -5 -52 -1 -4 -49 1 -1 -530 541 244 194 58 46 10 691 -630 -130 -158 -285 -56 -310 Foreign-owned assets in the U.S. -153 -71 -45 -5 -34 13 -16 Foreign official assets, net 104 22 5 12 4 1 1 Unilateral current transfers 141 -325 -5 -52 -49 1 -1 0 -1 -530 541 58 46 9 -2 1 691 -630 -285 -56 -310 -139 -324 Foreign-owned assets in the U.S. -455 306 342 104 320 162 506 Foreign official assets, net 551 450 97 117 73 44 142 Capital account Capital account transactions Financial account U.S. official reserve assets, net U.S. Government assets, net U.S. private assets, net Congressional Research Service 4 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit 2009 2008 2009 I IIIII 2010 III IV I II III U.S. Treasury Securities 328 135 6 32 56 42 47549 561 124 124 90 18 198 Foreign private assets, net -96 -144 -220 -157 246 -13 257246 -13 248 119 365 U.S. Treasury Securities 161 23 46 -29 -9 15 103 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 152 121 25 26 35 35 42 Financial derivatives -9 15 103 101 65 Financial derivatives -33 51 11 21 16 10 NA 85 162 20 -15 74 92 -54 Statistical discrepancy Source: Yorgason, Daniel R., and Paul W. FarelloScott, Sarah P., “U.S. International Transactions: FirstThird Quarter 2010.” BEA News Release, BEA 10-28, June 17, 2010Survey of Current Business, January 2011, p. 39. The data also indicate that the U.S. financial accounts were in surplus throughout the period, because they represent the opposite and offsetting transactions to the deficits in the current account. Indeed, the accounting of the balance of payments is such that the surplus in the financial accounts is equivalent to the deficit in the combined balance in the capital account, the statistical discrepancy, and the balance on the current account. The balance in the financial accounts represents the difference between the capital outflows associated with U.S. investments abroad, which are recorded as a negative value, and the capital inflows associated with foreign investment in the United States, which are recorded as a positive value. This investment is a combination of both private and official investments, or investments by private individuals and institutions and investments by governments and governmental institutions, respectively. Data for 2009the first three quarters of 2010 indicate that foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasury securities dropped sharply from dropped from similar purchases in 20082009, but private foreign purchases of Treasury securities in 2009 virtually collapsed from the amount recorded for 2007. Foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasury securities remained fairly even in the first quarter of 2010, while foreign private purchases of such securities rebounded noticeably in the first quarter of 2010 2010 rose sharply from that recorded in 2009. The data in Table 2 also indicate that private capital flows accountedgenerally account for the largest share of both U.S. capital inflows and outflows in 2009 and through the first quarter of 2010. Another way of viewing the data is presented in Table 3 which shows the net amount of the flows in the major accounts, or the difference between the inflows and outflows. In 2009 for instance, total net capital inflows representing the net balance on the current account, the capital account, and the statistical discrepancy, were a negative $216 billion, markedly less than the deficit of $578 recorded in 2008. This decrease in the overall net capital inflows occurred in part because of an increase in the surplus in the services account and in the income account. These totals, however, are subject to periodic billion, which was equivalent to the 216 recorded in the financial accounts. The 2009 values represent the smallest net amount recorded since 2006 and likely reflect the impact of the financial crisis and the economic recession. These totals, however, are subject to periodic revisions. Congressional Research Service 5 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Table 3. Summary of the Net Balances by Major Accounts in the U.S. Balance