Order Code RL32254
Small Business Tax Benefits:
Overview and
Economic Rationales
Updated March 3, 2008
Gary Guenther
Analyst in Public Finance
Government and Finance Division
Small Business Tax Benefits:
Overview and Economic Rationales
Rationale
Gary Guenther
Analyst in Public Finance
March 26, 2009
Congressional Research Service
7-5700
www.crs.gov
RL32254
CRS Report for Congress
Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
Summary
The federal tax burden on small firms and its implications foreffects on their performance
and rates of formation
and growth is one of thosea policy issuesissue that never seems to
vanish disappear from Congress’s legislative agenda.
Continuing congressional interest in the
issue has set the stage forled to the enactment of a string of legislative initiatives in the past
decade or so to reduce this burden. The 110th Congress, like many of its
predecessors, is considering various proposals to expand current small business tax
preferences, or create new ones.
This report describes the principal federal tax benefits for small firms and
examines the economic arguments for and against them. It will be updated when new
benefits are added to the federal tax code, or current ones are modified or repealed.
While the federal revenue cost of existing small business tax preferences is not
known, estimates of the revenue lost because of federal tax expenditures indicate that
this cost could exceed $11 billion in FY2007, according to the Treasury Department
and Joint Committee on Taxation. The following small business tax benefits have
the broadest reach outside agriculture: the taxation of small firms as passthrough
entities, the graduated rate structure for the corporate income tax, the expensing
allowance for equipment under Section 179 of the Internal Revenue Code, the
exemption of some small corporations from the corporate alternative minimum tax,
cash basis accounting, and the exclusion from taxation of capital gains on the sale or
disposition of certain small business stock.
These benefits raise numerous interesting and significant policy issues. For
many economistsseries of legislative
initiatives to reduce this burden in recent Congresses. In February 2009, the 111th Congress
passed a bill (the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009, P.L. 111-5) intended to spur
an economic recovery; it included several small business tax preferences.
This report describes the main federal tax benefits for small firms and examines the economic
arguments for and against them. It will be updated as needed.
While a comprehensive estimate of the federal revenue cost of existing small business tax
preferences cannot be made with available information, estimates by the Joint Committee on
Taxation and the Treasury Department of the revenue lost because of the larger federal tax
expenditures indicate that this cost will exceed $15 billion in FY2009. The following small
business tax benefits appear to have the widest reach outside the agricultural sector: the taxation
of small firms as passthrough entities; the graduated rate structure for the corporate income tax;
the expensing allowance for equipment under Section 179 of the Internal Revenue Code; the
exemption of some small corporations from the corporate alternative minimum tax; cash-basis
accounting; a tax credit for costs incurred by small firms in establishing pension funds for
employees; a tax credit for costs incurred by small firms in complying with the Americans with
Disabilities Act; and the exclusion from taxation of capital gains on the sale or disposition of
qualified small business stock.
These and other small business tax benefits raise some significant policy issues. For economists
who specialize in public finance, a key issue is whether or not preferential tax treatment for small
firms can be justified on economic grounds. If such a justification cannot be found,
then then
proposals to furtherextend or enhance small business tax preferences may distort the
allocation of economic resources among sectors.
Proponents of targeting tax relief atarguably could create more
economic problems than they solve.
Proponents of granting tax relief to small firms say such relief is justified for
several reasons. First, they claim thaton several grounds.
First, in their view, small firms create singular opportunities for
social and economic advancement.
Second, proponents point to evidence that rates
of small business formation are sensitive to tax rates. Third, small firms account for
significant shares of national income, jobs, and technological innovations. Fourth,
they can serve as powerful agents for economic renewal and structural change. And
last but not least, proponents maintain that small firms face constraints on their
ability to raise capital in debt and equity markets that do not apply to most large,
established firms.
Critics of small business tax preferences argue that it is difficult to justify them
on economic grounds. They say such preferences lessen the progressivity of the
federal income tax and raise the return on small business investment in ways that
undermine social welfare. In addition, critics contend that some small business tax
preferences are inappropriate or poorly designed, magnifying any efficiency losses
they might cause.
Contents
Firm Size: How Small Is Small? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
Main Federal Tax Benefits for Small Business . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
Taxation of Passthrough Entities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
Graduated Corporate Income Tax Rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
Expensing Allowance for Certain Depreciable Business Assets . . . . . . . . . . 7
Exemption of Certain Small Corporations From the
Corporate Alternative Minimum Tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
Amortization of Business Start-Up Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
Cash Basis Accounting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
Tax Incentives for Private Equity Investment in Small firms . . . . . . . . . . . 12
Partial Exclusion of Capital Gains on Certain
Small Business Stock . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
Losses on Small Business Investment Company Stock Treated
as Ordinary Losses without Limitation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
Rollover of Gains into Specialized Small Business
Investment Companies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
Ordinary Income Treatment of Losses on Sales of
Small Business Stock . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
Uniform Capitalization of Inventory Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
Simplified Dollar-Value LIFO Accounting Method for Small Firms . . . . . 17
Tax Credit for Pension Plan Start-Up Costs of Small Firms . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
Magnitude of Small Business Tax Benefits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Economic Role of Small Firms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
Economic Arguments For and Against Small Business Tax Preferences . . . . . . 20
Chief Economic Arguments in Favor of the Preferences . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
Special Economic Role of Small Firms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
Opportunities for the Social and Economic Advancement of
Immigrants, Women, and Members of Minority Groups . . . . . . 22
Imperfections in Capital Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
Impact of Progressive Income Taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
Chief Economic Arguments Against the Subsidies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
Equity Concerns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
Efficiency Concerns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
Other Concerns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
List of Tables
Table 1. Estimated User Cost of Capital Under-Expensing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
Small Business Tax Benefits:
Overview and Economic Rationales
Some policy issues never seem to vanish from the congressional legislative
agenda. One such issue is the federal tax burden on small firms and its effect on their
performance and prospects for growth.
Many lawmakers view small firms as a whole as a vital and indispensable
source of job creation, economic opportunity, and technological innovation. Many
of these same individuals regard current federal taxation of small firms both as a
barrier to their formation and a drag on their growth, and as a policy instrument for
stimulating their rates of formation and growth. Such a dual perspective has
facilitated the enactment of a variety of small business tax benefits in recent decades.
In addition, the 110th Congress is considering a number of proposals to further reduce
the tax burden on small business by enhancing some current small business tax
benefits, creating new ones, or simplifying tax compliance for small firms.
Existing small business tax benefits and proposals to enhance or expand them
raise several policy issues. One is the substantial resources transferred to small firms
through such subsidies and the long-term economic effects of this transfer.
Statements made by some lawmakers suggest that they think the long-term economic
benefits of small business tax preferences outweigh their short-term revenue cost.
Another key policy issue concerns whether these preferences can be justified on
economic grounds. If such a rationale cannot be found, or if it appears tenuous at
best, then small business tax preferences may end up harming social welfare in the
long run.
This report explores these issues by examining the main small business tax
preferences and the economic arguments for and against them. It begins with a brief
description of current federal tax preferences for small firms, then reviews what is
known about the economic role of small firms, and concludes with a discussion of
the principal economic arguments for and against these subsidies.
Firm Size: How Small Is Small?
When considering the ways in which the federal tax code favors small firms and
what is known about the economic role of small firms, it is useful to understand how
small firms are defined for tax purposes.
Crafting such a definition in a manner that is widely accepted is a challenge, as
there is no uniform definition of a small firm in the many federal laws and
regulations offering assistance to small business. Instead, several criteria are used to
CRS-2
identify the firms that qualify for the benefits. It is not clear from the language of
these laws and regulations why such variation exists.
The absence of a uniform definition of a small firm may have its roots in the
Small Business Act (P.L. 85-536, as amended), which defines a small firm as “one
that is independently owned and operated and which is not dominant in its field of
operation.1“ The act goes on to specify that the definition of a small firm may vary
from industry to industry to reflect important structural differences among those
industries.2 Under the act, the Small Business Administration (SBA) has the
authority to establish (and alter, if necessary) the size standards and limits for
determining eligibility for federal programs to assist small business, many of which
are administered by the SBA. All federal agencies administering programs to set
aside a certain proportion of procurement contracts for small firms are required to use
SBA size standards and limits. But for other small business programs, federal
agencies have the choice of using SBA size standards and limits or establishing their
own.
In general, three criteria are used to identify the firms eligible for federal small
business programs. Each specifies the maximum size a firm (including affiliates) can
attain and still participate in the programs to which the criterion applies.
For the most part, the SBA uses two criteria to determine eligibility for the
programs it administers: (1) number of employees and (2) average annual receipts
in the previous three years. Application of these criteria varies by industry. For
example, the sole criterion for most manufacturing and mining firms is employment
size, and the upper limit is 500 employees; by contrast, for most retail and service
firms, the sole criterion is average annual receipts, and the upper limit is $6 million.
SBA’s current size limits for small firms range from $0.75 million to $28.5 million
for average annual receipts, and from 100 to 1,500 for number of employees.3 The
SBA Administrator has the authority to modify size standards for particular
industries. Before a proposed change can take effect, SBA’s Office of Size Standards
(OSS) must undertake economic studies of the affected industries — focusing on the
degree of competition, average firm size, start-up costs, barriers to entry, and the
distribution of sales and employment by firm size — and use the results to make
recommendations to SBA’s Size Policy Board. If the board agrees with the
recommendations, then it normally advises the Administrator to approve the
proposed change.
A third criterion used by federal agencies is asset size. Under this standard,
eligible firms would own assets up to a certain threshold, such as $50 million.
Among federal programs granting special benefits to small business, use of this
criterion is more limited than the number of employees or average annual receipts.
1
15 U.S.C. § 632(a)(1)
2
See [http://app1.sba.gov/faqs/].
3
Ibid.
CRS-3
How does the federal tax code define a small firm? Again, there is no uniform
definition. Instead, a variety of criteria are used to determine eligibility for current
small business tax preferences, and there is no obvious reason why the size limit
varies from one preference to the next.4 Some preferences rely on asset size, receipt
size, or employment size to select eligible firms. Others confer benefits on small
firms not through a specified size standard but through the design of the preference
itself. A case in point is the small business expensing allowance under Section 179
of the Internal Revenue Code (IRC): although allowance is not limited to firms of
a particular size, its design effectively confines its benefits to relatively small firms.
The lack of a uniform definition of a small firm in the federal tax code has its
advantages and disadvantages. On the one hand, it can lead to a firm being eligible
for some small business tax preferences but not for others. On the other hand, the
absence of a uniform definition gives lawmakers flexibility in crafting tax benefits
for small firms. Regardless of the practical consequences of the lack of a uniform
definition, it makes firm size a flexible concept that lawmakers can reshape, almost
without limit, to suit their legislative aims.
Main Federal Tax Benefits for Small Business
In general, all business income is subject to federal taxation. But not all
business income is treated equally under the federal tax code. Its tax treatment can
differ in several ways.
The taxation of business income depends on whether or not a firm is organized
for tax purposes as a corporation. Corporate net income is taxed twice (at the firm
level and then at the shareholder level), whereas the net income of passthrough
entities such as S corporations, sole proprietorships, limited liability companies, or
partnerships is taxed once (at the shareholder level).
In addition, the taxation of business income depends on whether or not a
corporation or the owners of passthrough entities pay the alternative minimum tax
(AMT). Corporations or business owners paying the AMT may be taxed at lower
marginal rates than their counterparts paying the regular corporate income tax.
The tax burden on business income also depends on how investments are
financed. For example, the returns to corporate investments financed solely by debt
are subject to lower marginal effective tax rates than the returns to investments
financed solely by equity, because corporations may deduct interest payments from
taxable income but not dividend payments.
Firm size is another factor affecting the tax treatment of business income.
Various provisions of the federal tax code offer benefits to smaller firms that are not
available or of lesser value to larger firms. The code makes no explicit or formal
4
According to one source, the Internal Revenue Code contains at least 24 different
definitions of a small business. See Douglas K Barney, Chris Bjornson, and Steve Wells,
“Just How Small Is Your Business?,” National Public Accountant, Aug. 2003, pp. 4-6.
CRS-4
distinction between the taxation of small and large firms in that it does not have
separate sections for small and large firms. Rather, the code contains numerous
provisions scattered throughout its many chapters that confer preferential treatment
on relatively small firms but not on relatively large firms. Most of these provisions
come in the form of deductions, exclusions and exemptions, credits, deferrals, and
preferential tax rates. In general, tax preferences such as these lower the cost of
capital for new investment by eligible firms relative to non-eligible firms. Certain
other provisions benefit small firms by reducing the cost and or burden of complying
with tax laws, or by making tax relief contingent on providing certain fringe benefits
to employees.
The federal small business tax subsidies with the broadest reach outside
agriculture are described below. Excluded from the list are subsidies targeted at
small firms in specific industries, such as life insurance, banking, and energy
production or distribution. It is not known what the total revenue cost is for the
subsidies discussed below. Nevertheless, recent estimates by the Joint Committee
on Taxation (JCT) and the Treasury Department indicate that they reduced federal
revenue by over an estimated $11 billion in FY2007.5
Taxation of Passthrough Entities
Business enterprises operate in a variety of legal organizational forms. The
business laws of each state determine the range of available choices. For federal tax
purposes, five such forms are widely used: subchapter C corporations, subchapter
S corporations, sole proprietorships, partnerships, and limited liability companies
(LLCs).
A firm’s organizational form has important implications for the taxation of its
earnings. The earnings of C corporations are taxed twice: once at the corporate level
and again at the individual level when the earnings are distributed to shareholders or
owners as dividends or realized capital gains. By contrast, the earnings of all other
business entities are taxed only once: at the individual level of their owners or
shareholders. As a result, these entities are often referred to as passthrough entities:
their earnings are not taxed at the entity level but pass through to the owners.6 The
entities’ profits, losses, and items of income, deduction, exclusion, deferral, and
credit are attributed to the owners according to their shares of ownership, regardless
5
In FY2007, the estimated combined revenue loss for seven of the most important small
business tax preferences is $11.445 billion. It pertains to the following seven small business
tax preferences: (1) expensing of depreciable business property; (2) reduced rates on the
first $10 million of corporate taxable income; (3) cash accounting outside agriculture; (4)
the partial exclusion of capital gains on the sale of certain small business stock; (5) the
amortization of business start-up costs; (6) the tax credit for new retirement plan expenses
of small firms; and (7) the ordinary income treatment of losses on the sale of small business
corporation stock. See U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimates of Federal
Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2006-2010 (Washington: GPO, 2006), table 1; and
Office of Management and Budget, Analytical Perspectives, Budget of the United States
Government, Fiscal Year 2008 (Washington: U.S. Govt. Print. Off., 2007), table 19-1.
6
For more details on the taxation of non-corporate businesses, see CRS Report RL31538,
Passthrough Entities Not Taxed As Corporations, by Jack H. Taylor.
CRS-5
of whether the profits have been distributed. Most businesses operate as sole
proprietorships: in 2004, they accounted for 69% of federal business tax returns.
Next in order of importance were S corporations (12% of business tax returns),
followed by partnerships (8% of returns), C corporations (7% of returns), and LLCs
(4% of returns).7
There is no legal requirement that C corporations be relatively large in income,
asset or employment size, and that passthrough firms be relatively small. Yet such
a distinction holds in reality. In 2004, for example, the average C corporation’s asset
size was over six times greater than that of the average partnership and over 41 times
greater than that of the average S corporation.8
Whether a business owner would be better off operating as a C corporation or
as a passthrough entity is often a complicated decision involving a host of tax and
non-tax considerations. Key non-tax considerations include the legal liability of
shareholders, access to capital markets, and degree of shareholder control of
management. Foremost among the tax considerations are the relative tax rates for
corporate income, individual ordinary income, and long-term capital gains; the
investment horizon of investors; the holding period for corporate stock; and the rate
at which corporate profits are paid out as dividends.
Setting aside non-tax considerations for the moment, one can see that the current
mix of individual and corporate tax rates favors passthrough entities by a small
margin for investors in the highest income tax bracket. Such a group offers an
appropriate focus for this analysis because many small business owners are subject
to the highest marginal income tax rate. A few simple calculations prove this point.
In 2007, the top personal tax rate is 35%; most corporate profits are taxed at 35%;
and the top tax rate on long-term capital gains is 15%.9 Assuming an investment
horizon of one year — after which the firm’s assets are liquidated — tax
considerations alone would dictate that high-income investors would be better off
owning a business enterprise that is operated as a partnership rather than a
corporation. Under such a scenario, after-tax returns to a partnership would be $.65
for every dollar invested, whereas they would be $.55 for every dollar invested by a
corporation.10 Extending the investment horizon to five years does not alter the
7
Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income Bulletin: Spring 2007 (Washington: 2007),
pp. 256-260.
8
In 2004, the average asset size for partnerships returns was $4.6 billion; for S corporation
returns, $696 million; and for C corporation returns, $28.8 billion. See Internal Revenue
Service, Statistics of Income Bulletin: Fall 2006 (Washington: 2004), pp. 107 and
[http://irs.ustreas.gov/taxstats/index].
9
Under the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 (JGTRRA, P.L. 10827), in 2003, the top individual income tax rate is 35% and is scheduled to remain at that
level through 2010, and the maximum rate on long-term capital gains is 15% for assets sold
after May 6, 2003 and before January 1, 2009.
10
These tax rates are derived from the following formula: (1-tp) is less than or equal to (1tc) x (1- tcg), where tp is the highest personal tax rate, tc is the highest corporate tax rate,
and tcg is the maximum tax rate on long-term capital gains. See Myron S. Scholes, et. al.,
(continued...)
CRS-6
outcome. Assuming that all after-tax income earned during that period is reinvested
in the business, the firm’s assets are liquidated after five years, and individuals in the
top tax bracket can earn a pre-tax rate of return of 20% whether the business is
operated as a partnership or a corporation, partnerships would earn a higher after-tax
rate of return than corporations: 13.0% versus 11.3%.11
Nonetheless, it would be incorrect to view the taxation of passthrough entities
as a small business tax benefit. The reason is that a firm’s size has no bearing on its
eligibility to operate as a passthrough entity. Firms that are relatively large in
employment, revenue, or asset size are organized as S corporations or partnerships,
while firms that are relatively small in those measures operate as C corporations. In
2003, 16% of S corporations and 7% of partnerships filing federal income tax returns
reported business receipts of $1 billion or more, while 22% of C corporations filing
federal income tax returns reported business receipts of less than $25 million.12
Any tax advantage presently held by small passthrough entities may prove
ephemeral, as it has in the recent past. For instance, their present advantage would
shift to corporations if legislation were enacted that sharply reduces the top corporate
and long-term capital gains tax rates relative to the maximum individual income tax
rate.
Graduated Corporate Income Tax Rates
Corporations with less than $10 million in taxable income are subject to a set
of graduated federal income tax rates. The rate is 15% on the first $50,000 of
income, 25% on the next $25,000, and 34% on selected amounts up to $10 million.
Corporations with taxable incomes ranging from above $10 million to $15 million
pay a marginal rate of 35%. What is more, in two income ranges, corporations face
marginal tax rates greater than 35%. A corporation with taxable income between
$100,000 and $335,000 pays a marginal rate of 39%, which is five percentage points
greater than the marginal rate on taxable incomes just above and below that range.
And a corporation with taxable income of more than $15 million up to $18.3 million
pays a marginal rate of 38%. These higher rates are intended to offset the tax savings
firms realized when their tax rates were less than 35%. All corporate taxable income
above $18.3 million is taxed at a rate of 35%. As a result, the tax savings from the
10
(...continued)
Taxes and Business Strategy: A Planning Approach, 2nd edition (Upper Saddle River, NJ:
Prentice-Hall, Inc., 2001), p. 67.
