The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC): An Economic Analysis

February 1, 2016 (R44057)
Jump to Main Text of Report

Contents

Figures

Tables

Appendixes

Summary

The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) is a refundable tax credit available to eligible workers earning relatively low wages. The EITC, enacted nearly 40 years ago, has evolved from a relatively modest tax benefit to a significant antipoverty program. In light of potential congressional interest in modifying the credit, this report reviews the economic research on the EITC. An understanding of the economic impact of the credit, as well as its limitations and potential drawbacks, may inform future legislative modifications of the credit.

When initially enacted in the 1970s, there were two major purposes of the EITC. First, the credit was meant to encourage the nonworking poor with children to enter the workforce. Second, the credit was intended to help reduce the tax burdens of working poor families with children. Some policymakers at the time worried that taxes—especially payroll taxes—would reduce poor families' take-home pay to such an extent that they would need to rely on cash welfare. In the 1990s, the purpose of the credit was expanded to include poverty reduction, with a focus on encouraging welfare recipients—generally unmarried mothers—to work. At the time, the EITC was seen as a way to ensure that a full-time worker with children would not be in poverty.

As the credit has expanded and changed over time, researchers have evaluated various aspects of the credit:


The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC): An Economic Analysis

Introduction

The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) is a refundable tax credit available to eligible workers earning relatively low wages. Since the credit is refundable, an EITC recipient need not owe taxes to receive the benefit. Many low-income workers, especially those with children, may be eligible to receive the EITC.

The EITC, enacted 40 years ago, has evolved from a relatively modest tax benefit to a significant antipoverty program. As the credit has expanded and changed over time, researchers have evaluated various aspects of the credit, including

In light of potential congressional interest in modifying the credit, this report reviews the current economic research on the EITC. An understanding of the economic impacts of the credit, as well as its limitations and potential drawbacks, may inform future legislative modifications of the EITC.

This report first briefly outlines the history of the EITC, focusing on its evolution from a modest "work bonus" to a major antipoverty program. Next the report turns to an evaluation of the credit, reviewing the economic literature on how the credit has affected taxpayers' decisions to work (what economists refer to as "labor supply decisions"), how it has affected tax burdens among different taxpayers, and the complexity of administering this tax provision. This report does not provide a detailed overview of the credit. For more information on eligibility for and calculation of the EITC, see CRS Report R43805, The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC): An Overview, by [author name scrubbed] and [author name scrubbed].

Purpose and History of the Credit

Before the EITC's enactment in 1975, cash welfare payments were the primary form of federal financial support for poor families with children. However, during the 1960s and 1970s, in the face of increasing concern over growing welfare rolls,1 some policymakers became interested in alternative forms of aid. Economist Milton Friedman proposed a negative income tax (NIT) that would have provided a guaranteed minimum level of income administered through the tax code.2 President Nixon, influenced by the NIT, proposed in 1969 a "family assistance plan" (FAP) that would have benefited both the working and nonworking poor with children, effectively replacing the existing cash welfare program known at the time as Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC). While the Nixon plan never became law, it was twice approved by the House.3

Senator Russell Long, then chairman of the Senate Finance Committee, expressed interest in an alternative government assistance program which would encourage the poor to work by providing them with a "work bonus" or supplement to their wages. Senator Long's "primary objection to the NIT was that it provided its largest benefits to those without earnings"4 and would hence discourage people from working. In contrast, Senator Long stated that his proposed "work-bonus plan" was "a dignified way" to help poor Americans "whereby the more he [or she] works the more he [or she] gets."5

In addition, the work-bonus plan was seen as a way to help reduce increasing payroll tax burdens. The worker's share of payroll taxes had risen from 1.5% in 1950, to 3.0% in 1960, and 4.8% in 1970.6 During the 1960s and 1970s, there was a growing belief among policymakers that payroll taxes, as a regressive tax, especially burdened the working poor. Several antipoverty task forces also "showed that future refinancing of the Social Security system might encumber the poor even more."7 Advocates of the work-bonus plan believed that payroll taxes reduced the poor's income to such an extent that the only way they could make ends meet was to receive welfare. According to Long, his "work bonus plan" would "prevent the social security tax from taking away from the poor and low-income earners the money they need for support of their families."8

In 1975, the work bonus plan was enacted on a temporary basis as part of the Tax Reduction Act of 1975 and renamed the Earned Income Tax Credit.9 In addition to encouraging the poor to work and reducing their dependence on cash welfare, the credit was also viewed as a means to encourage economic growth in the face of the 1974 recession and rising food and energy prices.10 Since the EITC was viewed in part as an alternative to cash welfare, it was generally targeted to the same recipients—single mothers with children.11 (Childless poor adults would not receive the credit until the 1990s, discussed subsequently.) The credit was extended several more times on a temporary basis before being expanded and made permanent by the Revenue Act of 1978 (P.L. 95-600).12 Making the credit permanent reflected Congress's belief "that the earned income credit is an effective way to provide work incentives and relief from income and Social Security taxes to low-income families who might otherwise need large welfare payments."13

In the late 1980s and 1990s, policymakers remained interested in the EITC as an antipoverty program. A Wall Street Journal article from 1989 described the EITC as "emerging as the antipoverty tool of choice among poverty experts and politicians as ideologically far apart as Vice President Dan Quayle and Representative Tom Downey, a liberal New York Democrat."14 President Bill Clinton, a champion of the EITC as a poverty-reduction tool, declared that expanding the credit would "reward the work of millions of working poor Americans by realizing the principle that if you work 40 hours a week and you've got a child in the house, you will no longer be in poverty."15 As one scholar noted, "President Clinton's declaration completed the evolution of the EITC from Senator Long's modest 'work bonus' to a major antipoverty initiative."16

Before the 1990s, the EITC's structure limited its ability to reduce poverty among families of different sizes. As illustrated in Table 1, the EITC as originally designed did not vary by family size. Thus, as family size increased, the credit became less effective at helping a family meet its needs. The EITC was restructured to vary based on family size beginning modestly with the Omnibus Reconciliation Act of 1990 (OBRA90; P.L. 101-508) and greatly expanded by the Omnibus Reconciliation Act of 1993 (OBRA93; P.L. 103-66)17 Specifically, the EITC was now calculated such that at any given level of earnings, the credit was one size for a taxpayer with a single child and larger for taxpayers with two or more children. For example, when OBRA93's legislative changes had fully phased in, taxpayers with one child could receive a maximum credit of $2,152, while families with two or more children could receive a maximum credit of $3,556 in 1996.18 The 1993 bill also extended the credit to childless workers for the first time (see Table 1). Unlike the expansion of the credit for workers with children, the main rationale for this "childless EITC" was not poverty reduction. Instead the credit was intended to partly offset a gasoline tax increase included in OBRA93.19 The credit for childless workers was smaller than the credit for workers with children. It was calculated as 7.65% of the first $4,000 of earnings, for a $323 maximum credit in 1996. Notably, aside from inflation adjustments, the formula for the childless EITC has remained unchanged since OBRA93.

At the beginning of 2000, there was congressional interest among both political parties in reducing marriage penalties (although the means by which they intended to achieve this goal varied).20 For low-income taxpayers with little or no tax liability, a marriage penalty is said to occur when a married couple receives a smaller refund than the combined refund of each partner filing as unmarried. (Marriage bonuses also arise in the U.S. federal income tax code).21 In 2001, the Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT) identified the structure of the EITC as one of the primary causes of the marriage penalty among low-income taxpayers.22

In 2001, Congress chose to reduce the marriage penalty in the EITC. The Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001 (EGTRRA; P.L. 107-16) gradually increased the income level at which the credit phased out for married couples by $3,000 (adjusted for inflation). In 2009, ARRA temporarily increased EITC marriage penalty relief to $5,000, also adjusted for inflation. This change was originally in effect for 2009 and 2010. The increased marriage penalty relief was extended for 2011 and 2012 by the Tax Relief, Unemployment Insurance Reauthorization, and Job Creation Act of 2010 (P.L. 111-312) and further extended from 2013 until the end of 2017 by the American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012 (P.L. 112-240; ATRA). The Protecting Americans from Tax Hikes (PATH) Act (Division Q of P.L. 114-113) made the $5,000 of EITC marriage penalty relief permanent.

Table 1. Key Characteristics of the EITC Credit Formula Under Selected Laws, 1975-2009

 

1975

1978

1984

1986

1990

1993

2001

2009

 

P.L. 94-12

P.L. 95-600

P.L. 98-369

P.L. 99-514

P.L. 101-508

P.L. 103-66

P.L. 107-16

P.L. 111-5

Adjust Formula Parameters Such that the Amount of Credit Increases from Previous Statutory Levels
(e.g., change credit rate, earned income amount, phase-out rate or phase-out threshold, excluding marriage penalty relief)

Enacting legislation

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

no

yes
For families with 3+ children only

Credit Available Only to Workers with Children

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

no

no

no

Credit Amount Based on:

Earnings
(The credit amount changes with earnings, equal to earnings times the credit rate in the phase-in region, the max credit amount in the plateau, and declining proportional to the phase-out rate in the phase-out region)

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

Number of Children
(The credit formula based in part on family size, with different formulas used to calculate he credit based on the number of children)

no

no

no

no

yes

(credit formulas for families w/ 1 & 2+children)

yes

(credit formulas for families w/ 1 & 2+children)

yes

(credit formulas for families w/ 1 & 2+children)

yes

(credit formulas for families w/ 1,2, & 3+children)

Marital Status
(The credit phases out at a higher income level for married couples than for unmarried individuals with the same number of children. This differential is referred to as "marriage penalty relief.")

no

no

no

no

no

no

yes

(Up to $3,000 marriage penalty relief)

yes

($5,000 marriage penalty relief)

Credit Available to Childless Workers

no

no

no

no

no

yes

yes

yes

Credit Adjusted Annually for Inflation

no

no

no

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

Source: CRS analysis of P.L. 94-12, P.L. 95-600, P.L. 98-369, P.L. 99-514, P.L. 101-508, P.L. 103-66, P.L. 107-16, and P.L. 111-5.