of Payments (billions of dollars) 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 -$501 -$533 -$532 -$701 -$809 -$664 -$578 -$216 -485 -549 -672 -791 -847 -831 -835 -507 Total Net Services 61 54 62 76 87 130 136 132 Total Net Income 27 45 67 72 48 91 152 121 -65 -72 -88 -106 -91 -116 -122 -125 -1 -3 1 11 -4 -2 6 0 -38 -8 97 37 -2 65 85 162 $501 $533 $532 $701 $809 $664 578 216 Total Net Official 113 280 402 279 496 459 16 939 Total Net Private 388 253 130 422 284 199 594 -774 Direct Investment -70 -86 -170 76 -2 -123 -23 -134 Portfolio Investment 335 165 305 331 260 306 193 -185 Other Private (Banks) 123 173 -4 14 26 16 424 -455 0 0 0 0 30 6 -33 51 Total Net Capital Inflows Total Net Goods Total Net Transfers Total Net Capital Account Statistical Discrepancy Total Net Financial Account Financial Derivatives Source: Data developed by CRS from data published by the Department of Commerce. Commerce Department data indicate that foreign private purchases of Treasury securities turned negative between 1998 and 2001, in 2006, and again in 2009 and in 2006 as foreign private investors experienced net sales of Treasury securities, as indicated in Figure 1. By 2002, foreign private investors returned to acquiring Treasury securities, but the amount they acquired remained relatively level at $100 billion per year from 2002 to 2005. In contrast, foreign official net acquisitions of Treasury securities trended slightly upward between 2000 and 2002, but such net acquisitions more than doubled over the 2002 to 2004 period, rising to $273 billion in 2004. In 2005, though, official purchases of Treasury securities plummeted to $112 billion and were less than private purchases of $132 billion. In 2006, private foreign investors again reduced their net holdings of Treasury securities. This action was offset by a large increase in acquisitions of Treasury securities by foreign governments, directed at least in part to slow the decline in the international exchange value of the dollar. In 2009, foreign private investors accumulated $197 23 billion in Treasury securities, as foreign governments sharply increased their net purchases of Treasury securities, which rose from $98 billion in 2007 to $549 billion in 2008 and $561 billion in 2009 securities, down from $161 billion accumulated in 2008. Foreign governments, however, increased their net purchases of Treasury securities in 2009 , which rose from $549 billion in 2008 and $561 billion in 2009. According to data for the first three quarters of 2010, private investors had returned to acquiring U.S. Treasury securities, but such purchases continued to trail behind similar purchases by foreign governments. Congressional Research Service 6 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Figure 1. Foreign Private and Official Purchases of U.S.Treasury Securities, 1997-2009 $500 Trillions of dollars $400 $300 $200 $100 $0 -$100 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Year Official Private Source: Department of Commerce. The deficit in the net capital inflow account was financed by an offsetting net inflow in the financial account. One striking feature of the financial flows is the way the composition of the balances in the net financial account have changed over the period since 2002. Net private and net official capital inflows have changed abruptly since the period prior to 2002, when private inflows were greater than official inflows, as indicated in Figure 2. In 2004, 2006, and 2007, net official inflows exceeded net private inflows. In 2007, foreign private inflows of capital increased by more than 2%, but similar private outflows by U.S. citizens increased by more than 11%, so that the overall net private flows fell in 2007. In 2008, however2007, and 2009, net official inflows exceeded net private inflows. In 2000, private capital flows by U.S. citizens shifted from a net outflow of $1.4 trillion in 2007 to a net inflow of $500 billion in 2008. During the same period, U.S. official outflows increased from $22 billion in 2007 to $530 billion in 2008. In contrast, foreign private