Order Code RL31181
CRS Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
Research Tax Credit: Current Status,
Legislative Proposals in the 109th Congress,
and Policy Issues
Updated September 22, 2006Research Tax Credit: Current Status and Selected
Issues for Congress
Updated May 31, 2007
Gary Guenther
Analyst in Business Taxation and Finance
Government and Finance Division
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress
Research Tax Credit: Current Status,
Legislative Proposals in the 109th Congress,
and Policy Issues
Summary
Technological innovation makes crucial contributions to
Research Tax Credit: Current Status and Selected
Issues for Congress
Summary
Technological innovation is a major driving force behind long-term economic
growth, and research and development (R&D) isserves as the lifeblood of innovation. In
In economies dominated by free markets, competitive markets, privately owned firms are
responsible for a large share of R&D investment is
undertaken by private firms seeking, mainly in a bid to become more
competitive and improve their
prospects for future growth. Because firms generally
cannot capture all the returns
to their R&D investments, they are inclined to spend
less on R&D than its overall
economic benefits would warrant. ThePartly in a bid to
negate this inclination, the federal government supports business R&D in a
variety variety
of ways, including a tax credit for increases in R&D spending.
This report examines the status of the credit, summarizes its legislative history,
discusses some key policy issues it raises, and describes legislation in the 109th Congress
110th
Congress to modify or extend the credit. Itit. The report will be updated as legislative activity
warrants.
The research and experimentation (R&E) tax credit has never been a permanent
provision of the federal tax
code. Since its enactment in mid-1981, the credit has been
extended 1112 times and
significantly modified five times. In reality, the R&E tax credit has four
components: a regular credit, an alternative incremental credit (AIRC), a basic
research credit, and While the credit is often thought of as a single
unified credit, it has five components: (1) a regular credit, (2) an alternative
incremental credit (AIRC), (3) an alternative simplified credit (ASIC), (4) a basic
research credit, and (5) an energy research credit. All but the energy research credit are
are incremental in that the credit applies only to qualified research spending above
a base
amount. The credit expiredis due to expire at the end of 20052007.
In effect, the research tax credit seekstries to stimulate increased business R&D
investment by reducing the after-tax cost to firms of undertaking qualified research
beyond a base amount, which appears designed to approximate what a firm would
spend on R&D if there were no credit. Although most analysts and lawmakers view
research tax credits as a desirable policy instrument in theory, the current design of
the federal credit has made it a target of continuing criticism. A major concern is that
the design keeps the credit from being as effective as it might. Critics attribute this
problem to what they claim are five flaws in its design: (1) its lack of permanence,
(2) its weak and disparate incentive effects, (3) its non-refundable status, (4) its
inadequate and unsettled definition of qualified research, and (5) its lack of focus on. A key factor shaping the efficacy of the credit is the
sensitivity of firms to changes in the cost of R&D. Although most analysts and
lawmakers support the use of research tax credits in general, the design of the current
federal credit has long been a target of criticism. A major concern of critics is that
the design undermines the credit’s efficacy. Critics attribute this reduced
effectiveness to what they consider five flaws in the credit’s design: (1) a lack of
permanence, (2) inadequate and disparate incentive effects, (3) its non-refundable
status, (4) an unsettled definition of qualified research, and (5) a failure to target
R&D projects that generate much larger social returns than private returns.
NumerousAt least five bills to extend the credit and enhance its incentive effect have been
have been introduced in the 109th Congress. Some examples are H.R. 1736, H.R. 4845, H.R.
5115, S. 14, S. 627, S. 2109, and S. 2357. Each would extend the credit
permanently, raise the three rates for the AIRC to 3%, 4%, and 5%, and establish
what is known as an “alternative simplified credit.” For many firms, such a credit
would be equal to 12% of spending on qualified research above 50% of their average
qualified research spending in the three previous tax years. A bill passed by the
House on July 29, 2006 (H.R. 5970) would extend the credit through the end of 2007,
increase the three rates for the AIRC, and establish the same alternative simplified
credit. It is unclear whether the Senate will vote on the measure before the end of the
current Congress110th
Congress: S. 14, S. 41, S. 592, S. 833, and H.R. 1712. More specifically, S. 41 and
H.R. 1712 would extend the credit permanently; replace the regular credit, AIRC, and
ASIC with a new simplified credit equal to 20% of a firm’s qualified research
expenses above half of its average qualified research expenses in the three previous
tax years; make 80% of contract research expenses eligible for the credit; and
simplify the basic research credit. By contrast, S. 592 would extend the current credit
through 2012, and S. 14 and S. 833 would extend it permanently, without making
additional changes in the design of the credit.
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
Design of the Current R&E Tax Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
RegularQualified Research CreditExpenditures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
Regular Research Credit . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . 3
Qualified Research Expenditures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45
Alternative Incremental Research Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
Alternative Simplified Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
Basic Research Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
Energy Research Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
Legislative History of the Research Tax Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1011
Effectiveness of the Research Tax Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1314
Policy Issues Raised by the Current Research Tax Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1718
Lack of Permanence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Weak and DisparateUneven Incentive EffectEffects . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18. 19
Uneven Incentive Effect . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Weak Incentive Effect . . . . . . . . . .19
Weak or Inadequate Incentive Effect . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
Non-refundable Status . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2324
Unsettled and Ambiguous Definition of Qualified Research . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2425
Lack of Focus on R&D Projects With Relatively With Large Social Returns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2630
Legislation in the 109th110th Congress to ChangeModify the Research Tax Credit . . . . . . . . 2731
List of Tables
Table 1. Sample Calculations of the Regular and Alternative Incremental
R&E Tax Credits in 20032006 for an Established Firm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
Table 2. Sample Calculations of the Regular and Alternative Incremental
R&E Tax Credits in 20032006 for a Start-up Firm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
Table 3. U.S. Industrial R&D Spending, Federal R&D Spending,
and the
Research Tax Credit, 1996 to 2003 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
Table 4. Bills in the 109th Congress to Extend or Modify the R&E
Tax Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
Research Tax Credit: Current Status,
Legislative Proposals in the 109th Congress,
and Policy Issues
Introduction
Economists may be notorious for their lack of consensus on some important
policy issues (e.g.,17
Research Tax Credit: Current Status and
Selected Issues for Congress
Introduction
Economists may be notorious for their disagreements on a variety of important
policy issues. Notable examples include the long-term economic effects of large,
permanent tax cuts; the
impact of illegal immigration on domestic wages; and the
best way to achieve price
stability, full employment, and greater income equality). .
But on the questions of how
issues of the impact of technological innovation affectson economic growth in
the long run, and what role
governments should play and the proper role of public policy in the development of new
technologies, there is
surprisingly little disagreement.
Most economists subscribe to the notion relatively little discord among practitioners of what some call
the dismal science.
Most economists would agree that technological innovation has
accounted for
a major share of long-term growth in real per-capita income in the United
States.1 Technological innovation is one of those concepts that is hard to define in
a way that meets with universal acceptance. Economists with an interest in the
States.1
It is fair to ask what economists mean by technological innovation. After all, such
a complex idea can have different meanings among different professions.
Economists who study the dynamics of economic growth generally agree that innovation involves the
see innovation
as a convoluted and uncertain process that embraces the acquisition of new scientific
and technical knowledge and its application to the
development of new goods and
services or methods of production through a process
of experimentation that can be long and convoluted. Learning-by-doing and
research and experimentation. Learningby-doing and learning-by-using often play crucial roles in this process.
In economies dominated by freecompetitive markets, technological innovation is fueled by
the
driven by the unrelenting efforts of competing firms to gain, sustain, or reinforce a
decisive competitive advantage by
being among being the first to introduce, or use, or employ new or
improved products or services;
more efficient production processes; or better approaches tomore effective
strategies for management, marketing
and promotion, and customer service and support. The lifeblood of innovation is
support. Private investment in research and development (R&D), whose principal output is new
scientific and technical knowledge and knowhow serves as the
lifeblood of innovation.
Most economists would also agree that private R&D investment is likely to be
less than adequate in the absence of government intervention. The reason is simple:
firmswould be warranted by its economic benefits. The reason for this shortfall
lies in the nature of these benefits. Firms generally cannot capture all the economic returns to
their R&D investments,
even through the aggressive usein the presence of patents, trademarks, and other
instruments of
intellectual property protection. , and their strict enforcement.
Numerous studies have found that the average social returns to private R&D
1
Linda R. Cohen and Roger G. Noll, “Privatizing Public Research,” Scientific American,
Sept.September 1994, p. 72.
CRS-2
returns to private R&D investments greatly exceed the average private returns.2 This
finding holds true, regardless of
whether a firm invests in research projects directly
related tonarrowly focused on its existing lines of business, or it focuses its resources on basic research
business, or in research projects aimed at extending the boundaries of knowledge in a
particular scientific
discipline disciplines in ways that have no obvious or immediate
commercial applications.
Economists refer to any excess of social over private returns as the spillover
effects or external benefits of R&D. There are several channels through which the
returns from innovation may elude full capture by the innovating firms and spill over to
to society at large, including. Among the most common channels are reverse engineering by
competing firms and the purchase
of new goods and services at prices below the prices most consumers would be
willing to pay.3 When seen , migration of senior research scientists and engineers from one firm
to another, and the availability of new or newly improved goods and services at
prices lower than those most consumers would be willing to pay.3 When filtered
through the lens of conventional economic theory, these
the external benefits of
technological innovation take on the appearance of a market failure, in which too few
resources are allocated to the activities leading to the discovery and commercial
development of new technical knowledge and know-how. To remedy this failure,
most economists favoradvocate the adoption of public policies aimed at boosting or
supplementing private investment in R&D, especially those investments likely to
generate relatively large external benefits, such as basic research.
Partly in an effort to spurstimulate increased private investment in R&DR&D investment, the federal
government supports R&D in a variety of direct and indirect ways. Direct support
mainly comescomes mainly in the form of research performed by federal agencies and federal
grants for basic and applied research and development intended to support specificconcrete
policy goals, such as protecting the natural environment, exploring outer space,
advancing the treatment of chronicdeadly diseases, and strengthening the national defense.
Indirect support is more diffuse. The chief sources are federal funding of higher
education in engineering and the natural sciences, legal protection of intellectual
property rights, special allowances under antitrust law for joint research ventures, and
tax incentives for business R&D investment.
Federal tax law offers two such incentives: (1) a deduction for qualified
research spending under Section 174 of the Internal Revenue Code (IRC), and (2) a
non-refundable tax credit for qualified research spending above a base amount under
IRC Section 41 — known to some as the research and experimentation (R&E) tax
credit. credit, the
research tax credit, the R&D tax credit, or the credit for increasing research activities.
The deduction has been a permanent provision of the IRC since it was first
enacted in 1954; its enacted
in 1954. Its main advantages are that it simplifies tax accounting for R&D
expenditures and encourages business R&D investment by imposing a marginal
effective tax rate of 0 on the returns to such investment. A similar policy objective
undergirds the research tax credit, which has always been a temporary provision ofthe deduction simplifies tax accounting for
2
See, for example, Edwin Mansfield, “Microeconomics of Technological Innovation,” in
The Positive Sum Strategy, Ralph Landau and Nathan Rosenberg, eds. (Washington:
National Academy Press, 1986), pp. 307-325; and John C. Williams and Charles I. Jones,
“Measuring the Social Return to R&D,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 113, no. 4,
Nov.November 1998, pp. 1119-1135.
3
For a brief discussion of these channels, see Bronwyn H. Hall, “The Private and Social
Returns to Research and Development,” in Technology, R&D, and the Economy, Bruce L.
R. Smith and Claude E. Barfield, eds. (Washington: Brookings Institution and American
Enterprise Institute, 1996), pp. 140-141.
CRS-3
R&D expenditures and encourages business R&D investment by taxing the returns
to such investment at a marginal effective rate of 0. A similar policy objective
undergirds the research tax credit, which has been a temporary provision of the IRC
since it went into effect in July 1981. The credit is intended to stimulate more
business R&D investment than would occur in the absence of the credit by lowering
the after-tax cost of qualified research.4 But unlike the deduction, it complicates tax
compliance for firms claiming the credit. In FY2006, the combined budgetary cost
of these incentives totaled an estimated $10.0 billion, or 7.5% of the estimated
$132.3 billion spent on federal defense and non-defense R&D that year.5
This report examines the current status of the R&E tax credit, describes its
legislative history, discusses some important policy issues raised by it, and identifies
legislative proposals in the 110th Congress to extend the credit or enhance its
incentive effect. It will be updated to reflect significant legislative activity and other
developments affecting the status of the credit.
Design of the Current R&E Tax Credit
Although the research tax credit often is thought of as a single unified credit, it
has five discrete components: a regular research credit, an alternative incremental
research credit (or AIRC), an alternative simplified incremental credit (or ASIC), a
basic research credit, and a credit for energy research. Each is non-refundable, and
each is due to expire at the end of 2007. In any tax year, business taxpayers may
claim no more than the basic and energy research credits, plus one of the following:
the regular credit, the AIRC, or the ASIC. To prevent business taxpayers from
receiving two tax benefits for the same expenditures, any research tax credit claimed
must be subtracted from the amount of qualified research expenses deducted under
IRC section 174.
Qualified Research Expenditures
Ultimately, claims for the regular credit — as well as the AIRC and ASIC —
rest on the definition of qualified research expenditures (QREs). There are two
critical aspects to this definition.
One aspect deals with the nature of qualified research itself. Under IRC section
41(d), research must satisfy four criteria in order to qualify for the regular, AIRC, and
ASIC credits. First, it must involve activities that qualify for the deduction under
IRC section 174: which is to say that the activities must be “experimental” in the
laboratory sense and aimed at the development of a new or improved product or
process. Second, the research must be intended to discover information that is
4
For more information on the section 174 expensing allowance, see U.S. Congress, Senate
Committee on the Budget, Tax Expenditures, committee print, 107th Cong., 2nd sess.
(Washington: GPO, 2002), pp. 55-58.
5
Office of Management and Budget, Analytical Perspectives, Fiscal Year 2006
(Washington: GPO, 2005), pp. 66 and 317.
CRS-4
“technological in nature.” Third, it should seek to gain new technical knowledge that
is useful in the development of a new or improved “business component,” which is
defined as a product, process, computer software technique, formula, or invention to
be sold, leased, licensed, or used by the firm performing the research. And fourth,
the research must entail a process of experimentation aimed at the development of
a product or process with “a new or improved function, performance or reliability or
quality.” The third and fourth tests were added by the Tax Reform Act of 1986.
According to IRC section 41(d)(3), research meets the four criteria if it seeks to
develop a new or improved function for a business component, or to improve the
performance, reliability, or quality of a business component. By contrast, research
fails to meet these criteria if its main purpose is to modify a business component
according to “style, taste, cosmetic, or seasonal design factors.”
Business taxpayers, the courts, and the IRS have clashed repeatedly over the
application of the four criteria for qualified research. Although the IRS issued final
regulations clarifying the definition of qualified research in December 2003 (T.D.
9104), further disputes between business taxpayers and the IRS over what activities
qualify for the credit appear unavoidable.6
IRC section 41(d)(4) identifies activities for which the credit may not be
claimed. Specifically, the credit does not apply to research conducted after the start
of commercial production of a “business component”; research done to adapt an
existing business component to a specific customer’s needs or requirements; research
related to the duplication of an existing business component; surveys and studies
related to data collection, market research, production efficiency, quality control, and
managerial techniques; research to develop computer software for a firm’s internal
use (except as allowed in any regulations issued by the IRS); research conducted
outside the United States, Puerto Rico, or any other U.S. possession; research in the
social sciences, arts, or humanities; and research funded by another entity.
The second critical aspect of the definition of QREs concerns the expenses
eligible for the credit. Under IRC section 41(b)(1), qualified expenses arise from
both in-house research and contract research. In the case of in-house research, the
regular, AIRC, and ASIC credits apply to the wages and salaries of employees and
supervisors engaged in qualified research, as well as the cost of materials, supplies,
and leased computer time used in this research. In the case of contract research, the
three credits apply to the full amount paid for qualified research conducted by certain
small firms, colleges and universities, and federal laboratories; 75% of payments for
qualified research performed by certain research consortia; and 65% of payments for
qualified research performed by other non-profit entities dedicated to scientific
research.
It is useful to understand which expenses related to R&D investments are
ineligible for the credits. Specifically, they do not apply to spending on depreciable
assets used in qualified research such as buildings and equipment, overhead expenses
6
See the discussion of concerns raised by the current definition of qualified research in the
“Unsettled and Ambiguous Definition of Qualified Research” section of this report.
CRS-5
for such research (e.g., heating, electricity, rents, leasing fees, insurance, and property
taxes), and the fringe benefits of research personnel. The exclusion of these expenses
can have important implications for the incentive effect of the credit (more on this
later). Excluded expenses may account for 27% to 50% of business R&D spending.7
Regular Research Credit
The regular research tax credit has been extended 12 times and significantly
modified five times. Under IRC section 41(a)(1), it is equal to 20% of a firm’s QREs
beyond a base amount. Such an incremental design is intended to encourage firms
to spend more on R&D than they otherwise would by lowering the after-tax cost to
business taxpayers of investing in qualified research above some normal amount by
as much as 20%.8 Given that business R&D investment appears sensitive to its cost,
a decline in the after-tax cost of R&D should spur a rise in business R&D
investment, all other things being equal.9
The base amount for the regular credit seems designed to approximate the
amount a firm would spend on qualified research in the absence of the credit. As
such, the base amount can be viewed as a firm’s normal or preferred level of R&D
investment. Two rules govern the calculation of the base amount under IRC section
41(c). First, it must be equal to 50% or more of a firm’s QREs in a tax year — a rule
that some refer to as the 50-percent rule.10 Second, the base amount depends on
whether the business taxpayer is considered an established firm or a start-up firm.