Notes: This table does not reflect all the legislative changes that occurred to the EITC between 1975 and 2009, but instead focuses on major legislative changes to the credit formula. These include adjusting the credit for family size (including to those with no children), marital status, and for inflation, as well parameter changes (like the credit rate, earned income amount, phase-out rate and phase-out threshold).

Current Structure of the EITC23

There are eight formulas currently in effect to calculate the EITC (four for unmarried individuals and four for married couples, depending on the number of children they have), as illustrated in Table 2.

Table 2. The Value of the EITC by Number of Qualifying Children and Marital Status, 2015

number of qualifying children

0

1

2

3 or more

unmarried tax filers (single and head of household filers)

credit rate

7.65%

34%

40%

45%

earned income amount

$6,580

$9,880

$13,870

$13,870

maximum credit amount

$503

$3,359

$5,548

$6,242

phase-out threshold

$8,240

$18,110

$18,110

$18,110

phase-out rate

7.65%

15.98%

21.06%

21.06%

income when credit = 0

$14,820

$39,131

$44,454

$47.747

married tax filers (married filing jointly)

credit rate

7.65%

34%

40%

45%

earned income amount

$6,580

$9,880

$13,870

$13,870

maximum credit amount

$503

$3,359

$5,548

$6,242

phase-out threshold

$13,750

$23,630

$23,630

$23,630

phase-out rate

7.65%

15.98%

21.06%

21.06%

income when credit = 0

$20,330

$44,651

$49,974

$53,267

Source: IRS Revenue Procedure 2014-61 and Internal Revenue Code (IRC) Section 32.

For any claimant, the credit has three value ranges that vary by income as illustrated in Figure 1. First, the credit value increases to its maximum value from the first dollar of earnings until earnings reach the "earned income amount." Over this "phase-in range" the credit value is equal to the credit rate multiplied by earnings. When earnings are between the "earned income amount" and the "phase-out threshold"—referred to as the "plateau"—the credit amount remains constant at its maximum level. For each dollar over the "phase-out threshold," the credit is reduced by the phase-out rate until the credit equals zero. This final range of income over which the credit falls in value is referred to as the "phase-out range."

Figure 1. EITC for an Unmarried Worker with One Qualifying Child, 2015

Source: Congressional Research Service based on information in IRS Revenue Procedure 2014-61 and Internal Revenue Code Section 32.

How to Calculate the EITC

The following examples illustrate how to calculate the EITC for an unmarried taxpayer with one qualifying child at varying levels of income, as illustrated in Figure 1 and using the parameters in Table 2. (For simplicity, these examples assume that earned income equals adjusted gross income (AGI).)

Earned Income of $9,000: The taxpayer's income places them in the phase-in range of the credit. Their credit equals the credit rate multiplied by their earned income. In this case, 34% x $9,000 or $3,060.

Earned Income of $15,000: The taxpayer's income places them in the plateau of the credit. Their credit equals the maximum amount of the credit or $3,359.

Earned Income of $30,000: The taxpayer's income places them in the phase-out range of the credit. The maximum value of the credit ($3,359) is reduced by 15.98 cents for every dollar above the phase-out threshold of $18,110. When the taxpayer's earned income was $30,000, the credit would fall by $11,890 ($30,000 minus $18,110) multiplied by 15.98 cents or $1,900. In other words the credit would equal $1,459 ($3,359 minus $1,900).

Evaluation of the Credit

Generally, economists evaluate tax policies—including the EITC—through three different lenses: how the tax provision affects taxpayers' behavior ("efficiency"), how the tax provision affects tax burdens ("equity" or "fairness," which necessitates defining fairness), and the complexity of administering the tax provision ("administration"). A provision may be seen differently through these lenses. For example, a tax provision may simplify the tax code (improve administration), but result in an undesirable behavior (reduce efficiency). The following sections review the research on the EITC in terms of its impact on efficiency, equity, and administration.

Efficiency: How Has the Credit Affected Recipients' Decisions to Work?

Most economic research on the EITC has focused on how the credit affected the work decisions of the original target population of the EITC—unmarried mothers. Indeed unmarried claimants with children remain the majority of EITC recipients and receive the majority of EITC dollars.24 More recently, as the goals and structure of the credit have changed, there has also been some interest in how the credit affects the labor force decisions of married couples. A smaller body of research has examined the impact the EITC has on married secondary earners with children, generally assumed to be women.25 Research tends to examine either the impact that the credit had on a population's decision to start working ("work force participation") or on their decision to work a different number of hours. In some cases, research looks at both of these labor supply decisions. A detailed overview of the economic theory of the labor supply effect (decision to work and number of hours worked) of the EITC is provided in the Appendix.

Workforce Participation of Unmarried Workers

Studies indicate that the EITC has a positive effect on the labor force participation of single mothers.26 These studies generally examine how significant legislative expansions of the EITC influenced previously nonworking single mothers' decisions to enter the workforce.27 For example, one study found that the creation of a larger credit for unmarried individuals with two or more children in the early-1990s resulted in a sharp increase in employment among single mothers.28 Another study found that 34% of the increase in employment among single mothers between 1993 and 1999 was due to legislative expansions of the EITC.29 Other research found that "60% of the 8.7 percentage point increase in annual employment of single mothers between 1984 and 1996 is attributable to the EITC with its expansion."30 In addition to encouraging many single mothers to enter the workforce, the EITC also played a role in reducing welfare caseloads. Research evaluating the interaction between welfare policy and the EITC in the 1990s found that the EITC had a substantial effect in reducing new entries into the cash welfare program.31 In other words, many single mothers chose to work, and receive the EITC, rather than apply for welfare.

Workforce Participation of Married Workers

In comparison to unmarried workers, research is less conclusive as to the impact of the EITC on married secondary earners' decisions to start working. Some empirical evidence suggests that the EITC has caused a small percentage of married mothers to stay out of the labor force. One study, which assumed that married secondary earners were women, found that "the 1993 EITC expansion led to a one percentage point reduction in the participation rate of married mothers."32 Another study found that legislative changes that expanded the EITC resulted in some married women choosing not to work.33 Couples may decide, for example, that one spouse's EITC is sufficiently large to allow the other spouse to stay out of the workforce and instead raise children. These couples could determine that having two earners would not only reduce their EITC, but may also increase the cost of other expenses, like child care, ultimately lowering their disposable income. However, more recent research has found that among married women, the EITC has had a negligible effect on labor force participation.34

If the EITC is discouraging some secondary earners from working it would effectively be "subsidizing the lower earning partner in a married couple to stay home."35 Whether that is desirable from a policy perspective depends on policymakers' goals with respect to married couples with children.

Hours Worked of Unmarried Workers

Basic Economic Theory of How
Taxation Affects Labor Supply

Economists often use the theoretical framework of "income" and "substitution" effects to assess the impact income tax policies—including the EITC—have on labor supply (the decision to work and the number of hours worked). Underlying this framework is the assumption that when a worker is deciding whether to work more or work less, they are ultimately choosing between two goods: leisure (i.e., hours of not working) and consumption (after-tax dollars they can spend on goods).

Substitution effect: When wages increase, the cost of leisure also increases, since the cost of leisure is implicitly the foregone wages from not working.36 Given the laws of supply and demand (as the price of a good rises, consumption falls and vice versa), a worker will "consume less leisure" and hence work more according to the substitution effect.

Income Effect: As wages increase, a worker will have more income and consume more of all goods, including leisure. In other words, an individual will work less.

The ultimate impact a wage increase has on hours worked depends on which effect is greater. If the substitution effect is larger, an individual will work more hours as their wages increase. If the income effect is larger, an individual will work fewer hours as their wages increase.

Among unmarried workers, research on the impact of the EITC on hours worked is not necessarily consistent with theoretical predictions. Fundamental to the theoretical impact of the EITC on hours worked are the concepts of "income" and "substitution" effects. These effects can help economists predict how a worker will behave in response to a policy like the EITC.

For example, in the phase-in region of the credit, the EITC increases the compensation per hour worked (or the "marginal return to work"). For an unmarried worker with one child, $1 of wages pre-EITC will yield $1.34 of wages post-EITC. This additional income makes the worker feel richer for the same amount of work. If the worker has an income target ("I need to make $200 this week"), an increase in wages from the EITC means they can work less to achieve the same level of income. Economists refer to this as the "income effect" of the EITC. At the same time, an increase in the marginal return to work means that "not working" or "leisure" implicitly costs more in terms of foregone wages. Returning to the example of the unmarried worker with one child, not working now costs the individual $1.34 in foregone income instead of $1. Hence, the individual will consume less leisure, and work more. Economists refer to this as the "substitution effect" of the EITC. Hence, if a worker is in the phase-in range of the credit, the impact of the EITC is theoretically ambiguous. The income effect implies they work less, while the substitution effect implies they work more.

However, most EITC recipients' income places them in the plateau or phase-out region of the credit, where the economic framework of income and substitution effects suggest workers will be encouraged to reduce the hours they work.37

Yet, despite the theoretical predictions, most of the empirical evidence indicates the EITC has "had little effect on the number of hours they work."38 As one study stated,

...theory implies that the EITC will decrease hours worked among those already working because most recipients are on the plateau or phase-out portion of the credit schedule. However, recent hours worked patterns for EITC eligible individuals do not appear to fit this second prediction. Hours and weeks worked by likely recipient groups have not fallen. 39

There are several explanations as to why the EITC may have had little impact on the number of hours unmarried parents work. Chief among them is that the complexity and timing of the EITC limits its work incentive effect. Taxpayers may not understand the complex relationship between the credit's value and the worker's earnings, complexity that is likely compounded by receiving the credit the year after employment decisions are made. In addition, some experts suggest that instead of responding to the marginal impact that work has on their EITC amount (and overall tax liability), tax filers instead make their decision about how much they will work based on their average tax rate (their total taxes or refund divided by their total income).40 The impact of additional earnings on average tax rates is generally lower than its impact on marginal tax rates, which may also account for the limited impact of the EITC on hours worked. Finally, workers in low-wage jobs may not have the flexibility to alter the number of hours they work, even if they would like to.

