Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending
Marc Labonte
Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
September 8, 2015
Congressional Research Service
7-5700
www.crs.gov
R44185


Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

Summary
The worsening of the financial crisis in 2008 led the Federal Reserve (Fed) to revive an obscure
provision found in Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act (12 U.S.C. 344) to extend credit to
nonbank financial firms for the first time since the 1930s. Section 13(3) provides the Fed with
greater flexibility than its normal lending authority. Using this authority, the Fed created six
broadly based facilities (of which only five were used) to provide liquidity to “primary dealers”
(i.e., certain large investment firms) and to revive demand for commercial paper and asset-backed
securities. More controversially, the Fed provided special, tailored assistance exclusively to four
firms that the Fed considered “too big to fail”—AIG, Bear Stearns, Citigroup, and Bank of
America.
Credit outstanding (in the form of cash or securities) authorized by Section 13(3) peaked at $710
billion in November 2008. At present, all credit extended under Section 13(3) has been repaid
with interest and all Section 13(3) facilities have expired. Contrary to popular belief, under
Section 13(3), the Fed earned income of more than $30 billion and did not suffer any losses on
those transactions. These transactions exposed the taxpayer to greater risks than traditional
lending to banks through the discount window, however, because in some cases the terms of the
programs had fewer safeguards.
The Fed’s use of Section 13(3) in the crisis raised fundamental policy issues: Should the Fed be
lender of last resort to banks only, or to all parts of the financial system? Should the Fed lend to
firms that it does not supervise? How much discretion does the Fed need to be able respond to
unpredictable financial crises? How can Congress ensure that taxpayers are not exposed to
losses? Do the benefits of emergency lending outweigh the costs, including moral hazard? How
can Congress ensure that Section 13(3) is not used to “bail out” failing firms? Should the Fed tell
Congress and the public to whom it has lent?
The restrictions in Section 13(3) placed few limits on the Fed’s actions in 2008. However, in
2010, the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (P.L. 111-203) added
more restrictions to Section 13(3), attempting to ban future assistance to failing firms while
maintaining the Fed’s ability to create broadly based facilities. The Dodd-Frank Act also required
records for actions taken under Section 13(3) to be publicly released with a lag and required the
Government Accountability Office (GAO) to audit those programs for operational integrity,
accounting, financial reporting, internal controls, effectiveness of collateral policies, favoritism,
and use of third-party contractors.
Some Members of Congress believe that the Dodd-Frank Act did not sufficiently limit the Fed’s
discretion. In the 114th Congress, legislation—including H.R. 2625, H.R. 3189, and S. 1320—has
been introduced that would further modify Section 13(3). On July 29, 2015, H.R. 3189 was
ordered to be reported by the House Financial Services Committee. It would raise the threshold
for using Section 13(3), tighten the definition of solvency, limit borrowers to financial firms, and
provide a formula for setting the interest rate. A Fed governor has opposed further reducing the
Fed’s discretion under Section 13(3) on the grounds that the Fed needs “to be able to respond
flexibly and nimbly” to future threats to financial stability. Although Section 13(3) must be used
“for the purpose of providing liquidity to the financial system,” some Members of Congress have
expressed interest in—while others have expressed opposition to—the Fed using Section 13(3) to
assist financially struggling entities, including states, municipalities, and territories of the United
States.
This report does not discuss lending to banks under the Fed’s normal authority or other actions
taken by the Fed or federal government during the financial crisis.
Congressional Research Service

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

Contents
Introduction ..................................................................................................................................... 1
History of Section 13(3) .................................................................................................................. 1
Use of Section 13(3) in 2008 ........................................................................................................... 2
Broadly Based Facilities ........................................................................................................... 3
Special Assistance to Firms Deemed “Too Big to Fail” ............................................................ 6
Limits on Emergency Lending ........................................................................................................ 8
Restrictions on Emergency Lending in Place in 2008 .............................................................. 8
Changes in the Dodd Frank Act .............................................................................................. 10
Oversight Requirements ........................................................................................................... 11
Policy Issues .................................................................................................................................. 12
Why Was the Fed Established as a “Lender of Last Resort”? ................................................. 12
Who Should Have Access to the Lender of Last Resort?........................................................ 13
Lending to Nonbank Financial Firms?.............................................................................. 13
Lending to Nonfinancial Firms? ....................................................................................... 14
Lending to Government or Government Chartered Entities? ........................................... 14
Lending to Itself? .............................................................................................................. 15
What Are the Potential Costs of the Fed Making Loans to Nonbanks? .................................. 15
How Much Discretion Should the Fed Be Granted? ............................................................... 16
What Rate Should the Fed Charge? ........................................................................................ 18
Should Borrowers’ Identities Be Kept Confidential? .............................................................. 19
Selected Legislation in the 114th Congress .................................................................................... 20
H.R. 3189 ................................................................................................................................ 20
S. 1320 .................................................................................................................................... 20
H.R. 2625 ................................................................................................................................ 21

Figures
Figure 1. Loans Outstanding Under Broadly Based Facilities ........................................................ 6
Figure 2. Loans Outstanding for Special Assistance ....................................................................... 8

Tables
Table 1. Broadly Based Facilities Created in 2008 Under Section 13(3) ........................................ 4

Appendixes
Appendix. Details on the Actions Taken Under Section 13(3) in 2008 ......................................... 22

Contacts
Author Contact Information .......................................................................................................... 30
Acknowledgments ......................................................................................................................... 30
Congressional Research Service

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

Introduction
The financial crisis that began in 2007 and deepened in 2008 was the worst since the Great
Depression. The federal policy response was swift, large, creative, and controversial, creating
unprecedented tools to grapple with financial instability.1 Particularly notable were the actions
taken by the Federal Reserve (Fed) under its broad emergency lending authority, Section 13(3) of
the Federal Reserve Act (12 U.S.C. 344). This obscure section of the act was described in a 2002
review as follows: “To some this lending legacy is likely a harmless anachronism, to others it’s
still a useful insurance policy, and to others it’s a ticking time bomb of political chicanery.”2
Under normal authority, the Fed faces statutory limitations on whom it may lend to, what it may
accept as collateral, and for how long it may lend. Because many of the actions it took during the
crisis did not meet these criteria, Section 13(3) was used to authorize most of the Fed’s
emergency facilities created during the crisis to provide credit to nonbank financial firms. More
controversially, the Fed also invoked Section 13(3) to prevent the failure of Bear Stearns and
American International Group (AIG), two financial firms that it deemed “too big to fail.” The
Federal Reserve (Fed) also lent extensively to banks through the discount window and newly
created facilities and undertook “quantitative easing” (large scale purchases of Treasury and
mortgage-backed securities) during the crisis. Because these actions were taken under its normal
authority, they are beyond the scope of this report, as are other actions taken by the federal
government during the crisis.
The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (hereinafter, the Dodd-Frank
Act; P.L. 111-203) limited the Fed’s discretion under Section 13(3), but some Members of
Congress believe that these changes were insufficient. This report provides a review of the history
of Section 13(3), including its use in 2008. It discusses the Fed’s authority under Section 13(3)
before and after the Dodd-Frank Act. It then discusses policy issues and legislation to amend
Section 13(3).
History of Section 13(3)
One of the main reasons the Fed was created was to act as a “lender of last resort,” by providing
liquidity in the form of short-term loans to banks through the discount window. The Fed still
provides that service today, but the amount of liquidity extended is insignificant typically. Over
time, it became expected that banks would meet their short-term borrowing needs through private
markets under normal conditions. Discount window lending to banks occurs under the Fed’s
normal statutory authority.
Nonbank financial firms also face liquidity needs, but the history of Fed lending to nonbanks is
much more limited. Section 13(3) has been invoked rarely since it was enacted in 1932. The Fed
used it to make 123 loans to nonfinancial firms totaling $1.5 million from 1932 to 1936, until that
authority was superseded by new authority (Section 13b, which was subsequently repealed).3

1 For an overview, see CRS Report R43413, Costs of Government Interventions in Response to the Financial Crisis: A
Retrospective
, by Baird Webel and Marc Labonte.
2 David Fettig, Lender of More than Last Resort, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, December 1, 2002,
https://www.minneapolisfed.org/publications/the-region/lender-of-more-than-last-resort.
3 Howard Hackley, Lending Functions of the Federal Reserve Banks, Federal Reserve, 1973, p. 130. See also David
Fettig, Lender of More than Last Resort, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, December 1, 2002,
https://www.minneapolisfed.org/publications/the-region/lender-of-more-than-last-resort; James Dolley, “The Industrial
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
1

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

Section 13(3) can also be used to authorize lending to banks. After 1936, the Fed invoked Section
13(3) occasionally to make nonmember banks and credit unions eligible to borrow at the discount
window before 1980, when nonmember banks were permitted to access the discount window.4
Section 13(3) authority was not used to extend credit to nonbanks from 1936 to 2008. This
authority was then used extensively beginning in 2008 in response to the financial crisis—in very
different ways than it had been used previously.
Use of Section 13(3) in 2008
Section 13(3) was used to authorize multiple actions taken by the Fed when financial conditions
worsened at two points in 2008- around the time the investment bank Bear Stearns experienced
difficulties in March and following the failure of the investment bank Lehman Brothers in
September. Credit extended under Section 13(3) in 2008 can be divided into two broad
categories:
1. broadly based facilities to address liquidity problems in specific markets and
2. exclusive, tailored assistance to prevent the disorderly failure of individual firms
deemed too big to fail.5
Credit outstanding (in the form of cash or securities) under Section 13(3) peaked at $710 billion
in November 2008.6 Currently, all credit extended under Section 13(3) has been repaid with
interest and all 13(3) facilities have expired.7 Contrary to popular belief, under Section 13(3), the
Fed earned net income of more than $30 billion (more than half of which is related to AIG8) and
did not suffer any losses on those transactions.9 Nevertheless, some of these transactions exposed
the taxpayer to greater ex ante risks than the discount window because the terms of the programs
had fewer safeguards—in some cases involving non-recourse loans10 and troubled asset