11
The after-tax rate of return for a partnership is derived from the following formula: $1[1
+ R x (1- tp)]n, where R is the expected pre-tax rate of return, tp is the highest personal tax
rate, and n is the investment horizon. And the after-tax rate of return for a corporation is
derived from the following formula: $1[1 + R x (1- tc)]n (1- tcg) + (tcg x $1), where R and
n are the same as the previous formula, tc is the highest corporate tax rate, and tcg is the
maximum tax rate on long-term capital gains. See Scholes, Taxes and Business Strategy.
pp. 66-67.
12
Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income Bulletin: Spring 2006 (Washington: 2006),
pp. 144 and 324.
CRS-7
graduated rates of 15% to 34% are limited to corporations with taxable incomes
under $335,000.
This graduated rate structure mainly benefits corporations that are relatively
small in employment or asset size, because their taxable incomes are likely to stay
below the $335,000 threshold. It also gives owners of closely held small firms an
added incentive to incorporate in order to shield any profits from higher individual
tax rates. But not all small corporations are allowed to take advantage of the reduced
rates. Specifically, the taxable income of corporations providing services in the
fields of health care, law, engineering, architecture, accounting, actuarial science, the
performing arts, and consulting is taxed at a fixed rate of 35%, regardless of the
amount.
The graduated rate structure is not without drawbacks. Specifically, it gives
smaller corporations a disincentive to grow to the extent that their incomes are taxed
at rates above 34%. In this sense, the higher rates serve as a tax on growth.
The revenue loss arising from the reduced rates on the first $10 million of
corporate taxable income came to an estimated $4.3 billion in FY2007.13
Expensing Allowance for Certain
Depreciable Business Assets
Expensing is the most accelerated form of depreciation for tax purposes. It
entails treating the cost of a depreciable asset such as a machine or building as an
ordinary and necessary expense rather than as a capital expenditure. Ordinary and
necessary costs are deducted in the year in which they are incurred, whereas capital
costs normally are recovered over longer periods by applying the depreciation
methods and schedules allowed in the federal tax code.
Under Section 179 of the Internal Revenue Code (IRC), firms may expense (or
deduct) up to $250,000 of the cost of qualified business property — mainly
machinery and equipment and computer software — placed into service in 2008 and
write off the remaining basis (if any) using a temporary 50% partial expensing
allowance and current cost recovery rules.14 The allowance drops back to $125,000
in 2009 and 2010 and is indexed for inflation in those years. Starting in 2011 (and
each year thereafter), the maximum allowance is scheduled to drop to $25,000.
Owing to a rule known as the dollar limitation, not all firms are able to take
advantage of the expensing allowance. Under this limitation, the allowance is
reduced by the amount by which the total cost of qualified property placed in service
during a year exceeds a phase-out threshold. In 2008, this threshold is set at
13
U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for
Fiscal Years 2006-2010 (Washington: GPO, 2006), p. 35.
14
For more details on the design of the expensing allowance and its economic effects, see
CRS Report RL31852, Small Business Expensing Allowance: Current Status, Legislative
Proposals, and Economic Effects, by Gary Guenther. The limitation is higher in the case
of property used in certain economically distressed areas.
CRS-8
$800,000. It drops back to $500,000 in 2009 and 2010 and is indexed for inflation
in those years. Beginning in 2011 (and each year thereafter), the threshold is
scheduled to drop to $200,000. As a result, none of a firm’s spending on qualified
property placed into service in 2008 may be expensed once its total spending on such
property exceeds $1,050,000: $250,000 expending allowance plus $800,000 phaseout threshold.
The allowance serves as a robust tax subsidy for small business investment. It
mainly benefits firms that are relatively small in revenue, asset, or employment size
because of the phase-out threshold. In addition, the allowance stimulates investment
by firms that can take advantage of it by deferring taxes on part or all of the first-year
returns to investment in qualified assets. This deferral yields a zero marginal
effective tax rate on the returns to this investment through the standard economic
model for the determination of the user cost of capital.15
In FY2007, the allowance produced an estimated revenue loss of $3.2 billion.16
The revenue effects of the expensing allowance in a particular year depend on the
level of business investment in that year. In periods of rising business investment,
the allowance typically produces a net revenue loss. But when business investment
falls following a period of sustained expansion, the allowance can actually yield a net
revenue gain. This shift from loss to gain reflects the timing of depreciation
deductions under expensing. Some firms write off the entire cost of an asset in its
first year of use by claiming the Section 179 expensing allowance, leaving no
depreciation deductions to offset future income earned by the asset.
Exemption of Certain Small Corporations From
the Corporate Alternative Minimum Tax
Under current federal tax law, many corporations must compute their income
tax liability under both the regular tax and the alternative minimum tax (AMT) and
pay whichever is greater. Each tax has its own rates, allowable deductions, and rules
for the measurement of taxable income.
In general, the AMT applies a lower marginal rate to a broader tax base. It
expands the corporate tax base by including a number of tax preferences under the
regular corporate income tax in the computation of taxable income under the AMT.
In addition, most tax credits allowed under the regular corporate income tax cannot
be used to reduce AMT liability. The current AMT originated with the Tax Reform
Act of 1986 and is mainly intended to insure that all profitable corporations pay at
least some federal income tax.
As a result of the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 (P.L. 105-34), certain small
corporations have been exempt from the AMT since 1998. Eligibility is determined
by a corporation’s average annual gross receipts in the previous three tax years. All
corporations formed after 1998 are exempt from the AMT in their first tax year,
15
See Jane G. Gravelle, “Effects of the 1981 Depreciation Revisions on the Taxation of
Income From Business Capital,” National Tax Journal, vol. 35, no. 1, March 1982, pp. 2-6.
16
Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years
2006-2010, p. 34.
CRS-9
regardless of the size of their gross receipts. They remain exempt as long as their
average annual gross receipts do not exceed $5 million in their first three tax years,
and as long as their average annual gross receipts do not exceed $7.5 million in each
succeeding three-year period (e.g., 1999-2001, 2000-2002, etc.). If a corporation
loses its eligibility, it becomes subject to the AMT in the first tax year when it no
longer qualifies for the exemption and in every tax year thereafter, irrespective of the
size of its gross receipts.
There is some evidence that this exemption may give some eligible small
corporations a slight competitive advantage over comparable firms paying the AMT.
A 1997 study found that firms that invested heavily in machinery and equipment and
intangible assets like research and development (R&D), financed the bulk of their
investments through debt, and paid the AMT for five or more successive years had
a higher cost of capital than comparable firms that paid the regular income tax only
in the same period.17 In addition, the exemption gives owners of small firms an
incentive to incorporate, since the taxable income of passthrough entities is subject
to the individual AMT as well as the regular income tax.
A 2000 report by the Treasury Department’s Inspector General for Tax
Administration (TIGTA) suggested that the implementation of the exemption from
the AMT for small firms ran into some unexpected problems during the first year or
two of the exemption. According to the report, more than 2,300 small corporations
paid the AMT in 1998, though an examination of their federal income tax returns
indicated they qualified for the exemption. Their overpayments of the tax may have
totaled more than $25 million.18 The report attributed the erroneous payments to the
many complex changes in the corporate AMT made by the Taxpayer Relief Act of
1997 and the “short time” available to taxpayers and tax professionals to comprehend
the changes and apply them in filing 1998 tax returns. It recommended that the IRS
take a variety of steps to increase taxpayer awareness of the exemption, explain how
it is intended to work, and identify and contact taxpayers who erroneously paid the
AMT. In a recent follow-up report, TIGTA found that the IRS had taken many of
these steps, but that it still had failed to notify the more than 3,600 taxpayers who
may have mistakenly paid the AMT and fallen short of the agency’s commitment to
“inform and educate tax practitioners on what they need to do on their clients’
behalf.”19
It is not known whether there is a net revenue gain or loss from exempting small
corporations from the AMT. Exempt firms do not compute their AMT liability, but
they could end up paying the regular corporate income tax.
17
Andrew B. Lyon, Cracking the Code: Making Sense of the Corporate Alternative
Minimum Tax (Washington: Brookings Institution Press, 1997), pp. 77-97.
18
Treasury Department, Inspector General for Tax Administration, More Small Corporate
Taxpayers Can Benefit from the Alternative Minimum Tax Exemption Provision, no. 200130-019 (Washington: Nov. 2000), p. 4.
19
Treasury Department, Inspector General for Tax Administration, Significant Actions were
Taken to Address Small Corporations Erroneously Paying the Alternative Minimum Tax,
but Additional Actions Are Still Needed, no. 2003-30-114 (Washington: May 2003), pp. 4-5.
CRS-10
Amortization of Business Start-Up Costs
One of the principles underlying the federal income tax is that taxable income
should exclude all costs incurred in earning it. This implies that all ordinary and
necessary costs incurred in conducting a trade or business should be deducted from
a firm’s taxable income. The principle also implies that ordinary and necessary costs
paid or incurred in connection with starting or organizing a business should not be
deducted from current income. Rather, because these expenses can be viewed as an
attempt to create an asset with a useful life extending beyond one tax year, it can be
argued that they should be capitalized, added to the taxpayer’s basis in the business,
and recovered when the business is sold or ceases to exist.
Under IRC Section 195, however, business taxpayers who incurred or paid
business start-up and organizational costs and then entered the trade or business on
or before October 22, 2004 may amortize (or deduct in equal annual amounts) those
expenditures over not less than five years, beginning in the month when the new
trade or business commenced. But under a provision of the American Jobs Creation
Act of 2004 (P.L. 108-357), business taxpayers who incur or pay business start-up
and organizational costs after October 22, 2004 may be able to deduct up to $5,000
of those costs in the year when the new trade or business begins. This maximum
deduction is reduced (but not below zero) by the amount by which eligible
expenditures exceed $50,000. Any expenditures that cannot be deducted may be
amortized over a period of 180 months, beginning in the month when the new trade
or business commences. In order to claim either allowance, a taxpayer must have an
equity interest in the new trade or business and actively participate in its
management.
To qualify for amortization or the deduction, the start-up and organizational
costs must meet two criteria. First, they must be paid or incurred as part of an
investigation into creating or acquiring an active trade or business, as part of starting
a new trade or business, or as part of any activity done to produce income or profit
before starting a trade or business with the intention of making such activity into an
active trade or business. Second, the costs must be the similar in kind to costs that
would be considered deductible if they were paid or incurred in connection with the
expansion of an existing active trade or business in the same industry entered by the
taxpayer.
Business taxpayers who choose not to claim the deduction must capitalize all
start-up expenses.
The option to deduct as much as $5,000 in business start-up and organizational
costs clearly benefits fledgling firms with relatively small such costs. It permits the
owners of such firms to deduct expenses that otherwise could not be recovered until
they sell their interest in the business. In effect, the option accelerates the recovery
of certain essential up-front costs for these firms, and this acceleration can aid their
formation and growth by reducing the cost of capital and increasing cash flow at a
time when the firms’ access to capital may be severely restricted.
CRS-11
According to the Joint Tax Committee, the amortization or deduction of
qualified business start-up and organizational costs led to an estimated revenue loss
of $0.7 billion in FY2007.20
Cash Basis Accounting
Under IRC Section 446, firms must compute their taxable income according to
the same method of accounting they regularly use in keeping their books. Two
methods of financial accounting are widely used in the private sector: cash-basis and
accrual-basis. Under cash-basis accounting, which is the preferred method for selfemployed individuals, income generally is recorded when it is received in the form
of cash or its equivalent, and expenses generally are recorded when they are paid,
regardless of when the income is actually earned or the expenses are actually
incurred. By contrast, under accrual-basis accounting, income and expenses
generally are recorded when the transactions giving rise to them are completed or
nearly completed, regardless of when cash or its equivalent is received or paid. More
specifically, a firm using accrual-basis accounting records income when its right to
receive it is established, and expenses when the amounts are fixed and its liability for
the expenses is established. Each accounting method has its advantages: in general,
cash-basis accounting is much simpler to administer, but accrual-basis accounting
often yields a more accurate measure of a firm’s economic income because it
matches income with expenses with greater precision and rigor. An important
requirement in selecting an accounting method for tax purposes is that it clearly
reflect a business taxpayer’s income.
Current federal tax law requires firms that maintain inventories to use the
accrual method in computing taxable income. The following entities generally must
also use the accrual method of accounting for tax purposes: C corporations,
partnerships with C corporations as partners, trusts that earn unrelated business
income, and authorized tax shelters.
Nonetheless, the cash method may be used by these entities provided they are
not a tax shelter and fall into one or more of the following categories: (1) the entity
is engaged in farm or tree raising, (2) the entity is a qualified personal service
corporation, or (3) the entity is a firm (including C corporations) with $5 million or
less in average annual gross receipts during the previous three tax years. Moreover,
the IRS has ruled that the cash method of accounting may be used by most sole
proprietorships, S corporations, and partnerships with average annual gross receipts
of $1 million or less in the three previous tax years (IRS Rev. Proc. 2001-10), and by
firms with average annual gross receipts of $10 million or less whose main business
is providing services or fabricating products according to customer designs or
specifications (IRS Rev. Proc. 2002-28).
As these rules suggest, many of the firms permitted to use the cash method for
tax purposes are likely to be small in receipt, asset, or employment size. Cash-basis
accounting can confer the same tax benefit on small firms as the expensing allowance
20
Joint Tax Committee, Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2006-2010,
p. 35.
CRS-12
under IRC Section 179: the deferral of income tax payments. In principle, a firm
earns income when the legal right to be paid comes into existence. Under the cash
method of accounting, however, a firm may delay the recognition of income until
cash payments are received, thereby postponing the payment of tax on that income.
Although many small firms may be eligible to use cash-basis accounting for tax
purposes, it may not always be practical or advisable for them to do so. The reason
lies in the requirements of the income statements and balance sheets used in external
financial reports.21 Cash-basis accounting can distort a firm’s financial position in
at least two ways. First, it records only transactions involving cash or its equivalent,
thereby excluding transactions involving exchanges of assets or liabilities. Second,
the determination of net income under cash-basis accounting can be manipulated by
recording revenues or expenses long before or after goods and services are produced
or sold. Thus, small firms with a strong need to produce reliable and accurate
external financial reports may be better off eschewing cash-basis accounting
altogether.
The Joint Committee on Taxation estimates that the use of cash accounting
outside agriculture resulted in a revenue loss of $0.8 billion in FY2007.22
Tax Incentives for Private Equity Investment in Small firms
The federal tax code also contains several provisions intended to encourage the
investment of private equity capital into some start-up small firms that might
otherwise find it difficult raising the funds needed to finance current operations or
expansions. These provisions, which are described below, do so largely by
increasing the potential after-tax returns or reducing the potential after-tax losses on
equity investment in such firms. The same tax benefits are not available to investors
who acquire equity holdings in larger established firms.
Partial Exclusion of Capital Gains on Certain Small Business Stock.
Two important considerations in determining an individual’s income tax liability are
the recognition of income as ordinary or capital and the distinction between longterm and short-term capital gains or losses. A capital gain or loss arises when an
asset such as a stock or bond is sold or exchanged. If the selling price is greater than
the acquisition or purchase price, then the transaction yields a capital gain.
Conversely, a capital loss results when the selling price is less than the purchase
price. Capital assets held longer than 12 months and then sold or exchanged give rise
to long-term capital gains or losses, whereas sales or exchanges of capital assets held
one year or less produce short-term capital gains or losses. Short-term capital gains
are considered ordinary income and thus are taxed at regular income tax rates. By
contrast, long-term capital gains are considered capital income and thus are taxed at
21
See Robert Libby, Patricia A. Libby, and Daniel G. Short, Financial Accounting (Chicago:
Irwin, 1996), p. 111.
22
Joint Tax Committee, Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2006-2010,
p. 35
CRS-13
rates of 15% for individual taxpayers in income tax brackets above 15% and 5% for
individual taxpayers in the 10% and 15% income tax brackets.23
Under IRC Section 1202, non-corporate taxpayers (including partnerships,
LLCs, and S corporations) may exclude 50% of any gain from the sale or exchange
of qualified small business stock (QSBS) that has been held for more than five years.
The exclusion rises to 60% if the QSBS has been issued by a corporation based in an
empowerment zone. There is a cumulative limit on the gain from stock issued by a
single qualified corporation that may be excluded: in a tax year, the gain is limited
to the greater of 10 times the taxpayer’s adjusted basis of all QSBS issued by the firm
and disposed of during the year, or $10 million — reduced by any gains excluded by
the taxpayer in previous years. The remaining gain is taxed at a fixed rate of 28%.
As a result, the marginal effective tax rate on capital gains from the sale or exchange
of QSBS held for over five years is 14%. For individuals subject to the AMT, a
portion of the excluded gain is treated as an individual AMT preference item, which
means that it must be included in the calculation of AMT taxable income. The
portion is 42% for QSBS acquired on or before December 31, 2000 and disposed of
by May 6, 2003, 28% for QSBS acquired after December 31, 2000 and no later than
May 6, 2003, and 7% for QSBS acquired after May 6, 2003 and by December 31,
2008.24
To qualify for the partial exclusion, small business stock must satisfy certain
requirements. First, it must be issued after August 10, 1993 and must be acquired by
the taxpayer at its original issue, either directly or through an underwriter, in
exchange for money, property, or as compensation for services rendered to the issuer.
Second, the stock must be issued by a domestic C corporation whose gross assets do
not exceed $50 million before and immediately after the stock is issued. Third, at
least 80% of the corporation’s assets must be tied to the active conduct of one or
more qualified trades or businesses during “substantially all” of the five-year holding
period. Assets linked to working capital, start-up activities, or research and
development meet the active business test even if they are devoted largely to the
development of future assets or lines of business. Specialized small business
investment companies licensed under the Small Business Investment Act of 1958
also meet the active business test, making their stock eligible for the partial
exclusion.
Some small firms cannot benefit from the partial exclusion. Specifically, stock
issued by small C corporations primarily engaged in one of the following commercial
activities does not qualify for the partial gains exclusion: health care, law,
23
Under the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 (JGTRRA, P.L. 10827), the 15% rate applies to assets sold or exchanged after May 6, 2003 and before January
1, 2009; and the 5% rate to assets sold or exchanged after May 6, 2003 and before January
1, 2008. In 2008, long-term capital gains received by taxpayers in the 10% and 15% income
tax brackets are exempt from taxation, making the rate 0%. Assuming no change in current
tax law, beginning in 2009 and thereafter, the maximum long-term capital gains tax rates
will rise to 20% for taxpayers in income tax brackets above 15% and 10% for taxpayers
subject to marginal rates of 10% and 15%.
24
The 7% rate stems from a provision in JGTRRA.
CRS-14
engineering, architecture, hospitality, farming, insurance, finance, and mineral
extraction. And stock issued by the following domestic C corporations is not eligible
for the partial exclusion: current or former domestic international sales corporations
(DISCs), regulated investment companies (RICs), real estate investment trusts
(REITs), real estate mortgage investment conduits (REMICs), financial asset
securitization investment trusts (FASITs), cooperatives, or C corporations that have
claimed the possessions tax credit under IRC Section 936.
The partial exclusion for QSBS is intended to make it easier for small start-up
firms in a variety of industries to raise equity capital, despite considerable uncertainty
or skepticism among investors about their growth potential and future prospects for
commercial success. It does this by increasing the potential after-tax returns an
investor can earn on sales or exchanges of QSBS, relative to potential after-tax
returns on other investment opportunities, over five years.
JGTRRA substantially diluted the investment incentive provided by the partial
exclusion. Before the act, the maximum tax rates on long-term capital gains were
20% on assets held for at least one year and 18% for assets acquired after December
31, 2000 and held for more than five years, while the effective tax rate on capital
gains realized on sales or exchanges of QSBS was 14%. Though JGTRRA unified
and lowered the maximum tax rate on long-term capital gains to 15%, it made no
compensatory change in the taxation of capital gains on QSBS.
An estimated $270 million in revenue was not be collected in FY2007 because
of the exclusion.25
Losses on Small Business Investment Company Stock Treated as
Ordinary Losses without Limitation. Generally, losses on stock investments
are treated as capital losses for tax purposes. These losses may be used to offset any
capital gains in the same tax year, but individuals may use capital losses to offset no
more than $3,000 of ordinary income in a single tax year.