Recent Research

More recent research has provided a more complex picture of taxpayer behavior with respect to the EITC, behavior that might not be apparent in the previous analyses of aggregate data. Specifically, it is possible that in certain circumstances a worker may adjust their income level (including by adjusting hours worked) to maximize their credit. To understand this finding, it is important to remember that there are two inflection or "kink" points in the EITC schedule: at the earned income amount and at the phase-out threshold, as illustrated in Figure 1. The earned income amount is the lowest earnings level at which the credit reaches its maximum amount. The phase-out threshold is the highest earnings level at which the credit remains at its maximum amount. Recent research has examined whether taxpayers "bunch" around these inflection points. In other words, do taxpayers tend to earn the exact amount of money needed to get the largest credit?

One study found "clear evidence of bunching around the first kink point of the EITC—the point at which the credit reaches its maximum level."41 In addition, bunching tended to increase over time, suggesting taxpayers were learning about the structure of the EITC. This effect however was concentrated among the self-employed—who "tend to have a substantial ability to manipulate their earnings (both by reducing hours or reducing reported earnings)."42 No bunching effect was found among EITC recipients with only wage income and the authors did not report evidence of bunching around the second kink point of the EITC. However, these results did indicate that some self-employed individuals were aware of the EITC formula, and how it varied by earnings. Using high rates of "self-employed bunching" as a proxy for "high knowledge" about the structure of the EITC, a subsequent study focusing on wage earners found that EITC claimants who live in "high knowledge" neighborhoods tended to have wage earnings concentrated in the EITC plateau.43 Crucially, the authors noted that

the welfare consequences of the EITC depend on whether the higher concentration of earnings around the refund-maximizing plateau of the EITC schedule comes from increased earnings for those who would have been in the phase-in region or reduced earnings for those who would have been in the phase-out region.44

Assuming no changes in wage rates, this would imply workers would adjust the number of hours they work to maximize the credit. The authors found that the majority of the clustering effect in the plateau region was from workers whose income originally placed them in the phase-in region working more hours, rather than from those in the phase-out region working fewer hours. These studies suggest that low-income workers may respond to the EITC by increasing hours worked.

Some policymakers are interested in the impact of the EITC on unmarried workers' decision to marry, especially since many married EITC recipients may receive a smaller EITC as a married couple than their combined EITCs as two single tax filers. A smaller EITC for married couples (known as a "marriage penalty") could discourage cohabitating couples from marrying.45 (Importantly, certain couples can receive a marriage bonus from the EITC).

For example, in 2014, two single parents, each with one child and earned income of $15,000, would receive an EITC of $3,305 each for a total EITC of $6,610. If they married, their combined income would be $30,000, and with two children, their EITC would be $4,041.46 The EITC marriage penalty for this couple would be $2,659.

While limited, research indicates that the EITC's effects on marriage patterns are small and ambiguous.47

However, this newer research still does not explain why the EITC apparently does not lead to an overall reduction in hours worked among workers whose income places them in the phase-out range, even though economic theory suggests otherwise. As Hoynes states with respect to workers whose income places them in the phase-out region of the credit "we expect hours to decrease ... the literature has failed to find a consistent negative impact of the EITC on hours worked. This, I think, is a bit of a puzzle."48 One possible theory is that workers in the phase-in range are part-time workers and can increase their hours in response to the EITC, whereas workers in the phase-out range are likely full-time workers who might not have the option to cut back their hours.

Hours Worked of Married Workers

With respect to married couples, research focusing on the secondary earner found that the EITC does tend to result in a slight reduction of hours worked among these workers. One study found that EITC expansions resulted in a 0.57% to 4.37% reduction in hours worked among married women,49 while another study found a similar reduction of 1% to 4% of hours worked among married women.50

Decisions to Work of Childless Workers

Finally, studies have not focused on the labor supply effects of the EITC for childless workers. One reason may be because the EITC for childless workers was enacted after the credit for workers with children and unlike the credit for workers with children, the childless EITC formula was never expanded. As previously discussed, many studies of the EITC looked at how legislative expansions of the credit for workers with children affected their labor force decisions. The EITC for childless workers has effectively remained unchanged from its 1993 formula—except for annual inflation adjustments. In addition, the EITC for childless workers is likely too small to encourage workers to work at a low-wage job, especially on a full-time basis. For example, a childless worker working full time at a minimum wage job51 (40 hours a week, 50 weeks a year) would receive a $7 credit in 2014. In contrast, a single parent with just one child working full time at a minimum wage job would receive a $3,305 credit.

Equity: How Has the Credit Affected Poverty Rates and Tax Burdens?

When examining the impact the EITC has on fairness or equity, research has tended to focus on how the credit affects poverty rates and tax burdens among different groups of recipients. The EITC has had a significant impact on reducing poverty among recipients with children, but little impact among childless individuals. In addition, the EITC has increased inequity in the tax code between those with and without children.

Poverty Reduction

The EITC is one of the federal government's largest antipoverty programs,52 reflecting a trend toward reducing poverty through the tax code.53 The official poverty measure, however, is unable to capture the antipoverty impact of the EITC. The official poverty measure is calculated by comparing an individual's or family's resources, measured as pre-tax cash income (hence excluding the EITC), to a poverty threshold, roughly equal to three times the cost of spending on the U.S. Department of Agriculture's Economy Food Plan. If an individual's or family's resources are less than their applicable threshold, the individual or family is counted as poor.54

New experimental poverty measures that include government benefits like the EITC provide evidence of such programs' antipoverty effects. The U.S. Census Bureau found that when government tax and transfer programs were included in a broader measure of poverty, refundable tax credits were estimated to reduce poverty by three percentage points. This compares to a 1.6 percentage-point reduction for food assistance (known as SNAP or the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program) and a 0.2 percentage-point reduction for welfare (known as TANF or the Temporary Assistance for Needy Families).55 Although this analysis includes both the EITC and refundable portion of the child tax credit, the EITC is the largest refundable tax credit targeted to the poor, and previous research indicates that most of the antipoverty impact of refundable tax credits can be attributed to the EITC.56

The antipoverty effects of the EITC are not uniform across different types of households and tax filers. Figure 2 illustrates how pre-tax income of workers at the federal poverty level (FPL)57 changes after subtracting taxes owed (including payroll taxes) and adding back the EITC. Under the current federal income tax, married and unmarried childless workers with pre-tax income at the FPL tend to see their income remain below the poverty line after taxation, even when including the EITC. In contrast, married and unmarried workers with children whose pre-tax income is at the FPL will have post-tax income above the FPL because the EITC is greater than their payroll tax liability. Many poor tax filers, especially those with children, do not generally owe federal income tax.58

Figure 2. Effects of Taxes and EITC on Taxpayers at Poverty Level, 2014

Source: CRS calculations.

Notes: The term "tax" includes federal income tax and the employee's share of payroll taxes. Other tax credits that recipients may be eligible for, like the child tax credit, are not included.

In addition, as illustrated in Table 3, poor childless workers tend to have very low incomes, with 43% to 47% of those in poverty in extreme poverty, meaning their incomes are below 50% of the FPL. Although poor childless workers tend to be extremely poor, and poorer than their peers with children, childless workers receive a maximum EITC that is significantly smaller than the credit received by workers with children. Hence, the EITC reduces unmarried and married childless workers' poverty rates by 0.14% and 1.39%, respectively, in comparison to rates for workers with children that are at least 15 times larger (see Table 3).

As illustrated in Table 3, the EITC reduces poverty rates more for married parents than for single parents. The data also indicate, however, that a major factor in this difference may be that poor single parents are generally much more impoverished than their married peers. Hence, for poor single parents, the EITC may be too small to push them over the poverty threshold.

Table 3. The Impact of the EITC on Poverty Rates, 2012
(by marital status and number of related children under the age of 18)

Family Characteristics

Percentage of Families in Poverty Using an Alternative Measure of Income

Percentage Change in Poverty Rates from the EITC

Addendum: Percentage of Poor in Extreme Poverty (below 50% of the official federal poverty line)

Marital Status

Number of Related Children Under 18 in the Family

EITC Excluded from Income

EITC Included in Income

 

 

Single

0

22.29%

22.26%

-0.14%

47.41%

 

1

29.11%

24.74%

-15.02%

44.59%

 

2

33.97%

28.31%

-16.65%

41.75%

 

3

48.03%

41.26%

-14.10%

41.68%

Married

0

4.44%

4.38%

-1.39%

43.26%

 

1

5.27%

4.17%

-20.89%

36.06%

 

2

6.10%

4.46%

-26.86%

30.55%

 

3

10.04%

7.09%

-29.38%

29.69%

Source: CRS analysis of the 2013 Current Population Survey.59

Notes: The poverty rates in this table—both pre- and post-EITC—do not reflect the official poverty rate calculations. The poverty rates are calculated by comparing a family's resources to the official poverty threshold. For the purposes of this analysis, a family's resources include government benefits (like Social Security, food assistance, housing assistance, health benefits) net of taxes paid and expenses associated with work, like child care. The EITC is then included in one measure of resources, but excluded in the other. Both measures of resources are then compared with the official poverty threshold to determine if the individual or family is poor. This data illustrates several key aspects of the antipoverty effectiveness of the EITC based on marital status and number of children.

Tax Burdens

Tax burdens are the percentage of a taxpayer's income that is paid in taxes. In this report, the terms tax burdens, effective tax rates, and average tax rates are used interchangeably.