(...continued)
Advance Program of the Federal Reserve System,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 50, no. 2, February 1936,
p. 229.
4 Nationally chartered banks are required to be members of the Federal Reserve System. State chartered banks have the
option of becoming members. Until the Monetary Control Act of 1980 (P.L. 96-221), only member banks were allowed
to borrow at the discount window.
5 For more information, see CRS Report R42150, Systemically Important or “Too Big to Fail” Financial Institutions,
by Marc Labonte.
6 Total does not include asset guarantees for Citigroup and Bank of America, under which funds were never used.
7 One facility, Maiden Lane I, still held more than $1 billion of assets at the end of 2014. It has no debt and is not
authorized to purchase additional assets.
8 In addition to the $30 billion in net income received by the Fed, Treasury received an additional $17.6 billion as net
income on the sale of equity that the Fed originally received (and subsequently transferred to the Treasury) as
recompense for the Fed’s loan to AIG.
9 The income can be considered to be profits if defined as payments received in excess of principal outlayed. This
report does not consider whether the Fed earned economic profits on these transactions. For example, the income from
these transactions may have been partially offset by lost income if the Fed offset those facilities by holding fewer
Treasury securities on its balance sheet. One study attempts to estimate this effect for the Fed’s broadly based facilities
(but not for its special assistance to firms deemed “too big to fail.”) For Section 13(3) facilities, it estimates that the
facilities earned $8.1 billion in interest and fee income, but the “cost of funds” for those programs was $1.1 billion, so
the Fed earned $7 billion net income over the life of the programs. See Michael Fleming and Nicholas Klagge, “Income
Effects of Federal Reserve Liquidity Facilities,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Current Issues in Economics and
Finance
, vol. 17, no. 1, 2011, http://www.nyfedeconomists.org/research/current_issues/ci17-1.pdf.
10 Under a non-recourse loan, the creditor has no right to seek payment beyond the collateral posted in the event that the
loan is not repaid.
Congressional Research Service
2

link to page 25 link to page 7 Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

purchases, for example. The next two sections summarize this experience, with more detail
provided in the Appendix.11
Broadly Based Facilities
The Fed created six broadly based facilities under Section 13(3) in 2008 to extend credit to all
eligible borrowers within a particular class of nonbank financial firms or to a particular segment
of the nonbank financial market:
 The Term Securities Lending Facility (TSLF) and the Primary Dealer Credit
Facility (PDCF) were created to assist primary dealers (a group of investment
firms that are the Fed’s counterparties for open market operations).
 The Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity
Facility (AMLF), the Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF), and the
Money Market Investor Funding Facility (MMIFF) were created to support the
commercial paper market (the MMIFF was never used).
 The Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF) was created to support
the asset-backed securities (ABS) market.
 provides a summary of the terms and uses of these facilities. The CPFF was the
largest facility, and TALF was the smallest. As can be seen in the table, none of
these facilities extended credit after 2010.
Table 1 provides a summary of the terms and uses of these facilities. The CPFF was the largest
facility, and TALF was the smallest. As can be seen in the table, none of these facilities extended
credit after 2010.


11 For more information, see Federal Reserve, Office of the Inspector General, The Federal Reserve’s Section 13(3)
Lending Facilities to Support Overall Market Liquidity
, November 2010, http://oig.federalreserve.gov/reports/
FRS_Lending_Facilities_Report_final-11-23-10_web.pdf. See also U.S. Government Accountability Office (GAO),
Federal Reserve System: Opportunities Exist to Strengthen Policies and Processes for Managing Emergency
Assistance
, GAO-11-696, July 21, 2011, http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d11696.pdf. The Fed was required to report to
Congress on assistance provided pursuant to Section 13(3); these reports are posted at http://www.federalreserve.gov/
monetarypolicy/bst_reports.htm. See also the Fed’s website Credit and Liquidity Programs and the Balance Sheet,
available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_archive.htm.
Congressional Research Service
3


Table 1. Broadly Based Facilities Created in 2008 Under Section 13(3)

Usage
Terms and Conditions
Loans
Recourse/Haircut
Term
Date
Outstanding
Total
Number of
Announced-
Facility
at Peak
Income
Participants
Lending Rate/Fee
Expired
Term Securities
$235.5 bil ion
$0.8 bil ion
18
Set at auction, with minimum
Yes/Yes
28 days
Mar. 11, 2008-
Lending Facility (TSLF)
on Oct. 1,
fee of 10 to 25 basis points
Feb. 1, 2010
2008
Primary Dealer Credit
$146.6 bil ion
$0.6 bil ion
18
Rate set equal to Fed’s discount
Yes/Yes
overnight
Mar. 16, 2008-
Facility (PDCF)
on Oct. 1,
rate; fees of up to 40 basis
Feb. 1, 2010
2008
points for frequent users
Asset-Backed
$152.1 bil ion
$0.5 bil ion
11 from 7
Fed’s discount rate
No/No
120 or 270
Sept. 19, 2008-
Commercial Paper
on Oct. 1,
bank holding
days
Feb. 1, 2010
Money Market Mutual
2008
companies
Fund Liquidity Facility
(AMLF)
Commercial Paper
$348.2 bil ion
$6.1 bil ion
120
Markups of 100 to 300 basis
No/No
90 days
Oct. 7, 2008-Feb.
Funding Facility (CPFF)
on Jan. 21,
points over overnight index
1, 2010
2009
swap rate; fees of 10 to 100
basis points
Term Asset-Backed
$48.2 bil ion
$1.6 bil ion
177
Various markups over LIBOR
No/Yes
5 years for
Nov. 25, 2008-
Securities Loan Facility
on Mar. 17,
to Fed;
or federal funds rate; 10 to 20
CMBS, 3 years
Mar. 31, 2010
(TALF)
2010
$0.7 bil ion
basis point administrative fee
for other
(June 30, 2010,
to Treasury
for new CMBS)
Sources: Federal Reserve, Office of the Inspector General, The Federal Reserve’s Section 13(3) Lending Facilities to Support Overall Market Liquidity, November 2010; Federal
Reserve, Quarterly Report on Federal Reserve Balance Sheet Developments, various dates. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal Reserve System: Opportunities Exist to
Strengthen Policies and Processes for Managing Emergency Assistance
, GAO-11-696, July 21, 2011.
Notes: Expiration date for facilities marks date after which no new activities were authorized. For some facilities, existing loans remained outstanding after the
expiration date. Some facilities did not begin operations on the date announced. Recourse only includes to participant’s assets; Fed had recourse for AMLF and TALF
only in the case of material misrepresentation.

CRS-4

link to page 9 Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

All the facilities except for TALF were used to provide short-term liquidity, conceptually
comparable to the role of the discount window. The Fed made short-term loans through the PDCF
and TSLF to primary dealers to ensure that other primary dealers did not experience liquidity
crises in the wake of the primary dealer Bear Stearns’s financial difficulties. Commercial paper is
short-term debt issued by financial firms (including banks), nonfinancial firms, and pass-through
entities that issue ABS. The Fed set up its commercial paper facilities after a run on money
market mutual funds, who were large purchasers of commercial paper.
Through TALF, the Fed made three- and five-year loans to investors to encourage them to
purchase ABS other than residential mortgage-backed securities (MBS).12 ABS are an alternative
way that banks and nonbanks finance loans to consumers and businesses, and they are often
referred to as a form of shadow banking—activities that substitute for traditional bank lending
and deposit-taking.13 The decline in the value and liquidity of ABS during the crisis resulted in a
sharp contraction in their issuance, reducing the credit available to households and businesses.
Figure 1 plots loans outstanding for these five facilities from March 2008, when the first facility
was created, to October 2014, when the last loan was repaid. Usage of the facilities spiked
beginning in mid-September 2008, peaked in December 2008, and then tapered off relatively
quickly in 2009 as financial conditions stabilized. From 2010 to 2014, there were only residual
amounts of credit outstanding through TALF. According to GAO, use of the facilities was
relatively concentrated among a small number of borrowers—which may reflect concentration in
those markets.14

12 Other Federal Reserve and federal emergency programs beyond the scope of this report were aimed at supporting
mortgage-backed securities (MBS).
13 For more information, see CRS Report R43345, Shadow Banking: Background and Policy Issues, by Edward V.
Murphy.
14 U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal Reserve System: Opportunities Exist to Strengthen Policies and
Processes for Managing Emergency Assistance
, GAO-11-696, July 21, 2011, Tables 12, 20, 25, 27,
31, http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d11696.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
5

link to page 25 Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

Figure 1. Loans Outstanding Under Broadly Based Facilities
(March 2008-October 2014)
$700,000
$600,000
$500,000
s
n
$400,000
oilli $300,000
m
$200,000
$100,000
$0
TSLF
TALF
AMLF
PDCF
CPFF

Source: Federal Reserve, H.4.1 release, various dates.
Notes: For TSLF, lending took the form of Treasury securities. For CPFF, commercial paper was purchased. For
other facilities, lending took the form of cash. See Appendix for details.
Special Assistance to Firms Deemed “Too Big to Fail”
Section 13(3) was also invoked to provide exclusive, tailored assistance to prevent the disorderly
failure of four large financial firms on an ad hoc basis:
 In March 2008, the Fed assisted JP Morgan Chase’s takeover of Bear Stearns to
prevent the latter’s failure. Assistance was provided through first, a short-term
bridge loan and then, the purchase of Bear Stearns troubled assets, financed
through a $29 billion Fed loan;
 In September 2008, the Fed prevented AIG’s failure by initially providing it a
line of credit of $85 billion. The assistance was restructured several times, with
the loan eventually replaced by a Fed pledge to purchase up to $52.5 billion in
troubled assets in November (and the rest of the assistance shifted to Treasury);
 In November 2008, the Fed, Treasury, and the Federal Deposit Insurance
Cooperation (FDIC) announced a joint agreement to guarantee a more than $300
billion portfolio of Citigroup’s troubled assets;
 In January 2009, the Fed, Treasury, and FDIC announced a joint agreement to
guarantee a $118 billion portfolio of Bank of America’s troubled assets to assist
its takeover of Merrill Lynch. The agreement was never finalized.
These actions were motivated by concerns that the failure of any of these firms would increase
financial instability—in other words, the Fed viewed the firms as too big to fail or too
interconnected to fail.15 In all four cases, the Fed did not limit its action to those of a traditional

15 For more information, see CRS Report R42150, Systemically Important or “Too Big to Fail” Financial Institutions,
by Marc Labonte.
Congressional Research Service
6

link to page 11 link to page 11 Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

lender of last resort because problems at the firms were not limited to a need for short-term
liquidity. In the Fed’s view, the firms were not insolvent, but were vulnerable to losing access to
funding markets which could cause their failure.16 An evaluation of whether these four
institutions were solvent at the time was hampered by the “fog of war”—the Fed was forced to
judge their solvency hastily in the context of a crisis, in which the value of all assets was rapidly
declining and it was uncertain whether the decline was temporary or permanent. While some have
described this assistance as a bail out of failing firms, in all four cases, there was not clear
evidence that the firms were insolvent in the classic sense.17 In the case of Bear Stearns, JP
Morgan Chase was willing to pay more to acquire it than the value of the Fed’s assistance, but
later reported losses related to the transaction.18 The other three firms all eventually returned to
profitability once the crisis had ended, which means they may or may not have been solvent at the
time of the intervention.
As notable as who the Fed assisted is whom it chose not to assist—Lehman Brothers. Although
Lehman Brothers was an investment firm similar to Bear Stearns, the Fed chose not to help
facilitate its takeover by Barclays. Instead, Lehman Brothers filed for bankruptcy. Then-Chairman
Bernanke later testified that the Fed declined to assist Lehman Brothers because it held
inadequate collateral19—although some of the Fed’s other interventions under Section 13(3)
featured concerns about inadequate collateral. While one cannot say what would have happened
in the counterexample where the Fed had assisted Lehman Brothers, Lehman Brothers’ failure
marked the worsening of the financial crisis.
Troubled assets were purchased from Bear Stearns and AIG through three limited liability
corporations (LLCs) created and controlled by the Fed named Maiden Lane. Figure 2 shows
loans outstanding to the Maiden Lanes and directly to AIG. The direct loan to AIG was paid off in
2011. The asset holdings and loans of the Maiden Lanes tapered off slowly until 2011, when the
pace accelerated. The final Maiden Lane loan was fully repaid in 2012. Although Citigroup and
Bank of America were banks, this assistance was nevertheless authorized under Section 13(3)
because it took the form of asset guarantees. The guarantees to Citigroup and Bank of America
are not shown in Figure 2 because Fed funds were never extended under those guarantees.