Under IRC Section 1242, however, individuals who invest in small business
investment companies (SBICs) are permitted to deduct from ordinary income all
losses from the sale or exchange or worthlessness of stock in these companies. This
treatment is intended to foster private equity investment in these companies by
lowering the potential after-tax loss on an investment in a SBIC, relative to potential
after-tax losses on alternative investments.
SBICs are private regulated investment corporations that are licensed under the
Small Business Investment Act of 1958 to provide equity capital, long-term loans,
and managerial guidance to firms with a net worth of less than $18 million and less
than $6 million in average net income over the previous two years. They use their
own capital and funds borrowed with a SBA guarantee to make equity and debt
25
U.S. Office of Management and Budget, Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal
Year 2008: Analytical Perspectives (Washington: GPO, 2007), table 19-1, p. 288.
CRS-15
investments in qualified firms. For tax purposes, most SBICs are treated as C
corporations. In FY2002, SBICs provided $2.5 billion in financing for 2,610 firms.25
There are no known estimates of the revenue loss associated with this small
business tax benefit.
Rollover of Gains into Specialized Small Business Investment
Companies. In general, gains or losses on the sale or exchange of stocks are
recognized for tax purposes in the same year they are realized.
But under IRC Section 1044, which entered the federal tax code through the
Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1993, individual and corporate taxpayers who
satisfy certain conditions are allowed to roll over, free of tax, any capital gains on the
sale of publicly traded securities. The proceeds from the sale must be used to
purchase common stock or partnership interests in specialized small business
investment companies (SSBICs) licensed under the Small Business Investment Act
of 1958 within 60 days of the sale. SSBICs are similar to SBICs except that SSBICs
are required to invest in small firms owned by individuals who are considered
socially or economically disadvantaged — mainly members of minority groups. If
the proceeds from the sale exceed the cost of the SSBIC stock or partnership interest,
the excess is recognized as a capital gain and taxed accordingly. The taxpayer’s basis
in the SSBIC stock or partnership interest is reduced by the amount of any gain from
the sale of securities that is rolled over. The maximum gain that an individual can
roll over in a single tax year is the lesser of $50,000 or $500,000 less any gains
previously rolled over under this provision. For corporations, the maximum deferral
in a tax year is $250,000 or $1 million less any previously deferred gains.
There are no known estimates of the revenue loss associated with this small
business tax benefit.
Ordinary Income Treatment of Losses on Sales of Small Business
Stock. IRC Section 1244 allows taxpayers to deduct any loss from the sale,
exchange, or worthlessness of small business stock as an ordinary loss, rather than
a capital loss. For business taxpayers, ordinary losses are treated as business losses
for the sake of computing a net operating loss.
To qualify for this treatment, the stock must satisfy four criteria. First, it must
be issued by a domestic corporation after November 6, 1978. Second, the stock must
be acquired by an individual investor or his or her partnership in exchange for money
or other property, but not stock or securities. Third, the stock must be issued by a
small business corporation, which the statute defines as a corporation whose total
amount of money and property received as a contribution to capital and paid-in
surplus does not exceed $1 million when it issues the stock. Finally, during the five
tax years before loss on the stock is recognized, the firm must have derived more
than 50% of its gross receipts from sources other than royalties, rents, dividends,
interest, annuities, and stock or security transactions. The maximum amount that
25
See the website for the U.S. Small Business Administration’s SBIC program:
[http://www.sba.gov/INV/].
CRS-16
may be deducted as an ordinary loss in a tax year is $50,000 (or $100,000 for a
couple filing jointly).
This special treatment produced an estimated revenue loss of $50 million in
FY2007.26
Uniform Capitalization of Inventory Costs
Firms that earn income from the production, purchase, or sale of merchandise
are required to maintain inventories in order to determine the cost of goods sold
during a tax year. This cost is then subtracted from gross receipts in the computation
of their taxable income. In most cases, the cost of goods sold is calculated by adding
the value of a firm’s inventory at the beginning of the year to purchases of inventory
items made during the year and subtracting from that total the value of the firm’s
inventory at the end of the year.
IRC Section 263A requires business taxpayers engaged in the production of real
or tangible property, or in the purchase of real or tangible and intangible property for
resale, to “capitalize” (or include in the estimated value of their inventories) both the
direct costs of the property included in inventory and the indirect costs that can be
allocated to it. This requirement is known as the uniform capitalization rule and was
added to the tax code by the Tax Reform Act of 1986. In general, direct costs are the
material and labor costs arising from the production or acquisition of goods, and
indirect costs are the other costs incurred through the production or acquisition of
goods (e.g., repair and maintenance of equipment and facilities, utilities, insurance,
rental of equipment, land, or facilities, and certain administrative costs). Taxpayers
have some discretion in allocating indirect costs to production or resale activities, as
long as the methods used in the allocation produce reasonable and defensible results
for their trade or business.
Some small firms are exempt from the uniform capitalization rule. Specifically,
it does not apply to tangible or intangible property acquired for resale by a business
taxpayer with average annual gross receipts of $10 million or less in the previous
three tax years.
This exemption is advantageous because eligible firms face lower administrative
costs and less complexity in complying with income tax laws and have more control
over the timing of business expense deductions, creating opportunities for the
deferral of income tax liabilities.27
There are no known estimates of the revenue loss associated with this small
business tax benefit.
26
Office of Management and Budget, Budget of the U.S. Government in Fiscal Year 2008,
table 19-1, p. 288.
27
See Paul G. Schloemer, “Simplifying the Uniform Inventory Capitalization Rules,” Tax
Notes, vol. 53, no. 9, Dec. 2, 1991, pp. 1065-1069.
CRS-17
Simplified Dollar-Value LIFO
Accounting Method for Small Firms
Business taxpayers that maintain inventories to determine the cost of goods sold
in a tax year must estimate the value of their inventories at the beginning and end of
each tax year. Because it is time-consuming and costly to do this item by item, many
taxpayers use methods that assume certain item or cost flows.
One such method is known as “last-in-first-out”(or LIFO). LIFO assumes that
the most recently acquired goods are sold first. Consequently, LIFO allocates the
newest unit costs to the cost of goods sold and the oldest unit costs to the ending
inventory. The method can be advantageous to use when the cost of many inventory
items is rising, because LIFO yields a lower taxable income and inventory valuation
than other methods. There are various ways to apply LIFO. A widely used
application is known as the dollar-value method. Under this method, a taxpayer
accounts for its inventories on the basis of a pool of dollars rather than item by item.
Each pool includes the value of a variety of inventory items and is measured in terms
of the equivalent dollar value of the inventory items at the time they were first added
to the inventory account, or the base year. Using the dollar-value method is
complicated and costly for most taxpayers.28
But IRC Section 474, which was established by the Tax Reform Act of 1986,
allows some small firms to use a simplified dollar-value LIFO method. It differs
from the regular dollar-value method in the way in which inventory items are pooled,
and in the technique for estimating the base-year value of the pools. A firm is
eligible to use the simplified method if its average annual gross receipts were $5
million or less in the three previous tax years.
There are no known estimates of the revenue cost of this small business tax
benefit.
Tax Credit for Pension Plan Start-Up Costs of Small Firms
Under IRC Section 45E, qualified small firms may claim a non-refundable tax
credit for a portion of the start-up costs involved in setting up new retirement plans
for employees. The credit, which was enacted as part of the Economic Growth and
Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001, began in 2002 and originally was scheduled
to disappear (or “sunset”) after 2010. Section 811 of the Pension Protection Act of
2006 permanently extended the credit. It is a component of the general business
credit and thus subject to its limitations and rules for carryover.
The credit is equal to 50% of the first $1,000 in eligible costs incurred in each
of the first three years of a qualified pension plan’s existence. Eligible costs are
defined as the ordinary and necessary expenses incurred in connection with the
28
For more details on this method, see U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, Impact
on Small Business of Replacing the Federal Income Tax, JCS-3-96 (Washington, Apr. 23,
1996), pp. 18-19.
CRS-18
administration of the plan and the education of employees about the plan’s benefits
and requirements. Qualified plans include new defined benefit plans, defined
contribution plans, savings incentive match plans for employees, and simplified
employee pension plans. Firms with fewer than 100 employees who received at least
$5,000 in compensation in the previous year are eligible to claim the credit. They
can do so only if at least one highly compensated employee participates in the plan.
The credit is intended to give owners of small firms that never have offered
retirement benefits to employees a robust incentive to establish pension plans for
employees by reducing the after-tax cost of setting up and administering these plans
in their early years. Recent surveys have indicated that these costs often constitute
a formidable barrier to the creation of pension plans among small employers.
The Joint Committee on Taxation has estimated that less than $50 million in
revenues was foregone in FY2007 because of the credit.29
Magnitude of Small Business Tax Benefits
By now it should be clear that the federal tax code encourages the formation of
small firms and fosters their growth in a variety of ways. What is not clear is the
extent to which the tax code generally favors smaller firms over larger ones.
Answering this question raises difficult analytical issues that go beyond the scope of
this report. Nonetheless, it is possible to illustrate the potential magnitude of specific
small business tax preferences.
Consider the expensing allowance under IRC Section 179. In the minds of
many, the allowance epitomizes small business tax subsidies, even though its revenue
cost can be much lower than that of some other small business tax preferences and
many firms outside manufacturing derive little or no benefit from it. In a 1995 study,
Douglas Holtz-Eakin analyzed the effect of the expensing allowance on a firm’s user
cost of capital. As noted earlier, expensing stimulates business investment by
reducing the user cost of capital. Table 1 summarizes his findings.30 The first
column gives the assumed corporate tax rate; the second shows the required pre-tax
rate of return if the entire cost of the investment is expensed; the third provides the
required pre-tax rate of return if the entire cost is recovered through the depreciation
allowances allowed under federal tax law in the early 1990s; and the final column
displays the effective tax subsidy from expensing, which is expressed as the
difference (in percentage points) between the required rates of return shown in
columns three and two.
At least two conclusions can be drawn from the results. First, expensing
constituted a significant investment subsidy, and the extent of the subsidy rose with
29
Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years
2006-2010, p. 40.
30
Douglas Holtz-Eakin, “Should Small Businesses Be Tax-Favored?,” Tax Notes, vol. 48,
No. 3, Sept. 1995, p. 389. (In 2003, Dr. Holtz-Eakin was named the Director of the
Congressional Budget Office.)
CRS-19
a firm’s marginal tax rate. For example, at a tax rate of 15%, expensing lowered the
user cost of capital by about 11%; but at a rate of 35%, the reduction jumped to 28%.
Second, the user cost of capital under expensing fell as the tax rate increased because
tax deductions became increasingly valuable at higher tax rates.
Table 1. Estimated User Cost of Capital Under-Expensing
(%)
Corporate Tax
Rate
Expensing
Regular
Depreciation
Size of Subsidy
15%
17.95%
20.23%
2.28a
25
17.05
21.13
4.08
35
16.15
22.40
6.25
Source: Douglas Holtz-Eakin, “Should Small Business Be Tax-Favored?,” National Tax Journal,
Sept. 1995.
a
Percentage points, not percent.
Note: The calculations assume an interest rate of 9%, an inflation rate of 3%, and a rate of economic
depreciation of 13.3%. The following formula is used to compute the user cost of capital:
c / q = ( p - π + d /1 − t ) × (1 − tz ),
where c is the annual value of revenue from the investment, q is the purchase price of the capital
good, p is the after-tax financial cost of capital, pi is the rate of inflation, d is the rate of geometric
depreciation, t is the marginal tax rate, and z is the present value of depreciation allowances per
dollar of investment. In the case of expensing, z = 1.0; and in the case of regular depreciation, z =
0.2814.
Economic Role of Small Firms
Available data on the economic role of small firms indicate they make
significant contributions to the U.S. economy. A critical consideration in assessing
those contributions is the definition of a small firm. When small firms are defined
as independent business enterprises with fewer than 500 employees, they account for
over 99% of employers, more than 50% of private non-farm employment, about 47%
of private non-farm compensation (wages, salaries, and benefits), and over 50% of
nominal gross domestic product (GDP) in 2004.31 The economic importance of small
firms varies by industry. In 2002, the share of an industry’s contribution to GDP
accounted for by firms with fewer than 500 employees ranged from 20% for
information to 85% for other services.32 In addition, small firms generate a large
share of the new domestic jobs created each year. According to data reported by the
31
Small Business Administration, Office of Advocacy, Frequently Asked Questions
(Washington: August 2007), and Katherine Kobe, The Small Business Share of GDP, 19982004, report for the Small Business Administration (Washington: Apr. 2007), pp. 7 and 13.
32
Katherine Kobe, The Small Business Share of GDP, 1998-2004, p. 7.
CRS-20
Bureau of Labor Statistics, firms with less than 500 employees accounted for 65%
of net new job creation in the non-farm private sector, from the third quarter of 1992
through the first quarter of 2005.33
Most firms start out small in employment size, and their chances of eventually
growing into large successful firms are less than promising. Two-thirds of new firms
survive at least two years, and 44% last at least four years.34 Or, looking at it from the
flip side, well over one half don’t survive into their fifth year. Thus, while hundreds
of thousands of new firms come into existence annually, hundreds of thousands
existing firms cease functioning. This constant churning is reflected in the
fluctuating contributions of small firms to annual net job creation.
Small firms also make important contributions to the process of technological
innovation. According to a 2003 study by CHI Research, Inc., firms with fewer than
500 employees accounted for 41% of all patents filed by U.S. corporations from 1996
to 2000, and firms of that size produced 13 to 14 times as many patents per employee
as comparable large firms.35 The researchers also found that small firms filed 25%
of the patents related to biotechnology, 19% of the patents related to pharmaceuticals,
11% of the patents related to medical equipment and electronics, and 9% of the
patents related to chemicals other than pharmaceuticals.36
Economic Arguments For and Against Small
Business Tax Preferences
The economic importance of small firms as a whole calls into question the
underlying economic rationale for existing small business tax subsidies and proposals
to enhance them or add new ones. It is fair to ask why the subsidies are needed if
small firms normally account for substantial shares of domestic employment and
output and play vital roles in the commercial development of new technologies.
The answer to this question has implications for U.S. social welfare, as small
firms received over $11 billion in tax benefits in FY2007 — in addition to the
financial support they receive through other federal programs intended to aid small
business. If the economic arguments made in favor of these tax subsidies turn out to
be weak or untenable, then using these resources for other applications (e.g., reducing
the federal budget deficit or raising federal spending on public education or basic
research) may lead to better economic outcomes for a greater numbers of firms and
individuals.
33
Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, New Quarterly Data from BLS on
Business Employment Dynamics by Size of Firm (Washington: Dec. 2005), p. 3.
34
Small Business Administration, Frequently Asked Questions, Aug. 2007.
35
CHI Research, Inc., Small Serial Innovators: The Small Firm Contribution to Technical
Change, report for the Small Business Administration (Washington: 2003), p 3.
36
Ibid., p. 17.
CRS-21
In evaluating the economic arguments made in favor of small business tax
benefits, it should be recognized that persuasive non-economic arguments can be
made in favor of these benefits. Some lawmakers may assign a greater weight to
those arguments than any economic argument.
Nevertheless, the central focus of this section is the economic arguments for and
against such proposals and their merits. These arguments are discussed below.
Chief Economic Arguments in Favor of the Preferences
Proponents of small business tax subsidies generally cite four economic
justifications for them: (1) the special economic role played by small firms; (2) the
formidable barriers to their formation and growth in financial markets; (3) the impact
of relatively high marginal tax rates on the formation of small firms, and (4) the
unique opportunities for individual economic advancement offered by small business
ownership. Each is examined in some detail here.
Special Economic Role of Small Firms. As surprising as it may seem, the
economic contributions of small firms are often cited as reasons to provide federal
support for small business. For example, in his 2001 Senate floor remarks calling for
additional tax benefits for small firms, Senator Christopher Bond noted that “small
businesses represent more than 99% of all employers, employ 53% of the private
work force, create about 75% of the new jobs in this country, ... contribute 47% of
all sales in this country, and ... are responsible for 51% of private gross domestic
product.”37 Similarly, Senator Olympia Snowe asked for more tax benefits for small
firms in a 2003 floor statement: “[T]hey (small businesses) represent 99% of all
employers, employ 51% of private-sector workforce, provide about 75% of the net
new jobs, contribute 51% of the private-sector output, and represent 96% of all
exporters of goods.”38
Proponents of small business tax subsidies also point to the gains in economic
efficiency, dynamic structural changes, and important technological innovations often
attributed to small firms as justifications for the subsidies.
The gains in economic efficiency are thought to lie in evidence that small firms
supply certain goods and services more efficiently than large firms. As economist
Bo Carlsson has noted, this advantage can be found in industries where large
production runs and falling unit costs are dominant structural features; examples
include computers, automobiles, and steel.39 In industries such as these, small and
large firms tend to specialize in different products or services. As a result, they often
37
Sen. Christopher Bond, remarks in the Senate, Congressional Record, daily edition, vol.
147, Jan. 25, 2001, p. S576.
38
Sen. Olympia Snowe, remarks in the Senate, Congressional Record, daily edition, vol.
149, no. 6, Jan. 14, 2003, p. S299.
39
Bo Carlsson, “Small Business, Entrepreneurship, and Industrial Dynamics,” in Are Small
Firms Important? Their Role and Impact, Zoltan J. Acs, ed. (Boston: Kluwer Academic
Publishers, 1999), p. 100.
CRS-22
end up interacting more as close collaborators than as fierce competitors. In
Carlsson’s view, the dramatic rise in outsourcing among large U.S. firms in the
1990s had the effect of further hardening this division in labor between large and
small firms. Among the reputed advantages of small firms in the vast and complex
chain of supply undergirding the U.S. economy is greater flexibility in responding to
new market opportunities and competitive threats.
The belief that small firms can serve as powerful agents of dynamic economic
change and technological advance appears rooted in the critical roles played by small
start-up firms in the origins and rapid growth of certain high-technology industries
like computers and microelectronics. Two notable findings in the recent literature
on firm size and technological innovation are the contribution of small firms to
innovation seems to vary by industry, and that their contributions are likely to be
most significant in relatively young industries with relatively low levels of
concentration.40 The same literature offers some fresh evidence that in certain
industries small start-up firms are more adept than large established firms at
identifying promising commercial applications for new technologies and exploiting
these opportunities. During the 1980s and 1990s, many striking examples of this
competitive advantage emerged in biotechnology, microelectronics, computer
software, and electronic commerce.41
Experiences such as these have led some economists to conclude that small
entrepreneurial firms collectively serve as a vital and indispensable source of
economic growth and renewal. They contend that economic growth is marked by the
continuous creation and destruction of jobs and firms, and that small entrepreneurial
firms inject needed innovation and competition into this process. Carlsson has
claimed that without the “heterogeneity and volatility” provided by small start-up
firms, “the economy eventually stagnates or even collapses.”42
Opportunities for the Social and Economic Advancement of
Immigrants, Women, and Members of Minority Groups. Proponents of
small business tax subsidies also cite the benefits of small business ownership for
women, minority groups, immigrants, and the communities where they reside as an
important justification for the subsidies. They argue that owning and managing a
small business gives them access to the social and economic mainstream in the
United States. In addition, proponents claim that women-, minority-, and immigrantowned small firms benefit their immediate communities and society at large in ways
that go beyond direct economic effects.
There is evidence that female small business owners are more likely than their
male counterparts to encourage openness in workplace communication and decisionmaking, hire a diverse workforce, put into place desirable child-care programs, and
pay full benefits to employees. In addition, families with self-employed women who
40
Joshua Lerner, “Small Business, Innovation, and Public Policy,” in Are Small Firms
Important? Their Role and Impact, p. 160.
41
Ibid., p. 160.
42
Bo Carlsson, “Small Business, Entrepreneurship, and Industrial Dynamics,” p. 109.