Established firms are defined as firms with gross receipts and QREs in three or more
of the tax years from 1984 through 1988. Start-up firms, by contrast, are defined as
firms whose first tax year with both gross receipts and QREs occurred after 1983, or
firms that had fewer than three tax years from 1984 to 1988 with both gross receipts
and QREs.11 The base amount for all firms, established or start-up, is the product of
a fixed-base percentage and average annual gross receipts in the previous four tax
years. An established firm’s fixed-base percentage is the ratio of its total QREs to
total gross receipts in 1984 to 1988, capped at 16%. By contrast, a start-up firm’s
fixed-base percentage is set at 3% during the firm’s first five tax years with spending
on qualified research and gross receipts. Thereafter, the percentage gradually adjusts
to reflect a firm’s actual experience, so that by its eleventh tax year, the percentage
7
U.S. Office of Technology Assessment, The Effectiveness of Research and
Experimentation Tax Credits (Washington: 1995), p. 29.
8
For a variety of reasons, which will be discussed in a later section of the report, the actual
or effective rate of the credit is much lower than 20%.
9
Available studies indicate that the price elasticity of demand for R&D ranges from 0.2 to
2.0, which means that a 1% reduction in the cost of R&D would raise R&D spending
between 0.2% and 2%.
10
In other words, the expenses against which the regular research credit may be claimed can
equal no more than 50% of total QREs in a given tax year.
11
The definition of a start-up firm has changed a few times since the research credit was
enacted. Presently, it denotes a firm that recorded gross receipts and QREs in a tax year for
the first time after 1993.
CRS-6
equals the firm’s total QREs relative to its total receipts in the fifth through tenth tax
years.
In general, the lower a firm’s fixed-base percentage, the better its chances of
claiming the regular credit. And a firm can expect to benefit from the regular credit
if its ratio of QREs in the current tax year to average annual gross receipts in the
previous four tax years is greater than its fixed-base percentage. (See Table 1 for a
calculation of the regular credit for a hypothetical established firm, and Table 2 for
a calculation of the regular credit for a hypothetical start-up firm.)
Table 1. Sample Calculations of the Regular and Alternative
Incremental R&E Tax Credits in 2006 for an Established Firm
($ millions)
Year
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Gross Receipts
100
150
250
400
450
400
450
550
600
550
620
700
660
710
800
835
915
1,005
1,215
1,465
1,650
1,825
1,900
Qualified Research Expenses
5
8
12
15
16
18
18
20
25
23
20
25
35
30
35
45
50
53
60
70
85
95
100
Source: Congressional Research Service.
Calculation: Regular R&E Tax Credit
Compute the fixed-base percentage:
1. Sum the qualified research expenses for 1984 to 1988: $56 million.
2. Sum the gross receipts for 1984 to 1988: $1,350 million.
3. Divide the total qualified research expenses by the total gross receipts to
determine the fixed-base percentage: 4.0%.
CRS-7
Compute the base amount for 2006:
1. Calculate the average annual gross receipts for the four previous years (20022005): $1,539 million.
2. Multiply this average by the fixed-base percentage to determine the base amount:
$62 million.
Compute the regular tax credit for 2006:
1. Begin with the qualified research expenses for 2006 of $100 million and subtract
the base amount ($62 million) or 50% of the qualified research expenses for
2006 ($50 million), whichever is greater: $50 million.
2. Multiply this amount by 20% to determine the regular R&E tax credit for 2006:
$10 million.
Calculation: Alternative Incremental R&E Tax Credit
1. Calculate the average annual gross receipts for the four previous years (20022005): $1,539 million.
2. Multiply this amount by 1% and 1.5% and 2%: $15 million, $23 million, and $31
million.
3. Begin with the qualified research expenses for 2006 ($100 million) and subtract
1% and 1.5% and 2% (respectively) of the average annual gross receipts for
2002 to 2005: $85 million, $77 million, and $69 million.
4. Multiply the difference between $85 million and $77 million by 0.03: $0.24
million.
5. Multiply the difference between $77 million and $69 million by 0.04: $0.32
million.
6. Multiply $69 million by 0.05: $3.45 million.
7. Sum the totals from steps 4, 5, and 6 to determine the alternative incremental
R&E tax credit: $4.01 million.
Alternative Incremental Research Credit
Firms investing in qualified research that are unable to claim the regular credit
have the option of claiming the alternative incremental R&E tax credit (or AIRC),
under IRC section 41(c)(4). However, a decision to claim the AIRC does have
consequences for future tax years. When a firm elects the AIRC in a particular tax
year, it must continue to do so in future tax years, unless the firm receives permission
from the IRS to switch to another research credit. There is some concern that such
a rule deters firms from claiming the AIRC, even though they may be better off doing
so.
The definition of QREs for the AIRC is the same as the definition of QREs for
the regular credit. But that is where the similarity between the two credits ends.
Unlike the regular credit, which is equal to 20% of QREs in excess of a base amount,
the AIRC is equal to 3% of a firm’s QREs above 1% but less than 1.5% of its average
annual gross receipts in the previous four tax years, plus 4% of its QREs above 1.5%
but less than 2.0% of its average annual gross receipts in the previous four tax years,
plus 5% of its QREs greater than 2.0% of its average annual gross receipts in the
previous four tax years.
CRS-8the IRC since it was first enacted in July 1981: the credit seeks to stimulate increased
business R&D investment year after year by lowering the after-tax cost of qualified
R&D beyond the amount that firms would undertake in the absence of such a
subsidy.4 But the credit complicates the task of complying with tax laws and
regulations for firms claiming it. In FY2006, the combined budgetary cost of these
incentives is projected to total $10.0 billion; by contrast, federal defense and nondefense R&D spending may reach $132.3 billion.5
This report examines the current status of the R&E tax credit, its legislative
history, some important policy issues raised by it, and legislative proposals in the
109th Congress to extend the credit or enhance its incentive effect. It will be updated
as legislative activity and other developments affecting the credit warrant.
Design of the Current R&E Tax Credit
The R&E tax credit actually has four components: a regular research credit, an
alternative incremental research credit (or AIRC), a basic research credit, and a credit
for energy research. Each is non-refundable. In any tax year, business taxpayers may
claim the basic and energy research credits, as well as either the regular credit or the
AIRC. All four credits expired on December 31, 2005.
Regular Research Credit
The regular research tax credit has been extended 11 times and revised five
times. Under IRC section 41(a)(1), it is equal to 20% of a firm’s qualified research
expenditures (QREs) above a base amount. This incremental design is intended to
encourage firms to spend more on R&D from one year to the next than they
otherwise would by lowering the after-tax cost of the added R&D spending. (By
contrast, if the credit’s design were flat, the credit would be equal to 20% of a firm’s
total spending on qualified research in a tax year.) Under such a design, the federal
government bears 20% of the cost of any qualified research above the base amount,
for firms claiming the credit.6 Given that business R&D investment hinges in part
on its cost, a decline in the after-tax cost of R&D should spur a rise in business R&D
investment, all other things being equal.7
4
For more information on the section 174 expensing allowance, see U.S. Congress, Senate
Committee on the Budget, Tax Expenditures, committee print, 107th Cong., 2nd sess.
(Washington: GPO, 2002), pp. 55-58.
5
Office of Management and Budget, Analytical Perspectives, Fiscal Year 2006
(Washington: GPO, 2005), pp. 66 and 317.
6
For a variety of reasons, which will be discussed in a later section of the report, the actual
or effective rate of the credit is much lower than 20%.
7
Available studies indicate that the price elasticity of demand for R&D ranges from 0.2 to
2.0, which means that a 1% reduction in the cost of R&D would raise R&D spending
between 0.2% and 2%.
CRS-4
To grasp the links between the regular credit and business R&D investment, it
is essential to understand how the base amount is determined under IRC section 41(c)
and which research expenses qualify for the credit under IRC section 41(b) and 41(d).
In principle, the base amount of the regular credit approximates the amount a
firm would spend on qualified research in the absence of the credit, or its normal or
preferred level of R&D investment. Two rules govern the calculation of the base
amount under IRC section 41(c). First, it must be equal to 50% or more of a firm’s
QREs in a tax year — a rule that some refer to as the 50-percent rule.8 Second, a
firm’s base amount depends on whether the firm qualifies as an established firm or
a start-up firm. Established firms are defined as firms with gross receipts and QREs
in three or more of the tax years from 1984 through 1988. Start-up firms, by contrast,
are defined as firms whose first tax year with both gross receipts and QREs occurred
after 1983, or firms with fewer than three tax years with both gross receipts and
QREs from 1984 through 1988.9 For all firms, the base amount is the product of a
fixed-base percentage and average annual gross receipts in the previous four tax
years. An established firm’s fixed-base percentage is the ratio of its total QREs to
total gross receipts in 1984 to 1988, capped at 16%. A start-up firm’s fixed-base
percentage is set at 3% during the firm’s first five tax years after 1993 when it invests
in qualified research. Thereafter, the percentage gradually adjusts to reflect a firm’s
actual experience so that by the its eleventh tax year, the percentage equals the firm’s
total QREs relative to its total receipts in any five tax years it chooses from the fifth
through tenth tax years.
In general, the lower a firm’s fixed-base percentage, the better its chances of
claiming the regular credit. A firm can expect to benefit from the regular credit if its
ratio of QREs in the current tax year to average annual gross receipts in the previous
four tax years is greater than its fixed-base percentage. (See Table 1 for a calculation
of the regular credit for a hypothetical established firm, and Table 2 for a calculation
of the regular credit for a hypothetical start-up firm.)
Qualified Research Expenditures. Obviously, a key factor in claiming the
regular credit (as well as the AIRC) is the definition of QREs. In practice, there are
two critical aspects to this definition.
One aspect concerns the nature of qualified research itself. Under IRC section
41(d), research must satisfy four criteria in order to qualify for the regular or
alternative incremental research tax credits. First, the research must involve
activities that qualify for the deduction under IRC section 174 — which is to say that
the activities must be “experimental” in the laboratory sense and aimed at the
development of a new or improved product or process. Second, the research must
be intended to discover information that is “technological in nature.” Third, the
research should seek to gain new technical knowledge that is useful in the
8
In other words, the expenses against which the regular research credit may be claimed can
equal no more than 50% of total QREs in a given tax year.
9
The definition of a start-up firm has changed a few times since the research credit was
enacted. Presently, it denotes a firm that recorded gross receipts and QREs in a tax year for
the first time after 1993.
CRS-5
development of a new or improved “business component,” which is defined as a
product, process, computer software technique, formula, or invention to be sold,
leased, licensed, or used by the firm performing the research. Finally, the research
must entail a process of experimentation aimed at the development of a product or
process with “a new or improved function, performance or reliability or quality.”
The third and fourth tests were added by the Tax Reform Act of 1986, which also
directed the IRS to issue regulations clarifying the definition of qualified research.
In general, according to IRC section 41(d)(3), research satisfies these criteria if
it seeks to develop a new or improved function for a business component, or to
improve the performance, reliability, or quality of a business component. By
contrast, research fails to meet these criteria if its main purpose is to modify a
business component according to “style, taste, cosmetic, or seasonal design factors.”
Business taxpayers, the courts, and the IRS have clashed repeatedly over the
application of the four tests for qualified research in the real world of business R&D.
Although the IRS issued final regulations clarifying the definition of qualified
research in December 2003 (T.D. 9104), it seems unlikely that the regulations will
preclude further disputes between business taxpayers and the IRS over what activities
qualify for the credit.10
IRC section 41(d)(4) identifies the activities that do not qualify for the credit.
Specifically, the credit does not apply to research conducted after the start of
commercial production of a business component; research done to adapt an existing
business component to a specific customer’s needs or requirements; research related
to the duplication of an existing business component; surveys and studies related to
data collection, market research, production efficiency, quality control, and
managerial techniques; research to develop computer software for a firm’s internal
use (except as allowed in any regulations issued by the IRS); research conducted
outside the United States, Puerto Rico, or any other U.S. possession; research in the
social sciences, arts, or humanities; and research funded by another entity.
The other critical aspect of the definition of QREs is the expenses eligible for
the credit. Under IRC section 41(b)(1), these expenses relate to both in-house
research and contract research. In the case of in-house research, qualified expenses
are limited to the wages and salaries of employees and their direct supervisors who
are engaged in qualified research, the cost of materials and supplies (but not
depreciable property) used in this research, and leased computer time used in this
research. In the case of contract research, qualified expenses cover 75% of payments
for qualified research performed under contract by nonprofit scientific research
organizations and 65% of payments for qualified research performed under contract
by other entities.
The credit does not apply to spending on the structures and equipment used in
qualified research, overhead expenses related to such research — such as heating,
electricity, rents, leasing fees, insurance, and property taxes — and the fringe benefits
10
See the discussion of concerns raised by the current definition of qualified research on
pages 24 to 26.
CRS-6
of research personnel. As is discussed below, the exclusion of these costs has
implications for the incentive effect of the credit. In the past, QREs have accounted
for anywhere from 50% to 73% of total business R&D spending.11
Table 1. Sample Calculations of the Regular and Alternative
Incremental R&E Tax Credits in 2003 for an Established Firm
($ millions)
Year
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
Gross Receipts
100
150
250
400
450
400
450
550
600
550
620
700
660
710
800
835
915
1,005
1,215
1,465
Qualified Research Expenses
5
8
12
15
16
18
18
20
25
23
20
25
35
30
35
45
50
53
60
70
Source: Congressional Research Service.
Calculation: Regular R&E Tax Credit
Compute the fixed-base percentage:
1. Sum the qualified research expenses for 1984 to 1988: $56 million.
2. Sum the gross receipts for 1984 to 1988: $1,350 million.
3. Divide the total qualified research expenses by the total gross receipts to
determine the fixed-base percentage: 4.0%.
Compute the base amount for 2003:
1. Calculate the average annual gross receipts for the four previous years (19992002): $992.5 million.
2. Multiply this average by the fixed-base percentage to determine the base amount:
$39.7 million.
Compute the regular tax credit for 2003:
11
U.S. Office of Technology Assessment, The Effectiveness of Research and
Experimentation Tax Credits (Washington: 1995), p. 29.
CRS-7
1. Begin with the qualified research expenses for 2003 of $70 million and subtract
the base amount ($39.7 million) or 50% of the qualified research expenses for
2003 ($35 million), whichever is greater: $30.3 million.
2. Multiply this amount by 20% to determine the regular R&E tax credit for 2003:
$6.06 million.
Calculation: Alternative Incremental R&E Tax Credit
1. Calculate the average annual gross receipts for the four previous years (19992003): $992.5 million.
2. Multiply this amount by 1% and 1.5% and 2%: $9.925 million, $14.887 million,
and $19.850 million.
3. Begin with the qualified research expenses for 2003 ($70 million) and subtract
1% and 1.5% and 2% (respectively) of the average annual gross receipts for
1999 to 2002: $60.075 million, $55.113 million, and $50.150 million.
4. Multiply the difference between $60.075 million and $55.113 million by 0.0265:
$0.131 million.
5. Multiply the difference between $55.113 and $50.150 by 0.032: $0.159 million
6. Multiply $50.150 million by 0.0375: $1.881 million.
7. Sum the totals from steps 4, 5, and 6 to determine the alternative incremental
R&E tax credit: $2.17 million.
Alternative Incremental Research Credit
Firms undertaking qualified research that cannot claim the regular credit have
the option of claiming the alternative incremental R&E tax credit (or AIRC), under
IRC section 41(c)(4). When a firm elects to claim the AIRC in a particular tax year,
it must continue to do so in future tax years, unless the firm receives permission from
the IRS to switch to the regular credit. Some are concerned that such a rule deters
firms from claiming the AIRC, even though they may be better off doing so.
The definition of QREs for the AIRC is the same as the definition of QREs for
the regular credit. But that is where the similarity between the two credits ends.
Unlike the regular credit, which is equal to 20% of QREs in excess of a base amount,
the AIRC is equal to 2.65% of a firm’s QREs above 1% but less than 1.5% of its
average annual gross receipts in the previous four tax years, plus 3.2% of its QREs
above 1.5% but less than 2.0% of its average annual gross receipts in the previous
four tax years, plus 3.75% of its QREs greater than 2.0% of its average annual gross
receipts in the previous four tax years.
In general, firms can benefit from the AIRC if their QREs in the current tax year
exceed 1% of their average annual gross receipts during the past four tax years. In
addition, the AIRC is likely to be of greater benefit than the regular credit to business
taxpayers with relatively high fixed-base percentages, or whose research spending is
declining, or whose sales are growing much faster than their research spending. (See
Table 1 for a calculation of the AIRC for a hypothetical established firm, and Table
2 for a calculation of the AIRC for a hypothetical start-up firm.)
CRS-8
Table 2. Sample Calculations of the Regular and Alternative
Incremental R&E Tax Credits in 20032006 for a Start-up Firm
($ millions)
Year
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Gross Receipts
30
42
5655
60
210
305
400
475
600
Qualified Research Expenses
35
40
4845
55
65
73
82
90
105
Source: Congressional Research Service.
Calculation: Regular R&E Tax Credit
Compute the fixed-base percentage:
1. By definition, the firm is a start-up. According to current law, a start-up firm’s
fixed-base percentage is fixed at 3% for each of the five years after 1993 when
it has both gross receipts and qualified research expenses, and then it adjusts
according to a formula over the next six years to reflect the firm’s actual
research intensity. Thus, the fixed-base percentages are 3% for 19951999 through
19992002, 7.4% in 20002003, 8.89% in 20012004, 12.0% in 20022005, and 14.7% in 20032006.
Compute the base amount for 20032006:
1. Calculate the average annual receipts for the four previous years (1999-20022002-2005):
$347.5 million.
2. Multiply this amount by the fixed-base percentage to determine the base amount:
$51.1 million.