16 As described in the reports pursuant to Section 129, available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/
bst_reports.htm. In the case of Bank of America, losses were greatest at Merrill Lynch, which Bank of America was in
the process of acquiring. The Fed (and Treasury) may have been most concerned that if Bank of America was not
offered special assistance, the merger would fall through and Merrill Lynch would experience a disorderly failure.
17 The solvency of Bear Stearns and AIG is analyzed in William Cline and Joseph Gagnon, Lehman Died, Bagehot
Lives:
Why Did the Fed and Treasury Let a Major Wall Street Bank Fail?, Peterson Institute for International
Economics, Policy Brief no. PB 13-21, http://www.piie.com/publications/pb/pb13-21.pdf.
18 “JPMorgan Took a Bath on Bear Stearns Sale: Dimon,” Reuters, Oct 10, 2012, http://www.cnbc.com/id/49361397/.
19 Chairman Ben S. Bernanke, Remarks before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate
Sept. 23, 2008, available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20080923a1.htm.
Congressional Research Service
7

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

Figure 2. Loans Outstanding for Special Assistance
$140,000
$120,000
$100,000
s
n

$80,000
oilli $60,000
m
$40,000
$20,000
$0
ML I
ML II
ML III
AIG

Source: Federal Reserve, H.4.1 release, various dates.
Notes: ML I = Maiden Lane I, facility to assist the takeover of Bear Stearns; ML II = Maiden Lane II, facility to
assist AIG; ML III = Maiden Lane III, facility to assist AIG; AIG = direct loan from Fed to AIG. Funds were never
extended under asset guarantee to Citigroup and Bank of America.
Limits on Emergency Lending
Under normal authority, the Fed faces statutory limitations on whom it may lend to, what it may
accept as collateral, and for how long it may lend.20 If the Fed wishes to extend credit that does
not meet these criteria, it can turn to Section 13(3).
Restrictions on Emergency Lending in Place in 2008
Section 13(3) was not in the original Federal Reserve Act of 1913; it was added in 1932 (47 Stat
715). Until the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010, the authority was very broad, with few limitations. It
required that21
 at least five of the seven Fed governors find that there are “unusual and exigent
circumstances”22—while this phrase has no specific legal definition, it implies
that financial conditions are not normal;23

20 For more information on the discount window, see https://www.frbdiscountwindow.org/en/Pages/General-
Information/The-Discount-Window.aspx.
21 The interpretation of the statute that follows each bullet is based on Alexander Mehra, “Legal Authority in Unusual
and Exigent Circumstances: The Federal Reserve and the Financial Crisis,” University Of Pennsylvania Journal of
Business Law
, vol. 13, no. 1, pp. 221-227.
22 Unusual and exigent circumstances is not defined, but is considered a high threshold. See Alexander Mehra, “Legal
Authority in Unusual and Exigent Circumstances: The Federal Reserve and the Financial Crisis,” University Of
Pennsylvania Journal of Business Law
, vol. 13, no. 1, pp. 221-227, citing Thomas C. Baxter, Jr., Gen Counsel, Fed.
Res. Bank of N.Y., “The Legal Position of the Central Bank, The Case of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York,” Jan.
19, 2009, available at https://www.google.com/search?q=
thomas+c.+Baxter%2C+Jr.%2C+The+Legal+Position+of+the+Central+bank&ie=utf-8&oe=utf-8.
Congressional Research Service
8

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

 the Fed may “discount (for) any individual, partnership, or corporation”—that is,
assistance should take the form of a loan, and the loan may be made to private
individuals or businesses;
 the borrower must present “notes, drafts, and bills of exchange endorsed or
otherwise secured to the satisfaction of the Federal Reserve Bank”—that is, the
loan must be backed by collateral approved by the Fed;24
 the Fed shall charge an interest rate consistent with the same limitations applied
to the discount window;25 and
 “the Federal Reserve Bank shall obtain evidence that such individual,
partnership, or corporation is unable to secure adequate credit accommodations
from other banking institutions”—that is, there must be evidence that the
borrower does not have private alternatives.
These restrictions did not prevent the Fed from taking several unorthodox actions in 2008.
Notably, in some cases, “In form, these transactions were structured as loans. But in substance,
they permitted the Fed to move assets off the balance sheets of these institutions and onto its
own.”26 In the cases of AIG and Bear Stearns, the Fed purchased their assets through limited
liability corporations that it created and controlled (called Maiden Lane I, II, and III). This
structure allowed the Fed to comply with Section 13(3) because the asset purchases were financed
through loans from the Fed to the Maiden Lanes. The loans were backed by those assets and were
eventually repaid when the assets were sold off or matured.27 In the cases of Citigroup and Bank
of America, the firms were offered a guarantee in the event that they suffered losses on a portfolio
of assets, structured as a loan “provided ... on a nonrecourse basis, except with respect to interest
payments and fees.”28 The Fed also made a loan directly to AIG backed by the company’s general
assets, meaning there were no specific securities pledged in the event of nonpayment.29
Furthermore, the Fed has interpreted “unusual and exigent circumstances” to mean that assistance

(...continued)
23 If five governors are not available, the decision can be made unanimously by the governors available (12 U.S.C.
248r). On at least one occasion in 2008, because of vacancies on the Federal Reserve Board action under Section 13(3)
was approved with only four governors voting. See Federal Reserve, Report Pursuant to Section 129: Bridge Loan to
The Bear Stearns Companies
, http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/129bearstearnsbridgeloan.pdf;
Federal Open Market Committee, Conference Call of the Federal Open Market Committee on March 10, 2008,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/FOMC20080310confcall.pdf.
24 According to a working paper by legal counsel at the Fed, this requirement placed “virtually no restrictions on the
form a written credit instrument must take in order to be eligible for discount.” David H. Small and James A. Clouse,
“The Scope of Monetary Policy Actions Authorized under the Federal Reserve Act,” Federal Reserve, working paper,
July 19, 2004, p. 15.
25 The discount window standards referenced here state that rates shall be “fixed with a view of accommodating
commerce and business” (12 U.S.C. 357).
26 Alexander Mehra, “Legal Authority in Unusual and Exigent Circumstances: The Federal Reserve and the Financial
Crisis,” University Of Pennsylvania Journal of Business Law, vol. 13, no. 1, p. 235. This article also presents
arguments that the Fed nevertheless exceeded its legal authority for some transactions under Section 13(3).
27 The Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF) was also structured as a limited liability corporation (LLC) that
purchased commercial paper and was financed by loans from the Fed. The Fed also created LLCs associated with the
Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF).
28 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Report Pursuant to Section 129: Authorization to Provide
Residual Financing to Bank of America Corporation
, January 15, 2009, http://www.federalreserve.gov/
monetarypolicy/files/129bofa.pdf.
29 Federal Reserve, Report Pursuant to Section 129: Secured Credit Facility Authorized for American International
Group
, September 16, 2008, http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/129aigseccreditfacility.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
9

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

should be temporary, but routinely extended each facility’s expiration date until demand for credit
had waned.
One statutory revision to Section 13(3) affected the Fed’s actions in 2008. In 1991, the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act (P.L. 102-242; 12 U.S.C. 1811) contained a
provision that removed the requirement that collateral be “of the kind and maturities made
eligible for discount for member banks” at the discount window. According to the sponsor,
Senator Christopher Dodd, the rationale for the provision was to enable the Fed “to make fully
secured loans to securities firms in instances similar to the 1987 stock market crash.”30 Securities
firms, it was argued, would not necessarily hold the same sort of assets that banks used as
collateral at the discount window. By removing this language, the Fed had discretion to lend
against a broader array of assets.
Changes in the Dodd Frank Act
Concerns in Congress about some of the Fed’s actions under Section 13(3) during the financial
crisis led to the section’s amendment in Section 1101 of the Dodd-Frank Act. Generally, the
intention of the provision in the Dodd-Frank Act was to prevent the Fed from bailing out failing
firms while preserving enough of its discretion that it could create broadly based facilities to
address unpredictable market-access problems during a crisis.31 Specifically, the Dodd-Frank Act
 replaced “individual, partnership, or corporation” with “participant in any
program or facility with broad-based eligibility”;
 required that assistance be “for the purpose of providing liquidity to the financial
system, and not to aid a failing financial company.” It ruled out lending to an
insolvent firm, defined as in any bankruptcy, resolution, or insolvency
proceeding;
 required that loans be secured “sufficient(ly) to protect taxpayers from losses,”
and that collateral be assigned a “lendable value” that is “consistent with sound
risk management practices”;
 forbade “a program or facility that is structured to remove assets from the
balance sheet of a single and specific company”; and
 required the “prior approval of the Secretary of the Treasury.”
Proponents of the Dodd-Frank Act believed that the Fed’s authority to provide assistance to too
big to fail firms was no longer necessary because of other changes in the act. The Fed justified its
special assistance to too big to fail firms during the crisis on the grounds that these firms could
not be wound down without causing financial instability under existing law because of perceived
shortcomings of the bankruptcy process. Fed officials called for the creation of a resolution
regime for non-banks modeled on the FDIC’s bank resolution regime so that such assistance
would not be necessary in the future.32 Title II of the Dodd-Frank Act created such a regime,

30 Senator Christopher Dodd, Congressional Record, November 27, 1991, p. 36131. See also Walker Todd, “FDICIA’s
Emergency Liquidity Provisions,” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Review, Third Quarter, 1993.
31 See, for example, the Joint Explanatory Statement of the Committee of the Conference to P.L. 111-203, H.Rept. 111-
517, 111th Congress, June 29, 2010.
32 See, for example, Chairman Ben S. Bernanke, “Federal Reserve Programs To Strengthen Credit Markets And The
Economy,” Testimony Before the Committee on Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives, February 10, 2009,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20090210a.htm.
Congressional Research Service
10

link to page 19 Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

called the “Orderly Liquidation Authority.”33 While critics oppose Title II for reasons beyond the
scope of this report, proponents of the Dodd-Frank Act argue that eliminating the Fed’s ability to
prevent firms from failing under Section 13(3) will not result in financial instability now that
firms can undergo an orderly resolution under Title II. According to Ben Bernanke, chairman of
the Fed during the financial crisis, “With the creation of the [orderly] liquidation authority, the
ability of the Fed to make loans to individual troubled firms like Bear [Stearns] and AIG was no
longer needed and, appropriately, was eliminated.”34
As Section 13(3) was only for “unusual and exigent circumstances” and had not been used for
decades, the Fed had not promulgated a rule governing its use as of 2008, even though it had the
discretion to do so. The Dodd-Frank Act also required the Fed to promulgate a rule implementing
Section 1101 “as soon as is practicable,” and the Fed issued a proposed rule in 2013.35 Some
public comments criticized the rule for not adding meaningful quantitative or qualitative
definitions to the terms “unusual and exigent circumstances,” collateral, penalty rate, insolvency,
broadly based, or the duration of assistance.36 Generally, critics believe that the vagueness of the
rule is undesirable for the same reason that proponents view it as desirable—because it maximize
the Fed’s future discretion.37 To date, the proposed rule has not been finalized.
Oversight Requirements
Following the use of Section 13(3) in 2008, three laws have been enacted affecting congressional
oversight of emergency lending.
First, in 2008, Section 129 of the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act (P.L. 110-343) required
the Fed to report to the congressional committees of jurisdiction on the terms of and justification
for assistance within seven days of providing assistance under Section 13(3), with updates every
60 days.38
Second, in 2009, an amendment to the Helping Families Save Their Homes Act (Section 801 of
P.L. 111-22) included a provision that allows Government Accountability Office (GAO) audits of
“any action taken by the Board under ... Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act with respect to
a single and specific partnership or corporation.” This provision allowed GAO audits of the
Maiden Lane facilities and the asset guarantees of Citigroup and Bank of America, but it
maintained audit restrictions on non-emergency activities and the broadly based emergency
lending facilities.
Third, Section 1101 of the Dodd-Frank Act required that details on the assistance provided under
Section 13(3) be reported to the committees of jurisdiction within seven days, with regular
updates. Section 1103 required lending records (including details on the identity of the borrower