Tax Burdens by Income

The EITC changes the distribution of the tax burden across taxpayers at different income levels. Data from the Tax Policy Center (TPC), summarized in Table 4, illustrate the impact of the EITC on the effective tax rates paid by tax units in different income classes. TPC estimates that in 2013, the EITC lowered the average tax rates for tax units with income below $75,000, providing the greatest benefit to those with income between $10,000 and $20,000. Notably, the TPC estimates show that the EITC does not result in the poorest tax units paying the lowest average tax rates, as many tax units in the lowest income class are ineligible for the EITC or only eligible for a small EITC.60

Table 4. Federal Tax Rates With and Without the EITC, 2013

 

Average Federal Tax Rate

Average Decrease in Federal Tax Liability from Credit

Percent of Tax Units Who Receive the Benefit

Share of Total Value of EITC

Tax Units'
Cash Income Level

Without
EITC

With
EITC

 

 

 

Less than $10,000

7.6%

3.9%

$219

26.7%

4.2%

$10,000-$20,000

5.7%

1.8%

$583

29.3%

20.8%

$20,000-$30,000

7.9%

4.2%

$908

28.1%

27.0%

$30,000-$40,000

9.7%

7.4%

$818

27.3%

20.2%

$40,000-$50,000

11.2%

9.7%

$665

26.0%

14.2%

$50,000-$75,000

13.2%

12.7%

$306

16.8%

11.5%

$75,000-$100,000

15.0%

15.0%

$40

3.0%

0.9%

$100,000-$200,000

17.6%

17.6%

$3

0.1%

0.1%

$200,000+

22.6%

22.6%

$0

0.0%

0.0%

Source: Tax Policy Center, Table T13-0220, http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/numbers/Content/PDF/T13-0220.pdf.

Notes: Tax units in each income class include both those eligible and ineligible for the EITC. Cash income includes wages and salaries, investment (taxable dividends, realized net capital gains) and business income, as well as government transfer payments (Social Security, SSI, veterans benefits), employee contributions to tax-deferred retirement savings plans, and business income or loss. In addition, it includes both filing and non-filing units but excludes those that are dependents of other tax units. Tax units with negative adjusted gross income are excluded from their respective income class but are included in the totals. For a description of expanded cash income, see http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/TaxModel/income.cfm.

Tax Burdens by Family Structure

What is a "tax unit"?

When economists analyze the tax code or tax provisions, their analysis often focuses on the impact of tax policy on a "tax unit." A tax unit is defined as either an individual, or in the case of those filing a married joint return, a married couple, and all the dependents of the individual or married couple.

For the purposes of the analysis of tax burdens in this report only, "tax units" will sometimes be used interchangeably with the terms "families" or "households." However, the technical definition of "families" and "households" used by other government agencies like the Census Bureau may result in tax units and families and households differing.61

Economists also evaluate how tax provisions affect the tax burdens of different families. In effect, they evaluate the tax burdens of "equivalent" families or families that have the same standard of living. These families will have the same "ability-to-pay" a tax. Tax policies that result in families with the same "ability-to-pay" having the same tax burden are referred to as horizontally equitable by economists.

A family's ability to pay will be affected by the size and composition of the family. As families increase in size, they tend to need additional income to have the same standard of living as smaller families. However, the amount of additional resources will not be the same for each additional family member. For example, one study found that by using a commonly accepted formula—called an "equivalence scale"—to adjust for family size, a family composed of one individual with a cash income of $10,000, was equivalent to (i.e., had the same standard of living) as a family with two members and a cash income of $14,142, a family with three members and cash income of $17,321, and a family of four and cash income of $20,000.62

Using an equivalence scale developed to determine poverty thresholds for families of different sizes,63 one study concluded that the EITC resulted in tax rates among low-income tax filers that were horizontally inequitable.64 For example, when comparing families whose incomes were equivalent to $10,000 (what the researchers called "the reference income level"),65 the authors found that

At a $10,000 reference income, all effective tax rates are negative, and the rates range from -1.47 percent for a married couple with no children to -39.21 percent for a head-of-household return with two children, a difference of more than a third of income.66

Using equivalence scales developed by the Census Bureau,67 and calculating 2015 effective tax rates based on these income levels and family compositions, more recent analysis indicates that horizontal inequity also exists at higher income levels, as illustrated in Table 5. A major factor in this horizontal inequity among low-income tax filers is the larger EITC credit for families with children, which results in "dramatic differences between families with and without children."68,69 As incomes rise to around $25,000, the variation in effective tax rates falls among equivalent families, as fewer tax filers are eligible for the EITC or are eligible for a smaller EITC due to the phase out of the credit. In addition, the child tax credit further increases horizontal inequity between those with and without children. This has led researchers to conclude that "the clearest change that would increase horizontal equity ... is a larger EITC for single workers and childless couples."70

While the effective tax rates of "equivalent families" provided in Table 5 depend in part on the equivalence scale used, research indicates that horizontal inequities will still exist—though to different degrees—even when assumptions used to construct equivalence scales differ.71

Table 5. Effective Tax Rates for Families with the Same Reference Income, 2015

 

Single

Married
0 Children

Married
1 Child

Married
2 Children

Married
3 Children

HOH
1 Child

HOH
2 Children

HOH
3 Children

Reference Income Level: $10,000 for a Married Couple with No Children

Equivalent Income

$7,071

$10,000

$13,429

$15,257

$16,995

$10,670

$12,668

$14,538

Effective Tax Rate (w/o CTC)

-7.11%

-5.03%

-25.01%

-36.36%

-36.73%

-31.48%

-40.00%

-42.93%

Effective Tax Rate (w/CTC)

-7.11%

-5.03%

-32.46%

-48.42%

-49.08%

-40.85%

-51.45%

-54.84%

Effective Tax Rate (w/CTC & payroll)

0.54%

2.62%

-24.81%

-40.77%

-41.43%

-33.20%

-43.80%

-47.19%

Reference Income Level: $15,000 for a Married Couple with No Children

Equivalent Income

$10,607

$15,000

$20,143

$22,886

$25,493

$16,005

$19,001

$21,807

Effective Tax Rate (w/o CTC)

-2.65%

-2.61%

-16.68%

-24.24%

-22.64%

-20.99%

-27.90%

-24.78%

Effective Tax Rate (w/CTC)

-2.65%

-2.61%

-21.64%

-32.98%

-34.41%

-27.23%

-38.42%

-37.72%

Effective Tax Rate (w/CTC & payroll)

5.00%

5.04%

-13.99%

-25.33%

-26.76%

-19.58%

-30.77%

-30.07%

Reference Income Level: $25,000 for a Married Couple with No Children

Equivalent Income

$17,678

$25,000

$33,572

$38,143

$42,489

$26,676

$31,669

$36,344

Effective Tax Rate (w/o CTC)

4.17%

1.76%

-2.42%

-3.83%

-2.83%

-3.76%

-5.03%

-3.40%

Effective Tax Rate (w/CTC)

4.17%

1.76%

-5.40%

-9.07%

-9.89%

-7.51%

-11.34%

-11.65%

Effective Tax Rate (w/CTC & payroll)

11.82%

9.41%

2.25%

-1.42%

-2.24%

0.14%

-3.69%

-4.00%

Source: CRS calculations using a three-parameter "equivalence" scale used to calculate equivalent families for the supplemental poverty measure. For more information see Kathleen Short, The Supplemental Poverty Measure: 2013, U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Reports, October 2014, p. 19. Effective tax rates calculated using NBER's TAXSIM model for tax year 2015.

Notes: HOH: Head of Household filing status. CTC: The child tax credit. Negative tax rates indicate that that the tax filer receives a refund. These rates are calculated as the total tax divided by income. For the calculations, all income is assumed is assumed to be wage income, the taxpayer taxes no above-the line deductions, and the taxpayer takes the standard deduction and appropriate number of personal exemptions when calculating their taxable income. With respect to the number of children, all are assumed to be under 17, and hence with respect to the child tax credit, eligible for that credit. Payroll taxes are calculated as 7.65% of income.

Simplicity and Administrability: Are the EITC Eligibility Rules and Formula Calculations Easy for Taxpayers to Comply with and for the IRS to Administer?

One concern with the EITC is that its complex rules and formulas make it difficult for taxpayers to comply with and difficult for the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) to administer. Studies indicate that EITC errors by taxpayers (whether intentional or unintentional) result in a relatively high proportion of EITC payments being issued incorrectly. Monitoring for EITC compliance remains a challenge for the IRS.

Taxpayers Challenges Complying with the EITC

Taxpayer error in claiming the EITC has been an ongoing concern with the credit.72 Evidence suggests that the EITC's complex formulas and eligibility rules may result in taxpayers claiming the EITC in error. For example, a non-custodial parent who pays child support may erroneously assume they can claim that child for the credit—resulting in a larger credit than they would otherwise receive. Hence, taxpayer error—whether intentional or unintentional—can result in significant dollar amounts of the credit being claimed incorrectly.

Taxpayer noncompliance with the EITC is often measured in two ways—improper payments and overclaims.

Improper payments are generally smaller than overclaims since improper payments net out amounts recovered or protected by the IRS, while overclaims do not. In addition, the amount of EITC improper payments is reported annually. In contrast, overclaims—which are often discussed in research studies of the factors that lead to tax filer noncompliance—have historically been reported less frequently. The last two comprehensive IRS studies that examined overclaims were released in 1999 and 2014.74

The IRS estimates that in FY2013, 22% to 26% of EITC payments—between $13.3 billion and $15.6 billion—were issued improperly.75 EITC improper payments and rates are high when compared to the improper payments and rates of traditional spending programs (discussed further below in "Improper Payments and Administering a Social Benefit Through the Tax Code").76

In August 2014, the IRS released its most recent EITC compliance study examining the causes of EITC overclaims on 2006, 2007, and 2008 tax returns (henceforth referred to as the "2006-2008 EITC Compliance Study"). Total overclaims from the 2006-2008 EITC Compliance Study were estimated to be between $14.0 billion and $19.3 billion. The study found that between 79% and 85% of EITC dollars claimed incorrectly were claimed by tax filers ineligible for the credit (as opposed to those eligible for a smaller credit).

This study concluded that there were three major reasons77 for errors among claimants:

The 2006-2008 EITC Compliance Study found that the most frequent EITC error was incorrectly reporting income—in most cases self-employment income—and the largest error (in terms of overclaim dollars) was incorrectly claiming a child for the credit, as illustrated in Table 6. The most common qualifying child error was claiming a child who did not fulfill the residency requirement. The study also found that filing status errors are a source of EITC overclaims, although they are a relatively smaller cause of errors in comparison to income reporting and qualifying child errors.