Compute the regular tax credit:
1. Begin with the qualified research expenses for 20032006 ($105 million) and subtract
the base amount ($51.1 million) or 50% of the qualified research expenses for
20032006 ($52.5 million), whichever is greater: $52.5 million.
2. Multiply $52.5 million by 20% to determine the regular R&E tax credit for 20032006:
$10.5 million.
CRS-9
Calculation: Alternative Incremental R&E Tax Credit
1. Calculate the average annual gross receipts for the four previous years (1999200220022005): $347.5 million.
2. Multiply this amount by 1%, 1.5%, and 2%: $3.4755 million, $5.2122 million, and
$6.950 $6.9
million.
3. Begin with the qualified research expenses for 20032006 ($105 million) and subtract
1.0%, 1.5%, and 2.0% (respectively) of the average annual gross receipts for
1999 to 2002: $101.5252002 to 2005: $101.5 million, $99.7888 million, and $98.051 million.
CRS-9
4. Multiply the difference between $101.5255 million and $99.7888 million by 0.0265:
$0.046 03: $0.05
million.
5. Multiply the difference between $99.7888 million and $98.051 million by 0.032:
$0.056 04: $0.07
million.
6. Multiply $98.051 million by 0.0375: $3.7794.9 million.
7. Sum the totals from steps 4, 5, and 6 to determine the alternative incremental
R&E tax credit: $3.78 million.
Basic Research Credit
Firms joining with certain nonprofit organizations to perform basic research
under contract may claim a tax credit for some of their expenditures for this purpose
under IRC Section 41(e). A primary aim of the credit is to foster collaborative
research between U.S. firms and colleges and universities. The credit is equal to 20%
of total payments for qualified basic research above a base amount, which is known
as the “qualified organization base period amount.” This amount has little in
common with the base amount for the regular R&E tax credit, except that both
amounts are intended to approximate what firms would spend on qualified research
if there were no credits.12 Basic research is defined as “any original investigation for
the advancement of scientific knowledge not having a specific commercial
objective.” The credit does not apply to basic research done outside the United
States, or to basic research in the social sciences, arts, or the humanities. In addition,
the basic research credit applies only to payments for basic research performed under
a written contract by the following organizations: educational institutions, nonprofit
scientific research organizations (excluding private foundations), and certain grantgiving organizations. Payments made to joint research consortia involving two or
more firms, or to federal laboratories, for basic research do not qualify for the credit.
Firms conducting their own basic research may not claim the credit for their
expenditures for this purpose, but they may be added to their QREs for the regular
credit. And basic research payments eligible for the credit that do not exceed the
base amount are treated as contract research expenses and may be included in the
QREs for the regular credit.
12
Calculating a firm’s base amount for the basic research credit is more complicated than
calculating its base amount for the regular credit. For the basic research credit, a firm’s base
period is the three tax years preceding the first year in which it had gross receipts after 1983.
The base amount is equal to the sum of a firm’s minimum basic research amount and its
maintenance-of-effort amount in the base period. The former is the greater of 1% of the
firm’s average annual in-house and contract research expenses during the base period, or 1%
of its total contract research expenses during the base period. For a firm claiming the basic
research credit, its minimum basic research amount cannot be less than 50% of the firm’s
basic research payments in the current tax year. The latter is the difference between a firm’s
donations to qualified organizations in the current tax year for purposes other than basic
research and its average annual donations to the same organizations for the same purposes
during the base period, multiplied by a cost-of-living adjustment for the current tax year.
CRS-10
Energy Research Credit
Under IRC section 41(a)(3), business taxpayers may claim a tax credit equal to
20% of payments to certain entities for energy research. To qualify for the credit, the
payments must be made to a nonprofit organization that is exempt from taxation
under IRC section 501(a) and “organized and operated primarily to conduct energy
research in the public interest.” In addition, a minimum of five discrete entities must
contribute to the organization for energy research in a calendar year, and none of
these entities may account for more than half of funds received by the organization
for such research.
The credit also applies to the full amount of payments to colleges and
universities, federal laboratories, and certain small firms for energy research
performed under contract. In the case of small firms, q business taxpayer may claim
the credit only under two conditions. First, the taxpayer cannot own 50% or more of
the firm’s stock (if the firm is a corporation), or capital and profits (if the firm is a
non-corporate entity such as a partnership). Second, the firm must have employed
an average of 500 or fewer individuals in one of the previous two calendar years.
Because the credit is flat rather than incremental, it is more generous than the
any of the three other components of the research tax credit.
Legislative History of the Research Tax Credit
The R&E tax credit entered the tax code as a temporary provision through the
Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 (P.L. 97-34). In establishing the credit, the 97th
Congress was seeking to reverse a decline in spending on R&D by the private sector
as a share of U.S. gross domestic product that commenced in the late 1960s and
continued through the late 1970s. Some analysts thought the decline played a
significant role in the slowdown in U.S. productivity growth and the unsettling loss
of competitiveness by a variety of U.S. industries in that decade. Congress concluded
that a “substantial tax credit for incremental research and experimental expenditures
was needed to overcome the reluctance of many ongoing companies to bear the
significant costs of staffing and supplies, and certain equipment expenses such as
computer charges, which must be incurred to initiate or expand research programs
in a trade or business.”13
The initial credit was equal to 25% of qualified research spending above a base
amount, which was equal to average spending on such research in the three previous
tax years or 50% of current-year spending, whichever was greater. It is not clear
from available information why a statutory rate of 25% was chosen. Nonetheless, the
rate does not appear to have been based on a rigorous assessment of the gap between
private and social returns to business R&D investment, or the sensitivity of R&D
expenditures to declines in the after-tax cost of R&D. Any taxpayer that claimed the
13
U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, General Explanation of the Economic
Recovery Tax Act of 1981, joint committee print, 97th Cong., 1st sess. (Washington: GPO,
1981), p. 120.
CRS-11
credit but could not apply the entire amount against its current-year federal income
tax liability was allowed to carry the excess back as many as three tax years or carry
it forward as many as 15 tax years. The credit was in effect from July 1, 1981, to
December 31, 1985.
Congress made the first significant changes in the original credit with the
passage of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (P.L. 99-514). Among of host of changes in
the tax code, the act extended the credit through December 31, 1988 and made it part
of the general business credit, thereby subjecting it to a yearly cap. In addition, the
act lowered the statutory rate to 20%, modified the definition of QREs so that the
credit applied to research intended to produce new technical knowledge useful in the
commercial development of new products and processes, and created a separate 20%
incremental tax credit for payments to universities and certain other nonprofit
organizations for the conduct of basic research under a written contract. The
reduction in the credit’s rate seemingly was not based on an analysis of the credit’s
effectiveness in the first five years. Rather, it reflected the intent of Congress to
subject the credit to the overriding goals of the act — which were to lower income
tax rates across the board, broaden the income tax base, and narrow the differences
among the tax burdens on most business assets — and a recognition that business
R&D investment already received preferential treatment under the IRC section 174
expensing allowance.14
The regular research and basic research credits were further altered by the
Technical and Miscellaneous Revenue Act of 1988 (P.L. 100-647). Specifically, the
act extended the credits through December 31, 1989. It also curtailed the overall tax
preference for R&D investment by requiring business taxpayers to reduce any
deduction they claim for qualified research spending under IRC section 174 by half
of the total amount of any regular and basic research credits they claim. This rule had
the effect of lowering the maximum effective rate of the regular research tax credit
by a factor equal to 0.5 times a taxpayer’s marginal income tax rate.
Continuing disenchantment with the design of the original credit among
interested parties led to the enactment of further important changes in the regular
credit through the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1989 (OBRA89, P.L. 101239). Much of the disenchantment was directed at the formula for determining the
base amount of the credit. Critics rightly pointed out that under the formula — which
was based on a three-year moving average of a firm’s annual spending on qualified
research — an increase in a firm’s research spending from one year to the next would
increase its base amount in each of the following three years by one-third of the
increase in research spending, making it more difficult to claim the credit in that
period. Some maintained that such a design would be less cost-effective in spurring
continuous increases in business R&D investment than one in which a firm’s base
amount is independent of its spending on qualified research.15
14
U.S. Congress, General Explanation of the Tax Reform Act of 1986, joint committee print,
100th Cong., 1st sess. (Washington: GPO, 1987), p.130.
15
See U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee, The R&D Tax Credit: An Evaluation of
Evidence on Its Effectiveness, joint committee print, 99th Cong., 1st sess. (Washington: GPO,
(continued...)
CRS-12
To address this concern, OBRA89 modified the formula for the base amount so
that the amount was equal to the greater of 50% of its current-year QREs, or the
product of the firm’s average annual gross receipts in the previous four tax years and
its “fixed-base percentage.” This percentage was set equal to the ratio of a firm’s
total QREs to total gross receipts in the four tax years from 1984 to 1988, with the
percentage capped at 16%. OBRA89 also made the credit available on more
favorable terms to start-up firms, which it defined as firms that did not have gross
receipts and QREs in three of the four years from 1984 to 1988; these firms were
assigned a fixed-base percentage of 3%. In addition, the act effectively extended the
credits to December 31, 1990 by requiring that QREs incurred before January 1, 1991
be prorated, permitted firms to apply the regular credit to QREs related to current
lines of business and to possible future lines of business, and required firms claiming
the regular and basic research credits to reduce any deduction they claim under IRC
section 174 by the entire amount of the credits.
In 1990 and 1991, Congress passed two bills that, among other things,
temporarily extended the credits. The Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990
(P.L. 101-508) extended the credits through December 31, 1991 and repealed the
requirement that QREs made before January 1, 1991 be prorated. The Tax Extension
Act of 1991 (P.L. 102-227) further extended the credits to June 30, 1992. A major
obstacle to longer extensions of the credits — then and now — was the revenue cost
of doing so in the midst of rising federal budget deficits.
Although Congress passed two bills in 1992 that would have extended the
credits beyond June 30 of that year, President George H. W. Bush vetoed both for
reasons that had nothing to do with the credit. As a result, the credits expired and
remained suspended from July 1, 1992 until the enactment of the Omnibus Budget
Reconciliation Act of 1993 (OBRA93, P.L. 103-66) in August 1993. The act
extended the credits retroactively from July 1, 1992 through June 30, 1995. It also
modified the fixed-base percentage for start-up firms. Under OBRA93, firms lacking
gross receipts in three of the years from 1984 to 1988 were assigned a percentage of
3% for the first five tax years after 1993 in which it reported QREs. Starting in a
firm’s sixth year, the percentage was to adjust gradually so that by its eleventh year
the percentage would reflect its actual ratio of total QREs to total gross receipts in
five of its previous six tax years.
Congressional inaction allowed the credits to expire again on June 30, 1995.
They remained in abeyance until the enactment of the Small Business Job Protection
Act of 1996 (P.L. 104-188) in August 1996. The act retroactively reinstated the
credits from July 1, 1996, to May 31, 1997, leaving a one-year gap in the credit’s
coverage from its inception in mid-1981. It also expanded the definition of a start-up
firm to include any firm whose first tax year with both gross receipts and QREs was
1984 or later, added an alternative incremental research credit (i.e., the AIRC) with
initial rates of 1.65%, 2.2%, and 2.75%, and made 75% of payments for qualified
research to nonprofit organizations “operated primarily to conduct scientific
research” eligible for the regular or alternative incremental credits.
15
(...continued)
1985), pp. 17-22.
CRS-13
The credits yet again expired in 1997, but they were extended retroactively from
June 1, 1997, to June 30, 1998, by the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 (P.L. 105-34),
which President Clinton signed in October 1997. In the following year, the revenue
portion of the Omnibus Consolidated and Emergency Supplemental Appropriations
Act, 1998 (P.L. 105-277) further extended the credits from July 1, 1998, to June 30,
1999.
In a reprise of 1997, the credits expired again in 1999, and Congress passed a
bill late in the year reinstating them retroactively. Under the revenue portion of the
Ticket to Work and Work Incentives Improvement Act of 1999 (P.L. 106-170), the
credits were extended from July 1, 1999, to June 30, 2004. The act also increased the
three rates of the AIRC to 2.65%, 3.2%, and 3.75% and expanded the definition of
qualified research to include qualified research performed in Puerto Rico and the
other territorial possessions of the United States.
On October 4, 2004, President Bush signed into law the Working Families Tax
Relief Act of 2004 (P.L. 108-311), which included a provision extending the research
tax credit through December 31, 2005.
Finally, the Energy Policy Act of 2005 (P.L. 109-58) added a fourth component
to the research tax credit by establishing a credit equal to 20% of all payments to
qualified consortia, colleges and universities, federal laboratories, and eligible small
firms for contract energy research.
Beginning in the mid-1990s, a cycle emerged every time the credits were about
to expire, one that seems to have persisted to the present. The cycle starts with
supporters of the credit in Congress and among influential business groups calling
for a permanent extension of the credits and issuing stern denunciations of what they
see as the folly of repeated temporary extensions.16 In the next stage of the cycle,
leaders in both houses of Congress undertake serious negotiations on tax legislation
that often includes a permanent extension of the credit. But in the end, Congress and
the President agree to extend the credit one or two years, stymied by a recurring
inability to reconcile the revenue cost of such an extension with their budget
priorities.
Effectiveness of the Research Tax Credit
Perhaps the most important policy issue raised by the credit concerns how
effective it has been in the 25 years of its existence. There are two basic approaches
to assessing the credit’s effectiveness.
Among economists, the preferred approach is to compare the social benefit from
any added R&D engendered by the credit with the social cost of that R&D. Such a
comparison involves measuring the returns to society of the added R&D spending
and the social cost of all other possible public uses of this R&D (e.g., corporate
16
Martin A. Sullivan, “Research Credit Hits New Heights, No End in Sight,” Tax Notes, vol.
94, no. 7, Feb. 18, 2002, p. 801.
CRS-14
income tax rate cut, deficit reduction, increased federal spending on higher education,
or pollution abatement). The social cost of the credit can be thought of as the net loss
of tax revenue because of the credit and the public and private costs of administering
the credit. Unfortunately, this approach to assessing the effectiveness of the research
tax credit cannot be used because of difficulties in measuring the social returns to
R&D.17
As a result, economists have been forced to rely on a second, less sweeping
approach: estimating the additional R&D (if any) stimulated by the credit and
comparing the value of that R&D to the tax revenue lost because of the credit. Such
an approach rests on two assumptions: (1) that the social returns to R&D far exceed
the private returns and (2) that it is possible to determine the optimal size of the
subsidy for R&D.
An interesting policy question raised by this approach concerns whether the
subsidy should be offered as a tax credit or as a direct payment (e.g. research grant
or subsidized loan). If the value of the added R&D engendered by the credit were to
exceed the credit’s revenue cost, then it may be the case that the tax credit is a more
cost-effective way to boost private R&D investment than direct payments. But if the
revenue cost were to exceed the value of the added R&D, then it may be more costeffective for the federal government to pass up the credit in favor of direct
payments.18
Nonetheless, the question of whether the credit is more desirable than direct
payments as a means of boosting business R&D investment cannot be answered
solely on the basis of such a narrow comparison of cost and benefit. There are
circumstances in which a ratio of less than one does not necessarily mean that direct
payments are preferable to the credit as an R&D subsidy, and there are circumstances
in which a ratio of more than one does not necessarily mean that the credit is
preferable to a direct payment. On the one hand, if the average social returns to
business R&D investment are much higher than the average private returns, then it
is possible for social welfare to be enhanced through the use of the credit even though
the revenue cost of the credit exceeds the value of the added research it induces. In
this case, the credit could be considered a desirable and effective policy instrument
for raising business R&D investment. On the other hand, if the average social returns
to business R&D investment are only slightly greater than the average private returns,
then use of the credit might encourage firms to engage in too much R&D from the
perspective of social welfare, even if the added R&D induced by the credit were to
exceed its revenue cost. In this case, social welfare might be enhanced more if the
17
The principal barriers to measuring the social returns to R&D are developing adequate
price indices for the cost elements of R&D for specific industries, specifying the time period
in which to assess the productivity gains from R&D, and determining the depreciation rate
for a society’s stock of R&D assets. For a detailed discussion of these issues, see Bronwyn
H. Hall, “The Private and Social Returns to Research and Development,” in Technology,
R&D, and the Economy, Bruce L. Smith and Claude E. Barfield, eds. (Washington:
Brookings Institution, 1996), pp. 141-145.
18
This argument assumes that government research grants to the private sector do not lead
firms receiving the grants to reduce their own R&D spending by similar amounts.
CRS-15
federal government were to use the tax revenue lost to the credit for purposes with
greater social returns, and the credit could be seen as a less than desirable policy
instrument.
What do existing studies of the credit’s effectiveness say about its benefit-tocost ratio? For the most part, the studies are an exercise in counterfactual analysis.
They seek to answer the following question: how much more R&D did firms
undertake as a result of the credit than they would have undertaken if there were no
credit? Researchers use a variety of methods to estimate the amount of R&D
undertaken with and without the credit. These methods were examined in a 1995
study by economist Bronwyn Hall.19 She found that studies based on data from 1981
to 1983 differed markedly from those based on data from years after 1983. More
specifically, she found that the former set of studies generated estimates of the
additional R&D undertaken per dollar of the credit that were considerably lower than
the estimates offered by the latter set of studies. Taking into consideration the
strengths and weaknesses of both sets of studies, Hall concluded that the credit (as
of 1995) led to a “dollar-for-dollar increase in reported R&D spending on the
margin.”20 This meant that it had a benefit-to-cost ratio of one. (In other words, each
dollar of the credit stimulated one additional dollar of R&D investment.)
In theory, the credit stimulates increased business R&D investment by lowering
the after-tax cost of undertaking another dollar of R&D beyond some normal (or
base) amount. Firms can be expected to respond to this reduction in cost by spending
more on R&D, all other things being equal. So the critical considerations in
determining the share of business R&D investment in a year that can be attributed to
the credit are the responsiveness of business R&D investment to decreases in its
after-tax cost and the extent to which the credit lowers the average after-tax cost of
conducting R&D.