33 For more information, see the FDIC website https://www.fdic.gov/resauthority/.
34 Ben Bernanke, “Warren-Vitter and the Lender of Last Resort,” Brookings Institution, blog, May 15, 2015,
http://www.brookings.edu/blogs/ben-bernanke/posts/2015/05/15-warren-vitter-proposal.
35 Federal Reserve, “Federal Reserve Board Seeks Comment on Proposed Amendments to Regulation A Regarding
Emergency Lending Authority,” press release, December 23, 2013, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/
bcreg/20131223a.htm. For more information, see CRS Legal Sidebar WSLG1247, Fed’s Emergency Lending Rule Not
Finalized A Year After Public Comment Period
, by M. Maureen Murphy.
36 Comment letters are posted on the Fed’s website at http://www.federalreserve.gov/apps/foia/ViewComments.aspx?
doc_id=R-1476&doc_ver=1.
37 This debate is discussed below in the section entitled “How Much Discretion Should the Fed Be Granted?”
38 These reports are available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_reports.htm.
Congressional Research Service
11

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

and the terms of the loan) from the crisis to be publicly released on December 1, 2010,39 and
lending records from future programs created under Section 13(3) to be publicly released a year
after the facility was terminated or two years after lending ceased, whichever came first. Section
1102 allowed GAO to audit any action under Section 13(3) for operational integrity, accounting,
financial reporting, internal controls, effectiveness of collateral policies, favoritism, and use of
third-party contractors—but did not allow GAO to conduct an economic evaluation—and Section
1109 required GAO to conduct an audit of all Fed emergency facilities created between
December 2007 and enactment. GAO may not disclose confidential information until the lending
records are released.40
For more details, see CRS Report R42079, Federal Reserve: Oversight and Disclosure Issues, by
Marc Labonte.
Policy Issues
Why Was the Fed Established as a “Lender of Last Resort”?
Economists distinguish between liquidity problems and solvency problems facing financial firms.
Firms become insolvent when their assets are worth less than their liabilities (e.g., because their
assets have fallen in value). Liquidity (i.e., cash flow) problems arise because of the maturity
mismatch between a financial firm’s long-term assets and short-term liabilities. In any instance
where such a mismatch exists, no matter how much liquidity the firm holds, a firm is vulnerable
to a loss of liquidity if it cannot roll over its short-term liabilities—even if the firm is solvent. In a
crisis, creditors are unable to distinguish between solvent and insolvent firms, so both lose access
to liquidity. The classic example of a liquidity crisis is a bank run, in which depositors withdraw
their deposits (liabilities) and banks cannot liquidate loans (assets) to meet withdrawals. Holding
more cash and fewer loans would make a run less likely but could not completely prevent it, and
the unintended consequence would be that loans would be more expensive to customers. The Fed
was created as a lender of last resort with this scenario in mind—when its depositors withdrew
funds, a bank would be able to pledge its assets at the Fed’s discount window in exchange for
short-term loans. Because the Fed controls the money supply, it is in a unique position to
potentially provide unlimited liquidity. This position enhances its ability to credibly pledge to end
financial crises.
One alternative to the Fed acting as a lender of last resort in a crisis is to allow the panic to run its
course. Eventually the panic would subside, but crises can lead to significant contractions in real
economic activity and declines in prices. This was the approach followed in the nineteenth and
early twentieth centuries, until repeated panics resulted in the creation of the Fed. But while the
Fed’s emergency actions may have hastened the end of the recent crisis, the Fed alone could not
prevent the crisis nor restore financial stability. Ultimately, the mainstream view is that financial
conditions did not stabilize until the banking system was recapitalized through the Troubled Asset
Relief Program (TARP)41; the Fed does not have authority to recapitalize financial institutions.

39 The records can be accessed at http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/reform_transaction.htm.
40 The audit is available at U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal Reserve System: Opportunities Exist to
Strengthen Policies and Processes for Managing Emergency Assistance
, GAO-11-696, July 21, 2011,
http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d11696.pdf.
41 For more information, see CRS Report R41427, Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP): Implementation and Status,
by Baird Webel.
Congressional Research Service
12

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

Who Should Have Access to the Lender of Last Resort?
Lending to Nonbank Financial Firms?
Do nonbank financial firms also face liquidity problems, and does this justify the Fed’s
emergency authority? Although only banks accept deposits, many types of financial firms face a
maturity mismatch between long-term assets and short-term liabilities. As a result, many types of
financial firms are vulnerable to liquidity crises. In 2008, the availability of repurchase
agreements (repos) and commercial paper—two prominent types of short-term lending for
nonbanks—sharply and suddenly contracted, causing liquidity problems for banks and
nonfinancial firms. Thus, some nonbank financial firms could also benefit from access to Fed
lending in a liquidity crisis.
While some nonbank firms could benefit from access to a lender of last resort, policymakers
might decide to grant them access only if there is some wider societal benefit to doing so. Such
benefits could be because a failure to do so would result in financial instability, through spillover
effects (e.g., counterparty exposure), contagion, or the disruption of critical functions within the
financial system. Banks provide critical functions through their unique role in the payment
system, for example. Nonbanks do not play a similar role in the payment system, although they
are important participants in similar markets, such as the repo market, that might also be viewed
as critical.42
Before 2008, there was some debate about whether nonbank financial firms were systemically
important enough that there would be widespread repercussions if they faced a crisis. Likewise,
there was some debate about whether a nonbank crisis would significantly affect the availability
of credit to consumers and businesses. Crises cause economic contractions because financial
firms extend less credit to consumers and businesses to hoard liquidity. Over time, the nonbank
financial sector has grown in absolute terms and relative to banks. The 2008 experience suggests
that a nonbank crisis can be damaging to the availability of credit and the broader financial sector.
Thus, the rationale of having a lender of last resort to provide liquidity also extends to parts of the
nonbank financial system, although the tradeoffs may be different. This raises the question of
whether there should be disparate treatment of banks and nonbanks—banks receive continual
access to the discount window, whereas any given nonbank receives no access to the Fed in
normal conditions and uncertain access to the Fed in unusual and exigent circumstances. Should
nonbanks be allowed to be members of the Federal Reserve system to ensure access to the
discount window? If so, should they be subject to prudential supervision by the Fed?43
Not all uses of Section 13(3) during the crisis were for the purpose of providing short-term
liquidity, however. TALF loans had terms of three to five years and were intended to revive long-

42 For more information on critical functions, see Financial Stability Oversight Council, “Authority to Require
Supervision and Regulation of Certain Nonbank Financial Companies,” 77 Federal Register 21657, April 11, 2012,
http://www.treasury.gov/initiatives/fsoc/rulemaking/Documents/
Authority%20to%20Require%20Supervision%20and%20Regulation%20of%20Certain%20Nonbank%20Financial%20
Companies.pdf.
43 Another question raised by the crisis is whether foreign firms should have access to the Fed’s broadly based
emergency facilities. For each facility, foreign firms were not eligible to participate, but U.S. affiliates of foreign firms
or foreign affiliates of U.S. firms were, depending on the facility. Firms with foreign parent companies were large users
of some facilities. For example, 59% of credit extended under the CPFF went to U.S. subsidiaries of foreign firms.
Source: U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal Reserve System: Opportunities Exist to Strengthen Policies
and Processes for Managing Emergency Assistance
, GAO-11-696, July 21, 2011, http://www.gao.gov/new.items/
d11696.pdf, Figure 10.
Congressional Research Service
13

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

term consumer and business credit (by increasing the demand for ABS, which might be described
as increasing their liquidity). The AIG loan initially had a maturity of two years. The Maiden
Lane facilities set up for Bear Stearns and AIG and the asset guarantees for Citigroup and Bank of
America were all intended to help those firms with troubled assets. The Dodd-Frank Act now
requires that assistance provided under Section 13(3) be “for the purpose of providing liquidity to
the financial system, and not to aid a failing financial company.”
Lending to Nonfinancial Firms?
Another issue is whether Section 13(3) should ever be used to provide credit to nonfinancial
firms. In 2008, the Fed chose to use Section 13(3) to provide credit mainly to financial firms,
although nonfinancial firms were eligible to sell their commercial paper to the CPFF. The Dodd-
Frank Act limits actions under Section 13(3) to providing liquidity to the financial system, but
does not limit participants to financial firms. In the 1930s, emergency loans were made to
nonfinancial firms. Although nonfinancial firms might also have liquidity needs,44 they do not
generally face the maturity mismatch that makes liquidity risk inherent to financial firms. Loans
to nonfinancial firms are more likely to involve the provision of long-term credit. Liquidity
problems at nonfinancial firms may also pose less systemic risk than at financial firms because
they are less interconnected with the financial system and do not perform critical functions in the
financial system.
The advantage of providing long-term credit to nonfinancial firms is that it directly stimulates
physical capital investment spending on plant and equipment, which in turn directly stimulates
gross domestic product (GDP). The disadvantage is that it is more likely to put the Fed in the
position of “picking winners”, and the Fed has no expertise in evaluating the creditworthiness of
loan proposals. In two cases, the Fed made loans to intermediaries to avoid that problem. In other
words, the direct recipients of the loans were not the intended recipients of ultimate assistance.
AMLF made loans to banks to finance the purchase of commercial paper to relieve stress in the
commercial-paper market. TALF made loans to investment funds to purchase ABS to revive the
private-securitization market. The tradeoff in these two cases is that, to entice banks and
investors, respectively, to participate in these programs, the Fed made the terms of the programs
relatively attractive to them (the loans were non-recourse, for example), potentially reducing the
profits and increasing the risk exposure for the Fed.
Lending to Government or Government Chartered Entities?
Another category of firms that Congress might consider whether it wants to make ineligible for
assistance under Section 13(3) is entities associated with the government, such as government
agencies, government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs), or bridge banks created in an FDIC
resolution.45 Some Members of Congress have also expressed concern that Section 13(3) could be
used to assist state or municipal governments. The Fed has never used Section 13(3) for these
purposes. Current statute does not explicitly rule it out, although such an action might have
trouble meeting the statute’s various requirements, such as that the facility be broadly based for
the purpose of providing liquidity to the financial system.

