Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic
Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

Craig K. Elwell
Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
November 29, 2012
Congressional Research Service
7-5700
www.crs.gov
R41332
CRS Report for Congress
Pr
epared for Members and Committees of Congress

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

Summary
The 2007-2009 recession was long and deep, and according to several indicators was the most
severe economic contraction since the 1930s (but still much less severe than the Great
Depression). The slowdown of economic activity was moderate through the first half of 2008, but
at that point the weakening economy was overtaken by a major financial crisis that would
exacerbate the economic weakness and accelerate the decline.
Economic recovery began in mid-2009. Real gross domestic product (GDP) has been on a
positive track since then, although the pace has been uneven and slowed significantly in 2011.
The stock market has recovered from its lows, and employment has increased moderately. On the
other hand, significant economic weakness remains evident, particularly in the balance sheet of
households, the labor market, and the housing sector.
Congress was an active participant in the policy responses to this crisis and has an ongoing
interest in macroeconomic conditions. Current macroeconomic concerns include whether the
economy is in a sustained recovery, rapidly reducing unemployment, speeding a return to normal
output and employment growth, and addressing government’s long-term debt problem.
In the typical post-war business cycle, lower than normal growth during the recession is quickly
followed by a recovery period with above normal growth. This above normal growth serves to
speed up the reentry of the unemployed to the workforce. Once the economy reaches potential
output (and full employment), growth returns to its normal growth path, where the pace of
aggregate spending advances in step with the pace of aggregate supply. There is concern that this
time the U.S. economy will either not return to its pre-recession growth path but perhaps remain
permanently below it, or return to the pre-crisis path but at a slower than normal pace. Problems
on the supply side and the demand side of the economy have so far led to a weaker than normal
recovery.
If the pace of private spending proves insufficient to assure a sustained recovery, would further
stimulus by monetary and fiscal policy be warranted? One lesson from the Great Depression is to
guard against a too hasty withdrawal of fiscal and monetary stimulus in an economy recovering
from a deep decline. The removal of fiscal and monetary stimulus in 1937 is thought to have
stopped a recovery and caused a slump that did not end until WWII. Opponents of further
stimulus maintain that the accumulation of additional government debt would lower future
economic growth, but supporters argue that additional stimulus is the appropriate near-term
policy. There is concern that the “fiscal cliff,” the confluence of various spending cuts and tax rate
increases that are scheduled to occur at the beginning of 2013 unless policies are changed, could
have an adverse effect on the economic recovery.
In regard to the long-term debt problem, in an economy operating close to potential output,
government borrowing to finance budget deficits will in theory draw down the pool of national
saving, crowding out private capital investment and slowing long-term growth. However, the U.S.
economy is currently operating well short of capacity and the risk of such crowding out occurring
is therefore low in the near term. Once the cyclical problem of weak demand is resolved and the
economy has returned to a normal growth path, mainstream economists’ consensus policy
response for an economy with a looming debt crisis is fiscal consolidation—cutting deficits. Such
a policy would have the benefits of low and stable interest rates, a less fragile financial system,
improved investment prospects, and possibly faster long-term growth.
Congressional Research Service

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

Contents
Background ...................................................................................................................................... 1
Severity of the 2008-2009 Recession ........................................................................................ 1
Policy Responses to the Financial Crisis and Recession ........................................................... 2
Monetary Policy Actions ..................................................................................................... 2
Fiscal Policy Actions ........................................................................................................... 3
Is Sustained Economic Recovery Underway? ................................................................................. 3
The Shape of Economic Recovery ................................................................................................... 6
Demand Side Problems? ............................................................................................................ 7
Consumption Spending ....................................................................................................... 7
Investment Spending ......................................................................................................... 10
Net Exports ........................................................................................................................ 11
Supply Side Problems? ............................................................................................................ 14
Policy Responses to Increase the Pace of Economic Recovery............................................... 16
Fiscal Policy Actions Taken During the Recovery ............................................................ 17
Monetary Policy Actions Taken During the Recovery ...................................................... 20
A Lesson from the Great Depression ................................................................................ 22
Economic Projections .............................................................................................................. 23

Contacts
Author Contact Information........................................................................................................... 24