Little research has been done on how responsive business R&D investment is
to changes in its after-tax cost — as measured by the price elasticity of R&D
spending. The few available studies have come up with estimates of the long-run
price elasticity ranging from -0.2 to -2.0. These results imply that a decline in the
after-tax cost of R&D of 10% can be expected to produce a rise in R&D spending in
the long run of anywhere from 2% to 20%. In an analysis of the President Bush’s
FY2004 budget proposal, the Joint Tax Committee noted that “the general consensus
when assumptions are made with respect to research expenditures is that the price
elasticity of research is less than -1.0 and may be less than -0.5.”21
19
See Bronwyn H. Hall, Effectiveness of Research and Experimentation Tax Credits:
Critical Literature Review and Research Design, report prepared for the Office of
Technology Assessment, June 15, 1995, pp. 11-13, available at [http://emlab.berkeley.edu
/users/bhhall/papers/BHH95%200Artax.pdf].
20
21
Ibid., p. 18.
U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, Description of Revenue Provisions
Contained in the President’s Fiscal Year 2004 Budget Proposal, joint committee print, JCS7-03, 108th Cong., 1st sess. (Washington, March 2003), p. 250.
CRS-16
Much less doubt surrounds the impact of the credit on the after-tax cost of
qualified research: basically, one dollar of the credit reduces this cost by one dollar.
In offering such a credit, the federal government (or U.S. taxpayers) effectively is
sharing the cost of qualified research. Consequently, a measure of the overall
reduction in the after-tax cost of domestic business R&D investment as a result of the
credit is the credit’s average effective rate, which is the ratio of the total amount of
claims for the credit in a year to some measure of domestic business R&D spending,
such as QRE.
From the figures in Table 3, this rate can be computed for both QRE and
industry R&D spending. In 1996 to 2003, the average effective rate of the credit was
3.3% for industry R&D spending and 5.5% for QRE. This implies that the credit
lowered the after-tax cost of domestic business R&D by 3.3% and the after-tax cost
of qualified research by 5.5% over that period.
The gap between the rates reflects the differences between QRE and industry
R&D spending, as estimated by the National Science Foundation (NSF). On average,
total QRE was about 60% of business R&D spending from 1996 to 2003. The NSF
estimate aims to measure all R&D performed in the United States by firms and
funded by industry and other non-federal entities. It is based on annual surveys of
R&D in industry and covers the wages, salaries, and fringe benefits of research
personnel, as well as the cost of materials and supplies, overhead expenses, and
depreciation related to research activities; expenditures on plant and equipment used
in research are excluded, however.22 By contrast, QRE is the sum of spending on
research eligible for the credit, as reported by firms claiming the credit on their tax
returns, and covers wages and salaries, materials and supplies, leased computer time,
and 65% or 75% of contract research funded by these firms. One would expect
industry R&D spending to be greater, because it covers a broader array of R&D
expenses than QRE.
What can be said about the overall impact of the credit on domestic R&D? The
figures in Table 3 indicate that the credit delivered a modest stimulus to domestic
business R&D investment from 1996 to 2003. Specifically, assuming that the price
elasticity of demand for R&D is between -0.5 and -1.0 and the average effective rate
of the credit is .033, the credit might have boosted business R&D investment by
1.65% to 3.3% over that period.
22
National Science Foundation, Division of Science Resource Statistics, The Methodology
Underlying the Measurement of R&D Expenditures: 2000 (data update) (Arlington, VA:
Dec. 10, 2001), p. 2.
CRS-17
5.0 million.
Alternative Simplified Credit
The most recent addition to the array of research tax credits available under IRC
section 41 is what is known as the alternative simplified incremental credit (ASIC).
Under IRC section 41(c)(5), a business taxpayer may claim the ASIC in lieu of the
regular credit or AIRC. The ASIC is equal to 12% of a taxpayer’s QREs in the
current tax year above 50% of its average QREs in the three previous tax years. If
a taxpayer has no QREs in any of those years, then the credit is equal to 6% of its
QREs in the current tax year. As with the AIRC, a decision to claim the ASIC
remains in effect for succeeding tax years, unless a taxpayer gains the consent of the
IRS to claim another research credit.
Basic Research Credit
Firms that enter into contracts with certain non-profit organizations to perform
basic research may be able to claim a tax credit for some of their expenditures for this
purpose under IRC Section 41(e). A primary aim of the credit is to foster
collaborative research between U.S. firms and colleges and universities. The credit
is equal to 20% of total payments for qualified basic research above a base amount,
which is known as the “qualified organization base period amount.” This amount has
little in common with the base amount for the regular R&E tax credit, except that
both amounts seem intended to approximate what firms would spend on qualified
research in the absence of such credits.12
12
Calculating a firm’s base amount for the basic research credit is more complicated than
calculating its base amount for the regular credit. For the basic research credit, a firm’s base
period is the three tax years preceding the first year in which it had gross receipts after 1983.
The base amount is equal to the sum of a firm’s minimum basic research amount and its
maintenance-of-effort amount in the base period. The former is the greater of 1% of the
firm’s average annual in-house and contract research expenses during the base period, or 1%
of its total contract research expenses during the base period. For a firm claiming the basic
research credit, its minimum basic research amount cannot be less than 50% of the firm’s
(continued...)
CRS-10
For the purpose of the credit, basic research is defined as “any original
investigation for the advancement of scientific knowledge not having a specific
commercial objective.”
The credit does not apply to qualified basic research done outside the United
States, or to basic research in the social sciences, arts, or the humanities.
In addition, the basic research credit applies only to payments for qualified basic
research performed under a written contract by the following organizations:
educational institutions, nonprofit scientific research organizations (excluding private
foundations), and certain grant-giving organizations.
Firms conducting their own basic research may not claim the credit for their
expenditures for this purpose, but the spending can be included in their QREs for the
regular credit, AIRC, or ASIC. In addition, basic research payments eligible for the
credit that fall below the base amount are treated as contract research expenses and
may be included in the QREs for any of those credits.
Energy Research Credit
Under IRC section 41(a)(3), business taxpayers may claim a tax credit equal to
20% of payments to certain entities for energy research. To qualify for the credit, the
payments must be made to a non-profit organization exempt from taxation under IRC
section 501(a) and “organized and operated primarily to conduct energy research in
the public interest.” In addition, at least five discrete entities must contribute funds
to the organization for energy research in a calendar year; none of these entities may
account for more than half of total payments to the organization for such research.
The credit also applies to the full amount (i.e., 100%) of payments to colleges
and universities, federal laboratories, and certain small firms for energy research
performed under contract. In the case of small firms performing this research, a
business taxpayer may claim a credit for the full amount of payments under two
conditions only. First, the taxpayer cannot own 50% or more of the stock of the
small firm performing the research (if the firm is a corporation), or 50% or more of
the small firm’s capital and profits (if the firm is a non-corporate entity such as a
partnership). Second, the firm performing the research must have an average of 500
or fewer employees in one of the two previous calendar years.
Because the credit is flat rather than incremental, it is more generous than the
other four components of the research tax credit.
12
(...continued)
basic research payments in the current tax year. The latter is the difference between a firm’s
donations to qualified organizations in the current tax year for purposes other than basic
research and its average annual donations to the same organizations for the same purposes
during the base period, multiplied by a cost-of-living adjustment for the current tax year.
CRS-11
Legislative History of the Research Tax Credit
The research tax credit entered the tax code as a temporary provision through
the Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 (P.L. 97-34). In adopting the credit, the 97th
Congress was looking for ways to stem a decade-long decline in spending on R&D
by the private sector as a share of U.S. gross domestic product that commenced in the
late 1960s. Around the time the credit was enacted, more than a few analysts thought
the decline contributed to a slowdown in U.S. productivity growth and a surprising
loss of competitiveness by a variety of U.S. industries in the 1970s. A majority in
Congress concluded that a “substantial tax credit for incremental research and
experimental expenditures was needed to overcome the reluctance of many ongoing
companies to bear the significant costs of staffing and supplies, and certain
equipment expenses such as computer charges, which must be incurred to initiate or
expand research programs in a trade or business.”13
The initial credit was equal to 25% of qualified research spending above a base
amount, which was equal to average spending on such research in the three previous
tax years, or 50% of current-year spending, whichever was greater. It is not clear
from the historical record why a statutory rate of 25% was chosen. But there is no
evidence that the rate was chosen on the basis of a rigorous assessment of the gap
between private and social returns to business R&D investment, or the sensitivity of
R&D expenditures to declines in their after-tax cost. Any taxpayer that claimed the
credit and was unable to apply the entire amount against its current-year federal
income tax liability was allowed to carry the unused portion back as many as three
tax years, or forward as many as 15 tax years. The credit was supposed to remain in
effect from July 1, 1981, to December 31, 1985.
Congress made the first significant changes in the original research tax credit
with the passage of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA86, P.L. 99-514). Among the
many significant changes it made in the federal tax code, the act extended the credit
through December 31, 1988, and folded it into the general business credit under IRC
section 38, thereby subjecting it to a yearly cap. In addition, the act lowered the
credit’s statutory rate to 20%, modified the definition of QREs so that the credit
applied to research intended to produce new technical knowledge deemed useful in
the commercial development of new products and processes, and created a separate
20% incremental tax credit for payments to universities and certain other nonprofit
organizations for the conduct of basic research under a written contract. The
reduction in the credit’s rate appeared not to be based on any rigorous analysis of the
credit’s effectiveness in the first five years. Rather, it seemed to flow from the
overriding goals of TRA86, which were to lower income tax rates across the board,
broaden the income tax base, and shrink the differences in tax burdens among major
categories of business assets. Firms investing in R&D already benefitted from the
13
U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, General Explanation of the Economic
Recovery Tax Act of 1981, joint committee print, 97th Cong., 1st sess. (Washington: GPO,
1981), p. 120.
CRS-12
option to expense qualified R&D spending under the IRC section 174 expensing
allowance.14
The regular research and basic research credits were further altered by the
Technical and Miscellaneous Revenue Act of 1988 (P.L. 100-647). Specifically, the
act extended the credits through December 31, 1989. It also curtailed the overall tax
preference for private-sector R&D investment by requiring business taxpayers to
reduce any deduction they claim for research spending under IRC section 174 by half
of the total amount of any regular and basic research credits they claim. This new
rule decreased the maximum effective rate of the regular research tax credit by a
factor equal to 0.5 times a taxpayer’s marginal income tax rate.15
Continuing disappointment with the design of the original credit among
interested parties led to the enactment of additional significant changes in the regular
credit through the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1989 (OBRA89, P.L. 101239). Much of the disappointment stemmed from the formula for determining the
base amount of the credit. Critics rightly pointed out that under the formula, which
was based on a three-year moving average of a firm’s annual spending on qualified
research, an increase in a firm’s research spending in one year would increase its base
amount in each of the following three years by one-third of that increase in research
spending, making it more difficult to claim the credit in those three years. Some
argued that such a design would be less cost-effective in boosting business R&D
investment than one in which a firm’s base amount was independent of its current
spending on qualified research.16
To address this concern, OBRA89 changed the formula for the base amount so
that it was equal to the greater of 50% of a firm’s current-year QREs, or the product
of the firm’s average annual gross receipts in the previous four tax years and a
“fixed-base percentage.” The act set this percentage equal to the ratio of a firm’s
total QREs to total gross receipts in the four tax years from 1984 to 1988, capped at
16%. OBRA89 also made the credit available on more favorable terms to start-up
firms, which it defined as firms without gross receipts and QREs in three of the four
years from 1984 to 1988; these firms were assigned a fixed-base percentage of 3%.
In addition, the act effectively extended the credits to December 31, 1990 (by
requiring that QREs incurred before January 1, 1991, be prorated), permitted firms
to apply the regular credit to QREs related both to current lines of business and
possible future lines of business, and required firms claiming the regular and basic
research credits to reduce any deduction they claim under IRC section 174 by the
entire amount of the credits.
14
U.S. Congress, General Explanation of the Tax Reform Act of 1986, joint committee print,
100th Cong., 1st sess. (Washington: GPO, 1987), p.130.
15
For a business taxpayer in the 30% tax bracket, the rule reduced the maximum effective
rate of the regular research credit from 20% to 17.5%: .20 x [1 - (.5 x .30)].
16
See U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee, The R&D Tax Credit: An Evaluation of
Evidence on Its Effectiveness, joint committee print, 99th Cong., 1st sess. (Washington: GPO,
1985), pp. 17-22.
CRS-13
In 1990 and 1991, Congress passed two bills that, among other things,
temporarily extended the credits. The Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990
(P.L. 101-508) extended the credits through December 31, 1991, and repealed the
requirement that QREs made before January 1, 1991, be prorated. The Tax
Extension Act of 1991 (P.L. 102-227) pushed the expiration date for the credits
ahead to June 30, 1992. A major obstacle to longer extensions of the credits at the
time lay in congressional budget rules requiring that the revenue cost of lengthy or
permanent extensions be estimated over 10 fiscal years and offset with tax increases
or cuts in non-defense discretionary spending.
Although Congress passed two bills in 1992 that would have extended the
credits beyond June 30 of that year, President George H. W. Bush vetoed both for
reasons that had nothing to do with the design or incentive effects of the credits. As
a result, they expired and remained unavailable from July 1, 1992, until the
enactment of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1993 (OBRA93, P.L. 10366) in August 1993. The act extended the credits retroactively from July 1, 1992,
through June 30, 1995. It also modified the fixed-base percentage for start-up firms.
Under OBRA93, a firm lacking gross receipts in three of the years from 1984 to 1988
was assigned a percentage of 3% for the first five tax years after 1993 in which it
reported QREs. Starting in the firm’s sixth year, the percentage was to adjust
gradually so that by its eleventh year the percentage would reflect its actual ratio of
total QREs to total gross receipts in five of the previous six tax years.
Congressional inaction allowed the credits to expire again on June 30, 1995.
They remained inactive until the enactment of the Small Business Job Protection Act
of 1996 (P.L. 104-188) in August 1996. The act retroactively reinstated the credits
from July 1, 1996, to May 31, 1997, leaving a one-year gap in the credit’s coverage
since its inception in mid-1981. It also expanded the definition of a start-up firm to
include any firm whose first tax year with both gross receipts and QREs was 1984
or later, added an alternative incremental research credit (i.e., the AIRC) with initial
rates of 1.65%, 2.2%, and 2.75%, and made 75% of payments for qualified research
performed under contract by nonprofit organizations “operated primarily to conduct
scientific research” eligible for the regular or alternative incremental credits.
The credits expired again in 1997, but they were extended retroactively from
June 1, 1997, to June 30, 1998, by the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 (P.L. 105-34).
A further extension of the credits to June 30, 1999, was included in the revenue
portion of the Omnibus Consolidated and Emergency Supplemental Appropriations
Act, 1998 (P.L. 105-277).
In a reprise of events in 1997, the credits expired yet again in 1999. But
Congress passed a measure late in the year reinstating them retroactively. Under the
revenue portion of the Ticket to Work and Work Incentives Improvement Act of
1999 (P.L. 106-170), the credits were extended from July 1, 1999 to June 30, 2004.
The act also increased the three rates of the AIRC to 2.65%, 3.2%, and 3.75% and
expanded the definition of qualified research to include qualified research performed
in Puerto Rico and the other territorial possessions of the United States.
CRS-14
On October 4, 2004, President George W. Bush signed into law the Working
Families Tax Relief Act of 2004 (P.L. 108-311), which included a provision
extending the research tax credit through December 31, 2005.
The Energy Policy Act of 2005 (P.L. 109-58) added a fourth component to the
research tax credit by establishing a credit equal to 20% of all payments for energy
research performed under contract by qualified research consortia, colleges and
universities, federal laboratories, and eligible small firms.
Finally, under the Tax Relief and Health Care Act of 2006 (P.L. 109-432), the
research tax credit was extended retroactively through the end of 2007. The act also
raised the three rates for the AIRC to 3%, 4%, and 5%, and established a new
research tax credit, known as the alternative simplified credit (or ASIC). This fifth
component of the credit is equal to 12% of QREs in excess of 50% of average QREs
in the past three tax years; for business taxpayers with no QREs in any of the three
preceding tax years, the credit is equal to 6% of QREs in the current tax year.
Beginning in the mid-1990s, a cycle emerged every time the credits were about
to expire, one that seems active today. The cycle starts when staunch supporters of
the credit in Congress and among influential business groups issue public statements
calling for a permanent extension of the credits and denouncing what they see as the
folly of repeated temporary extensions.17 Often, the President in office when the
cycle begins supports such an extension. In the next stage of the cycle, leaders in
both houses of Congress enter into earnest negotiations on tax legislation that
includes a permanent extension of the credit. Still, in the end, Congress and the
President agree on a relatively short extension of the credit, stymied by an inability
to reconcile the revenue cost of a permanent extension with their other budget
priorities.
Effectiveness of the Research Tax Credit
For analysts and lawmakers alike, the most important policy issue raised by the
research tax credit concerns how effective it has been in the more than 25 years of its
existence. There are two basic approaches to assessing the credit’s effectiveness.
Among economists, the preferred approach is to compare the social benefit from
any added R&D stimulated by the credit with the social cost of that R&D. Such an
ambitious undertaking involves comparing the returns to society of the additional
R&D spending spurred by the credit with the opportunity costs to society of the
resources represented by this added R&D. The social cost of the credit can be
thought of as the net loss of tax revenue because of the credit and the public and
private costs of administering the credit. Unfortunately, this approach to assessing
the effectiveness of the research tax credit is of limited usefulness in policymaking,
17
Martin A. Sullivan, “Research Credit Hits New Heights, No End in Sight,” Tax Notes, vol.
94, no. 7, February 18, 2002, p. 801.