inflows of capital dropped from $1.6 trillion in 2007 to $47 billion in 2008. During the same period, foreign official inflows increased slightly from $481 billion in 2007 to $487 billion in 2008. As a result of these changes, net official flows, or the combination of U.S. and foreign officials flows dropped from a net outflow of $458 billion 2007 to a net inflows of $47 billion in 2008. In addition, net private flows increased from a net inflow of $199 billion in 2007 to a net inflow of $581 billion in 2008. In 2009, however, net private inflows dropped to a negative $774 billion, while net official inflows rose to nearly $1 trillion. Congressional Research Service 7 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Figure 2. Net Inflows of Private and Official Sources of Capital, 1997-2009 $1,000 Trillions of dollars $500 $0 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 -$500 -$1,000 Year Total Net Official Total Net Private Source: Department of Commerce. The data in Table 4 show the total net accumulation of U.S. securities, or the amount of securities purchased less those that were sold, by foreign private and official sources from 20012002-2009. The data indicate that in 2009, the net accumulation of U.S. securities continued to fall below the previous year, although net private purchases shifted from net sales in 2008 of $114 to a net accumulation of about $100 billion, primarily due to large net purchases by investors in Asia. doubled from the low reached in 2008. Part of this increase in net purchases reflects the change in net private from a negative $186.5 in 2008 to a positive $86 in 2009, reflecting increased net purchases of U.S. corporate stocks and U.S. Treasury securities. Private foreign investors operating in every area but Canada and Africa increased their accumulation of U.S. corporate stocks. However, foreign private investors generally reduced their continued reducing their net accumulation of corporate bonds, reflecting the deteriorating economic and profit conditions of most U.S. firms in 2009. In addition, both private and official investors reduced their net accumulation of other U.S. government agency bonds. Table 4. Net Foreign Purchases of Long-Term U.S. Securities (billions of dollars) 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 $428.3 $520.5 $767.8 $875.7 $1,099.1 $989.6 $245.6 $92.2236.3 $485.4 361.7 311.7 455.6 598.3 611.4 644.8 -113.7 94.9186.5 86.0 Corporate stocks 56.1 34.3 59.5 88.3 139.7 230.5 57.1 130.25 136.4 Europe 31.5 22.1 36.3 44.0 92.6 90.5 4.3 59.3-2.1 58.4 Total private and official net purchases of U.S. securities Total private purchases Congressional Research Service 2009 8 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit 2002 2003 2004 2005 United Kingdom 14.4 0.2 28.9 21.2 Canada 12.9 11.5 3.9 2007 2008 73.2 67.9 28.5 31.54 33.2 21.0 12.6 9.8 6.7 -3.01.9 -17.1 -2.3 3.1 14.8 34.4 95.4 3.01.7 34.91 0.8 0.5 -0.4 -0.4 1.8 1.1 3.75 5.23 Asia 23.0 2.8 5.5 8.7 -2.2 27.9 44.0 32.250.7 36.9 Of which: Japan 12.2 -2.3 4.9 -0.1 -1.2 -5.6 20.7 12.121.8 13.0 Africa -0.1 0.2 -0.1 0.3 0.0 -0.4 -4.7 -0.87 145.4 223.2 254.6 312.3 517.8 383.7 1.0 -86-51.4 -130.6 Europe 78.9 130.9 126.3 199.8 332.1 225.9 -62.5 -10080.4 -111.0 United Kingdom 55.8 89.0 69.6 144.7 203.6 130.5 -38.0 -59.446.3 -61.3 Canada -0.0 5.2 6.0 1.9 7.9 12.4 7-2.0 6.7-8.1 Caribbean financial centers 35.5 54.0 47.1 40.2 106.9 61.9 22.2 1.612.1 -7.4 4.6 6.7 20.2 7.3 9.3 4.7 1.7 3.8-13.7 -4.5 Asia 22.7 24.2 51.9 54.4 53.7 72.8 32.3 2.44 1.6 Japan 10.8 10.5 33.5 25.6 12.2 39.5 21.6 -2.37 -1.6 Africa 0.1 0.4 0.6 0.6 0.2 -0.4 -0.4 0.1 Other 3.6 1.7 2.6 8.1 7.7 6.4 0.7 -1.3 U.S. Treasury bonds 78.4 91.0 74.1 147.9 -71.9 39.2 13.0 101.5-20.0 85.9 Europe 38.7 18.1 38.2 65.2 -61.9 57.8 -65.9 -74.143.5 -33.0 Canada -5.0 11.4 16.3 21.8 14.7 -1.9 -5.76.2 42.32 Caribbean financial centers 14.8 6.2 22.1 44.9 -10.9 -6.2 172.6 3.9-9.8 3.1 3.0 -3.4 10.4 -2.1 9.8 -5.10 6.12 22.3 46.4 1.0 1.3 -10.7 -20.8 6929.3 11976.9 Africa 1.1 -0.2 0.7 1.7 1.1 1.5 7.10 1.1 Other 3.6 6.1 -0.8 2.5 -2.1 -1.1 -4.3 2.3 81.8 -36.8 67.4 49.8 25.8 -8.6 -184.8 -50.2172.6 -5.7 4.7 -29.4 13.3 -11.9 -8.1 42.3 0.9 -7-17.4 -14.6 United Kingdom 22.4 14.6 31.4 -1.3 -8.8 70.9 59.2 2.342.4 -12.9 Canada -1.9 -4.0 5.0 12.1 9.7 3.0 4.95.0 1.58 Caribbean financial centers 23.2 6.0 11.3 3.0 31.3 -21.6 -100.1 -28.075.8 7.9 7.5 4.9 1.8 7.1 3.4 2.8 0.8 -0.40.8 Asia 49.3 -11.9 36.4 40.2 -10.8 -34.6 -87.8 -10.981.4 2.8 Japan 16.8 -16.4 16.5 15.6 2.9 -14.9 -37.2 -239.0 -1.2 Africa 0.3 0.2 -0.1 -0.3 -0.3 -0.6 -2.8 -1.89 -2.0 Caribbean financial centers Latin America Corporate bonds Latin America Latin America Asia Federal agency bonds Europe Latin America Congressional Research Service 2006 2009 9 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit 2002 2003 2004 2005 Other -1.2 -2.7 -0.3 -0.4 Total official purchases 66.5 208.7 312.2 U.S. Treasury bonds 32.4 163.5 Other U.S. Government securities 30.5 Corporate bonds Corporate stocks 2006 2007 2008 2009 0.6 0.1 -0.8 -3.01.0 -2.4 277.4 487.7 344.8 359.3 -2.8422.8 399.4 256.8 156.9 233.5 76.6 205276.2 26497.7 39.9 41.7 100.5 219.8 171.5 65.8 -39.042.7 -120.1 5.6 5.6 11.5 19.1 28.6 51.6 35.0 -2.13 -2.0 -0.3 2.2 1.0 5.8 45.1 53.4 11.768.9 24.2 Source: Weinberg, Douglas B., and Erin M. WhitakerScott, Sarah P., “U.S. International Transactions: Fourth Quarter and Year 2009.” Survey of Current Business, April, 2010January, 2011. Table 8a. The U.S. Net International Investment Position As indicated above, the data in Tables Table 2 and Table 2 and 3 show that the trade deficit is accompanied by an equal capital inflow that represents an accumulation of dollar-denominated assets by foreigners. Some observers have equated the trade deficit and the associated accumulation of foreign-owned dollar-denominated assets as a debt that the U.S. economy owes to foreigners that will have to be repaid. This characterization, however, is not entirely appropriate. The debts owned by foreign investors represents claims on assets, rather than loans where payments on the principle and interest are specified according to a fixed schedule and where failure to meet the repayment schedule can result in the loans being called in and made payable in full. While foreign investors have expectations of a positive return on their dollar-denominateddollardenominated assets, returns, except for Treasury securities, are not guaranteed, but are subject to market forces. An important feature of claims by foreign investors on U.S. assets is that some or all of the profits or returns on the assets can be repatriated to the home country of the foreign investor, thereby reducing the returns that would otherwise would remain in the U.S. economy. According to the most commonly accepted approach to the balance of payments, macroeconomic developments in the U.S. economy are the major driving forces behind the magnitudes of capital flows, because the macroeconomic factors determine the overall demand for and supply of capital in the economy. Economists generally conclude that the rise in capital inflows can be attributed to comparatively favorable returns on investments in the United States when adjusted for risk, a surplus of saving in other areas of the world, the well-developed U.S. financial system, the overall stability of the U.S. economy, and the generally held view that U.S. securities, especially Treasury securities, are high quality financial instruments that are low risk. In turn, these net capital inflows (inflows net of outflows) bridge the gap in the United States between the amount of credit demanded and the domestic supply of funds, likely keeping U.S. interest rates below the level they would have reached without the foreign capital. These capital inflows also allow the United States to spend beyond its means, including financing its trade deficit, because foreigners are willing to lend to the United States in the form of exchanging goods, represented by U.S. imports, for such U.S. assets as stocks, bonds, U.S. Treasury securities, and real estate and U.S. businesses. While this exchange of assets is implicit in the balance of payments, the Department of Commerce explicitly accounts for this broad flow of dollar-denominated assets through the nation’s net international investment position. The U.S. net international investment position Congressional Research Service 10 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit represents the accumulated value of U.S.