CRS-23
work out of their homes are more stable than the average family.43 And in the case
of minority and immigrant groups, small business ownership helps to build tight-knit
social networks, providing job and skills training, and creating informal capital
markets.44
Imperfections in Capital Markets. Yet another economic argument made
in favor of small business tax subsidies is that they can ease or offset the barriers
faced by many small business owners and aspiring entrepreneurs to raising funds to
start or expand a business. If capital markets were truly efficient, then every small
business investment opportunity offering a rate of return above the cost of capital
would obtain the needed funding, regardless of the creditworthiness of the owners.
But proponents of government support for small business say that such is not the
case. In their view, many potential and current entrepreneurs are unable to borrow
or attract equity capital, largely because of inadequate information on the part of
lenders and investors. As a consequence, small business owners facing such a
constraint often are forced to finance projects out of their own resources or the
resources of friends and family members, or to abandon the projects altogether.
Small business owners facing severe liquidity constraints have an elevated risk of
failure.
Impact of Progressive Income Taxes. Supporters of tax relief for small
firms also maintain that taxes have a significant effect on three key decisions made
by any small business owners: how fast to grow the firm; whether to expand capital
investment — and if so, by how much; and whether to hire more employees — and
if so, how many? They cite a variety of studies suggesting that as individual or
corporate tax rates rise, small firms grow at a slower rate, invest less in new tangible
and intangible assets, and become increasingly less likely to expand employment.45
In their view, these effects, especially when contrasted with the economic
contributions of small firms (especially those that can rightly be called
entrepreneurial), offer a compelling argument in favor of granting/offering tax breaks
to these firms.
Chief Economic Arguments Against the Subsidies
While acknowledging the significant economic role played by small firms, some
analysts maintain it cannot serve as a justification for targeting tax subsidies at small
firms. Conventional economic analysis holds that government intervention in the
economy is warranted mainly to correct some kind of market failure. In general,
43
See Candida Brush and Robert D. Hisrich, “Women-Owned Businesses: Why Do They
Matter?,” in Are Small Firms Important? Their Role and Impact, pp. 111-127.
44
See John Sibley Butler and Patricia Gene Greene, “Don’t Call Me Small: The
Contribution of Ethnic Enterprises to the Economic and Social Well-Being of America,” in
Are Small Firms Important? Their Role and Impact (Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers,
1999), pp. 129-145.
45
Douglas Holtz-Eakin and Harvey Rosen, Economic Policy and the Start-up, Survival, and
Growth of Entrepreneurial Ventures, report submitted to the Small Business Administration,
May 2001, pp. 43-44.
CRS-24
market failures can be thought of as conditions that prevent or unduly retard the
emergence of economically efficient outcomes. Foremost among these conditions
are a lack of perfect competition, the presence of public goods, positive or negative
external effects (or externalities), the existence of incomplete markets, and imperfect
information on the part of consumers.46 Critics of small business tax subsidies say
there is no evidence that a market failure stands in the way of the formation or growth
of small firms. Moreover, by their way of thinking, such subsidies are likely to lead
to undesirable equity and efficiency effects.
Equity Concerns. Proponents of small business tax preferences generally do
not refer to their equity effects in defending them on economic grounds.
But critics maintain no such silence. In their view, small business tax
preferences undercut the progressivity of the federal individual income tax. Under
a progressive income tax, an individual’s tax liability depends on his or her income
so that taxpayers with higher taxable incomes pay higher taxes than taxpayers with
lower taxable incomes. But small business tax preferences weaken the link between
tax burden and income by reducing the tax burden on the earnings of small firms. It
is an axiom of public finance that individuals, and not firms, ultimately bear the
burden of business income taxes. While all owners of capital can be expected to
benefit from small business tax preferences, most of those benefits presumably end
up in the hands of small business owners, whose income and wealth tend to be well
above average for U.S. households.47
Efficiency Concerns. Critics also criticize small business tax subsidies on
efficiency grounds. In theory, income taxes reduce social welfare by distorting the
behavior of consumers and firms. As a result, the most desirable income taxes are
those that raise the needed revenue without preventing economic resources from
flowing to their most productive uses.
This doctrine of neutrality has important implications for tax policy. First, it
implies that the returns to all investments should be taxed at the same rate. Second,
the doctrine implies that any tax that is not uniform across firms may cause social
46
For more information on market failures, see Joseph E. Stiglitz, Economics of the Public
Sector, 3rd Edition (New York: W.W. Norton & Co., 2000), pp. 76-90.
47
According to a 1990 study by Charles Brown, James Hamilton, and James Medoff, the
average family owning a small business had an income that was 80% greater and wealth that
was five times greater than the average family. (See Charles Brown, James Hamilton, and
James Medoff, Employers Large and Small (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
1990), pp. 15-17.) More recently, in a study of the wealth and income of U.S. small
business owners from 1992 to 2001, researchers George W. Haynes and Charles Ou found
that, in 2001, the mean income of households with small business owners was $110,370,
compared to $42,108 for households with no business owners, and the mean net worth of
households with small business owners was $1,050,872, compared to $188,535 for
households with no business owners. (See George W. Haynes and Charles Ou, How Did
Small Business-Owning Households Fare During the longest U.S. Economic Expansion?,
report prepared for the Small Business Administration (Washington: June 2006) table 3, p.
26.
CRS-25
welfare to be less than optimal.48 Finally, it implies that taxes should not distort a
firm’s choice of inputs or its investment or production decisions.
Small business tax preferences, say critics, violate each of these policy
prescriptions. In their view, an efficient or desirable allocation of resources can be
achieved only if the tax code does not favor small firms over large firms, or
unincorporated firms over incorporated firms, or interfere with the natural growth
and evolution of firms, or encourage firms to attain a particular asset, employment,
or revenue size and remain there.49
A departure from the doctrine of neutral taxation to assist small firms might be
warranted if there were something uniquely valuable about the economic role of such
firms that can flourish only through targeted government support. Proponents of
small business tax preferences claim that small firms consistently create more jobs
and spawn more important technological innovations than large firms, and that
government support in the guise of tax subsidies is needed to ensure that they
continue to play these roles. But critics question both the premises and policy
recommendation of this argument.
Critics and proponents alike agree that small firms generally are a robust source
of job creation. According to data from the Small Business Administration, small
firms created between half and three-quarters of all new jobs from 1990 to 1997,
depending on how the employment size of a small firm is specified.50
Critics maintain, however, that for a variety of reasons these data do not
necessarily prove that small firms have a greater job-creating prowess than large
firms. To begin with, they note that the data raise more questions than they answer:
What does it mean to be small? When should a firm’s size be measured? Is gross
or net job creation a better indicator of job-creating prowess? And how long should
a job last before it is counted as a new job?
In addition, critics say there is an abundance of evidence that small firms are not
demonstrably and consistently better at creating jobs than large firms. First, there
appears to be considerable variation over time in the share of new jobs created by
small firms. In a widely cited study, David Birch and James Medoff estimated that
the share of total net new jobs generated by firms employing 100 or fewer workers
varied from about 40% to 140%, depending on the stage of the business cycle.51
48
Stiglitz, Economics of the Public Sector, pp. 567-569.
49
Douglas Holtz-Eakin, “Should Small Businesses be Tax-Favored?,” National Tax Journal,
vol. 48, no. 3, Sept. 1995, p. 390.
50
U.S. Small Business Administration, Office of Advocacy, Small Business FAQ,
(Washington: Dec. 2000).
51
See David Birch and James Medoff, “Gazelles,” in Labor Markets, Employment Policy,
and Job Creation, Lewis C. Solomon and Alec R. Levenson, eds. (Boulder, CO: Westview
Press, 1994), p. 162. The share of net new jobs created by firms with 100 or fewer workers
can exceed 100% in a year if these firms create more jobs than they destroy, all other firms
(continued...)
CRS-26
Second, most jobs created by small firms are created by new firms, which typically
start out small in employment or asset size. Yet many of these jobs do not last a long
time because most new firms fail within their first few years.52 Third, a few firms
accounted for most small business job creation between the late 1980s and early
1990s — Birch and Medoff labeled these firms “gazelles” — and these firms grew
swiftly from small to large, and in some cases from large back to small, suggesting
that their job-creating ability was unstable at best.53 Finally, during the 1970s and
1980s, large firms and plants dominated job creation and destruction in the
manufacturing sector, and there was no strong, systematic relationship between firm
size and net job growth rates.54
Critics also contend that even if small firms were to create more jobs than large
firms over time, there is no reason to think that government support for small
business would lead to faster employment growth. Economic analysis indicates that
the economy generates jobs through what can be described as a natural process of
growth, decline, and structural change; the size distribution of firms seems irrelevant
to this process. From this perspective, the level of national employment results from
a mix of factors that would swamp the employment effects of any government
support for small business. The key factors are fiscal and monetary policy, consumer
spending, business investment, and the difference between U.S. exports and imports.
Research and development (R&D) is the lifeblood of technological innovation,
which, in turn, serves as a primary engine of long-term economic growth.
Economists generally agree that without government support, business investment
in R&D would fall short of the socially optimal amount. Left to their own devices,
firms are likely to invest too little in R&D for two reasons. One is that they cannot
capture all the returns to R&D investment, mainly because other firms are able to
capitalize on the results of research in spite of available intellectual property
protection. A second reason is that some firms lack access to sufficient capital to
invest in R&D because they are unwilling or unable to provide investors with the
information they require to evaluate the potential returns on planned R&D
investments.55 This tendency to invest too little in R&D represents a market failure
in that too few resources are allocated to R&D in light of its potential economic
51
(...continued)
destroy more jobs than they create, and the net job gain arising from the former exceeds the
net job loss arising from the latter. For example, if firms with 100 or fewer employees
account for a net job gain of 100 and all other firms generate a net job loss of 25, then the
economy as a whole would realize a net job gain of 75, and the share of that gain attributable
to firms with 100 or fewer employees would be 133%.
52
Ibid., p. 8.
53
Birch and Medoff, “Gazelles,” pp. 162-164.
54
Steven J. Davis, John C. Haltiwanger, and Scott Schuh, Job Creation and Destruction
(Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1996), pp. 169-170.
55
Scott J. Wallsten, “Rethinking the Small Business Innovation Research Program,” in
Investing in Innovation: Creating a Research and Innovation Policy That Works, Lewis M.
Branscomb and James H. Keller, eds. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1998), p. 197.
CRS-27
benefits. To remedy this failure, many economists recommend government
intervention to encourage business R&D investment.
But critics of small business tax subsidies maintain that it is far from clear that
government support for this investment should be targeted at small firms. They point
to abundant evidence suggesting that both small and large firms launch the
innovations that help propel the processes of economic growth and structural change,
and that it is impossible to disentangle the contributions of one group from the other.
According to data reported by the National Science Foundation (NSF), larger firms
perform the vast share of business R&D: from 1992 to 1997, for example,
companies with fewer than 500 employees accounted for 14% of total business R&D
spending, whereas companies with 10,000 or more employees were responsible for
59% of these expenditures.56
Nonetheless, small firms and large firms each appear to have distinct advantages
as agents of technological innovation.57 In addition, numerous studies have looked
at the effects of firm size and market structure on innovation.58 On the whole, they
have found that no firm size is ideal for generating new successful commercial
technologies. Rather, there is evidence that in some industries, small firms were
more innovative than large firms, but in other industries, large firms had a decisive
edge in the generation of new technologies.
Other Concerns. Critics also question the suitability and effectiveness of
some current or proposed small business tax subsidies.
One argument made in favor of these subsidies is that the creation of new small
firms is needed to prevent the development of monopoly power by large firms. But
critics contend that the best way to achieve such a policy goal does not involve
government support for the formation and growth of small firms. They point out that
only a tiny share of small start-up firms survive and grow large enough to pose a
serious competitive threat to large entrenched firms in the same industry. In the view
of critics, antitrust law is a more effective policy tool than small business tax
subsidies for preventing the rise of monopoly power and other anti-competitive
business practices.
56
National Science Board, Science & Engineering Indicators — 2000, Vol. 1 (Arlington,
VA: 2000), appendix table 2-54, pp. A-97 and A-98.
57
On the one hand, small firms may have a greater potential than large firms to create
or dominate a new industry through R&D and may be more flexible than large firms
in the pursuit of promising R&D projects. On the other hand, large firms can more
easily cover the substantial sunken costs involved in conducting R&D and are more
likely to capture a large share of the returns to R&D investments through marketing
campaigns, the protection of intellectual property rights, and the creation of regional,
national, and international distribution and service and repair networks. See Wallsten,
“Rethinking the Small Business Innovation Research Program,” p. 197.
58
F. M. Scherer and David Ross, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance,
3rd edition (Boston: Houghton Mifflin Co., 1990), pp. 651-657.
CRS-28
Critics also note that if the aim of public policy is to stimulate employment
growth, then it makes little sense to offer small firms tax subsidies that lower the cost
of capital. The current expensing allowance is a case in point. Such a subsidy lowers
the cost of capital relative to labor, thereby encouraging small firms to substitute
machinery and equipment for labor. In theory, a tax subsidy like the allowance leads
to fewer workers being employed than would be the case in the absence of the
allowance.
Finally, critics argue that small business tax preferences should be avoided or
minimized because they impose an implicit or a hidden tax on business growth. This
tax has been described as the “notch problem,” and it is an inevitable result of the
design of many current tax preferences targeted at small firms. Under the typical
small business tax preference, firms lose the tax benefit when their workforce, assets,
or receipts surpass a certain limit specified by law. Such a design creates a
disincentive to grow beyond that limit.
The expensing allowance under IRC Section 179 illustrates this pitfall. In 2003,
the maximum allowance was $100,000 and the phaseout threshold was $400,000.
When a firm increased its investment that year in assets that qualified for the
allowance beyond $400,000, the amount that could be expensed was reduced dollar
for dollar, ultimately to zero when total investment reached $500,000. In effect, this
design gave firms an incentive to invest no more than $100,000 in qualified assets
in a single tax year. For any investment, the cost of capital depends in part on the
investor’s marginal tax rate. Jane Gravelle of CRS has estimated that under the
expensing allowance for 2003, the marginal effective tax rate on investment in
equipment was 0% on the first $100,000, 26% on amounts over $100,000 to
$400,000, 43% on amounts over $400,000 to $500,000, and 26% on amounts above
$500,000.59 Douglas Holtz-Eakin has pointed out that the design of the allowance
effectively raises a firm’s cost of capital at a time when its growth is boosting its
capital needs.60
Conclusions
There is no question that small firms make important contributions to the
performance and growth of the U.S. economy. Of course, the magnitude of the
contributions depends on how a small firm is defined. Under the definition used by
the SBA in administering its programs, it is fair to say that small business accounts
for a majority of private-sector jobs and private-sector output, generates many key
technological innovations, and serves as a potent agent of revitalization and structural
change in a variety of industries.
59
The estimate assumes a rate of inflation of 2% and a corporate tax rate of 35%. It is based
on a simulation done by Gravelle with the aid of the CRS capital stock model on May 9,
2003.
60
Holtz-Eakin, “Should Small Businesses Be Tax-Favored?,” p. 393.
CRS-29
These contributions may explain much of the strong backing inside and outside
Congress for government policies to assist small business. A prominent example of
such a policy is the preferential tax treatment received by many small firms. The
combined revenue cost of current federal small business tax subsidies, excluding the
tax treatment of passthrough entities, exceeded $11 billion in FY2007. A variety of
initiatives to expand these subsidies are being considered in the 110th Congress.
Mainstream economic analysis suggests that it is difficult to justify an expansion
of small business tax subsidies on equity or efficiency grounds. Small business tax
preferences reduce the tax burden on owners of small firms, diluting (to an unknown
extent) the progressivity of the federal individual income tax system. In addition, it
appears that small business tax preferences do little to advance social welfare.
Economic theory holds that the efficiency losses inevitably caused by income taxes
are minimized when taxes do not distort the production arrangements within firms
and all returns to capital are taxed at the same rate. Deviations from this theory of
uniform taxation are warranted to correct clear and obvious market failures. In the
case of small firms as a whole, there is no convincing evidence that some kind of
market failure is linked to their rates of formation and growth or to their performance
in a wide range of industries.
This is not to suggest that government support for small firms would never be
justified on economic grounds. If a market failure were to emerge that retards the
formation and growth of small entrepreneurial firms, government action to eradicate
the source of the failure would be warranted. One such market failure would be
imperfections in capital markets that impede the entry of new small entrepreneurial
firms or greatly diminish the chances of survival of existing small entrepreneurial
firms. Such a problem could be corrected through policy measures aimed at
expanding the flow of capital to small start-up firms but without greatly distorting the
allocation of capital within the economy at large. Tax subsidies might be useful in
this case, but to be effective, they would need to address the root causes of the capital
market imperfections. A continuing challenge for policymakers is to identify market
failures that disproportionately harm small firms and devise appropriate policy
responses.
The discussion presented here underscores the need for the development of a
robust model of the formation of small firms and their contributions to the economy.
As it now stands, considerable uncertainty surrounds these issues. Holtz-Eakin has
noted that the development of such a model would enable policymakers to determine
whether any market failures are interfering with the formation and growth of small
firms, identify the factors driving these failures, and develop policies that address
these factors.61
61
Ibid.maintain that the rate of small business formation responds favorably to
reductions in tax burdens. Third, they note that small firms make important contributions to
economic growth and employment over time. Fourth, small firms are thought to face special
constraints on their ability to raise needed capital in debt and equity markets. Finally, proponents
argue that tax preferences are needed to offset the financial burden placed on small firms as a
result of complying with a variety of federal regulations.
Critics of small business tax preferences find it difficult to justify them on economic grounds.
They say such preferences lessen the progressivity of the federal income tax and boost the returns
on small business investment in ways that distort the domestic allocation of economic resources.
In addition, critics contend that many existing small business tax preferences are inappropriate or
poorly designed (or in some cases, both), magnifying any efficiency losses associated with them.
Congressional Research Service
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
Contents
Firm Size: How Small Is Small?..................................................................................................1
Main Federal Tax Benefits for Small Business.............................................................................3
Taxation of Passthrough Entities ...........................................................................................4
Graduated Corporate Income Tax Rates.................................................................................5
Expensing Allowance for Certain Depreciable Business Assets .............................................6
Exemption of Certain Small Corporations From the Corporate Alternative Minimum
Tax ....................................................................................................................................8
Amortization of Business Start-Up Costs...............................................................................9
Cash-Basis Accounting ....................................................................................................... 10
Net Operating Losses .......................................................................................................... 12
Tax Incentives for Private Equity Investment in Small firms................................................ 12
Partial Exclusion of Capital Gains on Certain Small Business Stock .............................. 13
Losses on Small Business Investment Company Stock Treated as Ordinary
Losses without Limitation .......................................................................................... 14
Rollover of Gains into Specialized Small Business Investment Companies .................... 15
Ordinary Income Treatment of Losses on Sales of Small Business Stock ....................... 15
Uniform Capitalization of Inventory Costs .......................................................................... 16
Simplified Dollar-Value LIFO Accounting Method for Small Firms ................................... 16
Tax Credit for Pension Plan Start-Up Costs of Small Firms ................................................. 17
Tax Credit for Cost of Making A Business More Accessible to the Disabled ........................ 18
Economic Importance of Small Firms ....................................................................................... 18
Economic Arguments For and Against Small Business Tax Preferences ..................................... 20
Chief Economic Arguments in Favor of the Preferences ...................................................... 20
Special Economic Role of Small Firms ......................................................................... 20
Opportunities for the Economic Advancement of Immigrants, Women, and
Members of Minority Groups..................................................................................... 22
Imperfections in Capital Markets................................................................................... 22
Impact of Progressive Income Taxes ............................................................................. 23
Cost of Tax Compliance ................................................................................................ 23
Chief Economic Arguments Against the Subsidies............................................................... 23
Equity Concerns............................................................................................................ 24
Efficiency Concerns ...................................................................................................... 24
Other Concerns ............................................................................................................. 27
Concluding Remarks................................................................................................................. 28
Tables
Table 1. Estimated User Cost of Capital Under-Expensing...........................................................7
Contacts
Author Contact Information ...................................................................................................... 29
Congressional Research Service
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
S
ome policy issues never seem to disappear from Congress’s legislative agenda. One such
issue is the federal tax burden on small firms and its effect on their formation, performance,
and growth.