44 The Fed bought some commercial paper issued by nonfinancial firms through the CPFF. Because commercial paper
has short maturities, this action can be characterized as providing liquidity rather than long-term credit.
45 Direct lending to the federal government is prohibited by Section 14 of the Federal Reserve Act.
Congressional Research Service
14

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

Lending to Itself?
During the crisis, the Fed structured many of its transactions under Section 13(3) as loans to a
LLC that it created and controlled. It did so to comply with the Section 13(3) requirement that
assistance take the form of a loan. For example, in 2008, the Fed created the Commercial Paper
Funding Facility (CPFF) to purchase commercial paper, a debt security that is economically
equivalent to a short-term loan from the borrower’s perspective. In this case, the Fed was able to
purchase commercial paper by setting up a limited liability corporation (LLC) that it controlled
and lending the LLC funds to finance the purchases. Some of the commercial paper the CPFF
purchased was not collateralized, however, so it was not economically equivalent to a
collateralized loan.
These actions raise two policy issues. First, should Section 13(3) be restricted so that the Fed
cannot lend to LLCs it creates and controls? Second, should Section 13(3) be modified so that the
Fed can provide short-term liquidity by purchasing debt securities? 46
From an economic perspective, whether a company accesses short-term liquidity by taking out a
loan or issuing a debt security does not change its purpose. On practical grounds, since financial
firms increasingly rely on debt securities for liquidity needs, allowing the Fed to purchase them
would make it a more effective lender of last resort. But allowing the Fed to purchase securities
(directly or through LLCs it controls) to provide short-term liquidity faces the “slippery slope”
problem. The Fed also used LLCs in the Maiden Lanes case, where the goal was not to provide
short-term liquidity but to remove troubled assets from a firm’s balance sheet. The Dodd-Frank
Act maintained the Fed’s ability to create LLCs, but prohibits “a program or facility that is
structured to remove assets from the balance sheet of a single and specific company.” It might be
difficult to draw a bright line between debt securities purchased for liquidity purposes and other
types of securities.
What Are the Potential Costs of the Fed Making Loans to
Nonbanks?
Potential costs inherent in Section 13(3) lending can be divided into risks to taxpayers and
broader economic consequences. These costs can be weighed against the benefits of Section 13(3)
lending, which could be significant if the lending restores or maintains financial stability. While
lending poses risks to the taxpayer, if the Fed did not act, the economic losses from allowing a
financial crisis to run its course would also pose risks to taxpayers in terms of a larger federal
budget deficit and privately through higher unemployment, lost wealth, and so forth.
The risk to the taxpayer of lending is primarily default risk. The Fed can—but is not required to—
attach various conditions to its lending to minimize default, including requiring short maturities,
collateral in excess of the funds lent (i.e., applying a “haircut” to collateral), senior creditor
standing, and recourse if collateral proves insufficient. Note that the Fed has typically—but not
always—imposed all of these conditions to Section 13(3) assistance. Loans to nonbanks are
arguably not inherently riskier than loans to banks; to the extent that Section 13(3) programs were
riskier than the discount window, it was mainly because these conditions were loosened. Lending

46 The Fed is allowed to purchase a narrow range of securities under Section 14 of the Federal Reserve Act. Few
securities issued by private firms are permitted besides bank acceptances and bills of exchange, subject to limitations.
The Fed has purchased neither in modern times. For more information, see David H. Small and James A. Clouse, “The
Scope of Monetary Policy Actions Authorized under the Federal Reserve Act,” Federal Reserve, working paper, July
19, 2004, Section 3.4.
Congressional Research Service
15

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

to non-banks may also be riskier because the Fed can safeguard its lending to banks through
prudential supervision, but, with the exception of firms designated as “systemically important
financial institutions” (SIFIs) or structured as bank holding companies, the Fed has no jurisdiction
to supervise nonbanks for safety and soundness. In times of crisis, the Fed’s broader ability to
restore financial stability also reduces default risk for any specific loan.
In some cases, the Fed was able to protect the taxpayer through terms other than conventional
collateral pledges. For example, the Fed required that AIG provide it with compensation in the
form of an equity stake in the company in exchange for a loan. The Fed’s ability to protect
taxpayers against losses could be more limited in the future based on a recent court ruling. The
court found that the AIG equity stake was an illegal exaction.47 However, because the Dodd-
Frank Act prohibits assistance to single or failing firms, future scenarios in which the Fed would
need to take an equity stake to adequately protect taxpayers may be limited.
One broader economic concern with Section 13(3) lending raised by Chairman Jeb Hensarling is
that “its use risks exacerbating moral hazard costs.”48 Moral hazard is the concept that firms will
take greater risks if they are protected from negative outcomes. In this case, moral hazard occurs
because firms are more likely to be more reliant on short-term lending if they anticipate access to
Fed lending during a liquidity crisis. Some argue that Section 13(3) should be repealed or curbed
because of moral hazard, but Bernanke compares that approach to shutting down the fire
department to encourage fire safety, instead of toughening the fire code. Unlike lending to banks,
the Fed cannot mitigate moral hazard through prudential supervision, however, excepted in the
cases noted above.
Moral hazard concerns can be overstated. For instance, moral hazard arguably did not cause
nonbank financial firms to be reckless about liquidity management before the crisis, unless they
were able to anticipate that Section 13(3) would be used to provide them with liquidity, even
though it had never been used for that purpose before 2008. Thus, greater market discipline might
reduce moral hazard problems but cannot eliminate liquidity crises.
Another economic concern with Section 13(3) lending is that it could cause credit to be allocated
away from its most economically efficient use. In a liquidity crisis, when the availability of
private lending, by definition, is constrained, the likelihood that Fed lending comes at the expense
of private lending is lower. The legacy of aid to too-big-to-fail firms in 2008 might be more likely
to cause issues with credit allocation, particularly if markets expect it to be repeated in the future.
As discussed above, the Dodd-Frank Act prohibits the use of Section 13(3) to aid insolvent firms,
but defines insolvency relatively narrowly.
How Much Discretion Should the Fed Be Granted?
Limiting discretion is the common goal running throughout many of the diverse policy proposals
to alter Section 13(3). The fact that the Fed has broad discretion under Section 13(3) allowed the
Fed, for or better or worse, to act swiftly, pledge sizable interventions, create a diverse set of
facilities for a diverse set of lenders, and tackle multiple, disparate problems as they emerged. It
also explains why the Fed was able to provide assistance in forms not envisioned by Congress

47 For more information, see CRS Legal Sidebar WSLG1300, Court Finds AIG’s Bail-Out Terms Constitute an Illegal
Exaction but Awards No Damages
, by M. Maureen Murphy and David H. Carpenter.
48 Chairman Jeb Hensarling, comment letter to the Federal Reserve, docket number R-1476, January 13, 2014.
Congressional Research Service
16

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

that arguably were not always consistent with the spirit of a lender of last resort, such as the
Maiden Lane LLCs.49
Fed governor Jerome Powell believes that the Congress should maintain the Fed’s current
discretion under Section 13(3) because
One of the lessons of the crisis is that the financial system evolves so quickly that it is
difficult to predict where threats will emerge and what actions may be needed in the
future to respond. Because we cannot anticipate what may be needed in the future, the
Congress should preserve the ability of the Fed to respond flexibly and nimbly to future
emergencies. Further restricting or eliminating the Fed’s emergency lending authority
will not prevent future crises, but it will hinder the Fed’s ability to limit the harm from
those crises for families and businesses.50
In his view, the Dodd-Frank reforms “struck a reasonable balance ... (and) it would be a mistake
to go further and impose additional restrictions” on Section 13(3). Alternatively, some argue that
discretion can increase uncertainty, thereby increasing systemic risk. For example, some argue
that the failure of Lehman Brothers exacerbated financial instability because market participants
believed that it would receive Fed assistance similar to Bear Stearns and panicked when it did
not.
One potential drawback to discretion is that assistance might be provided in ways the Dodd-Frank
Act did not intend, such as to prevent a firm from failing. As noted above, the Dodd-Frank Act
modified Section 13(3) to rule out lending to an insolvent firm, but some critics are skeptical that
the Dodd-Frank Act successfully ruled out the use of Section 13(3) to aid an insolvent firm. For
example, the Fed’s proposed rule on Section 13(3) would allow the Fed to base a solvency
finding on the borrower’s certification, which can be defined as in a bankruptcy proceeding or
resolution process, as set out in the Dodd-Frank Act. One critic argued that “The notion that a
firm is only insolvent once it is already in a bankruptcy, resolution or receivership contradicts
both common sense and historical practice. Bankruptcy does not trigger insolvency, insolvency
triggers bankruptcy.” 51 He also argued that since Maiden Lane I was used to facilitate the
takeover of Bear Stearns (a failing firm) by JP Morgan Chase (a solvent firm), the Dodd-Frank
restrictions would not have prevented it because the Fed could have characterized the recipient of
the assistance to be JP Morgan Chase.52 As long as emergency authority exists, policymakers may
be tempted to use it to bail out a failing firm to avoid a crisis—and the broader the authority, the
more feasible it becomes.53

49 According to the legal counsel of the NY Fed, “The Congress that enacted Section 13(3) in the 1930’s envisioned the
Federal Reserve lending to companies, but it surely did not envision the Fed lending to an LLC, because that legal form
of organization would not be invented for another 40 years.” Thomas Baxter, “The Legal Position of the Central Bank.
The Case of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York,” speech delivered to Regulatory Response to the Financial Crisis
conference, January 19, 2009.
50 Governor Jerome H. Powell, “‘Audit the Fed’ and Other Proposals,” speech at the Catholic University of America,
Columbus School of Law, Washington, DC, February 9, 2015, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/
powell20150209a.htm.
51 Mark Calabria, comment letter, docket number R-1476, March 6, 2014, posted at http://www.federalreserve.gov/
SECRS/2014/March/20140313/R-1476/R-1476_030614_112088_544011429703_1.pdf.
52 Mark Calabria, comment letter, docket number R-1476, March 6, 2014, posted at http://www.federalreserve.gov/
SECRS/2014/March/20140313/R-1476/R-1476_030614_112088_544011429703_1.pdf.
53 This report takes no position on whether the Fed should bail out failing firms. Bailing out firms poses tradeoffs
between potential benefits to financial stability in the short run and potential costs, including moral hazard and risks to
taxpayers.
Congressional Research Service
17

link to page 25 Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

Arguably, another drawback to discretion is the potential for favoritism. Because the types of
nonbank financial firms are numerous and diverse, deciding who should get access to loans
involves trade-offs and judgments that are not completely technical in nature. For example, the
Fed set a high minimum loan size in TALF that effectively limited access to loans at below-
market interest rates to large investors. The decision to outsource certain functions of emergency
facilities to third-party vendors also creates the potential for favoritism.54
Congress could curb discretion by adding more restrictions to Section 13(3) or by requiring
Congressional approval for each action taken under Section 13(3). The latter proposal, depending
on the details, could potentially affect the timeliness and credibility of the Fed’s actions during a
crisis. Examples of additional restrictions Congress could add to Section 13(3) include
restrictions on who is eligible for assistance and the terms of assistance, such as acceptable
collateral or the rate that the Fed charges (discussed below). Congress could also add limits on the
amount of total assistance or assistance to one borrower.55 Granting the Fed discretion on these
issues is in part a judgment by Congress about whether it or the Fed can balance these competing
policy considerations more effectively. For example, favoritism concerns could potentially be
exacerbated or mitigated if Congress were more involved.
Another consideration for the degree of discretion provided is the Fed’s independence from
Congress and the Administration. The Fed argues that maintaining its independence is important
for the credibility and effectiveness of its monetary policy. At the same time, greater
independence complicates accountability to Congress. It is fair to question how much discretion
on Section 13(3) affects perceptions of monetary policy independence because 13(3) is used so
rarely. The Dodd-Frank Act’s requirement that assistance under Section 13(3) be preapproved by
the Treasury Secretary reduces the Fed’s independence from the Administration, although the
Treasury Secretary supported all of the Fed’s actions taken under Section 13(3) in 2008.
What Rate Should the Fed Charge?
In determining what rate the lender of last resort should charge, economists and central bankers
almost universally point to the maxim of Walter Bagehot—lend freely against good collateral, but
at a penalty.56 Consensus breaks down on how penurious the penalty rate should be. A penalty
rate (i.e., a rate that is higher than the market rate) achieves two goals: (1) it maximizes the return
to the central bank (and thus the taxpayer) and (2) it discourages lenders from turning to the
central bank instead of the private market when private credit is available (hence, the concept of
lender of last resort), thereby reducing moral hazard problems. These two goals call for making
the rate as high as possible. Alternatively, financial stability concerns call for making the rate as
close to market rates as possible. Higher rates will potentially undermine financial stability by
discouraging the use of Fed facilities, which may increase the stigma associated with borrowing
from the Fed (i.e., if lending is made unattractive to healthy firms, the decision to borrow could
be taken as a sign of desperation). Further, higher rates might weaken the health of the borrower,
thereby undermining the goal of restoring stability. This concept is most starkly demonstrated in
the case of assistance to AIG during the crisis (for details, see the Appendix). The terms of the