-owned assets abroad and foreign-owned assets in the United States measured on an annual basis at the end of the calendar year. Some observers refer to the net of this investment position (or the difference between the value of U.S.-owned assets abroad and the value of foreign-owned assets in the United States) as a debt, or indicate that the United States is a net debtor nation, because the value of foreign-owned assets in the United States is greater than the value of U.S.-owned assets abroad. In fact, the nation’s net international investment position is not a measure of the nation’s indebtedness similar to the debt borrowed by some developing countries, but it is simply an accounting of assets. By year-end 20082009, the latest year for which data are available, the overseas assets of U.S. residents totaled $19.417.8 trillion, while foreigners had acquired about $2320.8 trillion in assets in the United States, with direct investment measured at historical cost. As a result, the U.S. net international investment position was about a negative $3.62.9 trillion, with direct investment measured at historical cost, as indicated in Table 5. Table 5. U.S. Net International Investment Position (billions of dollars) Type of Investment 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Net international investment position of the United States: With direct investment at current cost -1,925.1 -2,225.8 -2,139.9 -3,469.2$-2,191.7 $-1,915.7 $-3,493.9 $-2,737.8 With direct investment at market value -1,850.9 -1,849.3 -1,506.6 -4,006.9808.5 -1,380.0 -4,164.2 -2,934.0 With direct investment at historical cost -2,129.9 -2,399.4 -2,334.2 -3,638.1 57.9378.2 -2,421.3 -3,661.4 -2,927.7 59.8 71.5 159.6 127.9 With direct investment at current cost 11,961.6 14,381.3 18,278.8 19,888.2 With direct investment at market value 12,947.8 15,900.0 20,055.3 19,260.6 With direct investment at historical cost 11,445.3 13,900.0 17,744.3 19,351.4 1,190.0 1,239.0 2,559.3 6,624.5 188.0 219.9 277.2 293.7 77.5 72.2 94.5 624.1 With direct investment at current cost 10,506.0 12,850.3 15,347.8 12,345.8 With direct investment at market value 11,492.2 14,368.9 17,124.3 11,718.2 With direct investment at historical cost 9,989.7 12,369.0 14,813.3 11,809.0 —At current cost 2,651.7 2,936.0 3,451.5 3,698.8 —At market value 3,638.0 4,454.6 5,228.0 3,071.2 —At historical cost 2,135.5 2,454.7 2,916.9 3,162.0 Foreign securities 4,329.3 5,604.5 6,835.1 4,244.3 Bonds 1,011.6 1,275.5 1,567.1 1,392.9 Corporate stocks 3,317.7 4,329.0 5,248.0 2,85114,428.1 18,339.9 19,244.9 18,379.1 With direct investment at market value 15,950.3 20,062.0 18,605.7 18,630.7 With direct investment at historical cost 13,721.6 17,264.2 18,721.8 17,836.0 1,239.0 2,559.3 6,127.5 3,512.0 219.9 277.2 293.7 403.8 72.2 94.5 624.1 82.8 With direct investment at current cost 12,897.1 15,408.9 12,199.6 14,380.5 With direct investment at market value 14,419.3 17,130.9 11,560.5 14,632.2 With direct investment at historical cost 12,190.6 14,333.2 11,676.5 13,837.5 —At current cost 2,948.2 3,552.9 3,742.8 4,051.2 —At market value 4,470.3 5,275.0 3,103.7 4,302.9 —At historical cost 2,241.7 2,477.3 3,219.7 3,508.1 Foreign securities 5,604.5 6,835.1 3,985.7 5,471.0 —Bonds 1,275.5 1,587.1 1,237.3 1,493.6 —Corporate stocks 4,329.0 5,248.0 2,748.4 3,977.4 Financial derivatives U.S.