CRS-15
largely because it is exceedingly difficult to measure accurately the social returns to
R&D.18
As a result, economists have tended to rely on a less sweeping and rigorous
approach: estimating the additional R&D (if any) stimulated by the regular credit,
and comparing the value of that R&D with the tax revenue lost because of the credit.
Such an approach examines the direct benefits (i.e., added R&D investment) and
costs (revenue loss) of the regular credit. It presupposes that the social returns to
R&D far exceed the private returns, and that the optimal size of any tax subsidy for
R&D can be estimated. The approach also sheds light on another policy issue raised
by research tax credits: namely, whether they are more cost-effective than direct
research subsidies such as government grants or subsidized loans. If the added R&D
stimulated by the regular credit were to exceed its revenue cost, then a case could be
made that a research tax credit is a more cost-effective way to boost overall R&D
investment than direct research subsidies. But if the revenue cost of the regular credit
were greater than the added R&D it engenders, then one can argue that direct
research subsidies are more cost-effective than tax subsidies in boosting overall R&D
investment.19
What do existing studies of the regular credit’s effectiveness say about its direct
benefits and costs? For the most part, these studies are an exercise in counterfactual
analysis. They attempt to answer the following question: how much more R&D did
firms claiming the credit perform as a result of the credit? Researchers use a variety
of methods to estimate the amount of R&D that can be attributed to the regular credit.
These methods were examined in a 1995 study by economist Bronwyn Hall.20 She
found that studies based on data from 1981 to 1983 differed markedly from those
based on data from 1984 and after. More specifically, she found that the earlier set
of studies produced lower estimates of the additional R&D undertaken per dollar of
the credit than the estimates produced by the later set of studies. In light of the
strengths and weaknesses of both sets of studies, Hall concluded that the credit
contributed to a “dollar-for-dollar increase in reported R&D spending on the
margin.”21 This meant that each dollar of the credit stimulated an additional dollar
of business R&D investment.
18
The principal barriers to measuring the social returns to R&D are developing adequate
price indices for the cost elements of R&D for specific industries, specifying the time period
in which to assess the productivity gains from R&D, and determining the depreciation rate
for a society’s stock of R&D assets. For a detailed discussion of these issues, see Bronwyn
H. Hall, “The Private and Social Returns to Research and Development,” in Technology,
R&D, and the Economy, Bruce L. Smith and Claude E. Barfield, eds. (Washington:
Brookings Institution, 1996), pp. 141-145.
19
This argument assumes that government research grants to the private sector do not lead
firms receiving the grants to reduce their own R&D spending by similar amounts.
20
See Bronwyn H. Hall, Effectiveness of Research and Experimentation Tax Credits:
Critical Literature Review and Research Design, report prepared for the Office of
Technology Assessment, June 15, 1995, pp. 11-13, available at [http://elsa.berkeley.edu/~
bhhall/papers/BHH95%20OTArtax.pdf].
21
Ibid., p. 18.
CRS-16
In theory, the credit stimulates increased business R&D investment by lowering
the after-tax cost of undertaking another dollar of R&D beyond some normal (or
base) amount. It is reasonable to expect firms investing in R&D to respond to this
reduction in cost by spending more on R&D, all other things being equal. So the
critical considerations in estimating the amount of business R&D investment that is
due to the credit are the responsiveness of business R&D investment to decreases in
its after-tax cost, and the extent to which the credit lowers the after-tax cost of
business R&D.
Relatively little research has been done on how responsive business R&D
investment is to changes in its after-tax cost. The standard measure of this sensitivity
is known as the price elasticity of R&D demand. Existing studies have come up with
estimates of the long-run price elasticity ranging from -0.2 to -2.0. These results
imply that a decline in the after-tax cost of R&D of 10% can be expected to produce
a rise in R&D spending in the long run of anywhere from 2% to 20%. In an analysis
of the President Bush’s FY2004 budget proposal, the Joint Tax Committee noted that
“the general consensus when assumptions are made with respect to research
expenditures is that the price elasticity of research is less than -1.0 and may be less
than -0.5.”22
As the main findings of Bronwyn Hall’s 1995 study (cited above) suggest, less
uncertainty surrounds the extent to which the regular credit shrinks the after-tax cost
of qualified research. Basically, one dollar of the credit reduces this cost by one
dollar. By making such a credit available, the federal government (or U.S. taxpayers)
effectively shares the cost of qualified research with the private firms financing it.
Thus, a measure of the overall reduction in the after-tax cost of domestic business
R&D investment as a result of the credit is the credit’s average effective rate, which
is measured as the ratio of the total amount of claims for the credit in a year to some
measure of domestic business R&D spending, such as QREs.
This rate can be computed for both QREs and total business R&D spending. As
Table 3 shows, the average effective rate of the credit from 1996 to 2003 was 3.3%
for industry R&D spending and 5.5% for QRE. These rates indicate that the credit
has lowered the after-tax cost of domestic business R&D by about 3% and the aftertax cost of qualified research by 5% to 6%.
The gap between the rates largely reflects the differences between QREs and
industry R&D spending, as estimated by the National Science Foundation (NSF).
Aggregate QREs came to 60% of aggregate business R&D spending from 1996 to
2003. The NSF estimate pertains to all domestic R&D performed by firms and
funded by industry and other non-federal entities. It is based on annual surveys of
R&D in industry and covers the wages, salaries, and fringe benefits of research
personnel, and the cost of materials and supplies, overhead expenses, and
depreciation related to research activities. The estimate excludes expenditures on
22
U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, Description of Revenue Provisions
Contained in the President’s Fiscal Year 2004 Budget Proposal, joint committee print, JCS7-03, 108th Cong., 1st sess. (Washington, March 2003), p. 250.
CRS-17
plant and equipment used in research.23 By contrast, QREs represent total spending
on qualified research that is eligible for the credit. They are reported on the tax
returns business taxpayers claiming the credit and cover wages and salaries, materials
and supplies, leased computer time, and 65% to 75% of contract research funded by
these entities. Given the differences between the two sources, one would expect
industry R&D spending to be greater than QREs, as it covers a broader segment of
R&D expenses than QREs.
What can be said about the impact of the regular credit on domestic R&D? The
figures in Table 3 indicate that the credit delivered a modest stimulus to domestic
business R&D investment from 1996 to 2003. Specifically, assuming that the price
elasticity of demand for R&D falls between -0.5 and -1.0, and the lowers the cost of
business R&D investment by 3.3%, the credit may have raised business R&D
investment by 1.65% to 3.3% over that period.
Table 3. U.S. Industrial R&D Spending, Federal R&D Spending,
and the Research Tax Credit, 1996 to 2003
($ billions)
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
Industry
R&D
Spendinga
121.0
133.6
145.0
160.3
180.4
181.6
177.5
183.3
Qualified
Research
Spendingb
38.3
85.3
95.9
102.7
109.9
99.8
116.1
124.5
Federal
R&D
Spendingc
70.6
73.5
75.3
80.3
83.1
91.2
102.0
117.4
CurrentYear
Research
Tax
Creditd
2.2
4.5
5.3
5.3
7.2
6.5
5.8
5.6
Source: National Science Foundation, Division of Science Resources Statistics, InfoBrief: Increase
in U.S. Industrial R&D Expenditures Reported for 2003 Makes Up For Earlier Decline; National
Science Foundation, Division of Science Resources Statistics, Survey of Federal Funds for Research
and Development: Fiscal Years 2000, 2001, and 2002; Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income
Division, e-mail data transmissions.
a. Total spending on domestic industrial R&D by companies and other non-federal entities, including
nonprofit organizations and state and local governments.
b. Spending on research that qualifies for the regular and alternative incremental research tax credits
as reported by business taxpayers claiming the credit on their federal income tax returns.
c. Budget authority for Federal defense and non-defense R&D spending by fiscal year.
23
National Science Foundation, Division of Science Resource Statistics, The Methodology
Underlying the Measurement of R&D Expenditures: 2000 (data update) (Arlington, VA:
December 10, 2001), p. 2.
CRS-18
d. Total value of claims for the regular, incremental and basic research tax credits included on federal
income tax returns. Because of limitations on the use of the general business credit, of which
the research credit is a component, the total amount of the research credit allowed in a particular
year is likely to differ from the amount claimed.
Policy Issues Raised by the
Current Research Tax Credit
Although mostMost policy analysts and lawmakers backendorse the use of tax incentives to
spur spur
increased domestic business R&D investment, the . Yet the current research tax credit authorized
by IRC Section 41
seems to attract more criticism than praise. A major concern is
of critics is that the
credit is lessnot as effective than it mightas it should be because of what critics see as flaws
in its present they say are flaws in its
design. In their view, the credit will yieldhave its intended benefits only if
these problems are fixedflaws are
corrected. Critics cite five problemsblame what they claim is the credit’s relatively weak incentive
effect on five shortcomings in particular: (1) the credit is not
a permanent provision
of the IRC; (2) it still has weak and arbitrary incentive effects; (3)
it is not refundable;
(4) the definition of qualified research is inadequate and remains
unsettled; and (5) the credit appears to subsidize R&D investment that generates
greater private returns than socialremains incomplete and too ambiguous; and
(5) the credit is not targeted at R&D investments that generate greater social returns
than private returns. Each problem is examined in turn below.
CRS-18below.
Lack of Permanence
The R&Eresearch tax credit expiredis due to expire on December 31, 2005, and a variety of bills are
2007. A few bills to
extend it permanently are being considered in the current Congress to extend the credit retroactively. It has
— a step that the
Bush Administration supports. The credit has never been a permanent provision of
the IRC, despite repeated attempts in Congress
to extend it permanently in the past
decade.2324 In fact, the credit has been extended
11 12 times, most recently by the Working Families Tax Relief Act of 2004 (P.L. 108311)Tax
Relief and Health Care Act of 2006.
This lack of permanence is a matter of concern to many because it is thought to diminish
weaken the credit’s incentive effect. As critics of the design of the current credit are wont to
point out, manyMany R&D projects have planning horizons
extending beyond a year or
two. They also point out that iffew years. If business managers cannot count on receiving the
credit over the expected life of an R&D project, then it isthey are unlikely to influence
decisions ontake it into
account when setting the size of annual R&D budgets, even if a credit exists when the
decisions are made. In such a situation, the credit
would have little or no influence over R&D investment decisions, defeating its
purpose. Instead of boosting R&D investment, a temporary R&D tax
credit could might
end up restraining it by compounding the considerable uncertainty that
typically surrounds characterizes projected
after-tax returns on planned R&D investments. This
added heightened uncertainty may convince
deter managers not to pursuefrom pursuing R&D projects they would
be inclined be likely to undertake if the
credit were permanent.
Nonetheless, However, there are reasons to think that not all firms investing in R&D are likely to be equally affected by
may be
affected in the same way by a temporary research tax credit. ThoseFirms with relatively
long R&D planning horizons
and relatively high fixed costs for R&D investment
24
The R&E tax credit has been in effect for each year between July 1, 1981, and the present
except for period from July 1, 1995, to June 30, 1996, when it expired. Since July 1, 1996,
the credit has not been renewed to include this period.
CRS-19
might show more sensitivity R&D investment costs can be expected to be more sensitive
to uncertainty in the availability of the credit than thosea research tax credit
than firms with shorter horizons and
more flexible investment costs. For example, the R&D investment plans of
pharmaceutical firms could be affected more by a temporary research tax credit than
those of software firms, simply because pharmaceutical R&D projects tend to have
much longer planning horizons and require much greater initial investment in plant
and equipment and staff training than do software R&D projects.
Weak and Disparate Incentive Effect
Critics maintain that another major problem with the credit lies in its incentive
it is conceivable (though hard to prove) that a string of temporary credits could cause
pharmaceutical firms to expand their research budgets at a slower rate than software
firms, for the simple reason that pharmaceutical R&D projects, on average, have
longer planning horizons and require greater initial investments in plant and
equipment than do software R&D projects.
Weak and Uneven Incentive Effects
Critics maintain that another major flaw in the credit can be found in its
incentive effect. In their view, this effect varies among firms conducting qualified
research in
ways that are not supported by economic theory and that thwart the undermines the
credit’s purpose.
The The credit’s incentive effect is also thought to be too weak to produce the levels of business
induce
the increases in business R&D investment warranted by its overallsocial returns. Critics
attribute these
shortcomings to the design of the regular and alternative incremental credits, AIRC, ASIC, and basic
research components of the credit.
Uneven Incentive Effect. The regular credit’s incentive effect appears to
vary widely among firms investing in qualified research, including those that steadily
gradually increase their R&D investment over an extended period. Evidence for such variation
can be found in a 1996 study by economist William Cox that looked at the firms with
sizable research budgets in 1994 that could have claimed the regular R&E tax credit.
23
The R&E tax credit has been in effect for each year between July 1, 1981, and the present
except for period from July 1, 1995, to June 30, 1996, when it expired. Since July 1, 1996,
the credit has not been renewed to include this period.
CRS-19
The starting point for the study was
variation can be found in a 1996 study by economist William Cox of firms that
examined which of a large group of domestic corporations with sizable research
budgets in 1994 should have be able to claim the regular research tax credit.
The study is based on a sample of 900 publicly traded U.S.-based
firms with the
largest R&D budgets, culled by Cox from a database maintained by
Compustat, Inc. On the defensible
plausible assumption that combined QREs for these firms
in 1994 were equal to 70% of their
reported R&D spending, Cox determined that
estimated that 62.5% of the firms could be considered
established firms because they had both
for the purpose of claiming the regular research tax credit, because
they had both business revenue and QREs in three of the years from 1984 to 1988;
the remainder
were treated as start-up firms. Cox found that 78% of the 900 firms
in the sample
(44.4% of the established firms and 33.5% of the start-up firms) could
have claimed
the R&E tax the credit in 1994, while 22% could have claimed no credit (18% of
established firms and 4% of start-up firms).2425 He also found that 34% of all firms
(32.3% of established firms and 1.7% of start-up firms) had QREs greater than their
base amounts but less than twice those amounts, allowing them to claim credits with
a marginal effective rate of 13%, and that 43.8% of all firms had QREs greater than
double their base amounts, enablingallowing them to claim credits with a marginal effective
rate of 6.5%.2526 These rates measure the reduction in the after-tax cost of qualified
research because of the as a result of the regular credit. In addition, Cox discovereddetermined that some of the most
research-intensive firms could claim either no credit or credits with marginal
effective rates half as large as the rates of the estimated credits claimed by firms with
much lower research intensities.
The results indicated that the credit was most beneficial to firms whose research
intensities had grown since their base periods and least beneficial to firms whose
research intensities had changed little or not at all or had shrunk since their base
periods. Firms whose research intensities had diminished found themselves in that
position for two reasons: (1) their R&D spending was lower in 1994 relative to their
base period; or (2) their sales revenue had grown faster than their R&D expenditures
over the same time span.
Critics of the current research credit say that such a pattern of R&D
subsidization is unfair and arbitrary, has no justification in economic theory, and
contravenes the intended purpose of the credit, which is to encourage firms to spend
more on R&D than they otherwise would in an effort to bolster their competitiveness
and the prospects for future growth in the U.S. economy. Cox noted that the widely
varying marginal effective rates of the research credit that R&D-performing firms
included in his study could claim “imply that society places a higher value on adding
R&D at certain firms than at others and on adding R&D of certain types than others,
when little or no basis for such different valuations exists.”26
There are two basic reasons for the credit’s disparate incentive effects: the rule
requiring the base amount for the regular credit to be equal to no less than 50% of
24
CRS Report 96-505, Research and Experimentation Tax Credits: Who Got How Much?
Evaluating Possible Changes, by William A. Cox, pp. 5-10. (The report is out of print.
Copies may be obtained from Gary Guenther (202) 707-7742, upon request.) (Hereafter
cited as Cox, Research and Experimentation Tax Credits.)
25
Their effective credit rate was lower because each firm was subject to the 50-percent rule,
which reduced the marginal effective rate of the credit on R&D spending above the base
amount by 50%.
26
Cox, Research and Experimentation Tax Credits, p. 10.
CRS-20
QREs, and the rule requiring established firms to use a fixed-base period of 1984 to
1988 in computing their fixed-base percentages. This period bears no relationship
to current economic or competitive conditions in most industries. As a result, many
of the firms that have existed since the early 1980s and invested heavily in R&D
relative to revenue back then now face a different set of incentives to invest in R&D.
In some cases, these incentives have led to much lower research intensities. Firms
in this position cannot claim the R&E tax credit, even though they still spend
substantial sums on R&D.27
Weak Incentive Effect. In claiming that the credit’s incentive effect is too
weak, critics have in mind some estimate of the credit rate necessary to raise business
R&D investment to socially optimal levels, as well as differences between the regular
credit’s statutory rate and its average marginal effective rate. Both aspects of this
alleged weakness are examined here.
Current R&D Tax Incentives are Inadequate. Some maintain that the
average effective rate of the credit is too low to boost business R&D investment to
levels commensurate with its overall economic benefits. To lend empirical support
to this contention, they point to another study by Cox, one that focused on the
efficacy of the R&E tax credit.28 Cox built his analysis around the premise that tax
incentives can overcome the private sector’s disposition to invest too little in the
creation of new technical knowledge and know-how. For this to happen, the
incentives must be designed so they target spending on R&D beyond what firms
would undertake on their own, and they must be large enough to “raise private aftertax returns on R&D investments to the levels that would result from applying the
same rate of taxation to the social rate of return from R&D.”29 A variety of
researchers have concluded that the median private rate of return on R&D investment
is roughly 50% of the median social rate of return.30 Thus, assuming that the average
social pre-tax rate of return is double the average private pre-tax rate of return, the
optimal R&D tax subsidy would double the private after-tax rate of return to R&D
investment. For example, at a corporate tax rate of 35%, after-tax returns would
equal 65% of pre-tax returns for firms organized as corporations. In this case, the
optimal R&D tax subsidy would double the private after-tax returns to R&D
investment by elevating them to 130% of pre-tax returns [2 x (1 - 0.35)], thereby
subsidizing private pre-tax returns by 30%.31
27
Two examples are aerospace and semiconductor chip manufacturers. See McGee Grisby
and John Westmoreland, “The Research Tax Credit: A Temporary and Incremental
Dinosaur,” Tax Notes, vol. 93, no. 12, Dec. 17, 2001, p. 1633.