54 For details on third-party vendors, see Federal Reserve, Office of the Inspector General, The Federal Reserve’s
Section 13(3) Lending Facilities to Support Overall Market Liquidity
, November 2010, p. 25
http://oig.federalreserve.gov/reports/FRS_Lending_Facilities_Report_final-11-23-10_web.pdf. The New York Fed’s
contracts with third-party vendors are posted at http://www.newyorkfed.org/aboutthefed/vendor_information.html.
55 In an earlier provision of the Dodd-Frank Act that was not enacted, total assistance under Section 13(3) would have
been limited to $4 trillion.
56 Walter Bagehot, Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market (New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons, 1873).
Congressional Research Service
18

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

initial Fed loan were more favorable to the taxpayer than the subsequent iterations of assistance,
which were repeatedly renegotiated for fear that overly harsh terms would compromise the
company’s viability.
There is also a question of how a market rate should be calculated during a crisis. Generally, two
features of a crisis are that markets become illiquid (so there are fewer transactions to observe)
and rates become higher. These features would argue for using a pre-crisis market rate as the
baseline. Critics incorrectly accused the Fed of charging below-market rates during the crisis.57
The seeming contradiction between the low rates charged by the Fed in absolute terms and the
fact that these rates were a markup above market rates is explained by the fact that the market
rates referenced by the Fed were directly influenced by monetary policy. At the same time, the
Fed was making these loans, it was in the process of reducing the federal funds rate to zero.
Should Borrowers’ Identities Be Kept Confidential?
The Fed has argued that allowing the public to know which firms are accessing its facilities could
undermine investor confidence in the institutions receiving aid because of a perception that
recipients are weak or unsound. A loss of investor confidence could potentially lead to
destabilizing runs on the institution’s deposits, debt, or equity. If institutions feared that this
would occur, the Fed argues, the institutions would be wary of participating in the Fed’s
programs. A delayed release of information mitigates, but does not eliminate, these concerns.
Some critics would view less Fed lending as a positive outcome, but if the premise that the Fed’s
lender of last resort role helps prevent financial crises by maintaining the liquidity of the financial
system is accepted, then an unwillingness by institutions to access Fed facilities makes the system
less safe. One study argues that the Fed’s decision to discourage banks to use the discount
window from 1929-1931 (at a time when identities were kept confidential) worsened the bank
panic in the Great Depression.58
Whether investors are less willing to borrow as a result of the disclosure of identities will not be
apparent until the next crisis. A historical example supporting the Fed’s argument would be the
experience with the Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC) in the Great Depression. When
the RFC publicized to which banks it had given loans, those banks typically experienced
depositor runs.59 A more recent example—disclosure of TARP fund recipients—provides mixed
evidence. At first, TARP funds were widely disbursed, and recipients included all the major
banks. At that point, there was no perceived stigma to TARP participation. Subsequently, many
banks repaid TARP shares at the first opportunity, and several remaining participants have
expressed concern that if they did not repay soon, investors would perceive them as weak.
The granularity of information to be disclosed is a policy issue. Aggregate information about
programs and activities that does not require the identification of borrowers tends to be more
useful for broad policy purposes, while current information on specific transactions within the
programs is of interest to investors. The Fed voluntarily released the former, but only reluctantly
released the latter when compelled to by legislation and lawsuits. For oversight purposes, the
former would suffice for answering most questions about taxpayer risk exposure, expected profits

57 The reliability of market benchmarks is another issue. In some cases, the rate charged by the Fed was tied to LIBOR,
and several banks have settled legal cases related to the manipulation of LIBOR during the financial crisis.
58 Gary Gorton and Andrew Metrick, “The Federal Reserve and Panic Prevention,” Journal of Economic Perspectives,
vol. 27, no. 4, Fall 2013, p. 53.
59 James Butkiewicz, “The Reconstruction Finance Corporation, the Gold Standard, and the Banking Panic of 1933,”
Southern Economic Journal, vol. 66, no. 2, October 1999, p. 271.
Congressional Research Service
19

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

or losses, potential subsidies, economic effects, and evaluating the state of the financial system.
The latter would be necessary for transparency around issues such as favoritism (certain firms
receiving preferential treatment over similar firms).60 Although preventing favoritism is a valid
policy goal, releasing the identities of borrowers to “name and shame” them is more questionable,
especially if one believes that these programs were helpful for providing liquidity and
maintaining financial stability. Naming and shaming is likely to result in less uptake of the
programs in the future. If one believes that these lending programs are not helpful, repealing
Section 13(3) would be more effective than undermining their effectiveness by stigmatizing
recipients.
As discussed above, the Dodd-Frank Act compromised between stability and oversight concerns
by requiring borrowers’ identities to be publicly released with a lag. Some Members of Congress
have expressed an interest in revisiting this issue.
Selected Legislation in the 114th Congress
H.R. 3189
The Fed Oversight Reform and Modernization Act (H.R. 3189) was ordered to be reported by the
House Financial Services Committee on July 29, 2015. Section 11 of the bill as ordered to be
reported amends Section 13(3) to limit the Fed’s discretion to make emergency loans. It limits
13(3) to “unusual and exigent circumstances that pose a threat to the financial stability of the
United States” and requires “the affirmative vote of not less than nine presidents of Federal
reserve banks” in addition the current requirement of the affirmative vote of five Fed governors.
It forbids the Fed from accepting as collateral equity securities issued by a borrower. It requires
the Fed to issue a rule establishing how it will determine sufficiency of collateral; acceptable
classes of collateral; any discount that will be applied to determine the sufficiency of collateral;
and how it will obtain independent appraisals for valuing collateral. It eliminates the current
language permitting the Fed to establish the solvency of a borrower based on the borrower’s
certification and specifies that before a borrower may be eligible for assistance, the Fed’s Board
and any other federal banking regulator with jurisdiction over the borrower must certify that the
borrower is not insolvent. It limits assistance to financial institution participants and defines
financial institution to require that the company be “predominantly engaged in financial
activities” and to preclude federal, state, and local government agencies and government-
controlled or sponsored entities. It requires the Fed to issue a rule establishing a minimum interest
rate on emergency loans based on the sum of the average secondary discount rate charged by the
Federal Reserve banks over the most recent 90-day period and the average of the difference
between a distressed corporate bond index (as defined by a rule issued by the Fed) and the
Treasury yield over the most recent 90-day period.
S. 1320
The Bailout Prevention Act (S. 1320) would amend Section 13(3) to limit the Fed’s discretion to
make emergency loans. It eliminates the current language permitting the Fed to establish the
solvency of a borrower based on the borrower’s certification and specified that a borrower may
not be eligible for assistance unless the Fed and all federal banking regulators with jurisdiction

60 Another option for addressing these types of questions would be to allow GAO, the Fed’s Inspector General, or some
other outside group to investigate confidential material without releasing it to the public.
Congressional Research Service
20

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

over the borrower certify that the borrower is not insolvent and issue a detailed public explanation
of the certification decision. The certification must be based on an assessment of “relevant
financial data” for the most recent 4 months and determine that the fair value of the borrower’s
assets exceeds the fair value of liabilities—adjusting for temporary market illiquidity. It forbids
the Fed from lending to a bridge company set up under Title II of the Dodd-Frank Act. It defines
broad-based eligibility to comprise at least five companies. Its sets the minimum interest rate on a
loan to be at least five percentage points above the yield on a Treasury security with a comparable
duration. It provides the Fed with authority to create a program that does not meet the bill’s
definition of broad-based eligibility or minimum lending rate, provided it notifies Congress
within three days. If a joint resolution authorizing the program to continue is not enacted within
30 days of receipt of that notice, the program terminates. Section 4 of the bill is unrelated to Fed
emergency lending.
H.R. 2625
The Bailout Prevention Act (H.R. 2625) would amend Section 13(3) to limit the Fed’s discretion
to make emergency loans. It eliminates the current language permitting the Fed to establish the
solvency of a borrower based on the borrower’s certification and specified that a borrower may
not be eligible for assistance unless the Fed and all federal banking regulators with jurisdiction
over the borrower certify that the borrower is not insolvent and issue a detailed public explanation
of the certification decision. The certification must be based on an assessment of “relevant
financial data” for the most recent 4 months and determine that the fair value of the borrower’s
assets exceeds the fair value of liabilities—adjusting for temporary market illiquidity. It forbids
the Fed from lending to a bridge company set up under Title II of the Dodd-Frank Act. It defines
broad-based eligibility to comprise at least five companies. Its sets the minimum interest rate on a
loan to be at least five percentage points above the yield on a Treasury security with a comparable
duration. It provides the Fed with authority to create a program that does not meet the bill’s
definition of broad-based eligibility or minimum lending rate, provided it notifies Congress
within three days. If a joint resolution authorizing the program to continue is not enacted within
30 days of receipt of that notice, the program terminates. It would reduce the delayed release of
unredacted GAO reports and lending records pertaining to Section 13(3) from one or two years to
60 days.