Paid Tax Preparers

Unlike previous studies, the 2006-2008 EITC Compliance Study examined different types of paid tax preparers who prepared tax returns which included EITC claims (these tax returns are sometimes referred to as "EITC returns"). The study found that among paid tax preparers, unenrolled preparers were both the most common type of tax preparers of EITC returns and among the most prone to erroneous claims of the credit. Unenrolled tax preparers generally do not pass the same testing requirements as enrolled preparers (e.g., attorneys and CPAs), and, in contrast to enrolled tax preparers, are limited in how they represent their clients before the IRS. The IRS does not conclude that these data are sufficient to indicate which preparers tend to be less capable or unscrupulous. More research may help to determine "the relative ability or integrity of unenrolled preparers."

Table 6. EITC Overclaims Attributable to Major Types of Error,
2006-2008 Annual Average

 

 

Amount Overclaimed (billions $2008)

Error Type

Number of Returns with Error (millions)

Low Estimate

High Estimate

Income Reporting Error

6.5

$4.5

$5.6

Qualifying Child Error

3.0

$7.2

$10.4

Filing Status Error

1.0

$2.3

$3.3

Total

11.9

$14.0

$19.3

Addendum

Total Number of Returns Claiming the EITC

23.7

Total Dollar Amount of EITC Claimed ($2008)

$49.3

Source: Table 1 (Addendum) and Table 5 of the 2006-2008 EITC Compliance Study.

Note: According to the IRS, the totals may be greater than the sum of each error type due to double counting. First, more than one type of error may occur on a given return. Second the estimate of overclaim dollars treats each error in isolation. Each estimate is calculated assuming the respective error is the only error eliminated. However a given amount of overclaim dollars may occur on a return with multiple errors, with the cost of one error influenced by presence and cost of the other error.

IRS Challenges in Administering the EITC

In addition to taxpayers facing challenges in complying with the EITC rules, the IRS may also face challenges in administering the credit. Specifically, the IRS may or may not be able to detect these errors and administer this tax benefit. Generally, the IRS does not reveal how it detects errors or flags questionable tax returns to prevent persons from using this information to circumvent IRS detection. However, public documents that evaluate the efficacy of the IRS error detection procedures do provide a general overview of some of the ways the IRS may attempt to detect errors, especially before a refund is issued. They also indicate challenges the IRS may face in accurately detecting taxpayer error.

One of the largest sources of qualifying child errors is the child failing to meet the EITC's residency requirement. But the IRS does not have a database containing information on children and with whom they live and for how long. While the IRS may use databases like the Federal Case Registry of child support orders (FCR) or various Social Security databases to try to verify the child meets the residency requirement, they may not always be accurate. For example, an IRS study examining the accuracy of the FCR in validating the residency requirement of the EITC found that of a sample of tax returns that FCR data flagged for audit, 23% of these returns once audited were found to have no adjustments in taxes owed. 78 In other words, 23% of these taxpayers were effectively compliant even though the FCR had flagged them as being noncompliant with the residency requirement of the EITC.

Similarly with respect to some income reporting errors, the IRS may not have information to accurately detect errors. Some observers have suggested that to verify income used to claim the credit the IRS may be able to compare income reported on the tax filer's tax return to information reported on third-party forms. In other cases—especially among the self-employed—the IRS may have incomplete information. Self-employed individuals generally have their compensation reported on a Form 1099. But this compensation does not necessarily represent self-employment income. Taxpayers may deduct a variety of business expenses from their compensation to determine their self-employment income. The IRS, however, does not receive third-party verification of these deductible expenses when a taxpayer files his or her income tax return. In contrast, wage income is directly reported on form W-2 and is provided to both the taxpayer and the IRS. Indeed, the availability of wage income information to both the taxpayer and the IRS may be a factor in the lower dollar amount of overclaims attributable to wage income reporting errors.

While the IRS may have challenges in detecting EITC errors, they are permitted to take certain measures to penalize those taxpayers who claim the credit in error. The IRS can, once they have determined a tax filer improperly claimed the EITC, subject that taxpayer to financial penalties and disallow them from claiming the credit in future years. If upon examination by the IRS, all or part of a taxpayer's EITC is denied, the taxpayer79

(1) must pay back the amount in error with interest; (2) may need to file the Form 8862, Information to Claim Earned Income Credit after Disallowance; (3) may be banned from claiming EITC for the next two years if we [the IRS] find the error is because of reckless or intentional disregard of the rules; or (4) may be banned from claiming EITC for the next ten years if we [the IRS] find the error is because of fraud.

Tax return preparers who erroneously claim the credit on behalf of clients may also be subject to financial penalties, suspension or expulsion from e-file, injunction preventing them from preparing returns or subjecting them to certain limitations, and other disciplinary action.

Improper Payments and Administering a Social Benefit Through the Tax Code

Since the EITC is both a needs-tested transfer to low-income Americans as well as a tax benefit, it is important to put the IRS's challenges in administering the EITC (as well as the high improper payment rate of the credit) in the context of both traditional spending programs and other tax benefits. Often the EITC error rate is compared to the error rates of other spending programs. For example, the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) has designated the EITC as a "high-error program" in comparison to other spending programs, with EITC improper payments the second highest in terms of the total dollar amount (behind Medicare Fee-for-Service) and the highest in terms of improper payment rate (improper payments as a percentage of total payments).80 However, the EITC is not administered like a traditional spending program, but administered as a tax benefit, which may ultimately affect error rates.

For example, some experts stress that spending programs may have lower improper payment rates than the EITC because they screen every participant before the benefit can be claimed. Such screenings generally involve high up-front administrative costs, but may lower the amount of benefits incorrectly paid out. In contrast, the administrative cost of the EITC is relatively minimal. In congressional testimony, the IRS Taxpayer Advocate noted that81

Using tax returns as the "application" for EITC benefits rather than a traditional screening process results in low cost with high participation as well as the risk of improper payment. The IRS has pointed out that for the EITC current administration costs are less than 1% of benefits delivered. This is quite different from other non-tax benefits programs in which administrative costs related to determining eligibility can range as high as 20% of program expenditures.

Minimal pre-filing eligibility verification—generally the norm among tax benefits—may reduce administrative costs but also lead to substantial amounts of the credit being claimed in error.

When revenue losses that arise from EITC errors are compared with other provisions of the tax code, they appear relatively small. A recent IRS report on the tax gap—tax liabilities not paid—found that the largest source of noncompliance with individual income tax laws was the underreporting of business income on individual income tax returns. The IRS estimates that in 2006, the underreporting of business income resulted in reduced revenues of $122 billion.82 As the Taxpayer Advocate stated in the Fiscal Year 2015 Objectives, when comparing the tax gap from the EITC noncompliance versus underreporting business income, "EITC overclaims account for 6% of the gross individual income tax noncompliance while business income underreported by individuals accounts for 51.9%."83

Concluding Remarks

When initially enacted in the 1970s, there were two major purposes of the EITC. First, the credit was meant to encourage the non-working poor (only those with children) to enter the workforce and be more self-sufficient. Second, the credit was intended to help reduce the tax burdens of working poor families with children. While these families were generally not subject to income taxes, they were subject to payroll taxes on their earnings. Some policymakers at the time worried that payroll taxes would reduce poor families' take home pay to such an extent that they would need to rely on cash welfare. In the 1990s, the purposes of the credit were expanded to include poverty reduction, with a focus on encouraging welfare recipients—generally unmarried mothers—to work.

If policymakers want to modify the EITC, it may be helpful to understand both the benefits and limitations or problems with the credit.84 Research on the EITC suggests that the EITC has generally achieved many policymakers' original goals: It has encouraged single mothers to enter the workforce and it has reduced poverty among families with children. However, studies also indicate limitations, unintended consequences, or problems with the EITC. Some research suggests it could discourage some married women from working. It has also been shown to exacerbate inequities in the tax code between taxpayers with and without children. In addition, approximately a quarter of all EITC payments are issued improperly. Improper payments are likely related to the complex eligibility rules of the credit, which can be difficult for taxpayers to comply with and difficult for the Internal Revenue Service to verify. For workers without children, the EITC has generally been shown to be ineffective at reducing poverty and no research has indicated it has any effect on encouraging childless individuals to enter the workforce.

The Economic Theory of the Impact of the EITC on Labor Supply

The EITC, in so far as it changes the marginal returns to work (compensation for each hour of work), will theoretically affect both unmarried and married workers' decisions to work and the amount that they work (i.e., the number of hours). The following is a detailed overview of the theoretical impact of the EITC on labor supply decisions (the decision to work and the number of hours worked).

Workforce Participation

According to economic theory, the EITC will unambiguously increase the workforce participation of single workers because these workers can only receive the credit if they work.85 And those who do not work are no better or worse off as a result of the EITC. As Eissa and Hoynes state "[t]he well-being of a taxpayer who does not work has not changed and any taxpayer who preferred working before [the EITC] will still prefer working, and some taxpayers may find that the additional after-tax income from the EITC makes it worth entering the workforce."86

Among married couples however, the theoretical impact the credit has on each spouse's labor force participation may differ and can be understood using the theoretical framework of "income" and "substitution" effects. In summary, when a tax policy, like the EITC, increases the marginal returns to work, this additional income makes the worker feel richer for the same amount of work. If the worker has an income target ("I need to make $200 this week"), an increase in wages from the EITC means they can work less to achieve the same level of income. Economists refer to this as the "income effect" of the EITC. At the same time, an increase in the marginal return to work means that "not working" or "leisure" implicitly costs more in terms of foregone wages. Hence, the individual will consume less leisure, and work more. This is referred to as the "substitution effect" of the EITC by economists.