It appears that many lawmakers regard small firms in general as a vital and unsurpassed source of
job creation, economic opportunity, and technological innovation. Many of these same
individuals are also inclined to see current federal taxation of small firms both as an obstacle to
their formation and a drag on their growth, and as an effective policy tool for boosting their rates
of formation and growth. Recent Congresses have passed numerous laws that have included a
variety of tax preferences for small firms. The 111th Congress has already proven to be no
exception. In February 2009 it passed legislation (the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act
of 2009, P.L. 111-5) to stimulate the economy that included several tax benefits targeted at small
firms. Numerous other bills to extend or enhance existing small business tax benefits, or create
new ones, have been introduced.
Existing small business tax benefits and proposals to enhance or expand them raise several policy
issues. For most economists, a key policy issue is whether the benefits can be justified on
economic grounds. If such a rationale cannot be found, or if the one set forth by proponents of
small business tax benefits can be shown to rest on untenable assumptions, then critics of these
benefits could be right in arguing that they damage social welfare in the long run. Another policy
issue tied to small business tax benefits concerns the use of preferential tax treatment to extend
assistance to small firms. The benefits entail costs in the guise of foregone tax revenues and the
resources required on the part of the federal government to administer the tax benefits, and on the
part of eligible small firms to comply with their requirements. Some question whether tax
subsidies are more cost-effective than alternative approaches to providing assistance to small
firms, such as grants, loan guarantees, and exemptions from certain federal regulations.
This report explores these issues by examining the main non-agricultural small business tax
preferences and the economic arguments for and against them. It begins with a brief description
of existing preferences for small firms, then reviews what is known about the economic
contributions of small firms, and concludes with a discussion of the principal economic
arguments for and against these subsidies.
Firm Size: How Small Is Small?
When examining the ways in which the federal tax code confers benefits on small firms and what
is known about the economic role of small firms, a critical analytical and policy issue is the
definition of a small firm.
It turns out that there is no standard or uniform definition of a small firm underlying the host of
federal laws and regulations offering assistance to small business. Instead, several criteria are
used to identify the firms that qualify for the benefits. Why such variation prevails is difficult to
discern from the language of these laws and regulations.
The absence of a standard definition of a small firm may reflect the lack of a consensus among
economists and other analysts on what constitutes a small firm. But this absence may also have its
roots in the Small Business Act (P.L. 85-536, as amended). The act defines a small firm as “one
Congressional Research Service
1
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
that is independently owned and operated and which is not dominant in its field of operation.1“ It
also notes that the definition of a small firm can vary from industry to industry to reflect
important structural differences among industries.2 Under the act, the Small Business
Administration (SBA) has the authority to establish or alter the size standards and limits for
determining eligibility for federal programs to assist small business, some of which are
administered by the SBA. All federal agencies administering programs that reserve a share of
their procurement contracts for small firms are required to use SBA size standards and limits. For
other federal programs or statutes offering support for small business, the definition of a qualified
firm does not necessarily have to conform to SBA size standards and limits.
In general, three criteria are used to identify the firms eligible for federal small business support
programs. Each specifies the maximum size a firm (including affiliates) can attain and still take
advantage of the benefits offered by the programs.
For the most part, the SBA uses two criteria to determine eligibility for the programs it
administers: (1) number of employees and (2) average annual receipts in the previous three years.
Application of these criteria can vary by industry. For example, the sole criterion for most
manufacturing and mining firms is employment size, and the upper limit is 500 employees; by
contrast, for most retail and service firms, the sole criterion is average annual receipts, and the
upper limit is $6 million. SBA’s current size limits for small firms range from $0.75 million to
$28.5 million for average annual receipts, and from 100 to 1,500 for number of employees. 3
The SBA Administrator has the authority to modify size standards for particular industries. Before
a proposed change can take effect, SBA’s Office of Size Standards (OSS) is required to undertake
an analysis of the likely impact of the change on the performance of the affected industry or
industries—focusing on the degree of competition, average firm size, start-up costs, barriers to
entry, and the distribution of sales and employment by firm size—and use the results to make
recommendations to SBA’s Size Policy Board. If the board agrees with OSS’s recommendations,
then it normally advises the Administrator to approve the proposed change.
A third criterion used by federal agencies is asset size. Under this standard, eligible firms would
hold assets up to a certain threshold, such as $50 million. Among federal programs offering
support to small business, use of this criterion is less frequent than number of employees or
average annual receipts.
How does the federal tax code define a small firm? Again, there is no uniform or standard
definition. Instead, several criteria are used to determine eligibility for current small business tax
preferences. Again, it is not clear why the criterion varies from one preference to the next.4 Some
preferences rely on asset size, receipt size, or employment size to select eligible firms. Others
confer benefits on small firms not through a mandatory size standard but through the design of
the preference itself. A case in point is the small business expensing allowance under Section 179
1
15 U.S.C. § 632(a)(1)
See U.S. Small Business Administration, FAQs: Frequently Asked Questions: Size Standards, available at
http://web.sba.gov/faqs/faqindex.
3
Ibid.
2
4
According to one source, the Internal Revenue Code contains at least 24 different definitions of a small business. See
Douglas K Barney, Chris Bjornson, and Steve Wells, “Just How Small Is Your Business?,” National Public
Accountant, Aug. 2003, pp. 4-6.
Congressional Research Service
2
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
of the Internal Revenue Code (IRC): although in principle allowance may be claimed by firms of
all employment, receipt, or asset sizes, its design effectively confines its benefits to relatively
small firms, as is discussed below.
The lack of a standard definition of a small firm in the federal tax code has its advantages and
disadvantages. On the one hand, it can lead to a situation where a firm is eligible for some small
business tax preferences but not for others, perhaps undercutting the incentive effect of at least
some of them. On the other hand, the absence of a standard definition might give lawmakers
greater flexibility in crafting tax benefits for small firms that mesh with larger policy objectives.
Main Federal Tax Benefits for Small Business
In general, all business income is subject to federal taxation, but not all business income is treated
the same way under the federal tax code.
The taxation of business income depends on several considerations. One is whether or not a firm
is organized for tax purposes as a corporation. Corporate net income eventually is taxed twice
(once at the firm level and a second time at the shareholder level), whereas the net income of
passthrough entities such as S corporations, sole proprietorships, limited liability companies, or
partnerships is taxed only once (at the shareholder level).
In addition, the taxation of business income depends on whether or not a corporation or the
owners of passthrough entities pay the alternative minimum tax (AMT). Corporations or business
owners paying the AMT may or may not be taxed at lower marginal rates than the rates they
would be subject to under the regular corporate income tax.
The tax burden on business income also can vary according to how investments are financed.
Corporations may deduct interest payments from taxable income but not dividend payments. As a
result, the returns to corporate investments financed solely by debt are taxed at lower marginal
effective rates than the returns to investments financed solely by equity.
Firm size is another factor that can affect the tax treatment of business income. Various provisions
of the federal tax code offer benefits to smaller firms that are not available, or are of lesser value,
to larger firms. The code makes no explicit or formal distinction between the taxation of small
and large firms in that it has no separate sections for small and large firms. Rather, there are
provisions scattered throughout its many chapters that confer preferential treatment on relatively
small firms only. Most of these provisions come in the form of deductions, exclusions and
exemptions, credits, deferrals, and preferential tax rates. In general, tax preferences such as these
lower the cost of capital for new investment by eligible firms relative to other firms. Some of the
provisions benefit small firms by reducing the cost and burden of complying with tax laws, or by
making tax relief contingent on providing certain fringe benefits to employees.
The federal tax subsidies targeted exclusively at smaller firms and with the widest reach outside
agriculture are described below. Excluded from the list are subsidies available only to small firms
in particular industries, such as life insurance, banking, and energy production or distribution.
Nor does the list include subsidies from which many small firms derive significant benefits but
that are also available to large firms, such as the research and work opportunity tax credits.
Congressional Research Service
3
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
It is not known what the total revenue cost is for the subsidies discussed below. Nevertheless,
recent estimates by the Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT) and the Treasury Department indicate
that they could lower federal revenue in FY2009 by at least $15 billion.5
Taxation of Passthrough Entities
Business enterprises operate in a variety of legal organizational forms. The business laws of each
state determine the range of available options. For federal tax purposes, five such forms are
widely used: subchapter C corporations, subchapter S corporations, sole proprietorships,
partnerships, and limited liability companies (LLCs).
A firm’s legal organizational form can have important implications for the taxation of its
earnings. The earnings of C corporations are taxed twice: once at the corporate level and again at
the individual level when the earnings are distributed to shareholders or owners as dividends or
realized capital gains. By contrast, the earnings of all other business entities are taxed only once:
at the individual level of their owners or shareholders. As a result, these entities are often referred
to as passthrough entities: their earnings escape taxation at the entity level but are passed through
to the owners.6 The entities’ profits, losses, items of income, deduction, exclusion, deferral, and
credit are attributed to the owners according to their shares of ownership, regardless of whether
the profits have been distributed. Most businesses operate as sole proprietorships: in 2005, they
accounted for 67% of federal business tax returns. Next in order of magnitude were S
corporations (12% of business tax returns), followed by partnerships (9% of returns), C
corporations (6% of returns), and farms (6% of returns).7
There is no legal requirement that C corporations be relatively large in income, asset or
employment size, and that passthrough firms be relatively small. Yet such a difference is the
reality: in 2005, for example, the average C corporation’s asset size was $32.1 billion, compared
to $5 million for the average partnership and $743 million for the average S corporation.8
Whether a business owner would be better off operating as a C corporation or as some kind of
passthrough entity is a complicated decision involving many tax and non-tax considerations. Key
non-tax considerations include the legal liability of shareholders, access to capital markets, and
degree of shareholder control of management. Foremost among tax considerations are relative tax
rates for corporate income, individual ordinary income, and long-term capital gains; the
investment horizon of investors; the holding period for corporate stock; and the rate at which
corporate profits are paid out as dividends.
5
In FY2008, the estimated combined revenue loss for six of the small business tax preferences discussed here is $11
billion. It covers the following small business tax preferences: (1) expensing of depreciable business property; (2)
reduced rates on the first $10 million of corporate taxable income; (3) cash accounting outside agriculture; (4) the
partial exclusion of capital gains on the sale of certain small business stock; (5) the amortization of business start-up
costs; and (6) the ordinary income treatment of losses on the sale of small business corporation stock. See U.S.
Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2008-2012, JCS-2-08
(Washington: GPO, 2008), tables 2 and 3; and Office of Management and Budget, Analytical Perspectives, Budget of
the United States Government, Fiscal Year 2009 (Washington: U.S. Govt. Print. Off., 2008), table 19-1.
6
For more details on the taxation of non-corporate businesses, see CRS Report RL31538, Passthrough Entities Not
Taxed As Corporations, by Jack H. Taylor, available upon request from the author.
7
U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, Tax Reform: Selected Financial Tax Issues Relating to Small Business
and Choice of Entity, JCX-48-08 (Washington: June 4, 2008), table 1, p. 8.
8
Ibid., tables 3 to 5, pp. 14-16.
Congressional Research Service
4
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
The current mix of individual and corporate tax rates favors passthrough entities by a small
margin for investors in the highest income tax bracket. A few simple calculations prove this point.
In 2009, the top personal tax rate is 35%; most corporate profits are taxed at 35%; and the top tax
rate on long-term capital gains is 15%.9 Assuming an investment horizon of one year—after
which the firm’s assets are liquidated—tax considerations alone would dictate that a high-income
individual would be better off owning a business enterprise operated as a partnership than as a C
corporation. Under such a scenario, after-tax returns to a partnership would be $0.65 for every
dollar invested, whereas they would be $0.55 for every dollar invested in a C corporation.10
Extending the investment horizon to five years does not alter the result. Assuming all after-tax
income earned during that period is reinvested in the business, the firm’s assets are liquidated
after five years, and individuals in the top tax bracket can earn a pre-tax rate of return of 20%
whether the business is operated as a partnership or a corporation, a partnership would earn a
higher after-tax rate of return than a C corporation: 13.0% versus 11.3%.11
Still, it would be incorrect to view the taxation of passthrough entities as a small business tax
benefit. This is because a firm’s size has no bearing on its ability to operate as a passthrough
entity. Some firms that are relatively large in employment, revenue, or asset size are organized as
S corporations or partnerships, while some firms that are relatively small in those measures of
size operate as C corporations. In 2005, 17% of S corporations and 7% of partnerships filing
federal income tax returns reported total receipts of more than $1 million, while 38% of C
corporations filing federal income tax returns reported total receipts of $100,000 or less.12
Any tax advantage presently held by passthrough entities has proven to be ephemeral in the
recent past. For instance, their present advantage would evaporate if legislation were enacted that
substantially reduces the top corporate and long-term capital gains tax rates relative to the
maximum individual income tax rate. In fact, current tax law could diminish or even extinguish
the current appeal of passthrough entities. The individual tax cuts enacted under the Bush
Administration are due to expire at the end of 2010. Assuming current law is not changed,
beginning in 2011, the maximum individual income tax rate would rise from 35% to 39.6%, and
the maximum long-term capital gains rate would increase from 15% to 20%.
Graduated Corporate Income Tax Rates
Corporations with less than $10 million in taxable income are subject to a set of graduated tax
rates. The rate is 15% on the first $50,000 of income, 25% on the next $25,000, and 34% on
9
Under the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 (JGTRRA, P.L. 108-27), in 2003, the top
individual income tax rate is 35% and is scheduled to remain at that level through 2010, and the maximum rate on longterm capital gains is 15% for assets sold after May 6, 2003 and before January 1, 2009.
10
These tax rates are derived from the following formula: (1-tp) is less than or equal to (1- tc) x (1- tcg), where tp is the
highest personal tax rate, tc is the highest corporate tax rate, and tcg is the maximum tax rate on long-term capital
gains. See Myron S. Scholes, et. al., Taxes and Business Strategy: A Planning Approach, 2nd edition (Upper Saddle
River, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 2001), p. 67.
11
The after-tax rate of return for a partnership is derived from the following formula: $1[1 + R x (1- tp)]n, where R is
the expected pre-tax rate of return, tp is the highest personal tax rate, and n is the investment horizon. And the after-tax
rate of return for a corporation is derived from the following formula: $1[1 + R x (1- tc)]n (1- tcg) + (tcg x $1), where R
and n are the same as the previous formula, tc is the highest corporate tax rate, and tcg is the maximum tax rate on
long-term capital gains. See Scholes, Taxes and Business Strategy. pp. 66-67.
12
Joint Committee on Taxation, Tax Reform: Selected Federal Tax Issues Relating to Small Business and Choice of
Entity, tables 3 to 5, pp. 14-16.
Congressional Research Service
5
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
amounts between $75,000 and $100,000 and between $335,000 and $10 million. Corporations
with taxable incomes ranging from $10 million to $15 million pay a marginal rate of 35%. In two
income ranges, corporations face marginal tax rates greater than 35%: a corporation with taxable
income between $100,000 and $335,000 pays a marginal rate of 39%; if its taxable income falls
between $15 million and $18.3 million, the firm pays a marginal rate of 38%. These higher rates
are intended to offset the tax savings that firms realized when their tax rates were below 35%. All
corporate taxable income above $18.3 million is taxed at a rate of 35%. As a result, the tax
savings from the rates of 15% to 34% are limited to corporations with taxable incomes under
$335,000.
This rate structure mainly benefits corporations that are relatively small in employment or asset
size. It also gives owners of closely held small firms an added incentive to incorporate in order to
shield any profits from higher individual tax rates. But not all small corporations are allowed to
take advantage of the reduced rates. Specifically, regardless of the amount, the taxable income of
corporations providing services in the fields of health care, law, engineering, architecture,
accounting, actuarial science, the performing arts, and consulting is taxed at a fixed rate of 35%.
The graduated rate structure has at least one unavoidable drawback: it gives small corporations a
disincentive to grow to the point where their net incomes are taxed at marginal rates above 34%.
It could be argued that rates above 34% serve as a tax on growth.
The revenue loss arising from the reduced rates on the first $10 million of corporate taxable
income could total an estimated $3.3 billion in FY2009.13
Expensing Allowance for Certain Depreciable Business Assets
Expensing is the most accelerated form of depreciation for tax purposes. It entails treating the
cost of a depreciable asset such as a machine or building as a current expense rather than as a
capital expenditure. Current costs are deducted in the year in which they are incurred, whereas
capital costs normally are recovered over longer periods by applying the depreciation methods
and schedules allowed in the federal tax code.
Under Section 179 of the Internal Revenue Code (IRC), firms may expense (or deduct) up to
$250,000 of the cost of qualified business property—mainly machinery, equipment, and computer
software—placed into service in 2008 and 2009, and write off the remaining basis (if any) using a
temporary 50% depreciation allowance and current cost recovery rules. 14 The expensing
allowance is scheduled to drop to $125,000 in 2010, before adjustment for inflation. Starting in
2011, the maximum allowance will be fixed at $25,000, with no adjustment for inflation.
Owing to a rule known as the dollar limitation, not all firms are able to take advantage of the
expensing allowance. Under this limitation, the allowance is reduced by the amount by which the
13
U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2008-2012,
JCS-2-08 (Washington: GPO, 2008), p. 71.
14
The Economic Stimulus Act of 2008 (P.L. 110-185) raised the maximum allowance to $250,000 and the phase-out
threshold to $800,000 for 2008 only. The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 (P.L. 111-5) extended
both limits through the end of 2009. Those limits are higher for firms located in certain economically distressed areas.
For more details on the design of the expensing allowance and its economic effects, see CRS Report RL31852, Small
Business Expensing Allowance: Current Status, Legislative Proposals, and Economic Effects, by Gary Guenther.
Congressional Research Service
6
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
total cost of qualified property placed in service during a year exceeds a phase-out threshold. In
2008 and 2009, this threshold is set at $800,000. It is scheduled to drop to $500,000 in 2010,
before an adjustment for inflation. Beginning in 2011, the threshold will be fixed at $200,000,
with no adjustment for inflation. So none of a firm’s spending on qualified property placed into
service in 2009 may be expensed once its total spending on such property exceeds $1,050,000:
the $250,000 expensing allowance, plus the $800,000 phase-out threshold.
The allowance has the potential to serve as a robust investment tax subsidy. Because of the phaseout threshold, it mainly benefits firms that are relatively small in revenue, asset, or employment
size. Generally, the allowance can stimulate business investment in two ways. First, it can lower
the user cost of capital for investment in qualified assets. In theory, expensing produces a zero
marginal effective tax rate on the returns to investment in those assets under the standard
economic model for the determination of the user cost of capital.15 Second, the allowance can
boost business investment by increasing the cash flow of firms that can take advantage of it. For
some firms, the cost of internal funds is lower than the cost of external funds such as loans or
equity; so their investment hinges on the availability of internal funds, their cash flow.
The impact of the allowance on the cost of capital is illustrated in a 1995 article by Douglas
Holtz-Eakin. Among other things, he assessed the effect of the expensing allowance on a firm’s
user cost of capital. Table 1 summarizes his findings.16 The first column provides the assumed
corporate tax rate; the second shows the required pre-tax rate of return if the entire cost of the
investment is expensed; the third column gives the required pre-tax rate of return if the entire cost
is recovered through the depreciation deductions allowed under federal tax law in the early 1990s;
and the final column presents the effective tax subsidy from expensing, which is expressed as the
difference (in percentage points) between the required rates of return shown in columns three and
two.
At least two conclusions can be drawn from the results. First, expensing offered a significant
investment subsidy, and the extent of the subsidy increased with a firm’s marginal tax rate. For
example, at a tax rate of 15%, expensing lowered the user cost of capital by about 11%; but at a
rate of 35%, the reduction jumped to 28%. Second, the user cost of capital under expensing
declined as the tax rate increased because tax deductions gain in dollar value at higher tax rates.