28
See CRS Report 95-871, Tax Preferences for Research and Experimentation: Are
Changes Needed?, by William A. Cox. (This report is out of print. Copies may be obtained
from Gary Guenther at (202) 707-7742, upon request.) (Hereafter cited as Cox, Tax
Preferences for Research and Experimentation.)
29
Ibid., p. 8.
30
See, for example, Edwin Mansfield, The Positive Sum Strategy, pp. 309-311.
31
Cox, Tax Preferences for Research and Experimentation, pp. 7-8.
CRS-21
Cox’s analysis implied that the optimal average effective rate for an R&D tax
subsidy, or a combination of such subsidies (e.g., a research tax credit combined with
expensing of research expenditures), was around 30%. In sorting through the policy
implications of this finding, Cox noted that such a rate is an average and thus does
not take into consideration the fact that the gap between private and social returns
varies considerably among R&D projects and may shift over time. As a result, using
the tax code
25
CRS Report 96-505, Research and Experimentation Tax Credits: Who Got How Much?
Evaluating Possible Changes, by William A. Cox, pp. 5-10. (The report is out of print.
Copies may be obtained from Gary Guenther (202) 707-7742, upon request.) (Hereafter
cited as Cox, Research and Experimentation Tax Credits.)
26
Their effective credit rate was lower because each firm was subject to the 50-percent rule,
which reduced the marginal effective rate of the credit on R&D spending above the base
amount by 50%.
CRS-20
the most research-intensive firms could claim either no credit, or they could claim
credits with a marginal effective rate half as large as the rate of the credits that could
be claimed by firms with much lower research intensities.
The results seemed to confirm a concern raised by the current regular credit:
that it was most beneficial to firms whose research intensities had grown since their
base periods and least beneficial to firms whose research intensities had changed
little, not at all, or shrunk since their base periods. Most firms whose research
intensities had declined found themselves in that position for two reasons: (1) their
R&D spending was lower in 1994 than in their base period; or (2) their sales revenue
had grown faster than their R&D expenditures over the same period.
Critics of the regular credit say that the pattern of R&D subsidization found in
the Cox study is unfair and arbitrary, has no justification in economic theory, and
undercuts the intended purpose of the credit, which is to encourage firms to spend
more on R&D than they otherwise would. Cox concluded that the wide variation in
the marginal effective rates of the research tax credit that firms in his study could
claim suggested “that society places a higher value on adding R&D at certain firms
than at others and on adding R&D of certain types than others, when little or no basis
for such different valuations exists.”27
Two rules governing the use of the regular credit explain most of its disparate
incentive effects: (1) the rule requiring the base amount for the regular credit to be
equal to 50% or more of QREs, and (2) the rule requiring established firms to use a
fixed-base period of 1984 to 1988 in computing their fixed-base percentages.
In combination, the two rules can produce strikingly disparate outcomes in the
use of the regular credit among firms spending substantial amounts on R&D. Of
particular concern to critics are firms whose research-intensity (as measured by
spending on R&D as a share of revenue) has shrunk over time. The structure of the
U.S. economy can and does change markedly in a period of 20 or so years; so it is
very likely that economic and competitive conditions in R&D-intensive industries
today bear little resemblance to the conditions that prevailed in the same industries
in the mid-to-late 1980s. Most of the firms that have stayed intact since the early
1980s and invested heavily in R&D as a share of revenue at that time presumably
face a much different competitive landscape and climate for R&D investment and
growth. In some cases, these changed circumstances have led established firms to
invest less in R&D as a share of revenues. Firms in this position may not be able to
claim the regular research credit, even if they spend relatively large sums on R&D.28
Weak or Inadequate Incentive Effect. In claiming that the regular credit’s
incentive effect is inadequate, critics are referring both to the credit rate deemed
essential to raise business R&D investment to socially optimal amounts, and to
27
28
Cox, Research and Experimentation Tax Credits, p. 10.
Two examples are aerospace and semiconductor chip manufacturers. See McGee Grisby
and John Westmoreland, “The Research Tax Credit: A Temporary and Incremental
Dinosaur,” Tax Notes, vol. 93, no. 12, December 17, 2001, p. 1633.
CRS-21
differences between the regular credit’s statutory rate and its average marginal
effective rate. Both aspects of the regular credit’s incentive effect are examined here.
Current R&D Tax Incentives are Inadequate. Critics maintain that the
average effective rate of the regular credit is too low to boost business R&D
investment to amounts commensurate with its overall economic benefits. To lend
empirical support to this contention, they point to another study by Cox, one that
focused on the efficacy of the research tax credit.29 Cox built his analysis around the
premise that tax incentives can overcome the private sector’s inclination to invest too
little in the creation of new technical knowledge and know-how. For tax incentives
to have this effect, they must be designed so they subsidize R&D spending above and
beyond what firms would undertake on their own, and they must be large enough to
“raise private after-tax returns on R&D investments to the levels that would result
from applying the same rate of taxation to the social rate of return from R&D.”30 A
variety of studies have concluded that the median private rate of return on R&D
investment is roughly 50% of the median social rate of return.31 Thus, assuming that
the average social pre-tax rate of return is two times the average private pre-tax rate
of return, the optimal R&D tax subsidy would double the private after-tax rate of
return to R&D investment. For example, given a corporate tax rate of 35%, after-tax
returns would equal 65% of pre-tax returns for corporations. In this case, the optimal
R&D tax subsidy would double the private after-tax returns to R&D investment by
increasing them to 130% of pre-tax returns [2 x (1 - 0.35)].
Cox’s analysis implied that the optimal average effective rate for an R&D tax
subsidy, or a combination of such subsidies (e.g., a research tax credit combined with
the treatment of research expenditures as a current business expense), was 30%. In
discussing the policy implications of this finding, Cox noted that such a rate is an
average and thus would not address the considerable variation among R&D
investments in the difference between private and social returns. So using tax
incentives to boost pre-tax returns on R&D investment by 30% across all industries
would provide excessive subsidies for projects with below-average spillover benefits
and insufficient subsidies for projects with above-average spillover benefits.
According to Cox, lawmakers should be aware that “this imprecision is unavoidable,
and its consequences are hard to assess.”32
How do existing federal tax subsidies for R&D investment compare with Cox’s
estimateassessment of the optimal R&D tax subsidy? To assessdetermine the incentive effect of current
current federal subsidies, he estimated the pre-tax and after-tax rates of return under thencurrent
1995 federal tax law for a variety of hypothetical R&D projects. The projects differed
according to
differed in the share of R&D expenditures devoted to depreciable assets like
29
See CRS Report 95-871, Tax Preferences for Research and Experimentation: Are
Changes Needed?, by William A. Cox. (This report is out of print. Copies may be obtained
from Gary Guenther at (202) 707-7742, upon request.) (Hereafter cited as Cox, Tax
Preferences for Research and Experimentation.)
30
Ibid., p. 8.
31
See, for example, Edwin Mansfield, The Positive Sum Strategy, pp. 309-311.
32
Ibid., p. 9.
CRS-22
structures and equipment, the share of R&D expenditures eligible for both expensing
under IRC section 174 and the R&Eregular research tax credit, and the economic lives of the
the intangible assets created by the investments. Cox compared the combined effect of
of expensing and the credit on after-tax returns to investment in capital-intensive,
intermediate, and labor-intensive R&D projects producing intangible assets with
economic lives of 3, 5, 10, and 20 years.33
Expensing has the effect of equatingequalizes the pre-tax and after-tax rates of return on
an investment, as
since it taxes the income earned by affected assets at a zero marginal
effective rate of
zero.34 For the averagetypical business R&D investment, it is likely that only part
of the of its total
cost may be expensed under IRC section 174, as the cost of tangible depreciable
assets like
structures and equipment doesdo not qualify for such treatment. Therefore,
the effect of how
expensing onaffects an R&D investment’s after-tax rate of return depends on
both two
factors: (1) the percentage of the total cost that is eligible for expensing and themay be expensed, and (2) the
marginal effective tax
rate on income earned by assets eligible for expensing.
At the same time, the R&Ethe assets (including labor) eligible
for expensing.
The regular research tax credit raises the after-tax rate of return only on
QREs QREs
above a base amount. So its effect on the after-tax returns to an R&D investment
depends on both the percentage of a project’sthe investment’s total cost that qualifies for the
credit and the
effective tax rate on income earned by assets eligible for the credit.
32
Ibid., p. 9.
33
In the case of capital-intensive projects, 50% of outlays go to structures and equipment,
35% qualify for expensing and the credit, and 15% qualify for expensing alone. In the case
of intermediate projects, 30% of outlays go to structures and equipment, 50% qualify for
expensing and the credit, and 20% qualify for expending alone. And in the case of laborintensive projects, 15% of outlays go to structures and equipment, 65% qualify for
expensing and the credit, and 20% qualify for expensing only.
34
See Jane G. Gravelle, “Effects of the 1981 Depreciation Revisions on the Taxation of
Income from Business Capital,” National Tax Journal, vol. 35, no. 1, Mar. 1982, pp. 2-3.
CRS-22
After allowing for effective tax rate on income earned by assets eligible for the credit.
Taking into account these limitations on the benefits of expensing and the research
tax
regular credit, Cox estimated that expensing and the credit together give rise toproduce median
after-tax rates of return ranging from 101.0% of pre-tax returns for a hypothetical
capital-intensive project yielding intangible assets with an economic life of 20 years
to 124.7% for a hypothetical labor-intensive project yielding intangible assets with an
an economic life of three years.35 The results led him to conclude that existing R&D tax
subsidies As these percentages are less than 130%, he
inferred that the R&D tax subsidies in existence in 1995 did not increase private
after-tax returns to R&D investments to the “levels
warranted by the spillover
benefits that are thought to be typical” for these
investments.36
Significant Gap Between Average Effective Rate of the Creditthe Credit’s Average Effective Rate and
Its Statutory Rate. Some critics of the current research tax credit viewsee the credit’s
incentive effect from a in a somewhat different perspective. To them, the critical considerationlight. For them, what counts most is any
difference between the regular credit’s average effective rate and its statutory rate of 20%.
Such a difference would arise from three of the rules governing the use of the credit
discussed earlier
33
In the case of capital-intensive projects, 50% of outlays go to structures and equipment,
35% qualify for expensing and the credit, and 15% qualify for expensing alone. In the case
of intermediate projects, 30% of outlays go to structures and equipment, 50% qualify for
expensing and the credit, and 20% qualify for expending alone. And in the case of laborintensive projects, 15% of outlays go to structures and equipment, 65% qualify for
expensing and the credit, and 20% qualify for expensing only.
34
See Jane G. Gravelle, “Effects of the 1981 Depreciation Revisions on the Taxation of
Income from Business Capital,” National Tax Journal, vol. 35, no. 1, March 1982, pp. 2-3.
35
Cox, Tax Preferences for Research and Experimentation, p. 15.
36
Ibid., p. 17.
CRS-23
20%. As noted earlier, whatever difference exists is due to three of the rules
governing the use of the credit.
One of the rules is the basis adjustment under IRC section 280C(c)(1), which
requires business taxpayers claiming the credit to reduce any investing in qualified research to reduce whatever
deduction for research
expenditures under IRC section 174 by the amount of the credit they claim. The
adjustment has the effect of taxingthey claim by any
research tax credit they claim. This adjustment effectively taxes the credit at a firm’s
marginal income tax rate.
Consequently, at the for business taxpayers subject to the
maximum corporate and individual tax rates of 35%, the basis
adjustment lowers adjustment decreases
the marginal effective rate of the credit from 20% to 13%.
Business taxpayers have
the option of computing the regular research credit at a rate
of 13%, instead of reducing any deductions of 13% and not adjusting
any deduction taken under section 174 and computing
the credit at the rate of 20%by the amount of the credit.
A second rule is the 50% rule, which requires that the base amount for the credit
not be less than 50%
regular credit equal 50% or more of a firm’s current-year QREs. The rule affectsmakes the
credit less beneficial to established firms
whose ratio of current-year QREs to gross
income is more than double their fixed-base
percentages, or more than double the
16% cap on the fixed-base percentage. It also
affects start-up makes the credit less attractive to startup firms whose current-year ratio of QREs to gross income exceeds 6%
during their
first five tax years, or whose current-year ratio is more than double their
fixed-base
percentages in the next six tax years. For both sets of firms, the rule further
reduces reduces
the marginal effective rate of the credit to 6.5%.
Yet another rule loweringA third rule affecting this rate is the exclusion of expenditures for equipment
and structures and overhead costs from expenses eligible for the regular credit —
even though
many business R&D investments involve the purchase of elaborate
buildings and
sophisticated equipment, and all R&D projects haveentail overhead costs.
The effect of the
exclusion on the marginal effective rate of the credit depends on the
overall share of an R&D
investment that is ineligible for the credit: as. As this share
rises, the rate fallsdrops, all other
things being equal. For example, if expenditures for
physical capital account for half
of the cost of an R&D investment, then the marginal
effective rate of the credit for the
entire investment is half of what it would be if the
entire cost were eligible for the
credit. For firms subject to the 50% rule that invest
in R&D projects where physical capital represents 50%
35
Cox, Tax Preferences for Research and Experimentation, p. 15.
36
Ibid., p. 17.
CRS-23
of the total cost and are subject to 50% rule of the total cost, the marginal
effective rate of the credit
could dropfall to 3.25%.
TheAs these considerations suggest, the key to bolstering the regular credit’s
incentive effect is to increase its average
effective rate. ThereIn essence, there are two
ways to do so. One is to keep its current statutory rate
and modify one or more of the
three rules driving a wedge between the credit’s
marginal effective rate and its
statutory rate. The second approach is to retain these
rules but to increase the credit’s
statutory rate.
Cox assessed the impactanalyzed the effect of both options on after-tax rates of return for the same
set of hypothetical R&D investments discussed above. In the case of labor-intensive
R&D projects, he estimated that existing R&D1995 research tax preferences yielded median aftertaxproduced median
after-tax returns that were 124.7% of pre-tax returns for projects producingyielding intangible assets
assets with an economic life of three years, and 115.5% for projects producing intangible
yielding
intangible assets with an economic life of 20 years. Getting rid ofRepealing the basis adjustment
for the
credit caused median after-tax returns to increase to 146.0% of pre-tax returns for
CRS-24
for assets with a three-year economic life, and 130.1% for assets with a 20-year economic
economic life.37 Increasing the statutory rate of the credit to 25% but retaining
existing rules
(including the basis adjustment) led to similar results: median after-tax
returns for
assets with a three-year economic life were an estimated 133.9% of pre-taxpretax returns,
and and an estimated 121.9% for assets with a 20-year economic life.38 As
one might expect, increasing
the rate to 25% and removing the basis adjustment led
to the biggest boost in the ratio
of after-tax returns to pre-tax returns: 165.8% for
assets with a three-year economic
life, and 143.4% for assets with a 20-year
economic life.
Assuming that the optimal R&D tax subsidy would raise after-tax returns to
130% of pre-tax returns, Cox’s analysis suggests that leaving the credit’s suggested that keeping the regular credit’s
statutory rate
at the current level of 20% but removing or relaxing the three rules
governing the
credit’s use might be the best policy option for significantly enhancing boosting
the credit’s
incentive effect.
Non-refundable Status
The R&Eresearch tax credit is non-refundable, which means that only firms with
sufficiently large income tax liabilities may benefit from itthe full amount of the credit
claimed in a tax year. In addition, the credit is
a component of the general business
credit (GBC) under IRC section 38, and therefore subject to its
limitations. For firms
undertaking qualified research, a key limitation is that the GBC
cannot exceed a
taxpayer’s net income tax liability, less the greater of its tentative
minimum tax under
the alternative minimum tax or 25% of its regular income tax
liability above $25,000.
Unused GBCs may be carried forward 20 years or back one
year. Although there are
some advantages to having an inventory of tax credits to
apply against future or past
tax liabilities, the disadvantages may outweigh the advantages.
For smaller, newly createdadvantages do not necessarily outweigh the disadvantages for all
firms investing in R&D. In the case of firms with sizable net operating losses, there
is no certainty
that stored credits can be used before they expire. In addition, the time value of
37
Ibid., p. 27.
38
Ibid., p. 27.
CRS-24
value of money means that a business taxpayer is better off using the full amount of
a tax credit nowtoday, rather than
five or 10 years from now.
Critics of the credit’s design saycontend that its non-refundable status poses a special
special problem for small, fledgling research-intensive firms. In recent decades, numerous
numerous commercially successful technological innovations have originated with
such firms.
Many of these firms have spentspend substantial sums on R&D, even though they lost large
sums of money in during their first
few years of existence, despite experiencing large financial losses. In the view of critics, the
credit’s
lack of refundability diminishes the typical small start-up firm’s prospects for survival
or growth because it cannot count on the credit as a possible source of funding for
R&D investments. They argue thatchances of
survival or growth, as the firm cannot count on the credit to reduce its cost of capital
for R&D investments. Some critics advocate making the credit wholly or partially refundable
refundable for firms under a certain asset or, employment size and age would strengthen the
, or age, as a means of
37
Ibid., p. 27.
38
Ibid., p. 27.