Economists generally assume that in a married couple, one spouse is the primary earner, and earns more of the household income than the secondary earner. In addition, economists generally assume that the primary earner makes their labor force participation decision first, and then the secondary earner decides whether to work (this is referred to as sequential family labor supply decisions). In such a model, the primary earner's labor force decision is the same as the one faced by an unmarried worker. They (and their family) will only receive the credit if they work, and hence the labor force participation of primary earners should unambiguously increase.

Given that the value of the EITC for a family is based on the combined earnings of both spouses, the secondary earner's labor force participation decision will depend on the distribution of income between the spouses. If the income of the primary earner is sufficiently low that it places the family in the phase-in region of the credit, then the secondary earner's decision to work will theoretically be ambiguous. On the one hand, by working, the secondary earner would increase the marginal returns to work of the married couple. According to the substitution effect, the secondary earner would be encouraged to work. On the other hand, the family might decide that the additional income from the EITC is sufficient for the family to meet their needs, and according to the income effect, the secondary earner may choose to remain out of the labor force. Given that these two effects move in opposing directions, it is unclear as to whether the labor force participation of secondary earners will increase in this situation, although most empirical research suggests that over this income range, the substitution effect is dominant (and hence the secondary earner will decide to start working).

However, the income of most earners implies that if they were to marry, the combined family income would place the family in the plateau or phase-out range of the credit.87 Over this income range, the income and substitution effects suggest that the secondary earner would be better off staying out of the labor force, which could lead to a reduction of the labor force participation of these individuals. If the secondary earner were to start working, the family's EITC would either remain constant (if the family remained in the plateau region of the credit), or fall in value (if the family was in the phase-out region of the credit). In either region, the family would still receive a credit, and the income effect would suggest that the secondary earner would be discouraged from entering the workforce. If the family's income placed them in the plateau region, the family would receive the same amount of the EITC regardless of the number of hours worked. In other words, the credit would not increase their hourly wage, and hence would have no substitution effect. If the family's income placed them in the phase-out region of the credit, the value of the credit would fall for each additional hour worked. Hence, the cost of leisure would decline, and according to the substitution effect, a secondary earner would be discouraged from working. Thus, in either case, the combined income and substitution effects would discourage some secondary earners from working.

Hours Worked

Economic theory suggests that the decision workers face in terms of how many hours to work will—like the decision a secondary earner faces in terms of working or not working—depend on the income and substitution effects of the credit. For unmarried workers, the impact of the credit will depend on their individual income, while for married workers the impact will depend on their combined family income. For clarity, the following discussion will refer to a single worker, but the same analysis holds for combined family income of a married couple.

As previously discussed, as the EITC phases in, it increases the marginal return to work for the worker.88 For example, as illustrated in Figure 1, in the phase-in range, one dollar of wages pre-EITC leads to $1.34 of wages post-EITC. An increase in the marginal return to work, will lead to the worker feeling richer and working less—the income effect—while also simultaneously raising the cost of not working and encouraging workers to work more—the substitution effect. Given these two opposing forces, the theoretical impact of the EITC on hours worked in this earnings range is ambiguous.

For workers whose income places them in the plateau region of the credit, the framework of income and substitution effects implies a worker will work less. In this plateau region, the worker receives the same amount of the EITC no matter how many hours they work. In other words, the credit does not increase their hourly wage, and hence has no substitution effect. But the credit does have an income effect, encouraging that worker to work less. In effect, if workers receive the same credit amount over a range of earnings, economic theory suggests some workers will choose to work the least number of hours to receive the credit (other workers in the plateau region may work more hours to receive more in wages).

As the credit phases out, it decreases a worker's marginal return to work (i.e., in the example in Figure 1, every additional dollar of pre-EITC earnings leads to a reduction of the EITC by almost 16 cents). Hence, the cost of leisure declines, and according to the substitution effect, a worker will work fewer hours. Even though the amount of the EITC is falling, it is still greater than zero in this range, meaning it still boosts income. Hence, according to the income effect, a worker will consume more leisure and work less. Therefore, economic theory suggests that workers whose incomes places them in the phase-out region of the credit will work less.

Author Contact Information

[author name scrubbed], Analyst in Public Finance ([email address scrubbed], [phone number scrubbed])

Footnotes

1.

The Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) caseload increased from 0.9 million families (3.4 million recipients) in 1961 to 1.7 million families (6.7 million recipients) in 1969. Congressional Research Service (CRS) compilation of data from the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (HHS).

2.

In general, a negative income tax would be structured to mirror a positive income tax. In a positive income tax, income above a certain threshold amount (for example, the standard deduction and the appropriate number of personal exemptions), is taxed. In a negative income tax system, the amount of income below a given threshold is refunded to the taxpayer at a given rate. For example, if a threshold was set at $10,000 for an individual, with a tax or refund rate of 10%, a taxpayer with $11,000 of income would pay $10 in tax. A taxpayer with $9,000 in income would receive a $10 refund. Hence, a taxpayer with zero income would receive a $1,000 refund. For more information on negative income tax, see Robert A. Moffitt, "The Negative Income Tax and the Evolution of U.S. Welfare Policy," NBER Working Paper Series | Working Paper 9751, June 2003.

3.

H.R. 16311 in the 91st Congress and H.R. 1 in the 92nd Congress.

4.

V. Joseph Hotz and John Karl Scholz, "The Earned Income Tax Credit," in Means-Tested Transfer Programs in the United States, ed. Robert A. Moffitt, (University of Chicago Press, 2003), p. 142, http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10256.pdf.

5.

Senator Russell Long, Remarks in the Senate, Congressional Record, September 20, 1972, pp. 33010-33011.

6.

Dennis J. Ventry, "The Collision of Tax and Welfare Politics: The Political History of the Earned Income Tax Credit, 1969-1999," National Tax Journal, vol. 53, no. 4 (December 2000), p. 993.

7.

In addition, "over the years, there were increases in the payroll tax rate, which increased from 2.0% of pay (1.0% each for employees and employers) in the 1937-1949 period to its current level of 12.4%." See CRS Report R42035, Social Security Primer, by [author name scrubbed].

8.

Senator Russell Long, Remarks in the Senate, Congressional Record, September 20, 1972, p. 33010.

9.

As originally enacted, the credit was equal to 10% of the first $4,000 in earnings. Hence, the maximum credit amount was $400. The credit phased out by 10% between incomes of $4,000 and $8,000.

10.

U.S. Congress, Senate Committee on Finance, Tax Reduction Act of 1975, Report to Accompany H.R. 2166, 94th Cong., 1st sess., March 17, 1975, S. Rept. 94-36, p. 11.

11.

For more information, see "Brief History of Cash Assistance" in CRS Report R43187, Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF): Size and Characteristics of the Cash Assistance Caseload, by [author name scrubbed].

12.

This law increased the maximum amount of the credit from $400 to $500. Under the 1978 law, the EITC was set at 10% of the first $5,000 of earnings (including net earnings from self-employment). The maximum credit of $500 was received for earnings between $5,000 and $6,000. For each dollar of AGI above $6,000, the EITC was reduced by 12.5 cents, reaching $0 at an AGI of $10,000.

13.

Joint Committee on Taxation, General Explanation of the Revenue Act of 1978, March 12, 1979, JCS-7-79, p. 51.

14.

David Wessel, "Expanded Earned-Income Tax Credit Emerges As the Anti-Poverty Program of Choice for Many," The Wall Street Journal, July 13, 1989, p. A16.

15.

"Presidential Address to Congress," Reuters transcript of a presidential speech as delivered. February 17, 1993.

16.

V. Joseph Hotz and John Karl Scholz, "The Earned Income Tax Credit," in Means-Tested Transfer Programs in the United States, ed. Robert A. Moffitt, (University of Chicago Press, 2003), p. 146, http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10256.pdf.

17.

The distribution of tax burden played an important role in the congressional negotiations of the 1990 Omnibus Reconciliation Act (OBRA90). Indeed, many commentators have noted that the expansion of the amount of the EITC was often discussed "as a straightforward way to alter the distributional characteristics of various deficit-reduction packages" in such a way as to benefit low-income Americans. V. Joseph Hotz and John Karl Scholz, "The Earned Income Tax Credit," in Means-Tested Transfer Programs in the United States, ed. Robert A. Moffitt, (University of Chicago Press, 2003), p. 146, http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10256.pdf. As part of the 1990 law, beginning in 1991, the credit for the first time was made larger for families with two or more children versus one child. However, these size differences were modest in comparison to what was enacted as part of the Omnibus Reconciliation Act of 1993. For example in 1992, the maximum credit for a tax filer with one child was $1,324. For families with two children the maximum credit was $1,384, $60 more. By contrast, in 1994, the maximum credit for a taxpayer with one child was $2,038, while the maximum credit for a taxpayer with two children was $2,528.

18.

More recently, the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 (ARRA; P.L. 111-5) further adjusted the EITC for larger families, enacting on a temporary basis a larger credit for families with three or more children. This change is currently scheduled to expire at the end of 2017.

19.

CRS Issue Brief, Earned Income Tax Credit: Should It Be Increased to End Poverty for the Working Poor, August 10, 1993, by James R. Storey, available upon request.

20.

For a contemporaneous account of the varying approaches to reduce the marriage penalty debated in 2000, see "Senate Panel Approves Marriage Penalty Relief," New York Times, March 31, 2000.

21.

For more information on marriage penalties and bonuses more generally in the tax code, see Joint Committee on Taxation, Overview of Present Law and Economic Analysis Relating to the Marriage Tax Penalty, the Child Tax Credit, and the Alternative Minimum Tax, March 7, 2001, JCX-8-01, pp. 2-6; and CRS Report RL33755, Federal Income Tax Treatment of the Family, by [author name scrubbed].

22.

The other major factor that the Joint Committee on Taxation identified as causing a marriage penalty among low income taxpayers was the size of the standard deduction. At the time, the standard deduction for married taxpayers did not equal twice the standard deduction for two singles. See Joint Committee on Taxation, Overview of Present Law and Economic Analysis Relating to the Marriage Tax Penalty, the Child Tax Credit, and the Alternative Minimum Tax, March 7, 2001, JCX-8-01, p. 3.

23.