-owned assets abroad: Financial derivatives U.S. official reserve assets U.S. Government assets, other U.S. private assets: Direct investment abroad: Congressional Research Service 11 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Type of Investment 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 U.S. claims by US nonbanking concerns 1,184.1 1,173.7 794.7 794.2 U.S. claims reported by US banks 3,160.4 3,847.1 3,676.3 4,064.1 With direct investment at current cost 16,619.8 20,255.6 22,738.8 21,116.9 With direct investment at market value 17,758.8 21,441.9 22,770.0 21,564.7 With direct investment at historical cost 16,099.8 19,685.5 22,383.2 20,763.7 1,179.2 2,487.9 5,967.8 3,384.1 2,833.0 3,411.8 3,940.0 4,373.8 With direct investment at current cost 12,607.6 14,355.9 12,830.9 13,359.0 With direct investment at market value 13,746.6 15,542.2 12,862.2 13,806.8 With direct investment at historical cost 12,087.7 13,785.8 12,475.3 13,005.8 —At current cost 2,154.1 2,410.5 2,521.4 2,672.8 —At market value 3,293.1 3,596.9 2,552.6 3,120.6 —At historical cost 1,634.1 1,840.5 2,165.7 2,319.6 567.9 639.8 850.9 826.2 U.S. other securities 5,372.3 6,190.0 4,620.8 5,287.2 —Corporate and other bonds 2,824.9 3,289.1 2,770.6 2,841.2 —Corporate stocks 2,547.5 2,900.9 1,850.2 2,445.9 U.S. currency 282.6 272.0 301.1 313.8 U.S. liabilities by U.S. nonbanking concerns 799.5 864.6 731.5 665.5 3,431.3 3,979.0 3,805.2 3,593.6U.S. claims by US nonbanking concerns 1,018.5 1,163.1 1,239.7 991.9 U.S. claims reported by US banks 2,506.5 3,146.7 3,821.5 3,410.8 With direct investment at current cost 13,886.7 16,607.1 20,418.8 23,357.4 With direct investment at market value 14,798.7 17,749.2 21,561.9 23,267.4 With direct investment at historical cost 13,575.2 16,299.4 20,078.5 22,989.4 1,132.1 1,179.2 2,487.9 6,465.0 2,306.3 2,825.6 3,404.0 3,871.4 With direct investment at current cost 10,446.3 12,602.3 14,526.9 13,021.1 With direct investment at market value 11,360.3 13,744.4 15,670.1 12,931.1 With direct investment at historical cost 10,136.6 12,294.6 14,186.6 12,653.1 —At current cost 1,906.0 2,151.6 2,450.1 2,646.8 —At market value 2,818.0 3,293.7 3,593.3 2,556.9 —At historical cost 1,594.5 1,843.9 2,109.9 2,278.9 643.8 567.9 639.7 885.0 U.S. other securities 4,353.0 5,372.4 6,190.1 4,703.5 —Corporate and other bonds 2,243.1 2,824.9 3,289.1 2,865.9 —Corporate stocks 2,109.9 2,547.5 2,901.0 1,837.6 U.S. currency 280.4 282.6 272.0 301.1 U.S. liabilities by U.S. nonbanking concerns 658.2 797.5 1,000.4 873.2 2,606.9 3,430.3 3,974.6 3,611.4 Foreign-owned assets in the United States: Financial derivatives Foreign official assets in the United States Foreign private assets: Direct investment in the United States: U.S. Treasury securities U.S. liabilities reported by U.S. banks Source: Nguyen, Elena L., “The International Investment Position of the United States at Yearend 20082009,” Survey of Current Business, July 20092010. p. 10-18. Foreign investors who acquire U.S. assets do so at their own risk and accept the returns accordingly, unlike the debt owed by developing countries where principle and debt service payments are guaranteed in advance. While foreign investors likely expect positive returns from their dollar-denominated assets, the returns on most of the assets in the international investment position, except for bonds, are not guaranteed and foreign investors stand to gain or lose on them similar to the way U.S. domestic investors gain or lose. As Table 5 indicates, the investments in the international investment position include such financial assets as corporate stocks and bonds, government securities, and direct investment8 in 8investment7 in 7 The United States defines foreign direct investment as the ownership or control, directly or indirectly, by one foreign person (individual, branch, partnership, association, government, etc.) of 10% or more of the voting securities of an incorporated U.S. business enterprise or an equivalent interest in an unincorporated U.S. business enterprise. 