Table 1. Estimated User Cost of Capital Under-Expensing
(%)
Corporate Tax Rate
Expensing
Regular Depreciation
Absolute Size of the Subsidy
15%
17.95%
20.23%
2.28a
25
17.05
21.13
4.08
35
16.15
22.40
6.25
Source: Douglas Holtz-Eakin, “Should Small Business Be Tax-Favored?” National Tax Journal, Sept. 1995.
15
See Jane G. Gravelle, “Effects of the 1981 Depreciation Revisions on the Taxation of Income From Business
Capital,” National Tax Journal, vol. 35, no. 1, March 1982, pp. 2-6. In effect, under expensing, the after-tax rate of
return on an investment becomes equal to the pre-tax rate of return. This happens because expensing reduces costs and
after-tax returns by the same proportion, which is determined by the tax rate.
16
Douglas Holtz-Eakin, “Should Small Businesses Be Tax-Favored?,” Tax Notes, vol. 48, No. 3, Sept. 1995, p. 389.
(In 2003, Dr. Holtz-Eakin was named the Director of the Congressional Budget Office.)
Congressional Research Service
7
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
Note: The calculations assume an interest rate of 9%, an inflation rate of 3%, and a rate of economic
depreciation of 13.3%. The following formula is used to compute the user cost of capital:
c / q = (p - + δ / 1 − τ ) ξ (1 − τζ ),
where c is the annual value of revenue from the investment, q is the purchase price of the capital good, p is the
after-tax financial cost of capital, pi is the rate of inflation, d is the rate of geometric depreciation, t is the
marginal tax rate, and z is the present value of depreciation allowances per dollar of investment. In the case of
expensing, z = 1.0; and in the case of regular depreciation, z = 0.2814.
a.
Percentage points, not percent.
In FY2009, the allowance could produce an estimated revenue loss of $6.0 billion.17 The revenue
effects of the expensing allowance in any year depend on the aggregate amount of business
investment in qualified assets. In periods of rising investment, the allowance typically leads to a
net revenue loss. But when investment falls following a period of expansion, the allowance can
actually yield a net revenue gain. This shift from loss to gain is due to the timing of depreciation
deductions under current tax law. Firms that can deduct the entire cost of an asset in its first year
of use by claiming the Section 179 expensing allowance have no depreciation allowances to
deduct from future taxable income generated by the asset.
Exemption of Certain Small Corporations From
the Corporate Alternative Minimum Tax
Under current federal tax law, many corporations must compute their income tax liability under
both the regular tax and the alternative minimum tax (AMT) and pay whichever is greater. Each
tax has its own rates, allowable deductions, and rules for the measurement of taxable income.
In general, the AMT applies a lower marginal rate to a broader tax base. It expands the corporate
tax base by adding a number of tax preferences under the regular corporate income tax to taxable
income under the AMT. In addition, most tax credits allowed under the regular corporate income
tax cannot be used to reduce AMT liability. The current AMT originated with the Tax Reform Act
of 1986 and is mainly intended to ensure that all profitable corporations pay at least some federal
income tax.
As a result of the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 (P.L. 105-34), certain small corporations have been
exempt from the AMT since 1998. Eligibility is determined by a corporation’s average annual
gross receipts in the previous three tax years. All corporations formed after 1998 are exempt from
the AMT in their first year with taxable income, regardless of the size of their gross receipts. They
remain exempt as long as their average annual gross receipts do not exceed $5 million in their
first three tax years, and as long as their average annual gross receipts do not exceed $7.5 million
in each succeeding three-year period (e.g., 1999-2001, 2000-2002, etc.). If a corporation loses its
eligibility, it becomes subject to the AMT in the first tax year when it no longer qualifies for the
exemption and in every tax year thereafter, regardless of the amount of its gross receipts.
There is reason to believe that this exemption gives some eligible small corporations what
amounts to a slight competitive advantage over comparable firms paying the AMT. A 1997 study
estimated that firms that invested heavily in machinery and equipment and intangible assets like
research and development (R&D), financed the bulk of their investments through debt, and paid
17
Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2008-2012, p. 71.
Congressional Research Service
8
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
the AMT for five or more successive years had a higher cost of capital than comparable firms that
paid the regular income tax only in the same period.18
The exemption also provides owners of small firms with an incentive to incorporate, since the
taxable income of passthrough entities is subject to the individual AMT through the tax returns
filed by individual owners.
A 2000 report by the Treasury Department’s Inspector General for Tax Administration (TIGTA)
found that the exemption from the AMT for small firms ran into some unexpected problems
during the first year or two it was in effect. According to the report, more than 2,300 small
corporations paid the AMT in 1998, even though an examination of their federal income tax
returns indicated they qualified for the exemption. Their overpayments of the tax may have
totaled more than $25 million.19 The report attributed the erroneous payments to the many
complex changes in the corporate AMT made by the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 and the “short
time” available to taxpayers and tax professionals to understand the changes and apply them in
filing 1998 tax returns. It recommended the IRS take certain steps to increase taxpayer awareness
of the exemption, explain how it was supposed to work, and identify and contact taxpayers who
erroneously paid the AMT. In a follow-up study, TIGTA found that the IRS had taken most of
these steps, but that the agency had failed to notify the more than 3,600 taxpayers thought to have
mistakenly paid the AMT. TIGTA came to the conclusion that the IRS had fallen short of its
obligation and promise to “inform and educate tax practitioners on what they need to do on their
clients’ behalf.”20
There is no estimate of the revenue cost of exempting small corporations from the AMT, but it is
probably less than $10 million a year. While exempt firms do not have to compute their AMT
liability, they do pay the regular corporate income tax if their taxable income is positive.
Amortization of Business Start-Up Costs
A key concept undergirding the federal income tax is that taxable income should exclude all the
costs incurred in earning it. This implies that all ordinary and necessary costs paid or incurred in
conducting a trade or business should be deducted from a firm’s taxable income. The concept also
implies that ordinary and necessary costs paid or incurred in connection with starting or
organizing a business should not be treated as current expenses, as they were not related to the
generation of income. Rather, because these expenses were incurred in an attempt to create an
asset (namely, the business) with a useful life extending beyond a single tax year, it stands to
reason that they should be capitalized, added to the owner’s basis in the business, and recovered
when the business is sold or ceases to exist.
But under IRC Section 195 (as amended by P.L. 108-357), business taxpayers who incur business
start-up and organizational costs after October 22, 2004, are allowed to deduct up to $5,000 of
18
Andrew B. Lyon, Cracking the Code: Making Sense of the Corporate Alternative Minimum Tax (Washington:
Brookings Institution Press, 1997), pp. 77-97.
19
U.S. Department of the Treasury, Inspector General for Tax Administration, More Small Corporate Taxpayers Can
Benefit from the Alternative Minimum Tax Exemption Provision, no. 2001-30-019 (Washington: Nov. 2000), p. 4.
20
U.S. Department of the Treasury, Inspector General for Tax Administration, Significant Actions were Taken to
Address Small Corporations Erroneously Paying the Alternative Minimum Tax, but Additional Actions Are Still
Needed, no. 2003-30-114 (Washington: May 2003), pp. 4-5.
Congressional Research Service
9
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
those costs in the year when the new trade or business begins. This maximum deduction is
reduced (but not below zero) by the amount by which eligible expenditures exceed $50,000. Any
eligible expenditures that cannot be deducted may be amortized over 15 years, beginning in the
month when the new trade or business begins to earn income. In order to claim the $5,000
deduction, a taxpayer must have an equity interest in the new trade or business and actively
participate in its management.
Business taxpayers who incurred or paid business start-up and organizational costs and then
entered a trade or business on or before October 22, 2004, could amortize (or deduct in equal
annual amounts) those expenditures over not less than five years, beginning in the month when
the new trade or business commenced.
To qualify for the current deduction, the start-up and organizational costs must meet two
requirements. First, they must be paid or incurred as part of an investigation into creating or
acquiring an active trade or business, as part of starting a new trade or business, or as part of an
activity done to produce income or profit before starting a trade or business with the aim of
converting the activity into an active trade or business. Second, the costs must be the similar in
kind to costs that would be deductible if they were paid or incurred in connection with the
expansion of an active trade or business in the same industry entered by a new firm.
Business taxpayers who choose not to claim the deduction must capitalize all start-up expenses.
The option to deduct as much as $5,000 in business start-up and organizational costs in the first
year of operation clearly benefits small start-up firms. It permits the owner of such a firm to
deduct expenses in the year when the business begins. Without such a provision, the expenses
could not be recovered until the owner sells his or her interest in the business. In effect, the option
accelerates the recovery of certain necessary business costs, and this acceleration can aid the
growth of small start-up firms by reducing their cost of capital and increasing their cash flow at a
time when their access to debt and equity markets may be limited. For firms that lose money in
their first year of operation, the deduction can increase their net operating losses for tax purposes,
which may be carried back up to two years or forward up to 20 years and used to offset taxes paid
or owed.21
According to the Joint Tax Committee, the amortization or deduction of qualified business startup and organizational costs could lead to an estimated revenue loss of $0.8 billion in FY2009.22
Cash-Basis Accounting
IRC Section 446 requires firms to compute their taxable income using the same method of
accounting they regularly employ in keeping their books, provided that method clearly reflects
income. For a business taxpayer’s method of accounting to clearly reflect income, it must treat
items of income and deductions consistently from one tax year to the next. Permissible methods
of accounting include the cash-receipts method, the accrual method, the installment method, the
21
Under the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 (P.L. 111-5), eligible firms with net operating losses in
the 2008 tax year may carry them back up to five years. Only firms with average annual gross receipts in the past three
tax years of less than $15 million may take advantage of this expanded carryback.
22
Joint Tax Committee, Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2008-2012, p. 71.
Congressional Research Service
10
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
long-term-contract method, the crop method, the special methods for research and development
expenditures, and the method for soil and water conservation expenditures.
Two methods of financial accounting are widely used in the private sector: cash-basis and
accrual-basis. Under cash-basis accounting, which is the preferred method for self-employed
individuals, income generally is recorded when it is received in the form of cash or its equivalent,
and expenses generally are recorded when they are paid, regardless of when the income actually
is earned or the expenses actually are incurred.
Under accrual-basis accounting, income and expenses generally are recorded when the
transactions giving rise to them are completed or nearly completed, regardless of when cash or its
equivalent is received or paid. More specifically, a firm using accrual-basis accounting records
income when its right to receive it is established, and expenses when the amounts are fixed and its
liability for the expenses is established.
Each accounting method has advantages. The principal advantage of cash-basis accounting is that
it is much simpler to administer. It also allows firms that use it to control the timing of items of
income or deductions. In contrast, accrual-basis accounting often yields a more accurate measure
of a firm’s economic income because it matches income with expenses with greater precision and
rigor.
In general, when an inventory is necessary to the operation of a business, a business taxpayer is
required to use the accrual method in computing taxable income ─ unless the IRS determines that
another method clearly reflects income and authorizes its use. Inventories are considered
necessary when a firm earns income from the production, purchase, or sale of merchandise. In
addition, C corporations, partnerships with C corporations as partners, trusts that earn unrelated
business income, and authorized tax shelters generally are required to use the accrual method of
accounting.
But there is an exception to this rule. Any partnership or C corporation with average annual gross
receipts of $5 million or less in the three previous tax years may use the cash method of
accounting. It also may be used by individuals, S corporations, and qualifying partnerships and
personal service corporations.
Moreover, even though purchases and sales of inventory items cannot be reported for tax
purposes using the cash method of accounting, the IRS has made an exception for sole
proprietorships, S corporations, and partnerships that reported average annual gross receipts of $1
million or less in the three previous tax years (IRS Rev. Proc. 2001-10), regardless of the nature
of their trade or business. The cash method may also be used by firms with average annual gross
receipts of $10 million or less in the three previous tax years, whose main business is providing
services or fabricating products according to customer designs or specifications (IRS Rev. Proc.
2002-28).
As these rules indicate, many of the firms permitted to use the cash method are relatively small in
receipt size. In effect, this method offers the same benefit to small firms as the expensing
allowance under IRC Section 179: the deferral of income tax payments. The federal tax code rests
in part on the notion that a firm receives income when it gains the legal right to be paid for
something it has provided. But under the cash method of accounting, a firm may delay the
recognition of income until cash payments are received, thereby postponing the payment of tax
Congressional Research Service
11
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
on that income, or lower its tax liability in a year by accelerating payments for expenses such as
supplies, repairs, interest, and taxes.
Despite the possible tax benefits to eligible small firms of using the cash method, it may not be in
their self-interest to do so when they need to issue accurate and reliable financial reports. Cashbasis accounting can distort a firm’s financial position in several ways. 23 First, because it records
transactions involving only cash or its equivalent, the method excludes transactions involving
exchanges of assets or liabilities. Second, the determination of net income under cash-basis
accounting can be manipulated by recording revenues or expenses long before or after goods and
services are produced or sold. As a result, small firms seeking to raise capital in debt or equity
markets may be better off using accrual-basis accounting.
The Joint Committee on Taxation estimates that the use of cash-basis accounting outside
agriculture will result in a revenue loss of $0.9 billion in FY2009.24
Net Operating Losses
A firm incurs a net operating loss (NOL) for tax purposes when its deductions exceed its gross
income. As a result, it has no income tax liability in an NOL year. An NOL may be used to
obtain a refund of taxes paid in previous years or to reduce or offset future tax liabilities. Under
IRC Section 172(b), a business taxpayer is permitted to carry an NOL back to each of the two tax
years preceding the NOL year and forward to each of the 20 tax years following that year.
A provision of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 (ARRA, P.L. 111-5)
extended the carryback period for NOLs to five years for eligible firms that incurred an NOL in
2008. Only firms with average annual gross receipts of $15 million or less in the NOL year and
the two previous tax years may take advantage of the extension. The provision is intended to
bolster the cash flow of small firms that have experienced a significant loss of revenue in the
current recession.
The Joint Committee on Taxation estimates that the NOL carryback expansion for qualified small
firms will produce a revenue loss of $4.7 billion in FY2009.25
Tax Incentives for Private Equity Investment in Small firms
The federal tax code also contains several provisions intended to encourage the investment of
equity capital in certain start-up small firms that might otherwise find it difficult to raise the funds
needed to finance current operations or expansions. These provisions, which are described below,
do so by increasing the potential after-tax returns or reducing the potential after-tax losses on
equity investment in such firms. The same tax benefits are not available to individuals who invest
in larger established firms.
23
See Robert Libby, Patricia A. Libby, and Daniel G. Short, Financial Accounting (Chicago: Irwin, 1996), p. 111.
Joint Tax Committee, Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2008-2012, p. 71.
25
Joint Tax Committee, Estimated Budget Effects of the Revenue Provisions Contained in the Conference Agreement
for H.R. 1, the “American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009,” JCX-19-09 (Washington: Feb. 12, 2009).
24
Congressional Research Service
12
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
Partial Exclusion of Capital Gains on Certain Small Business Stock
Two important considerations in determining an individual’s income tax liability are the
recognition of income as ordinary or capital and the distinction between long-term and short-term
capital gains or losses.
A capital gain or loss arises when a capital asset such as a stock or bond is sold or exchanged. If
the selling price is greater than the acquisition or purchase price, then the transaction yields a
capital gain. Conversely, a capital loss results when the selling price is less than the purchase
price.
Capital assets held longer than 12 months and then sold or exchanged give rise to long-term
capital gains or losses, whereas sales or exchanges of capital assets held one year or less produce
short-term capital gains or losses. Short-term capital gains are considered ordinary income and
thus are taxed at regular income tax rates. By contrast, long-term capital gains are considered
capital income and thus are taxed in 2009 at rates of 15% for individual taxpayers subject to
marginal income tax rates above 15% and 0% for individual taxpayers in the 10% and 15%
income tax brackets.
Under IRC Section 1202, non-corporate taxpayers (including partnerships, LLCs, and S
corporations) may exclude 50% of any gain from the sale or exchange of qualified small business
stock (QSBS) that has been held for over five years. The exclusion rises to 60% if the QSBS has
been issued by a qualified corporation based in an empowerment zone. And under a provision of
the ARRA, it becomes 75% for QSBS acquired from February 18, 2009, through December 31,
2010, and held for five years
There is a cumulative limit on the gain from stock issued by a single qualified corporation that
may be excluded: in a single tax year, the gain is limited to the greater of 10 times the taxpayer’s
adjusted basis of all QSBS issued by the firm and sold or exchanged during the year, or $10
million—reduced by any gains excluded by the taxpayer in previous years. The remaining gain is
taxed at a fixed rate of 28%. As a result, the marginal effective tax rate on capital gains from the
sale or exchange of QSBS held longer than five years is 14%: 0.5 x 0.28.
For individuals subject to the AMT, a portion of the excluded gain is treated as an individual
AMT preference item, which means that it must be included in the calculation of AMT taxable
income. The portion was 42% for QSBS acquired on or before December 31, 2000 and disposed
of by May 6, 2003; 28% for QSBS acquired after December 31, 2000 and disposed of by May 6,
2003; and 7% for QSBS acquired after May 6, 2003 and disposed of by December 31, 2008.26
To qualify for the partial exclusion, small business stock must satisfy certain requirements. First,
it must be issued after August 10, 1993 and must be acquired by the taxpayer at its original issue,
either directly or through an underwriter, in exchange for money, property, or as compensation for
services rendered to the issuing corporation. Second, the stock must be issued by a domestic C
corporation whose gross assets do not exceed $50 million before and immediately after the stock
is issued. Third, at least 80% of the corporation’s assets must be tied to the active conduct of one
or more qualified trades or businesses during “substantially all” of the requisite five-year holding
period. Assets used for working capital, start-up activities, or research and development meet the
26
The 7% rate stems from a provision in JGTRRA.
Congressional Research Service
13
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
active business test, even if they are devoted mainly to the development of future lines of
business. Specialized small business investment companies licensed under the Small Business
Investment Act of 1958 also meet the active business test, making their stock eligible for the
partial exclusion.
Not all small firms meeting these requirements can take advantage of the partial exclusion. Stock
issued by small C corporations primarily engaged in at least one of the following commercial
activities do not qualify for the partial gains exclusion: health care, law, engineering, architecture,
hospitality, farming, insurance, finance, and mineral extraction. And stock issued by the following
small C corporations is not eligible for the partial exclusion: current or former domestic
international sales corporations (DISCs), regulated investment companies (RICs), real estate
investment trusts (REITs), real estate mortgage investment conduits (REMICs), financial asset
securitization investment trusts (FASITs), cooperatives, or C corporations that have claimed the
possessions tax credit under IRC Section 936.
The partial exclusion for QSBS is intended to make it easier for small start-up firms in a variety
of industries to raise so-called patient equity capital. It does this by increasing the potential aftertax returns an investor can earn on sales or exchanges of QSBS, relative to potential after-tax
returns on similar investment opportunities, over five years. Supporters of the partial exclusion
say it is needed to overcome the lack of knowledge and deep uncertainty that surrounds the
growth prospects of new start-up firms in industries where sizable investments in research and
development over an extended period is a key to survival and expansion.
The Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 (JGTRRA) substantially diluted the
incentive effect of the partial exclusion. Before the act, the maximum tax rate on long-term
capital gains was 20% on assets held for at least one year and 18% for assets acquired after
December 31, 2000 and held for more than five years. By contrast, under the partial exclusion,
the effective tax rate on capital gains realized on sales or exchanges of QSBS has always been
14%. Though JGTRRA unified and lowered the maximum tax rate on long-term capital gains to
15%, it made no compensatory change in the taxation of capital gains for QSBS. Thus, a potential
buyer of QSBS in the highest tax bracket must evaluate whether the slight difference in rates is
worth the risks associated with owning the stock of new unproven firms for a minimum of five
years.