For a detailed overview of all the eligibility criteria, and a more detailed description of how the credit is calculated, see CRS Report R43805, The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC): An Overview, by [author name scrubbed] and [author name scrubbed].

24.

See Figure 10 in CRS Report R43805, The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC): An Overview, by [author name scrubbed] and [author name scrubbed]; and Elaine Maag, "Earned Income Tax Credit in the United States," Journal of Social Security lae, vol. 22, no. 1 (2015), p. 26.

25.

According to Eissa and Hoynes, among less-educated women (generally those with no more than a high school education), "85% of working wives earn less than their husbands." Nada Eissa and Hilary Williamson Hoynes, "Taxes and the Labor Market Participation of Married Couples: The Earned Income Tax Credit," Journal of Public Economics, vol. 88 (2004), p. 1937, http://www9.georgetown.edu/faculty/noe/jpube804.pdf.

26.

As Eissa and Hoynes state, "there is overwhelming evidence that the EITC encourages work among single mothers but little evidence that eligible working women adjust their hours in response to the EITC. Perhaps most striking about these findings is their consistency across different empirical methods ... as well as different EITC expansions." Nada Eissa and Hilary Hoynes, "Behavioral Responses to Taxes: Lessons from the EITC and Labor Supply," NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper 11729, 2005, p. 11, http://www.nber.org/papers/w11729.pdf.

27.

For example, see Bruce D. Meyer and Da. T. Rosenbaum, "Welfare, the Earned Income Tax Credit, and the Labor Supply of Single Mothers," Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 116 (3), August 2001, pp. 1063-1114, http://harrisschool.uchicago.edu/sites/default/files/MeyerRosenbaumQJE01.pdf.

28.

Bruce D. Meyer, "Labor Supply at the Extensive and Intensive Margins: The EITC, Welfare and Hours Worked," American Economic Review, vol. 92, May 2002, pp. 373-379, http://www.ipr.northwestern.edu/publications/docs/workingpapers/2002/IPR-WP-02-04.pdf.

29.

Jeffrey Grogger, "The Effects of Time Limits, the EITC, and Other Policy Changes on Welfare Use, Work, and Income among Female-Head Families," Review of Economics and Statistics, May 2003, p. 405.

30.

National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), The Earned Income Tax Credit Raises Employment, The NBER Digest, http://www.nber.org/digest/aug06/w11729.html.

31.

Jeffrey Grogger, Welfare Transitions in the 1990s: The Economy, Welfare Policy, and the EITC, National Bureau of Economic Research, January 2003, http://www.nber.org/papers/w9472.pdf.

32.

Nada Eissa and Hillary Williamson Hoynes, "Behavioral Responses to Taxes: Lessons from the EITC and Labor Supply," NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper 11729, 2005, p. 15, http://www.nber.org/papers/w11729.pdf.

33.

David Ellwood, "The Impact of the Earned Income Tax Credit and Social Policy Reforms on Work, Marriage, and Living Arrangements," National Tax Journal, vol. 534 (December), http://www.ntanet.org/NTJ/53/4/ntj-v53n04p1063-1106-impact-earned-income-tax.pdf. Other research that found a similar negative effect of the EITC on the labor force participation of secondary earners includes Nada Eissa and Hillary Williamson Hoynes, "The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Labor Supply of Married Couples," National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper no. 6856, 1998, http://www.nber.org/papers/w6856; and Nada Eissa and Hilary Williamson Hoynes, "Taxes and the Labor Market Participation of Married Couples: The Earned Income Tax Credit," Journal of Public Economics, vol. 88 (2004), p. 1956, http://www9.georgetown.edu/faculty/noe/jpube804.pdf.

34.

Bradley T. Heim, The Impact of the Earned Income Tax Credit on the Labor Supply of Married Couples: A Structural Estimation, Working Paper: Office of Tax Analysis, U.S. Department of the Treasury, January 12, 2010, p. 22, http://home.comcast.net/~bradheim/files/HeimEITCFamLS.pdf.

35.

Elaine Maag, "Earned Income Tax Credit in the United States," Journal of Social Security Law, vol. 22, no. 1 (2015), p. 26.

36.

For example, if a job would pay an individual $20/hour, the cost to an individual of not working would be $20 per hour of leisure.

37.

In 2008, 71% of head-of-household filers were estimated to have earnings that placed them in the plateau or phase-out range of the EITC. See Tax Policy Center, Table T14-0114 at http://taxpolicycenter.org/numbers/displayatab.cfm?Docid=4171&DocTypeID=7.

38.

Congressional Budget Office, Effective Marginal Tax Rates for Low- and Moderate-Income Workers, November 2012, http://www.cbo.gov/publication/43709, p. 2.

39.

Bruce D. Meyer, "Labor Supply at the Extensive and Intensive Margins: The EITC, Welfare and Hours Worked," American Economic Review, vol. 92, May 2002, pp. 373-379, http://www.ipr.northwestern.edu/publications/docs/workingpapers/2002/IPR-WP-02-04.pdf.

40.

Congressional Budget Office, Effective Marginal Tax Rates for Low- and Moderate-Income Workers, November 2012, http://www.cbo.gov/publication/43709, p. 2.

41.

Emmanuel Saez, "Do Taxpayers Bunch at Kink Points?" American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, August 2010, p. 181, http://eml.berkeley.edu/~saez/saezAEJ10bunching.pdf.

42.

Elaine Maag, "Earned Income Tax Credit in the United States," Journal of Social Security Law, vol. 22, no. 1 (2015), p. 25.

43.

Raj Chetty, John N. Friedman, and Emmanuel Saez, "Using Differences in Knowledge Across Neighborhoods to Uncover the Impacts of the EITC on Earnings," NBER Working Paper Series | Working Paper 18232, July 2012, p. 35, http://eml.berkeley.edu/~saez/chetty-friedman-saezNBER12EITC.pdf.

44.

Ibid, p. 35.

45.

The EITC marriage penalty occurs because (1) the maximum credit for married joint filers is not double the maximum credit for single filers; (2) the income level at which the EITC phases out for married couples is not double the level for singles; and (3) the value of the EITC is affected by the presence and number of children (as well as earnings), and hence marriage may reduce the EITC depending on the number of children each spouse brings to the marriage. The Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001 (EGTRRA; P.L. 107-16) provided marriage penalty relief for the EITC by raising the phase-out income level of the EITC for married couples by $3,000 in comparison to the phase-out income level for unmarried EITC recipients. The American Recovery and Relief Act of 2009 (ARRA; P.L. 111-5) temporarily increased marriage penalty relief for the EITC by raising the phase-out income level by $5,000 for married couples in 2009 and indexing the $5,000 for tax year 2010. While the American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012 (ATRA; P.L. 112-240) made the EGTRRA provisions for marriage penalty relief permanent, the increase in marriage penalty relief to $5,000 (indexed for inflation) made by ARRA was extended for only five years (the expansion will sunset on December 31, 2017).

46.

For 2013 levels, see IRS Publication 596, 2013 Earned Income Credit (EIC) Table, http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-pdf/p596.pdf. The 2014 levels are calculated using the parameters provided in IRS Revenue Procedure 2013-35, http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-drop/rp-13-35.pdf.

47.

David Ellwood, "The Impact of the Earned Income Tax Credit and Social Policy Reforms on Work, Marriage, and Living Arrangements," National Tax Journal, vol. 53, no. 4 (December 2000), pp. 1063-1106, http://ntj.tax.org/wwtax%5Cntjrec.nsf/53542C9468D27BA085256AFC007F39D9/$FILE/v53n4p21063.pdf.

48.

Hilary Hoynes, "The EITC Disincentive: A Reply To Paul Trampe," Econ Journal Watch, vol. 4, no. 3 (September 2007), pp. 321-325.

49.

Heim. "The Impact of the Earned Income Tax Credit on the Labor Supply of Married Couples," 22.

50.

The authors do note that "these modest effects, however, mask substantial heterogeneity across the population of married EITC-eligible families. Women in the phase-out range of the credit experience the greatest reductions, between three and 17 percent." See Nada Eissa and Hilary Hoynes, "The Hours of Work Response of Married Couples: Taxes and the Earned Income Tax Credit," April 2004, p. 20, https://gspp.berkeley.edu/assets/uploads/research/pdf/CESifo_EissaHoynes.pdf.

51.

For more information, see U.S. Department of Labor, Wage and Hour Division. http://www.dol.gov/whd/minimumwage.htm.

52.

CRS Report R41625, Federal Benefits and Services for People with Low Income: Programs, Policy, and Spending, FY2008-FY2009, by [author name scrubbed].

53.

See Len Burman and Elaine Maag, The War on Poverty Moves to the Tax Code, Tax Policy Center, January 6, 2014, http://www.urban.org/UploadedPDF/1001711-war-on-poverty-moves-to-tax-code.pdf.

54.

For more information, see CRS Report R41999, The Impact of Refundable Tax Credits on Poverty Rates, by [author name scrubbed].

55.

See Table 5a in Kathleen Short, The Research Supplemental Poverty Measure: 2012, U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Reports, November 2013, http://www.census.gov/prod/2013pubs/p60-247.pdf.

56.

CRS Report R41999, The Impact of Refundable Tax Credits on Poverty Rates, by [author name scrubbed].

57.

In this analysis, the federal poverty level equals the 2014 poverty guidelines provided by the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. For more information, U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Office of The Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, 2014 Poverty Guidelines. http://aspe.hhs.gov/poverty/14poverty.cfm.

58.

For more information, Tax Policy Center, Distribution of Tax Units That Pay No Individual Income Tax; by Expanded Cash Income Level, Current Law, 2014, Table T13-0231, August 29, 2013, http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/numbers/displayatab.cfm?DocID=3990.

59.