15 CFR § 806.15 (a)(1). Similarly, the United States defines direct investment abroad as the ownership or control, directly or (continued...) Congressional Research Service 12 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit businesses and real estate. The value of these assets, measured on an annual basis, can change as a result of purchases and sales of new or existing assets; changes in the financial value of the assets that arise through appreciation, depreciation, or inflation; changes in the market values of stocks and bonds; or changes in the value of currencies. For instance, in 20082009, U.S. private holdings abroad declined in value $15.3 trillion to $12.3 trillion due to a large decline in the value rose in value from $11.7 trillion to $13.8 trillion, with direct investment valued at historical cost, due in part to an increase in the value of foreign corporate stocks, reflecting the decline rise in stock market values in nearly all exchanges after the low values reached in 2008, combined with a decline in the exchange value of the dollareuro, which depreciatesappreciates the value of assets held abroad when translated into dollar equivalents. Similarly, the value of foreign owned corporate stocks in the United States fell sharplyrose in value in 20082009, pulling downup the overall investment investment position of foreign investors. The Department of Commerce uses three different methods for valuing direct investments that yield roughly comparable estimates for the net position, although the three methods do provide estimates on U.S. direct investment abroad and foreign direct investment that can be considerably different at times.9 8 The foreign investment position in the United States continues to increase as foreigners acquire additional U.S. assets and as the value of existing assets appreciates. These assets are broadly divided into official and private investments reflecting transactions by governments among themselves and transactions among the public. While the foreign official share of the overall amount of capital inflows has grown sharply as indicated in Table 3, the overall foreign official share of foreign-owned assets in the United States has remained relatively modest. As Figure 3 indicates, official asset holdings were valued at about $3.84.4 trillion in 20082009, or about 1720% of the total foreign investment position, a share that has remainedincreased slightly in recent years after remaining relatively stable over the 14-year period of 1994 to 20082009. Official assets include such monetary reserve assets as gold, the reserve position with the International Monetary Fund (IMF), and holdings of foreign currency. An important component of foreign official holdings in the United States is the acquisitions of U.S. Treasury securities by foreign governments. At times, such acquisitions are used by foreign governments, either through coordinated actions or by themselves, to affect the foreign exchange price of the dollar. Foreign currency holdings account for a relatively small share of the total foreign investment position.109 (...continued) indirectly, by one person (individual, branch, partnership, association, government, etc.) of 10% or more of the voting securities of an incorporated business enterprise or an equivalent interest in an unincorporated business enterprise. 15 CFR § 806.15 (a)(1). 98 For additional information, see CRS Report RL32964, The United States as a Net Debtor Nation: Overview of the International Investment Position , by James K. Jackson. 109 For additional information, see CRS Report RL32462, Foreign Investment in U.S. Securities, by James K. Jackson. Congressional Research Service 13 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Figure 3. Foreign Official and Private Investment Positions in the United States, 1994-2008 16 14 Trillions of dollars 12 10 8 6 4 2 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 r 19 99 r 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 20 06 20 07 20 08 19 96 19 95 19 94 20 09 0 Year Foreign official assets Private assets Source: Department of Commerce. Private asset holdings are comprised primarily of direct investment in businesses and real estate, purchases of publicly traded government securities, and corporate stocks and bonds. As indicated in Figure 4, the composition of U.S. assets abroad and foreign-owned assets in the United States differ in a number of ways. The strength and uniqueness of the U.S. Treasury securities markets make these assets sought after by both official and private foreign investors, whereas U.S. investors hold few foreign