CRS-25
both solving this problem and improving the domestic climate for technological
innovation innovation.39
Unsettled and Ambiguous Definition of Qualified Research
Another important policy issue raised by the current research tax credit relates to the
definition of qualified research. More specifically, firms investing in R&D face
continuing uncertainty over how the IRS will interpret final regulations on the
definition of qualified research issued in December 2003, and when the IRS will
address certain key issues left unresolved by those regulations. Critics say this
double-edged uncertainty undermines the effectiveness of the credit and inflates the
cost of compliance with it. Lasting doubt about which research projects do and do not
qualify for the credit may deter some firms from claiming it and may encourage others
to re-label or repackage certain ordinary business expenses to make them eligible for
the credit. Additionally, a lack of clarity over where the line is drawn between
research that does and does not qualify for the credit sets the stage for costly,
prolonged legal disputes between business taxpayers and the IRS over which claims
for the credit are valid.
From 1981 through 1985, research that could be expensed under IRC section 174
also qualified for the credit, with three exceptions: the credit did not apply to research
conducted outside the United States, research in the social sciences or humanities, or
research funded by another entity. In response to mounting concerns that business
taxpayers were claiming the credit for activities that had little to do with technological
innovation, Congress tightened the definition by adding two tests through the Tax
Reform Act of 1986.40 Under the act, qualified research still had to satisfy the criteria
for qualified research under IRC section 174. But it also was required to serve the
purpose of discovering information that is technological in nature and useful in the
development of a new or improved product, process, or some other kind of intellectual
property with commercial applications. And “substantially all” of the research had to
involve a process of experimentation aimed at developing a new or improved
to the activities that qualify for it. At its core, the issue concerns the definition of
qualified research and how the IRS and business taxpayers apply it in the real world
of business R&D.
Critics argue that the statutory definition in IRC section 41(d) and IRS
regulations implementing it are vague and incomplete. This lack of clarity and
finality, in their view, often paves the way for protracted and costly disputes between
business taxpayers and the IRS over the validity of claims for the credit. Critics say
that these disputes can curtail the stimulative effect of the credit by denying the full
benefit of credits claimed by some firms investing in R&D, and by deterring some
other firms investing in R&D from claiming the credit on the grounds that its
potential benefits are dwarfed by the costs associated with IRS scrutiny of claims for
the credit.
Under the original credit, which was in effect from 1981 through 1985, research
expenditures qualified for the credit if they were also eligible for expensing under
IRC section 174. There were three exceptions to this general rule: no credit could
be claimed for research conducted outside the United States, research in the social
sciences or humanities, and any portion of research funded by another entity. Section
174 allows business taxpayers to deduct all “research or experimental expenditures”
incurred in connection with their trade or business, but it does not define these
expenditures.
The IRS filled this gap by issuing regulation 1.174-2(a), which defined research
or experimental expenditures. According to the regulation, these expenditures refer
to “research and development costs in the laboratory sense” and generally include
“all such costs incident to the development or improvement of a product.”
Expenditures can be considered R&D costs in the “experimental or laboratory sense
if they fund activities intended to discover information that would eliminate
uncertainty concerning the development or improvement of a product.” Uncertainty
exists in the R&D process when the information available to researchers does not
indicate how to proceed in developing a new product or improving an existing one.
According to the regulation, the proper focus in determining whether research
expenditures qualify for expensing under section 174 is the “nature of the activity to
which the expenditures relate, not the nature of the product or improvement being
developed.”
39
For further discussion of the possible benefits to small firms of making the credit wholly
or partially refundable, see Scott J. Wallsten, “Rethinking the Small Business Innovation
Research Program,” in Investing in Innovation, Lewis M. Branscomb and James H. Keller,
eds. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1998), pp. 212-214.
40
See P.L. 99-514, Section 231.
CRS-25
function, performance, or quality for a product or process. The act also directed the
IRS to issue regulations clarifying and implementing the new tests.
Nearly 12 years passed before the IRS issued proposed regulations on the
definition of qualified research in December 1998. Its release provoked a storm of
controversy. Two key issues addressed by the proposal were how to identify
information that is technological in nature and what it means to discover such
information. Most of the comments on the proposed regulations received from tax
practitioners and business taxpayers were critical of positions staked out by the IRS.
In response, the agency made some changes in the proposal and issued what was
intended to be a final set of regulations in December 2000 (T.D. 8930). But about a
month later, the Treasury Department published a notice (Notice 2001-19) retracting
those regulations, requesting further comment “on all aspects” of them, promising a
careful review of all questions and concerns raised about the suspended regulations,
and pledging to issue any changes to the final regulations in proposed form for
additional comment.41 In December 2001, the IRS fulfilled the pledge by releasing
a another set of proposed regulations (REG-112991-01). Tax practitioners generally
responded favorably to the proposal.42
On December 30, 2003, the IRS published final regulations (T.D. 9104) in the
Federal Register clarifying the definition of qualified research.43 The regulations
made some important changes to previous guidance, while reassuring business
taxpayers that the IRS would not challenge positions taken by them if they were
consistent with previous regulations.
Under T.D. 9104, information is considered technological in nature if the process
used to discover the information draws on the principles of the physical or biological
sciences, engineering, or computer science. In addition, the regulations state that
taxpayers do not need to demonstrate that the information “exceeds, expands, or
refines the common knowledge of skilled professionals in the particular field of
science or engineering in which the taxpayer is performing the research” for it to be
considered technological in nature.
The regulations also explain what it means to engage in a “process of
experimentation.” Basically, such a process has three elements. First, the outcome
of a process of experimentation must be uncertain at the outset. Second, the process
must enable researchers to identify a variety of alternative approaches to achieving a
desired outcome. And third, the researchers must use certain scientific methods for
41
Sheryl Stratton, “Treasury Puts Brakes on Research Credit Regs; Practitioners Applaud,”
Tax Notes, vol. 90, no. 6, Feb. 5, 2001, pp. 713-715.
42
For more details on the latest set of proposed regulations and reactions to them in the
business community, see David Lupi-Sher and Sheryl Stratton, “Practitioners Welcome New
Proposed Research Credit Regulations,” Tax Notes, Dec. 24, 2001, vol. 93, no. 13, pp. 16621665.
43
Alison Bennett, “IRS Issues Final Research Credit Rules With Safe Harbor For Qualified
Activities,” Daily Report for Executives, Bureau of National Affairs, Dec. 23, 2003, p. GG2.
CRS-26
evaluating these alternatives (e.g., modeling, simulation, and a systematic trial-anderror investigation).
Although the regulations clarified a number of important questions, they did not
address an issue that is important to many firms: whether or not research to develop
internal-use software is eligible for the credit. In proposed regulations issued in 2001,
the IRS stated that any costs incurred to develop such software were eligible for the
credit only if the software was intended to be unique or novel and to differ in a
“significant and inventive” way from previous software. Not surprisingly, the
meaning of “significant and inventive” has been a subject of contentious debate
between IRS examiners and taxpayers ever since. The regulations offer no guidance
on this question.
Another unresolved issue with widespread reach is the definition of gross
receipts for an affiliated group of companies. How these receipts are characterized
helps determine a business taxpayer’s base amount for the credit. Contradictory
rulings by the IRS on this issue have caused considerable confusion for some U.S.based multinational corporations with majority-owned foreign subsidiaries.44
Lack of Focus on R&D With Large Social Returns
Another key policy issue raised by the credit relates to its efficacy in spurring
increased business investment in R&D projects yielding relatively large spillover
benefits — or its “bang for the buck.” Critics question whether an additional dollar
of the credit leads to more investment in R&D with relatively high social returns than
does an additional dollar of direct government spending on basic or applied research.
For many analysts and lawmakers, an advantage of the credit over direct
spending is that private companies, and not the federal government, decide which
R&D projects are subsidized. Under current federal tax law, firms claim the credit for
projects they decide to fund, and the federal government ends up bearing some of the
cost.45 The tax subsidy enables market forces to determine which projects are pursued
and which are jettisoned. Supporters of the credit believe that such an approach is
more likely to promote valuable diversity in the search for new technical knowledge
and knowhow than a direct subsidy such as federal R&D grants.
But some critics of the credit say that it does a poor job of targeting R&D
projects with large external benefits. While there are no known data to test this claim,
it seems plausible. In general, business managers and owners are driven to seek the
highest possible return on investment. Consequently, in selecting R&D projects to
pursue, they are likely to assign a higher priority to projects likely to earn substantial
profits for their firms in the short run than to projects likely to expand the frontiers of
knowledge in a scientific field but to yield relatively meager returns in the short run.
Such a predisposition is reflected in domestic industrial R&D spending: in 2001,
44
Annette B. Smith, “Continuing Uncertainty on Research Credit Definition of Gross
Receipts,” Tax Adviser, vol. 35, no. 7, July 1, 2004, p. 407.
45
Joseph E. Stiglitz, Economics of the Public Sector (New York: W.W. Norton, 2000),
p. 348.
CRS-27
according to data published by the National Science Foundation, U.S. industry spent
a total of $184.9 billion on R&D, of which 5% went to basic research, 22% to applied
research, and 73% to development.46 Such an allocation creates the impression that
the credit is mainly subsidizing R&D projects with relatively modest social returns.
Some would modify the credit to give firms a stronger incentive to invest in basic
research than in applied research or development. Among the options are redefining
qualified research so that it applies only to basic research, and altering the basic
research credit so that it applies to all basic research undertaken by a business taxpayer
and offers a higher statutory rate than the regular R&E tax credit.
In deciding whether to modify the credit to make it a more effective tool for
stimulating business investment in R&D projects with relatively high social returns,
lawmakers should keep in mind that the federal government has long served as the
primary source of funding for basic research performed in the United States. In 2004,
the federal government funded 62% of this research, compared to shares of 16% for
industry, 13% for colleges and universities, and 9% for other nonprofit
organizations.47 This preponderance is neither surprising nor unjustified, given that
most firms are reluctant to invest more in basic research than applied research or
development because of the difficulty of capturing all or most of the returns on
investment in basic research and the greater uncertainty surrounding those returns.
Legislation in the 109th Congress
to Change the Research Tax Credit
The research tax credit has enjoyed strong bipartisan support since its inception,
and there is no reason to think that this support has weakened in the current Congress.
Numerous bills that would permanently extend the research tax credit have been
introduced in the 109th Congress, most notably H.R. 1454, H.R. 1736, H.R. 2665,
H.R. 4845, H.R. 5058, H.R. 5115, S. 14, S. 627, S. 2109, S. 2199, S. 2357, and S.
2720. Three of these measures (H.R. 1454, H.R. 1736, and S. 627) focus solely on
46
National Science Foundation, Division of Science Resource Studies, National Patterns
of Research and Development: 2003, NSF 05-308 (Arlington, VA: 2005), tables B-4 to B-6,
pp. 74, 76, and 78.
For industry, the NSF defines basic research as “original investigations for the advancement
of scientific knowledge ... which do not have specific commercial objectives, although they
may be in fields of present or potential interest to the reporting company;” applied research
as “research projects which represent investigations directed to the discovery of new
scientific knowledge and which have specific commercial objectives with respect to either
products or processes;” and development as “the systematic use of the knowledge or
understanding gained from research directed toward the production of useful materials,
devices, systems or methods, including design and development of prototypes and
processes,” but excluding quality control, routine product testing, and production.
47
See Brandon Shackelford, “U.S. R&D Continues to Rebound in 2004,” InfoBrief, NSF06306 (Arlington, VA: Jan. 2006), p. 3.
CRS-28
altering the existing credit; H.R. 1736 and S. 627, which are companion bills, have
garnered substantial bipartisan backing.48 The other bills have broader aims and
would modify the credit as a key element of strategies aimed at achieving goals as
varied as improving the domestic climate for technological innovation (S. 2199 and
S. 2720), reducing U.S. dependence on foreign sources of oil (H.R. 2665), and
encouraging an increased flow of equity capital into biomedical research corporations
(H.R. 5115).
Many of the bills that would permanently extend the credit would also change its
design with the intent of enhancing its effectiveness. For example, H.R. 1736, H.R.
2665, H.R. 4845, H.R. 5115, S. 14, S. 627, S. 1020, S. 2109, and S. 2357 would raise
the three rates for the AIRC to 3%, 4%, and 5%. Most of these bills (H.R. 1736, H.R.
4845, H.R. 5115, S. 14, S. 627, S. 1020, S. 2109, and S. 2357) would also establish
a second alternative research tax credit — known as the “alternative simplified credit”
— that would be equal to 12% of a firm’s spending on qualified research in a tax year
above 50% of its average QREs in the three previous tax years; for firms that did not
have qualified research expenditures in at least one of the preceding three tax years,
the credit would be equal to 6% of qualified research expenditures in the current tax
year. In addition, S. 2199 would raise the statutory rates for the regular and basic
research credits from 20% to 40%, and S. 14, S. 2199, S. 2357 would make 100% of
payments made to private research consortia for qualified research eligible for a 20%
tax credit. S. 2720 would break new ground by scrapping the current research credit
starting in 2008 and replacing it with a credit equal to 20% of QREs above 50% of a
firm’s average QREs in the three previous tax years (the credit would be 10% of all
QREs in the current tax year for firms with no QREs in one or more of the three
previous tax years) and making 80% of contract research expenses and 100% of
payments for basic research conducted by certain organizations eligible for the credit.
Recent legislative activity in the 109th Congress suggests that it is more likely to
pass a temporary extension of the credit rather than a permanent one. Two measures
with a provision extending the credit have been considered by either the House or
Senate: H.R. 4297, the tax reconciliation bill, and H.R. 5970, the so-called “trifecta
bill.”
In the case of H.R. 4297, the version passed by the House would have extended
the expired credit through the end of 2006, whereas the version passed by the Senate
would extended it through the end of 2007. In addition, both versions would have
increased the rates of the AIRC to 3%, 4%, and 5% and established the same
alternative simplified credit described above. The conference committee formed to
reconcile differences between the two versions of H.R. 4297 agreed to remove the
provision extending and modifying the credit (along with a number of other popular
expired tax benefits, such as the work opportunity tax credit and the deduction for
state and local sales taxes) from the version that was enacted (the Tax Increase
Prevention and Reconciliation Act of 2005, P.L. 109-222). Two considerations lay
behind this decision: (1) a $70 billion cap on total revenue losses from FY2006
through FY2010 under the FY2006 budget resolution approved by the House and
48
As of April 25, 2006, H.R. 1736 had 127 cosponsors (52 Democrats and 75 Republicans),
and S. 627 had 47 cosponsors (20 Democrats and 27 Republicans).
CRS-29
Senate; and (2) a resolve on the part of the leadership of the House and Senate to
include in H.R. 4297 certain tax provisions (e.g., an extension through 2008 of the
current 15% tax rates on capital gains and dividends) that would be unlikely to pass
in the Senate without the protections the offered by the budget reconciliation process.
Conferees reportedly agreed to include an extension of the expired tax provisions in
a “trailer” bill that could be attached to a pension reform bill (H.R. 4) then in
conference.49
A trailer bill (better known as the trifecta bill) emerged about two months after
President Bush signed H.R. 4297 into law in May 2006 in the form of H.R. 5970. The
bill would combine an extension of various expired tax provisions with an increase
in the federal minimum wage and a reduction in the estate tax. One of its provisions
would retroactively extend the research tax credit through 2007, raise the rates of the
AIRC to 3%, 4%, and 5%, and create an “alternative simplified credit” equal to 12%
of a firm’s QREs in excess of 50% of its average QREs in the three previous tax years
(or 6% of QREs in the current tax year for firms without QREs in each of the three
previous tax years). The increase in the rates for the AIRC and the creation of the new
alternative credit would take effect in 2007. After a brief debate, the House passed
the measure by a vote of 230 to 180 on July 29, 2006. In the Senate, a procedural
motion to end debate on H.R. 5970 and proceed to a vote fell four votes short of
passage on August 3. It now appears unlikely that the Senate will reconsider the bill
before it adjourns near the end of September for the mid-term elections.50 As a result,
there is growing concern among proponents of the credit that it will not be renewed
before the end of the current Congress.
The Bush Administration favors a permanent extension of the research tax credit
and has expressed a willingness to work with Congress to improve its incentive
effect.51
An important consideration (some would say an insurmountable barrier in the
current fiscal climate) for Congress in deciding whether to extend or enhance the
credit is the projected revenue cost of doing so. Recent and projected federal budget
deficits have heightened concern over this cost and are making it difficult to enact
legislation addressing perceived problems with the current credit. The Bush
Administration estimates that a permanent extension of the credit would entail a
revenue loss of $86.4 billion from FY2007 through FY2016.52 Obviously, the revenue
loss would be greater if a permanent extension were coupled with changes in the
design of the credit intended to improve its incentive effect.
49
Wesley Elmore, “Congress Sends $70 Billion Tax Cut to President’s Desk,” Tax Notes,
vol. 777, no. 7, May 15, 2006, pp. 743-745.
50
Kurt Ritterpusch and Jonathan Nicholson, “Estate Tax Cut Dead Before Elections But
Extenders to Remain as Sweetner,” Daily Report for Executives, BNA, Sept. 22, 2006, p.
G-2.
51
Department of the Treasury, General Explanations of the Administration’s Fiscal year
2007 Revenue Proposals (Washington: Feb. 2006), p. 131.
52
Ibid., p. 131.
CRS-30
Table 4 summarizes the provisions of bills in the 109th Congress that would
modify the credit.
Table 4. Bills in the 109th Congress to Extend or Modify
the R&E Tax Credit
Bill Number
Provisions Related to the Credit
H.R. 1454, H.R. 1736,
H.R. 2665, H.R. 4845,
H.R. 5058, H.R. 5115, S.
14, S. 627, S. 2109, S.
2199, and S. 2357
Permanently extends the regular, alternative incremental, basic
research, and energy research credits.
House-Passed Version of
H.R. 4297
Extends the regular, alternative incremental, basic research, and
energy research credits through the end of 2006.
Senate-Passed Version of
H.R. 4297, H.R. 5970, and
S. 1020
Extends the regular, alternative incremental, basic research, and
energy research credits through the end of 2007.