Congressional Research Service
21

link to page 30 link to page 26 Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

Appendix. Details on the Actions Taken Under
Section 13(3) in 2008

Term Securities Lending Facility
Shortly before Bear Stearns suffered its liquidity crisis, the Fed created the Term Securities
Lending Facility (TSLF) on March 11, 2008, to expand its existing securities lending program for
primary dealers.61 Primary dealers are financial firms that are the Fed’s counterparties for open
market operations, including investment banks that were ineligible to access the Fed’s lending
facilities for banks. At the end of 2007, there were 20 primary dealers, including Bear Stearns.62
The proximate cause of Bear Stearns’ crisis was its inability to roll over its short-term debt, and
the Fed created the TSLF and the Primary Dealer Credit Facility (discussed below) to offer an
alternative source of short-term liquidity for primary dealers.
Primary dealers were already allowed to borrow securities from the Fed on an overnight basis
before the crisis. The TSLF extended the length of the loans and acceptable collateral, and
signaled that the Fed was willing to lend on a larger scale. Under the TSLF at its peak, each week
primary dealers could borrow up to $200 billion of Treasury securities for 28 days, as opposed to
overnight. Primary dealers need access to Treasury securities because of their use in repurchase
agreements (repos), which are an important source of short-term financing. Figure A-1 shows the
decline in primary dealer repos outstanding in 2008. At various points, loans could be
collateralized with some of the following: private-label mortgage-backed securities (MBS) with
an AAA/Aaa rating, agency commercial MBS, agency collateralized mortgage obligations, and
all investment-grade debt securities. On July 30, 2008, the Fed created the TSLF Options
Program within the TSLF that allowed primary dealers to pre-negotiate options to borrow
securities. No securities were borrowed through the TSLF after August 2009, and the facility
expired February 1, 2010. The TSLF experienced no losses and earned income of $781 million
over the life of the program.

61 For more information, see New York Fed documents collection on the TSLF posted at http://www.newyorkfed.org/
markets/tslf.html.
62 The official list of current primary dealers is posted at http://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/pridealers_current.html.
Lists of past primary dealers are available at http://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/Dealer_Lists_1960_to_2014.xls.
Congressional Research Service
22

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

Figure A-1. Primary Dealer Repos Outstanding
(2002-2012, weekly)
$5,000
s
n
oil
$4,500
liB $4,000
$3,500
$3,000
$2,500
$2,000
$1,500
$1,000
02
10
15
23
28
04
09
17
22
30
07
12-
19
24
01
07
14
20
27-
02
09
14
01-
07-
01-
07-
01-
08-
02-
08-
02-
08-
03-
09-
03-
09-
04-
10-
04-
10-
04-
11-
05-
11-
02-
02-
03-
03-
04-
04-
05-
05-
06-
06-
07-
07
08-
08-
09-
09-
10-
10-
11
11-
12-
12-
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20

Source: New York Fed, Primary Dealer Statistics.
Notes: Includes overnight, continuing, and term agreement repos.
Primary Dealer Credit Facility
Shortly after Bear Stearns’ liquidity crisis, the Fed created the Primary Dealer Credit Facility
(PDCF) on March 16, 2008. The PDCF can be thought of as analogous to a discount window for
primary dealers.63 Loans were made at the Fed’s discount rate, which was set slightly higher than
the federal funds rate during the crisis. Loans were made on an overnight basis, with recourse,
and they were fully collateralized, limiting their riskiness. Acceptable collateral at times included
Treasuries; government agency debt; investment grade corporate, mortgage-backed, asset-backed,
and municipal securities; and certain classes of equities. The PDCF expired on February 1, 2010.
Borrowing from the facility was sporadic, with average daily borrowing outstanding above $10
billion in the first three months and falling to zero in August 2008. Much of this initial borrowing
was done by Bear Stearns, before its merger with JPMorgan Chase was complete. Borrowing
picked up again in September 2008 and peaked at $148 billion on October 1, 2008. No loans were
outstanding after May 2009. The PDCF experienced no losses and earned interest income of $0.5
billion over the life of the program.
Commercial Paper Funding Facility and Asset-Backed Commercial
Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility
To meet liquidity needs, many large firms routinely issue commercial paper, which is short-term
debt purchased directly by investors that matures in less than 270 days, with an average maturity

63 For more information, see New York Fed documents collection on the PDCF posted at http://www.newyorkfed.org/
markets/pdcf.html; Tobias Adrian et al., The Federal Reserve’s Primary Dealer Credit Facility, Current Issues in
Economics and Finance, vol. 15, no. 4, August 2009, http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/current_issues/ci15-4.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
23

link to page 27
Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

of 30 days. The three broad categories of commercial paper issuers are financial firms,
nonfinancial firms, and pass-through entities that issue commercial paper backed by assets. The
commercial paper issued directly by firms tends not to be backed by collateral, because these
firms are viewed as large and creditworthy, and the paper matures quickly.
Individual investors are major purchasers of highly rated commercial paper through money
market mutual funds (MMMFs) and money market accounts. On September 16, 2008, a MMMF
called the Reserve Fund “broke the buck,” meaning that the value of its shares had fallen below
par value of $1. This occurred because of losses it had taken on short-term debt issued by Lehman
Brothers, which filed for bankruptcy on September 15, 2008. Money market investors had
perceived breaking the buck to be highly unlikely, and its occurrence set off a generalized run on
MMMFs, as investors simultaneously attempted to withdraw an estimated $250 billion of their
investments—even from funds without exposure to Lehman.64 The decline in commercial paper
outstanding after September 2008 is illustrated in Figure A-2.
Figure A-2. Commercial Paper Outstanding
(2000:Q1-2015:Q1, quarterly)

Source: Federal Reserve, Z.1 release.
Fearing that disruption in the commercial paper markets could make overall problems in financial
markets more severe, the Fed announced on September 19, 2008, that it would create the Asset-
Backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (AMLF). This facility
made nonrecourse loans to banks to purchase asset-backed commercial paper. As the commercial
paper matured, the loans were repaid. Because the loans were nonrecourse, the banks had no
further liability to repay any losses on the commercial paper collateralizing the loan. At its peak
in early October 2008, the AMLF had loans of $152 billion outstanding. However, the AMLF
would soon be superseded in importance by the creation of the Commercial Paper Funding
Facility (CPFF), and lending fell to zero in October 2009. The AMLF experienced no losses and

64 Figure cited in Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke, “Financial Reform to Address Systemic Risk,” speech at the Council on
Foreign Relations, March 10, 2009, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20090310a.htm.
Congressional Research Service
24

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

earned income of $0.5 billion over the life of the program. The facility expired on February 1,
2010.
On October 7, 2008, the Fed announced the creation of the CPFF to purchase all types of three-
month, highly rated U.S. commercial paper, secured and unsecured, from issuers.65 The CPFF
charged an interest rate equal to the three-month overnight index swap rate plus 1 percentage
point for secured corporate debt, 2 percentage points for unsecured corporate debt, and 3
percentage points for asset-backed paper. The CPFF could buy as much commercial paper from
any individual issuer as that issuer had outstanding in the year to date. Any potential losses borne
by the CPFF would ultimately be borne by the Fed. At its peak in January 2009, the CPFF held
$351 billion of commercial paper, and holdings fell steadily subsequently. The facility expired
February 1, 2010. It earned income of $6.1 billion over the life of the program and suffered no
losses.
In the case of the AMLF, the banks were not intended recipients of assistance, but rather were the
intermediary through which assistance flowed to the commercial paper market. According to
GAO, 92% of credit extended under AMLF was channeled through two custodial banks
(JPMorgan Chase and State Street) that were among the three largest providers of fund
administration and account services for MMMFs.66 The CPFF removed the role of banks as
intermediary and provided Fed assistance directly to commercial paper issuers.67
On October 21, 2008, the Fed announced the creation of the Money Market Investor Funding
Facility (MMIFF) and pledged to lend it up to $540 billion. The MMIFF was planned to lend to
private-sector special purpose vehicles (SPVs) that invest in commercial paper issued by highly
rated financial institutions. Each SPV would have been owned by a group of financial firms and
could only purchase commercial paper issued by that group. The intent was for these SPVs to
purchase commercial paper from money market mutual funds and similar entities facing
redemption requests to help avoid runs, such as the run on the Reserve Fund. The MMIFF was
never accessed, and the facility expired on October 30, 2009.
Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility
On November 25, 2008, the Fed created the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF)
in response to problems in the market for asset-backed securities (ABS).68 According to the Fed,
“new issuance of ABS declined precipitously in September and came to a halt in October. At the
same time, interest rate spreads on AAA-rated tranches of ABS soared to levels well outside the

65 For more information, see New York Fed documents collection on the CPFF posted at http://www.newyorkfed.org/
markets/cpff.html; Tobias Adrian et al., “The Federal Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility,” Federal Reserve
Bank of New York, Economic Policy Review, May 2011, p. 25, http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/epr/11v17n1/
1105adri.pdf.
66 U.S. Government Accountability Office (GAO), Federal Reserve System: Opportunities Exist to Strengthen Policies
and Processes for Managing Emergency Assistance
, GAO-11-696, July 21, 2011, Table 12, http://www.gao.gov/
new.items/d11696.pdf.
67 To comply with statute, the CPFF was set up as a special purpose vehicle (SPV) controlled by the Fed that borrowed
from the Fed to finance its commercial paper purchases.
68 For more information, see New York Fed documents collection on TALF posted at http://www.newyorkfed.org/
markets/talf.html and http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/epr/12v18n3/1210ashc.pdf; Sumit Agarwal, Jacqueline
Barrett, Crystal Cun, and Mariacristina De Nardi, “The asset-backed securities markets, the crisis, and TALF,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, Economic Perspectives, 4Q/2010, p. 101, https://www.chicagofed.org/~/media/publications/
economic-perspectives/2010/4qtr2010-part1-agarwal-barrett-cun-denardi-pdf.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
25

link to page 29
Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

range of historical experience, reflecting unusually high risk premiums.”69 The decline in ABS
issuance is illustrated in Figure A-3. The Fed feared that if lenders could not securitize these
types of loans, less credit would be extended to consumers, exacerbating the economic downturn.
Figure A-3. Asset-Backed Securities Issuance
(2000-2015, annually)

Source: Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association, data accessed at http://www.sifma.org/
uploadedFiles/Research/Statistics/StatisticsFiles/SF-US-ABS-SIFMA.xls?n=55152.
Note: Does not include mortgage-backed securities.
Rather than purchase ABS directly, the Fed made nonrecourse loans to private investment funds
to purchase recently issued ABS with the highest credit rating, using the ABS as collateral. The
minimum loan size was $10 million. Eligible collateral included new securities backed by auto
loans, student loans, small business loans, and credit card loans. TALF was later expanded to
include “legacy” commercial MBS. The loans had a term of up to three years for most types of
assets (and up to five years for some types of assets), but were repaid when the underlying ABS
matured or was sold. Interest rates were set at a markup over different maturities of the London
Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) or the federal funds rate, depending on the type of loan and
underlying collateral.
If the ABS had lost value, because the loans were nonrecourse, the losses would have been borne
by the Fed and the Treasury (through TARP) instead of by the borrower—an unusual feature that
made TALF riskier for taxpayers than typical Fed lending facilities. The Fed lent less than the
market value of the collateral, so the Fed would not have borne losses on the loans until losses
exceeded the value of this “haircut” (different ABS receive different haircuts). In addition,
Treasury initially set aside $20 billion of TARP funds to cover any losses.70

69 Federal Reserve, “Federal Reserve Announces the Creation of the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility
(TALF),” press release, November 25, 2008.
70 On July 20, 2010, Treasury reduced its loss exposure to $4.3 billion, maintaining the 10% maximum loss exposure in
light of the actual loans outstanding when the program ended.
Congressional Research Service
26