An estimated $0.5 billion in revenue will not be collected in FY2009 because of the exclusion.27
Losses on Small Business Investment Company Stock Treated as Ordinary
Losses without Limitation
Generally, losses on investments in stock are treated as capital losses for tax purposes. These
losses may be used to offset any capital gains in the same tax year, but individuals may also use
any combination of short-term and long-term capital losses to offset up to $3,000 in ordinary
income in a single tax year.
Under IRC Section 1242, however, individuals who invest in small business investment
companies (SBICs) are permitted to deduct from ordinary income all losses from the sale or
27
Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2008-2012, p. 71.
Congressional Research Service
14
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
exchange or worthlessness of stock in these companies. This treatment is intended to foster equity
investment in these companies by lowering the after-tax loss on an investment in an SBIC,
relative to after-tax losses on similar investments.
SBICs are private regulated investment corporations that are licensed under the Small Business
Investment Act of 1958 to provide equity capital, long-term loans, and managerial guidance to
firms with a net worth of less than $18 million and less than $6 million in average net income
over the previous two years. They use their own capital and funds borrowed at favorable rates
through SBA loan guarantees to make equity and debt investments in qualified firms. For tax
purposes, most SBICs are treated as C corporations.
There are no known estimates of the revenue loss associated with this small business tax benefit.
Rollover of Gains into Specialized Small Business Investment Companies
In general, gains or losses on the sale or exchange of stocks are recognized for tax purposes in the
tax year when they are realized.
But under IRC Section 1044, which was created by the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of
1993, individual and corporate taxpayers who satisfy certain conditions are allowed to roll over,
free of tax, any capital gains on the sale of publicly traded securities. The proceeds from the sale
must be used to purchase common stock or partnership interests in specialized small business
investment companies (SSBICs) licensed under the Small Business Investment Act of 1958
within 60 days of the sale. SSBICs are similar to SBICs except that SSBICs are required to invest
in small firms owned by individuals who are considered socially or economically
disadvantaged—mainly members of minority groups.
If the proceeds from the sale exceed the cost of the SSBIC stock or partnership interest, the
excess is recognized as a capital gain and taxed accordingly. The taxpayer’s basis in the SSBIC
stock or partnership interest is reduced by the amount of any gain from the sale of securities that
are rolled over. The maximum gain an individual can roll over in a single tax year is the lesser of
$50,000 or $500,000 less any gains previously rolled over under this provision. For corporations,
the maximum deferral in a tax year is the lesser of $250,000 or $1 million less any previously
deferred gains.
There are no known estimates of the revenue loss associated with this small business tax benefit.
Ordinary Income Treatment of Losses on Sales of Small Business Stock
IRC Section 1244 allows taxpayers to deduct any loss from the sale, exchange, or worthlessness
of qualified small business stock as an ordinary loss, rather than a capital loss. For business
taxpayers, ordinary losses are treated as business losses in computing a net operating loss.
To qualify for this treatment, the stock must meet four requirements. First, it must be issued by a
domestic corporation after November 6, 1978. Second, the stock must be acquired by an
individual investor or a partnership in exchange for money or other property, but not stock or
securities. Third, the stock must be issued by a small business corporation, which the statute
defines as a corporation whose total amount of money and property received as a contribution to
capital and paid-in surplus totals less than $1 million when it issues the stock. Finally, during the
Congressional Research Service
15
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
five tax years before a loss on the stock is recognized, the firm must have derived more than 50%
of its gross receipts from sources other than royalties, rents, dividends, interest, annuities, and
stock or security transactions. The maximum amount that may be deducted as an ordinary loss in
a tax year is $50,000 (or $100,000 for a couple filing jointly).
This special treatment is likely to lead to an estimated revenue loss of $50 million in FY2009.28
Uniform Capitalization of Inventory Costs
Firms that earn income from the production, purchase, or sale of merchandise are required to
maintain inventories in order to determine the cost of goods sold during a tax year. This cost is
subtracted from gross receipts in the computation of taxable income. In most cases, the cost of
goods sold is determined by adding the value of a firm’s inventory at the beginning of the year to
purchases of inventory items made during the year and subtracting from that total the value of the
firm’s inventory at the end of the year.
IRC Section 263A requires business taxpayers engaged in the production of real or tangible
property, or in the purchase of real or tangible and intangible property for resale, to “capitalize”
(or include in the estimated value of their inventories) both the direct costs of the property
included in inventory and the indirect costs that can be allocated to it. This requirement is known
as the uniform capitalization rule and was added to the tax code by the Tax Reform Act of 1986.
In general, direct costs are considered the material and labor costs tied to the production or
acquisition of goods, and indirect costs refer to the other costs incurred through the production or
acquisition of goods (e.g., repair and maintenance of equipment and facilities, utilities, insurance,
rental of equipment, land, or facilities, and certain administrative costs). Taxpayers have some
discretion in assigning indirect costs to production or resale activities, as long as the methods
used in the allocation produce reasonable and tenable results for their trade or business.
Nonetheless, some small firms are exempt from the uniform capitalization rule. Specifically, it
does not apply to tangible or intangible property acquired for resale by a business taxpayer that
had average annual gross receipts of $10 million or less in the three previous tax years.
This exemption is beneficial because eligible firms face lower administrative costs and less
complexity in complying with income tax laws and have more control over the timing of business
expense deductions, opening up opportunities for the deferral of income tax liabilities.29
There are no known estimates of the revenue loss associated with this small business tax benefit.
Simplified Dollar-Value LIFO
Accounting Method for Small Firms
Business taxpayers that maintain inventories to determine the cost of goods sold are required to
estimate the value of their inventories at the beginning and end of each tax year. Because doing
28
Office of Management and Budget, Analytical Perspectives: Budget of the U.S. Government in Fiscal Year 2009
(Washington: GPO, 2008), table 19-2, p. 294.
29
See Paul G. Schloemer, “Simplifying the Uniform Inventory Capitalization Rules,” Tax Notes, vol. 53, no. 9, Dec. 2,
1991, pp. 1065-1069.
Congressional Research Service
16
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
this item by item is time-consuming and costly, many taxpayers use methods that assume certain
item or cost flows.
One such method is known as “last-in-first-out”(or LIFO). LIFO operates on the assumption that
the most recently acquired goods are sold before all other goods. Consequently, LIFO assigns the
newest unit costs to the cost of goods sold and the oldest unit costs to the ending inventory. The
method can be advantageous when the cost of many inventory items is rising, because it yields a
lower taxable income and inventory valuation than other methods. There are various ways to
apply LIFO. A widely used application is known as the dollar-value method. Under this method, a
taxpayer accounts for its inventories on the basis of a pool of dollars rather than specific items.
Each pool includes the value of a variety of inventory items and is measured by the dollar value
of the inventory items when they were first added to the inventory account; the year when the
items are first added is known as the base year. Using the dollar-value method is complicated and
costly for most business taxpayers.30
But IRC Section 474, which was added to the tax code by the Tax Reform Act of 1986, allows
eligible small firms to use a simplified dollar-value LIFO method. It differs from the regular
dollar-value method in the way in which inventory items are pooled and the technique for
estimating the base-year value of the pools. A firm is eligible to use the simplified method if its
average annual gross receipts were $5 million or less in the three previous tax years.
There is no known estimate of the revenue cost of this small business tax benefit.
Tax Credit for Pension Plan Start-Up Costs of Small Firms
Under IRC Section 45E, qualified small firms may claim a non-refundable tax credit for a portion
of the start-up costs they incur in setting up new retirement plans for employees. The credit,
which was enacted as part of the Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001,
began in 2002 and originally was scheduled to disappear (or “sunset”) after 2010. But a provision
of the Pension Protection Act of 2006 permanently extended the credit. It is a component of the
general business credit and thus subject to its limitations and rules for carryover.
The credit is equal to 50% of the first $1,000 in eligible costs incurred in each of the first three
years a qualified pension is operative. Eligible costs are defined as the ordinary and necessary
expenses incurred in administering the plan and informing employees about the plan’s benefits
and requirements. Qualified plans consist of new defined benefit plans, defined contribution
plans, savings incentive match plans for employees, and simplified employee pension plans.
Firms with fewer than 100 employees, each of whom received at least $5,000 in compensation in
the previous year, are eligible to claim the credit. They can do so only if at least one highly
compensated employee participates in the plan.
The credit gives owners of small firms an incentive to establish pension plans for employees by
lowering the after-tax cost of setting up and administering these plans in their first three years.
Recent surveys have indicated that these costs can serve as a formidable barrier to the creation of
pension plans by small employers.
30
For more details on this method, see U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, Impact on Small Business of
Replacing the Federal Income Tax, JCS-3-96 (Washington, Apr. 23, 1996), pp. 18-19.
Congressional Research Service
17
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
There is no known estimate of the revenue cost for the credit.
Tax Credit for Cost of Making A Business More Accessible to the
Disabled
Under IRC Section 44, an eligible small firm may claim a non-refundable credit for expenses it
incurs to make its business more accessible to disabled individuals. The credit is equal to 50% of
the amount of eligible expenditures in a tax year over $250 but not greater than $10,250. In the
case of a partnership, this upper limit applies separately at the partnership level and at the partner
or individual level; the same distinction holds in the case of a subchapter S corporation. The
disabled access credit is a component of the general business credit under IRC Section 38 and
thus subject to its limitations.
To qualify for the credit, a firm must satisfy one of two requirements: its gross receipts (less any
returns and allowances) in the previous tax year totaled no more than $1 million, or it employed
no more than 30 persons on a full-time basis during that year. A worker is considered a full-time
employee if he or she works at least 30 hours a week for 20 or more weeks in a calendar year.
Qualified expenses are defined as the amounts an eligible small firm pays or incurs to bring its
business into compliance with the Americans With Disabilities Act of 1990 (ADA). They must be
reasonable in amount and necessary in light of legal requirements. Eligible expenses include
those related to removing architectural, communication, transportation, or physical barriers to
making a business accessible to or usable by disabled individuals; providing interpreters or other
effective methods of making materials understandable to hearing-impaired individuals; and
supplying qualified readers, taped texts, and other effective methods of making materials
understandable to visually impaired individuals.
The credit is intended to ease the financial burden on smaller firms of complying with the
mandates of the ADA. There is no known estimate of the credit’s revenue cost.
Economic Importance of Small Firms
Available data on small firms indicate they make significant contributions to the performance of
the U.S. economy. A critical consideration in measuring and evaluating those contributions is the
definition of a small firm. As one might expect, the broader the definition, the larger the
economic impact of small firms. This link between the nature of small firms and their economic
impact makes it likely that any discussion of the economic importance of these firms rests on an
arbitrary assumption about the size of the population of small firms.
When small firms are defined as independent business enterprises with fewer than 500
employees, as the SBA does in publishing data on small business, there are indications that they
play a major role in domestic economic output. In 2005, according to the SBA, firms of that size
accounted for 99.7% of employers, employed more than 50% of private non-farm workers, and
were responsible for 47% of private non-farm compensation (wages, salaries, and benefits). A
separate study came to the conclusion that from 1998 to 2004, firms with 500 or fewer employees
Congressional Research Service
18
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
accounted for about 50% of nominal gross domestic product (GDP).31 And it appears that small
firms generate a large share of the new domestic jobs created each year. According to data
reported by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, firms with less than 500 employees accounted for 65%
of net new job creation in the non-farm private sector, from the third quarter of 1992 through the
first quarter of 2005.32 In addition, recent research sponsored by the Center for Economic Studies
at the U.S. Census Bureau found that new firms accounted for 3% of annual U.S. employment
from 1987 to 2005, and that without their contribution, annual net employment growth would
have been -1.2%. This finding implied that existing firms (large and small in employment size)
were a drag on net job growth in that period and whatever growth happened was due to business
formation or the creation of new firms.33
Yet a more restrictive definition of a small firm can yield a different picture of the economic
importance of small business. According to a recent study by some economists at the Bureau of
Labor Statistics, firms with fewer than 100 employees accounted for 45.0% of average quarterly
net job growth from June 1990 to September 2005, while firms with fewer than 500 employees
accounted for 63.7%.34
The economic importance of small firms varies by industry. In 2002, the share of an industry’s
contribution to GDP attributable to firms with fewer than 500 employees ranged from 20% for
information services to 85% for other services.35
Most firms start out small in employment size, and the likelihood is remote that a particular small
start-up firm will grow into a large, stable, and mostly profitable firm. Two-thirds of start-up
firms survive at least two years, and 44% last at least four years.36 So while hundreds of
thousands of new firms typically are formed each year, nearly as many small firms also fail. This
constant churning is reflected in the fluctuating contributions of small firms to annual net job
creation in the United States.
There are also some indications that small firms have made significant contributions in the past
decade or so to the development of new commercial technologies, and that these contributions
have varied by industry. According to a 2003 study by CHI Research, Inc., firms with fewer than
500 employees contributed 41% of all patents filed by domestic corporations from 1996 to 2000.
The authors also found that firms of that size produced 13 to 14 times as many patents per
employee as larger firms in the same period. 37 Small firms in the study filed 25% of the patents
related to biotechnology, 19% of the patents related to pharmaceuticals, 11% of the patents related
31
Small Business Administration, Office of Advocacy, Frequently Asked Questions (Washington: August 2007), and
Katherine Kobe, The Small Business Share of GDP, 1998-2004, report for the Small Business Administration
(Washington: Apr. 2007), pp. 7 and 13.
32
Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, New Quarterly Data from BLS on Business Employment Dynamics
by Size of Firm (Washington: Dec. 2005), p. 3.
33
John Haltiwanger, Ron Jarmin, and Javier Miranda, Business Formation and Dynamics by Business Age: Results
from the New Business Dynamics Statistics, discussion paper, May 2008, p. 14.
34
Jessica Helfand, Akbar Sadeghi, and David Talan, “Employment Dynamics: Small and Large Firms Over the
Business Cycle,” Monthly Labor Review, Mar. 2007, p. 41.
35
Katherine Kobe, The Small Business Share of GDP, 1998-2004, p. 7.
36
Small Business Administration, Frequently Asked Questions, updated Sept. 2008.
37
CHI Research, Inc., Small Serial Innovators: The Small Firm Contribution to Technical Change, report for the Small
Business Administration (Washington: 2003), p 3.
Congressional Research Service
19
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
to medical equipment and electronics, and 9% of the patents related to chemicals other than
pharmaceuticals.38
Economic Arguments For and Against Small
Business Tax Preferences
What is known about the economic importance of small firms raises the question of why the
subsidies are needed if small firms normally account for substantial shares of domestic
employment and output and play significant roles in the commercial development of certain new
technologies.
The answer to this question is not unimportant, as small firms received perhaps more than $11
billion in tax benefits in FY2008—in addition to the financial support they received through other
federal programs targeted at small business. If the economic arguments made in favor of these tax
subsidies turn out to be weak or untenable on theoretical or empirical grounds, then using these
resources for other purposes (e.g., reducing the federal budget deficit or raising federal spending
on infrastructure improvement or basic research) may lead to higher levels of economic output
per capita in the future.
In evaluating the economic arguments made in favor of small business tax benefits, it should be
recognized that persuasive non-economic arguments are also raised in support of these benefits.
Some lawmakers attach considerable weight to those arguments. A case in point is the notion that
small business is an effective vehicle for expanding the middle class because it can lift people out
of poverty.
Nevertheless, only the economic arguments for and against small business tax benefits are
discussed below.
Chief Economic Arguments in Favor of the Preferences
Proponents of small business tax subsidies generally cite four economic justifications for them:
(1) the special economic role played by small firms; (2) the barriers to their formation and growth
in financial markets; (3) the impact of high marginal tax rates on the formation of small
entrepreneurial firms, and (4) the unique opportunities for individual economic advancement
offered by small business ownership.
Special Economic Role of Small Firms
The economic contributions of small firms are sometimes cited as a reason to extend government
support to small business. For example, in remarks made on the Senate floor in 2001 advocating
additional tax benefits for small firms, Senator Christopher Bond stated that “small businesses
represent more than 99% of all employers, employ 53% of the private work force, create about
75% of the new jobs in this country, ... contribute 47% of all sales in this country, and ... are
38
Ibid., p. 17.
Congressional Research Service
20
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
responsible for 51% of private gross domestic product.”39 By the same token, in 2003, Senator
Olympia Snowe urged her colleagues in the Senate to back the creation of more tax benefits for
small firms by pointing out that “they (small businesses) represent 99% of all employers, employ
51% of private-sector workforce, provide about 75% of the net new jobs, contribute 51% of the
private-sector output, and represent 96% of all exporters of goods.”40
Some proponents of small business tax subsidies take this view a step further by arguing that
small firms are deserving of government support because they generate special economic benefits
that larger firms generally cannot replicate. These benefits can be seen in the multitude of jobs
and new technologies they create over time, in their innumerable and ever-changing linkages to
larger firms in the economic supply chain, and in their contributions to economic renewal and
change. The net effect of the special economic benefits generated by small firms is to make the
economy grow faster and become more productive.
According to proponents, the efficiency and productivity gains can be seen in evidence that small
firms supply certain goods and services more efficiently than large firms. Economist Bo Carlsson
has noted that this advantage is apparent in industries where large production runs and falling unit
costs are dominant structural features; examples include computers, automobiles, and steel. 41 In
industries such as these, small and large firms often specialize in specific products or services. As
a result, they tend to interact more as partners or suppliers than as competitors. In Carlsson’s
view, the dramatic rise in outsourcing among large U.S. firms in the 1990s had the effect of
reinforcing and deepening this division in labor between large and small firms. Among the
supposed advantages of small firms in the vast and complex supply chain undergirding the U.S.
economy are greater flexibility and quickness in responding to new market opportunities and
competitive threats.
The belief that small firms can serve as agents of dynamic economic change and technological
advance may have its roots in the roles played by small start-up firms in the origins and growth of
certain technologically advanced industries like computers and microelectronics. Two notable
findings in the recent literature on firm size and technological innovation are that the contribution
of small firms to innovation varies by industry, and that their contributions are likely to be most
significant in relatively young industries where no firm has accumulated substantial market
power.42 The same literature provides fresh evidence that in certain industries, small start-up firms
have proven more adept than large established firms at identifying promising commercial
applications for new technologies and exploiting them. During the 1980s and 1990s, many
instances of small start-up firms gaining a temporary advantage this way emerged in
biotechnology, microelectronics, computer software, and electronic commerce. 43
Findings such as these have led some economists to conclude that small entrepreneurial firms
play a vital and indispensable role in the overall process of economic growth and renewal. They
39
Sen. Christopher Bond, remarks in the Senate, Congressional Record, daily edition, vol. 147, Jan. 25, 2001, p. S576.
40
Sen. Olympia Snowe, remarks in the Senate, Congressional Record, daily edition, vol. 149, no. 6, Jan. 14, 2003, p. S
299.
41
Bo Carlsson, “Small Business, Entrepreneurship, and Industrial Dynamics,” in Are Small Firms Important? Their
Role and Impact, Zoltan J. Acs, ed. (Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1999), p. 100.
42
Joshua Lerner, “Small Business, Innovation, and Public Policy,” in Are Small Firms Important? Their Role and
Impact, p. 160.
43
Ibid., p. 160.
Congressional Research Service
21
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
note that economic growth over time is marked by the continuous creation and destruction of jobs
and firms. In their view, without the continuous entry of small entrepreneurial firms, this process
would slow down to the point that the standard of living would stagnate and perhaps even
decline. Carlsson has argued that in the absence of the “heterogeneity and volatility” provided by
small start-up firms, “the economy eventually stagnates or even collapses.”44
Opportunities for the Economic Advancement of Immigrants, Women, and
Members of Minority Groups
Proponents of small business tax subsidies also cite the economic benefits of small business
ownership for women, minority groups, immigrants, and the communities where they live as an
important justification for the subsidies. They argue that owning and managing a small business
gives them the opportunities to increase their income and independence and to move into the
economic mainstream of the United States.
In addition, proponents claim that women-, minority-, and immigrant-owned small firms benefit
their immediate communities and society at large in ways that go beyond direct economic effects.