These figures were calculated using the Current Population Survey Table Calculator available at http://www.census.gov/cps/data/cpstablecreator.html. To access this data, under "Data options, "Get Count of: Persons in Poverty Universe (everyone except unrelated individuals under 15)" for the "Latest Year" of "2013" was selected. Under "Define Your Table," the row variables of "family size," "marital status," and "related children under 18," and the column variable of "poverty status-alternative," were selected. Under "Poverty Thresholds," "Official Poverty Thresholds" was selected. And finally, under "Income Definition," the income definition was customized to include all selected sources of income and expenses, except (1) "Economic Recovery Payments," (2) "Public housing and rent subsidies FMR-based estimates," and (3) "Work-related expenses excluding childcare." These figures were compared with ones that were identical, except for under "Income Definition" the federal earned income credit was de-selected as a source of income. The percentage difference in these two poverty rates is reported in Table 3.

60.

There are several reasons why the poorest tax filers (income <$10,000) may, even after including the EITC, still pay on average higher tax rates than the next highest income class of tax filers (income between $10,000 and $20,000). First, this income class may include a greater proportion of recipients of the childless EITC, a relatively small credit compared to EITC recipients with children. Indeed, while over a quarter of tax filers in this income class are eligible for the EITC, they received 4.2% of the total value of the credit in 2013. When examining how the EITC affects only tax filers with children, the poorest tax filers with children do have the lowest average federal tax rate as a result of the EITC. Specifically, the average federal tax rate for those with less than $10,000 of income is -15.4%; among those with income between $10,000 and $20,000, -13.0%; and among those with income between $20,000 and $30,000, -8.0%, increasing as income rises. For more information, see http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/numbers/Content/PDF/T13-0220.pdf. In addition, the lowest income class in the Tax Policy Center data may also include nonworking populations who are ineligible for the EITC, including retirees and the disabled.

61.

For more information, see Tax Policy Center, The Numbers: Frequently Asked Questions, T07-9999-Tax Model FAQ, August 12, 2008, question #6, http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/numbers/displayatab.cfm?DocID=1535#q6.

62.

See Julie-Anne Cronin, Portia DeFilippes, and Emily Y. Line, "Effects of Adjusting Distribution Tables for Family Size," National Tax Journal, vol. 65, no. 4 (December 2012), pp. 739-758.

63.

Gravelle and Gravelle use an equivalence scale recommended by the National Academy of Sciences to improve the federal measure of poverty. This equivalence scale adjusts for both family size and the different needs of adults versus children. More information can be found at "Chapter 3: Adjusting Poverty Thresholds," in Measuring Poverty: A New Approach, ed. Constance F. Citro and Robert T. Michael (National Academies Press, 1995), https://www.census.gov/hhes/povmeas/methodology/nas/report.html.

64.

Jane Gravelle and Jennifer Gravelle, "Horizontal Equity and Family Tax Treatment: The Orphan Child of Tax Policy," National Tax Journal, vol. 59, no. 3 (September 2006).

65.

Using their equivalence scale, Gravelle and Gravelle found that a married couple filing jointly with no children and $10,000 of income was equivalent to a married couple with one child and $12,338 of income, a married couple with two children and $14,498 of income, and a married couple with three children and $16,529 of income. For more information, see Table 1B in Gravelle and Gravelle, "Orphan Tax Policy," 635.

66.

Gravelle and Gravelle, "Orphan Tax Policy," 636.

67.

These equivalence scales are calculated using a three-parameter scale used to calculate equivalent families for the supplemental poverty measure. For one and two adult families, the scale is (adults)^0.5. For single parents the scale is (adults+0.8*first child+0.5*other children)^0.7. For all other families, the scale is (adults+0.5*children)^0.7. For more information see Kathleen Short, The Supplemental Poverty Measure: 2013, U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Reports, October 2014, p. 19, https://www.census.gov/content/dam/Census/library/publications/2014/demo/p60-251.pdf.

68.

Gravelle and Gravelle, "Orphan Tax Policy," 636.

69.

The authors also state that the phasing out of the credit as income rises also has an impact on the horizontal inequity of the credit, particularly among married tax filers in comparison to unmarried recipients. Specifically, married tax filers with the same ability to pay as unmarried tax filers need more income, which may result in them being in the phase-out portion of the credit. Hence families with the same "ability to pay" may receive a smaller EITC.

70.

Gravelle and Gravelle, "Orphan Tax Policy," 648.

71.

Gravelle and Gravelle use a formula for an equivalence scale that assumes that there are economies of scale within families, such that a family of four (two children and two adults) needs 235% of the income of a family of one adult. As one assumes greater economies of scale within a family, all else being equal, the horizontal inequity of the tax code increases among "equivalent" low-income tax payers. Conversely, if one assumes that there are no economies of scale, horizontal inequities are lessened—though still exist—among low-income "equivalent" families.

72.

In the mid-1990s, when Congress debated significantly expanding the credit, taxpayer noncompliance was cited as a significant problem. Specifically, many policymakers were concerned by noncompliance rates reported in a Government Accountability Office (GAO) report. This GAO report reported on an IRS study of a sample of EITC returns during a two-week period in January 1994. The "IRS' preliminary analysis of the returns showed that an estimated 29% of the 1.3 million EIC returns filed electronically during the period had claimed too large a refund, and about 13% of the returns filed was estimated by the IRS as having intentionally claimed too much EIC." General Accounting Office, Tax Administration: Earned Income Credit—Data on Noncompliance and Illegal Alien Recipients, GAO/GGD-95-27, October 1994, p. 1. In 2002, the IRS released another study concerning EITC overclaims that also found a significant amount of taxpayer error. See Internal Revenue Service, Compliance Estimates for Earned Income Tax Credit Claimed on 1999 Returns, February 28, 2002, http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/compeitc.pdf.

73.

The Internal Revenue Service, Compliance Estimates for the Earned Income Tax Credit Claimed on 2006-2008 Returns, Publication 5162, Washington, DC, August 2014, http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/EITCComplianceStudyTY2006-2008.pdf, p. 2.

74.

For more information on improper payments and overclaims, see CRS Report R43873, The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC): Administrative and Compliance Challenges, by [author name scrubbed]

75.

For more information, see Treasury Inspector General for Tax Administration (TIGTA), The Internal Revenue Service Fiscal Year 2013 Improper Payment Reporting Continues to Not Comply with the Improper Payments Elimination and Recovery Act, March 31, 2014, http://www.treasury.gov/tigta/auditreports/2014reports/201440027fr.pdf.

76.

Generally tax provisions are scored as a reduction of revenue. The refundable portion of the EITC however is designated as an outlay, and hence comparable to a spending program. However, noncompliance with other tax laws can result in reduced revenue. The OMB Payment Accuracy does not compare noncompliance in spending programs (improper payments) to noncompliance in tax programs (foregone revenue).

77.

In addition to the major factors identified in the 2006-2008 EITC Compliance Study that lead to EITC overclaims, the study also identified other minor factors that lead to erroneous claims of the credit. These include errors in applying EITC tie-breaker rules when more than one person can claim a qualifying child, not having a valid Social Security number (SSN), not being a U.S. citizen or resident, not being age 25-64 if claiming the childless EITC, and being the dependent of another taxpayer. In the 2006-2008 EITC Compliance Study, approximately 700,000 returns annually included one of these errors, resulting in overclaims of between $900 million to $1.4 billion annually. In comparison, the total number of returns with overclaims is estimated at 11.9 million, resulting in between $14.0 billion and $19.3 billion in overclaims annually.

78.

Internal Revenue Service W&I Research Group 5, Evaluation of Non-Custodial Parents Reported by the Federal Case Registry and their EITC Eligibility, October 2011. This IRS study is not publicly available. A redacted version is available from the author upon request.

79.

See The Internal Revenue Service, EITC Central, Consequences of Not Meeting Your Due Diligence Requirements, October 3, 2014, http://www.eitc.irs.gov/Tax-Preparer-Toolkit/dd/consequences.

80.

For more information, see the U.S. Government's Payment Accuracy website at https://www.paymentaccuracy.gov/high-priority-programs.

81.

House Committee on Ways and Means, Subcommittee on Oversight, Written Statement of Nina E. Olson, National Taxpayer Advocate, Hearing on Improper Payments in the Administration of Refundable Credits, http://waysandmeans.house.gov/uploadedfiles/olsen_testimony.pdf, May 25, 2011, p. 9.

82.

The Internal Revenue Service, "Tax Gap for Tax Year 2006," press release, January 6, 2012, http://www.irs.gov/pub/newsroom/overview_tax_gap_2006.pdf.

83.

Taxpayer Advocate Service, Fiscal Year 2015 Objectives Report to Congress: Research Initiatives, Washington, DC, p. 158, http://www.taxpayeradvocate.irs.gov/userfiles/file/FY15-Full-Report/Research.pdf.

84.

For an overview of legislation introduced in the 113th Congress to modify the EITC, see CRS Report R43763, The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC): Legislation in the 113th Congress, by [author name scrubbed].

85.

The decision of a worker to go from non-working to working can also be understood using the framework of income and substitution effects. When a worker goes from non-working to working, his or her wage goes from zero to a positive amount. According to the substitution effect, the worker will consume less leisure and hence work more. Crucially, for this worker, there is no income effect from choosing to work, since they have no income to begin with (and conversely already have the maximum amount of leisure). Hence with no income effect, and a substitution effect resulting in increased work, a non-worker will choose to work.

86.

Nada Eissa and Hilary Williamson Hoynes, "Taxes and the Labor Market Participation of Married Couples: The Earned Income Tax Credit," Journal of Public Economics, vol. 88 (2004), p. 1937, http://www9.georgetown.edu/faculty/noe/jpube804.pdf.

87.

In 2008, 71% of head-of-household filers were estimated to have earnings that placed them in the plateau or phase-out range of the EITC. See Tax Policy Center, Table T14-0114 at http://taxpolicycenter.org/numbers/displayatab.cfm?Docid=4171&DocTypeID=7.

88.

It is possible that in some cases employers could reduce wages in response to the availability of the EITC. Employer's "recapture" of part of the EITC would lessen the impact the EITC had in increasing the marginal return to work for the worker. However, a variety of factors would limit the extent to which employers could recapture the credit, including both federal and state minimum wages, living wages, and the supply of low-wage workers.