government securities. As a result, foreign official assets in the United States far outweigh U.S. official assets abroad. Both foreign private and official investors have been drawn at times to U.S. government securities as a safe haven investment during troubled or unsettled economic conditions. Congressional Research Service 14 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit Figure 4. U.S. and Foreign Investment Position, By Major Component, 2008 US banks Nonbanks Stocks Bonds Govt. securities Direct investment Derivatives Official assets $0 $1 $1 $2 $2 $3 $3 $4 $54 $65 $75 Trillions of dollars U.S. Assets Foreign Assets Source: Department of Commerce. Implications The persistent U.S. trade deficit raises concerns in Congress and elsewhere due to the potential risks such deficits may pose for the long term rate of growth for the economy. In particular, some observers are concerned that foreigner investors’ portfolios will become saturated with dollardenominated assets and foreign investors will become unwilling to accommodate the trade deficit by holding more dollar-denominated assets. The shift in 2004 in the balance of payments toward a larger share of assets being acquired by official sources generated speculation that foreign private investors had indeed reached the point where they were no longer willing to add more dollar-denominated assets to their portfolios. This shift was reversed in 2005, however, as foreign private investments rebounded. Another concern is with the outflow of profits that arise from the dollar-denominated assets owned by foreign investors. This outflow stems from the profits or interest generated by the assets and represent a clear outflow of capital from the economy that otherwise would not occur if the assets were owned by U.S. investors. These capital outflows represent the most tangible cost to the economy of the present mix of economic policies in which foreign capital inflows are needed to fill the gap between the demand for capital in the economy and the domestic supply of capital. Indeed, as the data presented indicate, it is important to consider the underlying cause of the trade deficit. According to the most commonly accepted economic approach, in a world with floating Congressional Research Service 15 Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit exchange rates and the free flow of large amounts dollars in the world economy and international access to dollar-denominated assets, macroeconomic developments, particularly the demand for and supply of credit in the economy, are the driving forces behind the movements in the dollar’s international exchange rate and, therefore, the price of exports and imports in the economy. As a result, according to this approach, the trade deficit is a reflection of macroeconomic conditions within the domestic economy and an attempt to address the issue of the trade deficit without addressing the underlying macroeconomic factors in the economy likely would prove to be of limited effectiveness. In addition, the nation’s net international investment position indicates that the largest share of U.S. assets owned by foreigners is held by private investors who acquired the assets for any number of reasons. As a result, the United States is not in debt to foreign investors or to foreign governments similar to some developing countries that run into balance of payments problems, because the United States has not borrowed to finance its trade deficit. Instead the United States has traded assets with foreign investors who are prepared to gain or lose on their investments in the same way private U.S. investors can gain or lose. It is certainly possible that foreign investors, whether they are private or official, could eventually decide to limit their continued acquisition of dollar-denominated assets or even reduce the size of their holdings, but there is no firm evidence that such presently is the case. Author Contact Information James K. Jackson Specialist in International Trade and Finance jjackson@crs.loc.gov, 7-7751 Congressional Research Service 16