For example, there is evidence that female small business owners are more likely than their male
counterparts to encourage openness in workplace communication and decision-making, hire a
diverse workforce, put into place desirable child-care programs, and pay full benefits to
employees. In addition, families with self-employed women who work out of their homes seem
more stable than the average family. 45 And in the case of minority and immigrant groups, small
business ownership helps to build tight-knit social networks, providing job and skills training, and
creating informal capital markets.46
Imperfections in Capital Markets
Yet another economic argument made in favor of small business tax subsidies is that they can
ease or offset the barriers facing many small business owners and aspiring entrepreneurs in trying
to raise the funds needed to start or expand a business.
If capital markets were truly efficient, then every business investment opportunity offering a pretax rate of return that exceeds the cost of capital would be funded, regardless of the profitability,
cash flow, size, or age of a firm. But proponents of government support for small business say
that such is not the case for small firms. In their view, many aspiring entrepreneurs are unable to
borrow or attract equity capital, largely because lenders and investors lack the information needed
to evaluate the profit potential of the proposed venture. As a consequence, small business owners
confronted by such a constraint are often forced to finance projects out of their own resources or
the resources of friends and family members, or to abandon the dream of owning their own
business altogether. In addition, established small business owners facing severe liquidity
constraints may have an elevated risk of failure.
44
Bo Carlsson, “Small Business, Entrepreneurship, and Industrial Dynamics,” p. 109.
See Candida Brush and Robert D. Hisrich, “Women-Owned Businesses: Why Do They Matter?,” in Are Small Firms
Important? Their Role and Impact, pp. 111-127.
46
See John Sibley Butler and Patricia Gene Greene, “Don’t Call Me Small: The Contribution of Ethnic Enterprises to
the Economic and Social Well-Being of America,” in Are Small Firms Important? Their Role and Impact (Boston:
Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1999), pp. 129-145.
45
Congressional Research Service
22
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
For these reasons, proponents maintain that government support is required to enable cashstrapped small firms to gain access to the funds they need to grow.
Impact of Progressive Income Taxes
Supporters of tax relief for small firms also maintain that taxes have a significant effect on three
key decisions made by any small business owner: how fast to grow the firm; whether to expand
capital investment—and if so, by how much; and whether to hire more employees—and if so,
how many? They cite a variety of studies suggesting that as individual or corporate tax rates rise,
small firms tend to grow at a slower rate, invest less in new assets, and become less likely to
expand employment.47 In their view, these effects of higher tax burdens are sufficient reason to
offer tax breaks to small firms.
Cost of Tax Compliance
Some proponents of small business tax preferences argue that they are also justified because of
the inordinate costs the federal government imposes on small firms through the numerous
regulations (including taxes) they must comply with. In their view, the preferences offset at least
some of those costs, which can be highly regressive. In the case of tax laws and regulations, the
regressivity lies in the fixed cost of compliance and the measures of size (e.g., sales, assets, or
employees) over which that cost is distributed. Proponents maintain that the cost of tax
compliance puts small firms at a competitive disadvantage because their cost per employee is
much higher than it is for larger firms in the same industries.
Chief Economic Arguments Against the Subsidies
Not everyone agrees with the arguments made by proponents of small business tax preferences to
justify them on economic grounds.
Critics of the preferences cite conventional economic analysis as a justification for eliminating
most, if not all, of them. Conventional economic analysis holds that government intervention in
the economy generally is warranted to correct some market failure. In general, market failures can
be thought of as a set of circumstances that prevents or hinders the emergence of an economically
efficient outcome. Foremost among the market failures that call for government intervention are a
lack of perfect competition, the presence of public goods, positive or negative external effects (or
externalities), the existence of incomplete markets, and imperfect information on the part of
consumers.48 Critics of small business tax subsidies say there is no evidence that any such market
failure stands in the way of the formation or growth of small firms. In particular, they maintain
that there is no evidence that imperfections in capital markets are leading to the formation of too
few or to the failure of too many small firms, or that small firms generate external benefits that
larger firms cannot replicate. According to critics, in the absence of a market failure, the use of
such subsidies is likely to produce undesirable equity and efficiency effects.
47
Douglas Holtz-Eakin and Harvey Rosen, Economic Policy and the Start-up, Survival, and Growth of Entrepreneurial
Ventures, report submitted to the Small Business Administration, May 2001, pp. 43-44.
48
For more information on market failures, see Joseph E. Stiglitz, Economics of the Public Sector, 3rd Edition (New
York: W.W. Norton & Co., 2000), pp. 76-90.
Congressional Research Service
23
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
Equity Concerns
Proponents of small business tax preferences generally do not refer to their equity effects in
defending them on economic grounds.
But to critics, those equity effects provide a reason to oppose the preferences. In their view, small
business tax preferences undercut the progressivity of the federal individual income tax. Under a
progressive income tax, an individual’s tax liability depends on his or her taxable income; so
taxpayers with higher taxable incomes pay higher taxes than taxpayers with lower taxable
incomes. But small business tax preferences weaken the link between tax burden and income by
reducing the tax burden on the earnings of small firms.
Among public finance economists, it is widely thought that individuals, and not firms, ultimately
bear the burden of business income taxes, or reap the benefits of tax subsidies. Critics argue that
small business tax benefits ultimately increase the after-tax earnings of small firms, which
eventually become part of the income of small business owners, whose income and wealth tend to
be well above average for U.S. households.49
Efficiency Concerns
Critics also assail small business tax subsidies on efficiency grounds. In theory, income taxes
reduce social welfare by driving a wedge between the costs and benefits of the many options for
consumption and production facing individual consumers and firms. As a result, conventional
economic theory holds that the most desirable tax system is one that raises needed revenue
without diverting economic resources from their most productive uses. A case in point is a lumpsum tax: it would impose the same tax on all individuals, regardless of income or wealth.
This doctrine of neutrality has important implications for tax policy. First, it implies that the
returns to all investments should be taxed at the same rate. Second, the doctrine implies that any
tax that is not uniform across firms is likely to damage social welfare.50 Finally, it implies that
taxes should not distort a firm’s choice of inputs or its investment or production decisions.
Small business tax preferences, say critics, violate each of these policy prescriptions. In their
view, an efficient or desirable allocation of resources can be achieved only if the tax code does
not favor small firms over large firms, or unincorporated firms over incorporated firms, or
interfere with the natural growth and evolution of firms, or encourage firms to attain a certain
asset, employment, or revenue size and grow no further.51
49
According to a 1990 study by Charles Brown, James Hamilton, and James Medoff, the average family owning a small
business had an income that was 80% greater and wealth that was five times greater than the average family. (See
Charles Brown, James Hamilton, and James Medoff, Employers Large and Small (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press, 1990), pp. 15-17.) More recently, in a study of the wealth and income of U.S. small business owners from 1992
to 2001, researchers George W. Haynes and Charles Ou found that, in 2001, the mean income of households with small
business owners was $110,370, compared to $42,108 for households with no business owners, and the mean net worth
of households with small business owners was $1,050,872, compared to $188,535 for households with no business
owners. (See George W. Haynes and Charles Ou, How Did Small Business-Owning Households Fare During the
longest U.S. Economic Expansion?, report prepared for the Small Business Administration (Washington: June 2006)
table 3, p. 26.
50
Stiglitz, Economics of the Public Sector, pp. 567-569.
51
Douglas Holtz-Eakin, “Should Small Businesses be Tax-Favored?,” National Tax Journal, vol. 48, no. 3, Sept. 1995,
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
24
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
A departure from the doctrine of neutral taxation to assist small firms through tax subsidies might
be warranted if there were something uniquely valuable about the economic role of such firms,
and if that role can achieve its full expression only through targeted government support.
Proponents of small business tax preferences claim that small firms consistently create more jobs
and spawn more important technological innovations than large firms, and that government
support is needed to ensure that they continue to play these roles. But critics question both the
premises and policy implications of this claim.
Small Firms and Job Creation
Critics and proponents alike agree that small firms generally are a robust source of job creation.
According to data from the Small Business Administration, small firms created between 60% and
80% all net new U.S. jobs from 1995 to 2005, depending on how the employment size of a small
firm is specified.52
Critics maintain, however, that for a variety of reasons these data do not necessarily prove that
small firms possess a greater job-creating prowess than large firms. To begin with, they note that
the data fail to address some important questions about the measurement of job creation and firm
size: What does it mean to be small? When should a firm’s size be measured? Is gross or net job
creation a better indicator of job-creating prowess? And how long should a job last before it is
counted as a net new job?
In addition, critics say there is an abundance of evidence that small firms are not consistently
better at creating jobs than large firms. First, there appears to be considerable variation over time
in the share of new jobs created by small firms. In a widely cited study, David Birch and James
Medoff estimated that the share of total net new jobs generated by firms employing 100 or fewer
workers varied from about 40% to 140%, depending on the stage of the business cycle.53 Second,
most of the jobs created by small firms result from the formation of new firms, which typically
start out small in employment or asset size. Yet many of these jobs do not last a long time, as
most new firms fail within their first few years.54 Third, a few firms accounted for most small
business job creation between the late 1980s and early 1990s—Birch and Medoff labeled these
firms “gazelles”—and these firms grew swiftly from small to large, and in some cases from large
back to small, suggesting that their job-creating ability was unstable at best.55 Finally, during the
1970s and 1980s, though large firms and plants dominated job creation and destruction in the
(...continued)
p. 390.
52
U.S. Small Business Administration, Office of Advocacy, Frequently Asked Questions, (Washington: Sept. 2008).
53
See David Birch and James Medoff, “Gazelles,” in Labor Markets, Employment Policy, and Job Creation, Lewis C.
Solomon and Alec R. Levenson, eds. (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1994), p. 162. The share of net new jobs created
by firms with 100 or fewer workers can exceed 100% in a year if these firms create more jobs than they destroy, all
other firms destroy more jobs than they create, and the net job gain arising from the former exceeds the net job loss
arising from the latter. For example, if firms with 100 or fewer employees account for a net job gain of 100 and all
other firms generate a net job loss of 25, then the economy as a whole would realize a net job gain of 75, and the share
of that gain attributable to firms with 100 or fewer employees would be 133%.
54
Ibid., p. 8.
55
Birch and Medoff, “Gazelles,” pp. 162-164.
Congressional Research Service
25
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
manufacturing sector, there was no strong, systematic relationship between firm size and net job
growth rates.56
Critics also contend that even if small firms were to create more jobs than large firms over time,
there is no reason to think that government support for small business would generate ever-faster
employment growth. Economic analysis shows that the economy generates jobs through what can
best be described as a natural process of growth, decline, and structural change; the size
distribution of firms seems to be incidental, nothing more than a byproduct of this process.
Therefore, the level of national employment over time is the product of a mix of factors that
would overwhelm the employment effects of any government support for small business. The key
factors are fiscal and monetary policy, consumer spending, business investment, and the
difference between U.S. exports and imports.
Small Firms and Technological Innovation
Research and development (R&D) is the lifeblood of technological innovation, which, in turn,
serves as a powerful engine of long-term economic growth and structural change. Economists
generally agree that without government support, business investment in R&D would fall short of
the socially optimal amount. Left to their own devices, firms are inclined to invest too little in
R&D mainly for two reasons. One is that they cannot capture all the returns to R&D investment,
as other firms capitalize on the results of research in spite of intellectual property protection. A
second reason is that some firms (mainly small start-up firms) lack access to the financial capital
needed to undertake planned R&D projects because potential lenders and investors lack the
information they need to assess the profit potential of those projects.57 This predisposition to
invest less in R&D than its likely economic benefits would warrant represents a market failure.
To remedy this failure, most economists advocate the use of a variety of government policies
aimed at spurring increased business R&D investment.
But critics of small business tax subsidies question the notion that government R&D support
should be targeted at small firms. They point to evidence demonstrating that both small and large
firms develop the new technologies that drive economic growth and structural change. Critics
also claim that the same evidence indicates that it is often impossible to disentangle the
contributions of one group of firms from the other. According to data from the National Science
Foundation (NSF), larger firms perform the vast share of business R&D: in 2005 and 2006, for
example, companies with fewer than 500 employees performed 18% of the industrial R&D
conducted in the United States, whereas companies with 10,000 or more employees were
responsible for 52% of that R&D.58
Nonetheless, small firms and large firms each appear to have distinct advantages as agents of
technological innovation. 59 On the one hand, small firms may be more likely than large firms to
56
Steven J. Davis, John C. Haltiwanger, and Scott Schuh, Job Creation and Destruction (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press,
1996), pp. 169-170.
57
Scott J. Wallsten, “Rethinking the Small Business Innovation Research Program,” in Investing in Innovation:
Creating a Research and Innovation Policy That Works, Lewis M. Branscomb and James H. Keller, eds. (Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press, 1998), p. 197.
58
National Science Foundation, U.S. Business R&D Expenditures Increase in 2006; Companies’ Own and Federal
Contributions Rise, Info Brief (NSF-08-313), August 2008, table 1, p. 2.
59
See Wallsten, “Rethinking the Small Business Innovation Research Program,” p. 197.
Congressional Research Service
26
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
create or dominate a new industry through R&D, and they may be more flexible than large firms
in the pursuit of research goals. On the other hand, large firms can more easily raise the funds
needed to finance the substantial sunken costs involved in R&D investments and are likely to
capture a larger share of the returns to R&D investments through marketing campaigns, the
aggressive use of intellectual property protection, and the creation of regional, national, and
international distribution, service, and repair networks.
In addition, some studies have looked at the effects of firm size and market structure on
innovation.60 On the whole, they have found that no firm size appears to be ideal for generating
new successful commercial technologies. Rather, there is evidence that in some industries, small
firms were more innovative than large firms, but in other industries, large firms had a decisive
edge in the generation of new technologies.
Other Concerns
Critics also assail small business tax preferences on the grounds that existing ones often poorly
serve their intended purposes or are simply ineffective.
One argument made in favor of the subsidies is that the creation of new small firms is needed to
prevent the development of monopoly power by large firms. But critics contend that the best way
to achieve that result does not involve government support for the formation and growth of small
firms. They point out that only a tiny fraction of small start-up firms survive and grow to the
point where they pose a serious competitive threat to large, entrenched firms in the same industry.
In the view of critics, antitrust law is a much more effective policy tool than small business tax
preferences for thwarting the acquisition of monopoly power and other anti-competitive business
practices.
Critics also note that if the aim of public policy is to stimulate employment growth, then it seems
irrational to offer small firms tax subsidies that lower the cost of capital, and not the cost of labor.
The current expensing allowance is a case in point. Such a subsidy lowers the cost of capital
relative to the cost of labor, thereby implicitly encouraging small firms to substitute machinery
and equipment for labor where technically feasible. In theory, a tax subsidy like the allowance
could lead to lower employment than would be the case if the tax code offered no subsidies for
the purchase of capital assets.
Yet another concern about small business tax preferences is that they impose an implicit or a
hidden tax on business growth. This tax, which is known among public finance economists as the
“notch problem,” is the inevitable result of the design of many current tax preferences targeted at
small firms. Under the typical small business tax preference, firms lose the tax benefit when their
workforce, assets, or receipts surpass a designated limit. Such a design obviously creates a
disincentive to grow beyond that limit.
The expensing allowance under IRC Section 179 illustrates this problem. In 2003, the maximum
allowance was $100,000 and the phaseout threshold $400,000. When a firm increased its
investment in assets that qualified for the allowance beyond $400,000, the amount that could be
expensed was reduced dollar for dollar—ultimately to zero when total investment reached
60
F. M. Scherer and David Ross, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, 3rd edition (Boston:
Houghton Mifflin Co., 1990), pp. 651-657.
Congressional Research Service
27
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
$500,000. In effect, this design gave firms a significant incentive to invest no more than $100,000
in qualified assets in a single tax year. For any investment, the cost of capital depends in part on
the investor’s marginal tax rate. Jane Gravelle of CRS estimated that under the expensing
allowance for 2003, the marginal effective tax rate on investment in equipment was 0% on the
first $100,000, 26% on amounts above $100,000 to $400,000, 43% on amounts above $400,000
to $500,000, and 26% on amounts above $500,000.61 For a small firm hoping to accelerate its
growth, the design of the allowance can increase its cost of capital at a time when its growth is
boosting its capital needs.62
Concluding Remarks
Available economic data suggest that small firms make important contributions to the
performance and growth of the U.S. economy. But the magnitude of the contributions depends
critically on how a small firm is defined. Under the definition used by the SBA in administering
its programs to support small firms, it appears that small business accounts for a majority of
private-sector jobs and about half of private-sector output, generates many technological
innovations, and serves as an agent of revitalization and structural change in a variety of
industries. A more restrictive definition would yield a different picture of the economic
importance of small firms.
These contributions arguably seem to undergird the strong support inside Congress for
government policies to assist small business. A concrete manifestation of this support is the
preferential tax treatment received by many small firms. The combined revenue cost of current
federal small business tax subsidies may have exceeded $11 billion in FY2008. Owing largely to
the political clout of the small business community and widespread agreement among lawmakers
that the federal government should take steps to stimulate the economy, the 111th Congress is
likely to consider a variety of initiatives to extend or expand these subsidies.
Still, conventional economic analysis can challenge the view that small business tax preferences
are justified on economic grounds. The preferences have the effect of lowering the tax burden on
owners of small firms, diluting (to an extent that is difficult to measure) the progressivity of the
federal individual income tax system. Furthermore, the preferences seemingly do little to promote
growth in productivity and the output of goods and services. In theory, any tax other than a lumpsum tax causes efficiency losses by distorting the behavior of consumers and firms. In the case of
production, the best possible outcome is an income tax system that does not distort the production
arrangements within firms and taxes all returns to capital at the same rate. Most economists hold
that departures from this doctrine of uniform or neutral taxation are warranted only to correct
clear and harmful market failures. But in the case of small firms, there is no evidence that a
market failure is affecting their formation, performance, or growth in ways that harm social
welfare.
This is not to suggest that government support for small firms cannot ever be justified on purely
economic grounds. If convincing evidence were to emerge that the formation and growth of small
entrepreneurial firms are critical to an efficient allocation of economic resources, and that some
61
The estimate assumes a rate of inflation of 2% and a corporate tax rate of 35%. It is based on a simulation done by
Gravelle with the aid of the CRS capital stock model on May 9, 2003.
62
Holtz-Eakin, “Should Small Businesses Be Tax-Favored?” p. 393.
Congressional Research Service
28
Small Business Tax Benefits: Overview and Economic Rationale
market failure was unduly restraining their formation or growth, then even critics might accept
that government action to correct the failure would be warranted.
One possible market failure would be imperfections in capital markets that unreasonably denied
promising small start-up firms access to the financial capital they need to develop new products
and services and grow their business. In theory, this problem could be resolved through a series of
policy measures aimed at breaking down the barriers that were preventing these firms from
gaining the funding they desired without diverting the overall flow of capital away from its most
productive uses. Tax subsidies might be helpful, but to be cost-effective, they would need to
address the root causes of the capital market imperfections at a lower economic cost than
alternative policy responses, such as increased federal regulation of financial markets or the
establishment of a federally subsidized lending facility.
Another possible market failure would involve conclusive evidence that small firms as a whole
are more innovative than other firms and thus are responsible for a disproportionately large
proportion of the positive externalities arising from technological innovation. It seems improbable
that such a market failure would materialize, however, given that these externalities are tied to
specific innovations, not to the operations of a specific class of firms.
If anything, the findings of this report suggest the need for a robust model of the process by
which small firms are formed and grow and contribute to the total output of goods and services
and productivity over time. As the report has suggested, considerable uncertainty still surrounds
this process. As some economists have noted, the development of such a model might make it
easier for policymakers to determine whether a market failure lies behind any problems facing a
wide swath of small firms; identify the key factors contributing to any market failure that is
detected; and devise appropriate and cost-effective remedies for the problem. 63 Further research
on the economic contributions of small business is needed to develop such a model.
Author Contact Information
Gary Guenther
Analyst in Public Finance
gguenther@crs.loc.gov, 7-7742
63
Ibid.
Congressional Research Service
29