H.R. 1736, H.R. 2665, the
House- and Senate-Passed
Versions of H.R. 4297,
H.R. 4845, H.R. 5115,
H.R. 5970, S. 14, S. 627,
S. 1020, S. 2109, and S.
2357
Raises the three rates of the alternative incremental credit to 3%,
4%, and 5%.
H.R. 1736, the House- and
Senate-Passed Versions of
H.R. 4297, H.R. 4845,
H.R. 5115, H.R. 5970, S.
14, S. 627, S. 1020, S.
2109, and S. 2357
Creates an alternative simplified credit equal to 12% of qualified
research expenses in excess of 50% of the taxpayer’s average
qualified research expenses in the three previous tax years, and
6% of qualified research expenses in the current tax year for
taxpayers with no qualified research expenses in at least one of the
three previous tax years.
S. 14
Makes 100% of payments to certain small firms, universities, and
federal laboratories for contract research eligible for the credit.
Senate-Passed Version of
H.R. 4297, S. 14, S. 2199,
and S. 2357
Makes the full amount of payments to tax-exempt private research
consortia with at least five contributing members eligible for what
is now a 20% research credit.
Source: Congressional Research Service
CRS-26
Responding to a concern that business taxpayers were claiming the credit for
activities that had more to do with product development than genuine technological
innovation, Congress tightened the definition by adding three tests through the Tax
Reform Act of 1986 (TRA86).40 Under the act, qualified research still had to involve
activities eligible for expensing under section 174. But such activities also had to
satisfy the following criteria:
!
they were directed at discovering information that “technological in
nature” and useful in the development of a new or improved
business component of the taxpayer;
!
they constituted “elements of a process of experimentation;”
!
and they were intended to improve the function, performance,
quality or reliability of a business component.41
The act defined a business component as “a product, process, computer software,
technique, formula, or invention” held for sale or lease, or to be used by a taxpayer
in its trade or business. It also specified that research aimed at developing new or
improved internal-use software could qualify for the credit only if it met the general
requirements for the credit, was intended to develop software that was innovative and
not commercially available, and involved “significant economic risk.”
In light of the significant changes made by the act, there was a pressing need for
the IRS to issue final regulations clarifying the meaning and limits of the three new
tests for qualified research. But for reasons that are not entirely clear in hindsight,
the IRS did not issue proposed regulations (REG-105170-97) on the tests until
December 1998.
Among other things, they set forth guidelines for determining whether or not a
business taxpayer investing in R&D has discovered information that is “technological
in nature” and “useful in developing a new or improved business component of the
taxpayer” through a “process of experimentation that relates to a new or improved
function, performance, reliability, or quality.” The IRS proposed that research would
meet what became known as the discovery test if it were intended to obtain
“knowledge that exceeds, expands, or refines the common knowledge of skilled
professionals in the particular field of technology or science.” At the same time, the
agency noted that such a standard did not necessarily mean the credit would be
denied in the case of business taxpayers who made technological advances in an
“evolutionary” manner, or business taxpayers who failed to achieve the desired
result, or business taxpayers who were not the first to achieve a certain technological
advance. In addition, the IRS proposed that research would meet the experimentation
test if it were to draw upon the “principles of physical or biological sciences,
engineering, or computer science (as appropriate)” to evaluate “more than one
alternative designed to achieve a result where the means of achieving the result are
40
41
See P.L. 99-514, Section 231.
U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, General Explanation of the Tax Reform Act
of 1986, JCS-10-87 (Washington: GPO, 1987), pp. 132-134.
CRS-27
uncertain at the outset.” Such an evaluation should involve developing, testing, and
refining or discarding hypotheses related to the design of new or improved business
components.
The release of the proposed regulations unleashed a wave of criticism from the
business community. Much of the dissent focused on the proposed guidelines for
discovering technological information. A widely voiced complaint was that the
common knowledge test violated the intent of Congress and would prove
burdensome and unworkable for tax practitioners because it was too subjective.
Most tax practitioners and business taxpayers who commented on the proposal urged
the IRS to scrap the test.42
After reviewing the many critical comments it received, along with recent case
law and the legislative history of the research tax credit, the IRS issued what it
described as a final set of regulations (T.D. 8930) on the definition of qualified
research in late December 2000. While differing somewhat from the proposed
regulations, the final regulations retained the common knowledge test for
determining whether or not the information gained through research was
technological in nature and useful in the development of a new or improved business
component. But they further clarified the application of the test by noting that the
“common knowledge of skilled professionals in a particular field of science or
engineering” referred to information that would be known by such professionals if
they were to investigate the state of knowledge in a field of science or engineering
before undertaking a research project. The final regulations also carved out a safe
harbor for patents by affirming that a business taxpayer would be presumed to have
passed the common knowledge test if the taxpayer could prove it had been awarded
a patent for a new or improved business component. Moreover, they set down new
standards for determining when the development of computer software for internal
use qualified for the credit. Specifically, research on internal-use software was
eligible for the regular credit or AIRC only if it satisfied the general requirements for
the credits, entailed “significant economic risk,” and led to the development of
innovative software that was not commercially available.
The final regulations seemed to arouse as much opposition within the business
community as the proposed regulations that preceded them. A principal bone of
contention was the IRS’s insistence on retaining the controversial discovery test.
Many tax practitioners also complained that a number of the provisions in the final
regulations were not included in the proposed regulations, precluding public
comment on those provisions.43
These criticisms spurred the IRS to take an unusual procedural step. About one
month after the release of the regulations, the Treasury Department published a
notice (Notice 2001-19) retracting them. The notice also requested further comment
“on all aspects” of the suspended regulations, promised that the IRS would carefully
42
Sheryl Stratton and Barton Massey, “Major Changes to Research Credit Rules Sought at
IRS Reg Hearing,” Tax Notes, May 3, 1999, pp. 623-624.
43
David L. Click, “Treasury Discovers Problems With New Research Tax Credit
Regulations,” Tax Notes, March 12, 2001, p. 1531.
CRS-28
review all questions and concerns raised about them, and committed the IRS to issue
any changes to the final regulations in proposed form for additional comment.44
In December 2001, the IRS delivered on this promise by releasing more
proposed regulations (REG-112991-01). They departed in some important ways
from previous guidance. Among other things, the regulations jettisoned the
requirement set forth in T.D. 8930 that qualified research seek to discover
“knowledge that exceeds, expands, or refines the common knowledge of skilled
professionals in a particular field of science or engineering.” They also revised the
definition of a process of experimentation so that it was seen as a “process designed
to evaluate one or more alternatives to achieve a result where the capability or the
method of achieving that result, or the appropriate design of that result is uncertain
as of the beginning of the taxpayer’s research activities.” The determination of
whether a taxpayer engaged in such a process should be made on the basis of relevant
facts and circumstances. In addition, the proposed regulations defined internal-use
software as software that is developed not to be sold, leased, or licensed to third
parties and specified that internal-use software is eligible for the credit only if it is
intended to be novel in its design or applications. Tax practitioners and business
taxpayers generally welcomed the proposed changes.45
On December 30, 2003, the IRS published still another set of final regulations
(T.D. 9104) clarifying the definition of qualified research and other matters related
to the credit.46 Some analysts viewed them as an attempt by the IRS to follow strictly
congressional intent in altering the definition of qualified research in TRA86.
The regulations specified that information is technological in nature if the
process of experimentation used to discover it relies on the principles of the physical
or biological sciences, engineering, or computer science. They did not retain the
discovery test included in T.D. 8930, but affirmed that taxpayers can be deemed to
have discovered information that is technological in nature by using “existing
technologies.... and principles of the physical or biological sciences, engineering, or
computer science.” Such a discovery would not hinge on whether a taxpayer
succeeds in its quest to develop a new or improved business component. At the same
time, having a patent for a business component would be considered “conclusive
evidence that a taxpayer has discovered information that is technological in nature
that is intended to eliminate uncertainty concerning the development or improvement
of (such a) component.”
44
Sheryl Stratton, “Treasury Puts Brakes on Research Credit Regs; Practitioners Applaud,”
Tax Notes, vol. 90, no. 6, February 5, 2001, pp. 713-715.
45
For more details on the latest set of proposed regulations and reactions to them in the
business community, see David Lupi-Sher and Sheryl Stratton, “Practitioners Welcome New
Proposed Research Credit Regulations,” Tax Notes, December 24, 2001, vol. 93, no. 13, pp.
1662-1665.
46
Alison Bennett, “IRS Issues Final Research Credit Rules With Safe Harbor For Qualified
Activities,” Daily Report for Executives, Bureau of National Affairs, December 23, 2003,
p. GG-2.
CRS-29
In addition, T.D. 9104 sheds additional light on what constituted a “process of
experimentation.” Basically, the regulations noted that such a process had three
critical elements. First, the actual outcome must be uncertain at the outset. Second,
the process must allow researchers to identify more than one approach to achieving
a desired outcome. And third, researchers must use certain scientific methods to
evaluate the efficacy of these alternatives (e.g., modeling, simulation, and a
systematic trial-and-error investigation). The regulations stressed that a process of
experimentation is evaluative in nature, and therefore “often involves refining
throughout much of the process the taxpayer’s understanding of the uncertainty the
taxpayer is trying to address.” A taxpayer’s relevant facts and circumstances should
be considered in determining whether it has engaged in such a process.
Although the regulations clarified a number of important issues regarding the
definition of qualified research, they did not address several other issues that are
important to many firms.
One such issue concerns the circumstances under which spending on the
development of internal-use software can be deemed eligible for the credit. In
proposed regulations issued in 2001, the IRS stated that any costs incurred to develop
such software were eligible for the credit only if the software was intended to be
unique or novel and to differ in a “significant and inventive” way from previous
software. But in the absence of further guidance on the meaning of “significant and
inventive,” disputes between IRS examiners and business taxpayers over the validity
of claims for the credit involving internal-use software are more likely than not. One
analyst has noted that since the release of the final regulations, the IRS has
interpreted the definition of significant and inventive in a way that imposes the same
requirements on the development of internal-use software as the discovery test that
the regulations eliminated.47
Another unresolved issue is the eligibility of research aimed at achieving
significant cost reductions. Cost reduction is not identified in the statute as a purpose
of qualified research, but the research required to lower costs can be as challenging
as research done to improve a business component’s reliability or performance.
Some have pointed out that research that allows a product or process to deliver the
same performance at a reduced cost represents an improvement in performance.48
Yet another unresolved issue with widespread reach is the definition of gross
receipts for an affiliated group of companies. How these receipts are characterized
helps determine a business taxpayer’s base amount for the credit. Contradictory
rulings by the IRS on this issue have caused considerable confusion for some U.S.based multinational corporations with majority-owned foreign subsidiaries.49
47
Christopher J. Ohmes, David S. Hudson, and Monique J. Migneault, “Final Research
Credit Regulations Expected to Immediately Affect IRS Examinations,” Tax Notes, February
23, 2004, p. 1024.
48
Michael D. Rashkin, Research and Development Tax Incentives: Federal, State, and
Foreign (Chicago: CCH Inc., 2003), p. 87.
49
Annette B. Smith, “Continuing Uncertainty on Research Credit Definition of Gross
(continued...)
CRS-30
Lack of Focus on R&D Projects With
Relatively Large Social Returns
In the minds of some critics, another key policy issue raised by the credit relates
to its efficacy in spurring increased business investment in R&D projects yielding
relatively large spillover benefits — or the credit’s “bang for the buck.” They
question whether an additional dollar of the credit leads to more investment in R&D
with relatively high social returns than does an additional dollar of direct government
spending on basic or applied research.
For many analysts and lawmakers, an advantage of the credit over direct
research spending is that private companies, and not the federal government, decide
which R&D projects are subsidized. Under current federal tax law, firms claim the
credit for projects they decide to fund, and the federal government bears some of the
cost.50 The credit, used in combination with the expensing of research spending,
enables market forces to determine which projects are pursued and which are
jettisoned. Supporters of the credit believe that such an approach is more likely to
promote greater diversity in the search for new technical knowledge and knowhow
with profitable commercial applications than a direct subsidy such as federal R&D
grants.
But some critics of the credit say that it does an exceptionally poor job of
targeting R&D projects with large external benefits. While there are no known
studies investigating this claim, it seems plausible. In general, business managers
and owners seek the highest possible return on their investments. Consequently, in
selecting R&D projects to pursue, it makes sense that they would assign a higher
priority to projects likely to earn substantial profits for their firms in the short run
than to projects likely to expand the frontiers of knowledge in a scientific field but
to yield relatively meager returns in the short run. Such a predisposition is more than
a matter of speculation. It is reflected in domestic industrial R&D spending: in 2001,
according to data published by the National Science Foundation, U.S. industry spent
a total of $184.9 billion on R&D, of which 5% went to basic research, 22% to
applied research, and 73% to development.51 This allocation reinforces the
49
(...continued)
Receipts,” Tax Adviser, vol. 35, no. 7, July 1, 2004, p. 407.
50
Joseph E. Stiglitz, Economics of the Public Sector (New York: W.W. Norton, 2000),
p. 348.
51
National Science Foundation, Division of Science Resource Studies, National Patterns
of Research and Development: 2003, NSF 05-308 (Arlington, VA: 2005), tables B-4 to B-6,
pp. 74, 76, and 78. For industry, the NSF defines basic research as “original investigations
for the advancement of scientific knowledge ... which do not have specific commercial
objectives, although they may be in fields of present or potential interest to the reporting
company;” applied research as “research projects which represent investigations directed
to the discovery of new scientific knowledge and which have specific commercial objectives
with respect to either products or processes;” and development as “the systematic use of the
knowledge or understanding gained from research directed toward the production of useful
materials, devices, systems or methods, including design and development of prototypes and
(continued...)
CRS-31
impression that the credit is mainly subsidizing R&D projects with relatively modest
social returns.
Some would modify the credit to give firms a stronger incentive to invest in
basic research than in applied research or development. Among the options are
redefining qualified research so that it applies to what is regarded as basic research
only, and altering the basic research credit so that it offers a higher statutory rate than
the regular R&E tax credit to basic research undertaken by a business taxpayer.
In considering whether to modify the credit to make it a more effective tool for
stimulating business investment in R&D projects with relatively high social returns,
lawmakers should keep in mind that the federal government has long served as the
primary source of funding for basic research performed in the United States. In 2004,
the federal government funded 62% of this research, compared to shares of 16% for
industry, 13% for colleges and universities, and 9% for other nonprofit
organizations.52 This preponderance is neither surprising nor unjustified. Most firms
are disinclined to invest more in basic research than applied research or development
for the simple reasons that it is much more difficult to capture all or most of the
returns on investment in basic research and the returns on this investment are more
uncertain.
Legislation in the 110th Congress
to Modify the Research Tax Credit
By all accounts, the research tax credit has enjoyed strong bipartisan support
since its inception. There is no evidence that this support has weakened in the
current Congress. A major concern raised by any legislative initiative to bolster
permanently the credit’s efficacy is the revenue cost of doing so at a time when the
federal budget is in deficit and the House and Senate are operating under a so-called
“pay-as-you-go” budget rule that requires any increases in discretionary spending or
tax cuts to be offset by revenue increases or reductions in discretionary spending.
To date, at least five bills to modify the research tax credit have been introduced
in the 110th Congress: S. 14, S. 41, S. 592, S. 833, and H.R. 1712. All would extend
the credit: S. 14, S. 41, S. 833, and H.R. 1712 permanently; S. 592 through 2012.
In addition, S. 41(which Senate Finance Committee Chairman Max Baucus
introduced on January 4, 2007) and H.R. 1712 (which Representative Eddie Bernice
Johnson introduced on March 27) would make the following changes in the credit as
of January 1, 2008:
!
replace the current regular, AIRC, and ASIC credits with an
alternative simplified credit equal to 20% of QREs above a
51
(...continued)
processes,” but excluding quality control, routine product testing, and production.
52
See Brandon Shackelford, “U.S. R&D Continues to Rebound in 2004,” InfoBrief, NSF06306 (Arlington, VA: January 2006), p. 3.
CRS-32
base amount of 50% of average QREs in the three previous
tax years — or 10% of QREs for business taxpayers with no
QREs in at least one of the three previous tax years;
!
increase the share of payments for contract research eligible
for the credit from 65% to 80%;
!
simplify the basic research credit so that it is equal to 20% of
payments for contract basic research performed by educational
institutions, certain scientific research organizations, and
certain grant institutions; and
!
require the IRS to complete a study for the House Ways and
Means Committee and the Senate Finance Committee of
taxpayer compliance with the record keeping requirements for
the credit; the study should be completed within one year of
the enactment of the provisions of S. 41 and focus on the
extent to which business taxpayers maintain adequate records
to justify claims for the credit and the burdens imposed on
such taxpayers and the IRS by failures to comply with those
requirements.
The Baucus/Johnson proposal has attracted support from several advocacy groups
representing the interests of the private sector, including the National Association of
Manufacturers.
In his budget proposal for FY2008, President Bush backs a permanent extension
of the research tax credit and expresses a willingness to work with Congress to
improve its incentive effect.53
A critical consideration for Congress in deciding whether to extend the credit
permanently or enhance its incentive effect is the projected revenue cost of doing so.
Recent and projected federal budget deficits have heightened concern over this cost
and the reinstatement of a “pay-as-you-go” budget rule in the current Congress
represent formidable obstacles to passing legislation addressing perceived problems
with the current credit. The Bush Administration estimates that a permanent
extension of the credit would entail a cumulative revenue loss of $117.3 billion from
FY2008 through FY2017.54 There is no question that the revenue loss would be
greater if a permanent extension were coupled with changes in the design of the
credit intended to improve its efficacy.
53
Department of the Treasury, General Explanations of the Administration’s Fiscal Year
crsphpgw
2008 Revenue Proposals (Washington: February 2007), p. 105.
54
Ibid., p. 131.