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

Peaking at $48 billion, TALF turned out to be a relatively small program compared with the $200
billion program envisioned by the Fed or the $1 trillion program later envisioned by Treasury. In
part, this was because the issuance of assets eligible for TALF remained low, which reflected the
depressed state of securitization markets and may imply that TALF was unable to overcome
investor aversion to ABS. (While TALF was in operation beginning in March 2009, a sizable
share of ABS issued were used as collateral for TALF loans. Thus, issuance might have been even
lower without the presence of TALF.)
Unlike most other Fed lending facilities, the amount outstanding under TALF steadily rose
through 2009. The facility stopped making new loans at the end of June 2010 for loans using
newly issued commercial MBS as collateral and in March 2010 for loans using other assets. The
last TALF loan was repaid on October 29, 2014. All TALF loans were repaid in full, with
interest.71 Over the life of the program, TALF made profits of $1.6 billion for the Fed and $0.7
billion for the Treasury.
Bear Stearns
Unable to roll over its short-term debt as a result of investor concerns about its mortgage-related
losses, the investment bank Bear Stearns faced bankruptcy in 2008. Fearing that Bear Stearns was
“too big to fail” and posed systemic risk,72 the Fed stepped in to broker a merger. On March 14,
2008, the Fed provided a $12.9 billion bridge loan on a nonrecourse basis to JP Morgan Chase to
provide Bear Stearns with liquidity, which was repaid with interest. On March 16, JPMorgan
Chase agreed to acquire Bear Stearns. As part of the agreement, the Fed agreed to lend $28.82
billion to Maiden Lane I, a Delaware limited liability corporation (LLC) that it created, to
purchase financial securities at market value from Bear Stearns. These securities were largely
mortgage-related assets that were too illiquid for JPMorgan Chase to be willing to acquire.
Maiden Lane I, not JP Morgan Chase, was to repay the Fed interest and principal using the funds
from the sale of the assets. JP Morgan Chase took a first loss position through a subordinated loan
of $1.15 billion, receiving an interest rate of 4.5% above the discount rate on that position,
compared with an interest rate of 2.5% above the discount rate on the Fed’s loan. Any additional
losses would be borne by the Fed, and any profits in excess of the loans would accrue to the Fed.
Profits or losses for the Fed and JP Morgan Chase were dependent on whether the market value of
those assets rose or declined after Maiden Lane I acquired them.
By November 2012, proceeds from the sale or maturation of Maiden Lane I assets were sufficient
to fully repay principal and accrued interest to the Fed ($765 million) and JP Morgan Chase. As
of December 30, 2014, the value of remaining assets held by Maiden Lane I was $1.7 billion.73
Once those remaining assets are sold or have matured, the Fed will realize additional capital gains
that would be greater or less than $1.7 billion (less expenses), depending on whether the value of
those assets subsequently rises or falls.

71 Federal Reserve, Final Report Pursuant to Section 129(b), November 21, 2014, http://www.federalreserve.gov/
monetarypolicy/files/129periodicupdate20141121.pdf.
72 For more information, see CRS Report R42150, Systemically Important or “Too Big to Fail” Financial Institutions,
by Marc Labonte.
73 Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Maiden Lane Transactions, http://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/
maidenlane.html.
Congressional Research Service
27

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

American International Group
In September 2008, facing losses on various operations, AIG experienced a significant decline in
its stock price and downgrades from the major credit rating agencies.74 These downgrades led to
immediate demands for significant amounts of collateral (approximately $14 billion to $15 billion
in collateral payments, according to contemporary press reports).75 As financial demands on the
company mounted, bankruptcy appeared a possibility, as had occurred with Lehman Brothers on
September 15, 2008. Many feared that AIG was too big to fail due to the potential for widespread
disruption to financial markets resulting from such a failure.
On September 16, 2008 (prior to the existence of TARP), the Fed announced that it was taking
action to support AIG in the form of a secured two-year line of credit with a value of up to $85
billion and an interest rate of 8.5 percentage points above the three-month LIBOR. In addition,
the government received warrants to purchase up to 79.9% of the equity in AIG. On October 8,
2008, the Fed announced that it would lend AIG up to an additional $37.8 billion against
securities held by its insurance subsidiaries.76
In early November 2008 (following the creation of TARP), the financial support for AIG was
restructured. The restructured financial support consisted of (1) reducing the size of the Fed loan
to up to $60 billion, with the term lengthened to five years and the interest rate reduced by 5.5
percentage points; (2) purchasing $40 billion in preferred shares through TARP; and (3) replacing
the $37.8 billion loan with up to $52.5 billion total in asset purchases by the Fed through two
LLCs known as Maiden Lane II and Maiden Lane III. The 79.9% equity position of the
government in AIG remained essentially unchanged after the restructuring of the intervention.
In March 2009, the assistance was restructured further through (1) a partial payback of the Fed
loan through a swap of debt for equity in two AIG subsidiaries worth approximately $25 billion,
reducing the maximum to $35 billion and (2) commitments for additional future TARP purchases
of up to $29.8 billion in preferred shares at AIG’s discretion, and the conversion of existing shares
into shares with optional dividend payments.77 The Maiden Lane LLCs continued operating under
the previous terms, with the actual loans extended to the LLCs totaling $43.9 billion at their peak.
In September 2010, AIG and the government announced another restructuring of the
government’s assistance. This restructuring closed on January 14, 2011. The expressed goal was
to simplify the government’s interest in AIG and provide a path for the government to divest its
stake in AIG. The essence of the plan called for (1) ending the Fed’s involvement with AIG
through loan repayment and transfer of the Fed’s equity interests to Treasury and (2) converting
the government’s $49.1 billion in existing preferred shares into common shares, which could then
be sold to the public over time. The specific steps involved several interlocking transactions,

74 For details on the Fed’s assistance, see New York Fed, Actions Related to AIG, http://www.newyorkfed.org/
aboutthefed/aig/index.html. For more information on the federal assistance to AIG, see CRS Report R42953,
Government Assistance for AIG: Summary and Cost, by Baird Webel.
75 See, for example, “U.S. to Take Over AIG in $85 Billion Bailout; Central Banks Inject Cash as Credit Dries Up,”
Wall Street Journal, September 17, 2008, pp. A1-A6.
76 In October 2008, AIG also announced that it had applied to the Fed’s broadly available Commercial Paper Funding
Facility (CPFF) and was approved to borrow up to $20.9 billion at the facility’s standard terms. At its peak use in
January 2009, AIG had commercial paper worth $16.1 billion outstanding from the CPFF. AIG continued to access the
facility until it expired in February 2010. Over the life of the facility, AIG paid $0.4 billion in interest to the CPFF.
AIG’s use of the CPFF is included in the CPFF totals, not the AIG totals, in this report.
77 AIG issued $1.6 billion of additional preferred shares to the government in recognition of accrued, unpaid dividends
on the initial $40 billion in assistance.
Congressional Research Service
28

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

including the initial public offering of a large AIG subsidiary, the sale of several other AIG
subsidiaries, and the use of up to approximately $20 billion in TARP funds to transfer equity
interests from the Fed to the Treasury.
All of the Fed loans have been repaid, and the assets held in the Maiden Lane LLCs have been
sold. Maiden Lanes II and III were formally terminated on November 12, 2014. The Fed earned
interest of $8.2 billion on the loan to AIG and $9.5 billion on the Maiden Lanes. In addition to the
income received by the Fed, Treasury received an additional $17.6 billion on the sale of equity
that the Fed originally received (and subsequently transferred to the Treasury) as recompense for
the Fed’s loan to AIG.
Citigroup
On November, 23, 2008, the Treasury, Fed, and Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)
announced a joint intervention in Citigroup, which had previously received $25 billion in TARP
Capital Purchase Program funding.78 This exceptional intervention to “[support] financial
stability” consisted of an additional $20 billion purchase of preferred shares through the TARP
Targeted Investment Program and a government guarantee for a pool of $306 billion in Citigroup
assets (reduced to $301 billion when the guarantee was finalized on January 16, 2009) through
the TARP Asset Guarantee Program, the FDIC, and the Fed.79
In December 2009, Citigroup and Treasury reached an agreement to cancel the asset guarantee.
While the asset guarantee was in place, no losses were claimed and no federal funds were paid
out. The Fed’s share of the termination fee for the asset guarantee was $50 million.80
Bank of America
On January 16, 2009, the Treasury, Fed, and FDIC announced a joint intervention in Bank of
America, which had previously received $25 billion in TARP Capital Purchase Program funds.
Bank of America’s losses were largest at Merrill Lynch, which it was in the process of taking
over. The Fed and Treasury may have been most concerned that if Bank of America was not
offered special assistance, the merger would fall through and Merrill Lynch would experience a
disorderly failure. “[A]s part of its commitment to support financial market stability,”81 this
exceptional assistance included the purchase of an additional $20 billion of Bank of America
preferred shares through the TARP Targeted Investment Program and a joint guarantee on a pool
of up to $118 billion of certain Bank of America assets (largely those acquired through its merger
with Merrill Lynch). The announced guarantee was to remain in place for 10 years for residential
mortgage-related assets and 5 years for all other assets. Bank of America would have borne up to

78 U.S. Treasury, “Joint Statement by Treasury, Federal Reserve, and FDIC on Citigroup,” press release hp-1287,
November 23, 2008.
79 For information on Citigroup’s TARP shares, see CRS Report R41427, Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP):
Implementation and Status
, by Baird Webel.
80 U.S. Treasury, “Treasury Prices Sale of Citigroup Subordinated Notes for Proceeds of $894 Million, Providing an
Additional Profit for Taxpayers on TARP Citigroup Investment,” press release, February 5, 2013,
http://www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-releases/Pages/tg1841.aspx; U.S. Treasury, “Taxpayers Receive $10.5
Billion In Proceeds Today From Final Sale Of Treasury Department Citigroup Common Stock,” press release,
December 10, 2010, http://www.financialstability.gov/latest/pr_12102010.html; Federal Reserve, “Support for Specific
Institutions,” available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_supportspecific.htm.
81 U.S. Treasury, “Treasury, Federal Reserve, and the FDIC Provide Assistance to Bank of America,” press release
hp1356, January 16, 2009.
Congressional Research Service
29

Federal Reserve: Emergency Lending

the first $10 billion of losses on the assets, with subsequent losses split 90% to the government
and 10% to Bank of America. Within the government, the losses were to be split between the
TARP Asset Guarantee Program, the FDIC, and the Fed.
Although the asset guarantee was announced in January 2009, a final agreement was never
signed. On September 21, 2009, Bank of America announced that it had negotiated a $425 million
termination fee (of which, the Fed received $57 million) that allowed it to withdraw from the
Asset Guarantee Program.82

Author Contact Information

Marc Labonte

Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
mlabonte@crs.loc.gov, 7-0640

Acknowledgments
The Appendix is adapted from CRS Report R43413, Costs of Government Interventions in Response to the
Financial Crisis: A Retrospective
, by Baird Webel and Marc Labonte. “Selected Legislation in the 114th
Congress” was co-authored with M. Maureen Murphy.

82 U.S. Treasury, “Asset Guarantee Program,” available at http://www.treasury.gov/initiatives/financial-stability/TARP-
Programs/bank-investment-programs/agp/Pages/overview.aspx. The termination agreement is available at
http://www.treasury.gov/initiatives/financial-stability/programs/investment-programs/agp/Documents/BofA%20-
%20Termination%20Agreement%20-%20executed.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
30