Congressional Research Service

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

Background
Severity of the 2008-2009 Recession
The 2008-2009 recession was long and deep, and according to several indicators was the most
severe economic contraction since the 1930s (but still much less severe than the Great
Depression). The slowdown of economic activity was moderate through the first half of 2008, but
at that point the weakening economy was overtaken by a major financial crisis that would
exacerbate the economic weakness and accelerate the decline.1
When the fall of economic activity finally bottomed out in the second half of 2009, real gross
domestic product (GDP) had contracted by approximately 5.1%, or by about $680 billion.2 At this
point the output gap—the difference between what the economy could produce and what it
actually produced—widened to an estimated 8.1%. The decline in economic activity was much
sharper than in the nine previous post-war recessions, in which the fall of real GDP averaged
about 2.0% and the output gap increased to near 4.0%. However, the recent decline falls well
short of the experience during the Great Depression, when real GDP decreased by 30% and the
output gap probably exceeded 40%.3
As output decreased the unemployment rate increased, rising from 4.6% in 2007 to a peak of
10.1% in October 2009, and remaining only slightly below that high into 2011. The U.S.
unemployment rate has not been at this level since 1982, when in the aftermath of the 1981
recession it reached 10.8%, the highest rate of the post-war period. (During the Great Depression
the unemployment rate reached 25%.) This rise in the unemployment rate translates to about
7 million persons put out of work during the recession. Another 8.5 million workers have been
pushed involuntarily into part-time employment.4
The recession was intertwined with a major financial crisis that exacerbated the negative effects
on the economy. Falling stock and house prices led to a large decline in household wealth (net
worth), which plummeted by over $16 trillion or about 24% during 2008 and 2009. In addition,
the financial panic led to an explosion of risk premiums (i.e., compensation to investors for
accepting extra risk over relatively risk-free investments such as U.S. Treasury securities) that
froze the flow of credit to the economy, crimping credit supported spending by consumers such as
for automobiles, as well as business spending on new plant and equipment.5

1 See CRS Report R40007, Financial Market Turmoil and U.S. Macroeconomic Performance, by Craig K. Elwell.
2 Real GDP is the total output, adjusted for inflation, of goods and services produced in the United States in a given
year.
3 Data on real GDP are available from the Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, at
http://www.bea.gov/national/index.htm#gdp. Size of output gap is based on CRS calculations using Congressional
Budget Office estimate of potential GDP, data for which is available at FRED Economic Data, St. Louis Fed, at
http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/GDPPOT.
4 Data on unemployment and employment are available from the Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, at
http://www.bls.gov/.
5 Data on wealth and financial flows available at the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/Current/z1r-5.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
1

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

The negative shocks the economy received in 2008 and 2009 were, arguably, more severe than
what occurred in 1929. However, unlike in 1929, the severe negative impulses did not turn a
recession into a depression, arguably because timely and sizable policy responses by the
government helped to support aggregate spending and stabilize the financial system.6 That
stimulative economic policies would have this beneficial effect on a collapsing economy is
consistent with standard macroeconomic theory, but without the counterfactual of the economy’s
path in the absence of these policies, it is difficult to establish with precision how effective these
policies were.
Policy Responses to the Financial Crisis and Recession
Both monetary and fiscal policies as well as some extraordinary measures were applied to counter
the economic decline. This policy response is thought to have forestalled a more severe economic
contraction, helping to turn the economy into the incipient economic recovery by mid-2009.
These policies likely continued to stimulate economic activity into 2012.
Monetary Policy Actions
To bolster the liquidity of the financial system and stimulate the economy, during 2008 and 2009
the Federal Reserve (Fed) aggressively applied conventional monetary stimulus by lowering the
federal funds rate to near zero and boldly expanding its “lender of last resort” role, creating new
lending programs to better channel needed liquidity to the financial system and induce greater
confidence among lenders. Following the worsening of the financial crisis in September 2008, the
Fed grew its balance sheet by lending to the financial system. As a result, between September and
November 2008, the Fed’s balance sheet more than doubled, increasing from under $1 trillion to
more than $2 trillion.
By the beginning of 2009, demand for loans from the Fed was falling as financial conditions
normalized. Had the Fed done nothing to offset the fall in lending, the balance sheet would have
shrunk by a commensurate amount, and some of the stimulus that it had added to the economy
would have been withdrawn. In the spring of 2009, the Fed judged that the economy, which
remained in a recession, still needed additional stimulus. On March 18, 2009, the Fed announced
a commitment to purchase $300 billion of Treasury securities, $200 billion of Agency debt (later
revised to $175 billion), and $1.25 trillion of Agency mortgage-backed securities.7 The Fed’s
planned purchases of Treasury securities were completed by the fall of 2009 and planned Agency
purchases were completed by the spring of 2010. At this point, the Fed’s balance sheet stood at
just above $2 trillion.8 (Further monetary policy actions taken to accelerate the pace of economic
recovery are discussed later in the report.)

6 See IMF, World Economic Outlook, October 2009, Chapter 2, at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2009/02/
pdf/c2.pdf.
7 Agency debt and securities are issued by “government sponsored enterprises” (GSEs), such as Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac.
8 For further discussion of Fed actions in this period, see CRS Report RL34427, Financial Turmoil: Federal Reserve
Policy Responses
, by Marc Labonte.
Congressional Research Service
2

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

Fiscal Policy Actions
Congress and the Bush Administration enacted the Economic Stimulus Act of 2008 (P.L. 110-
185). This act was a $120 billion package that provided tax rebates to households and accelerated
depreciation rules for business. Congress and the Obama Administration passed the American
Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 (ARRA; P.L. 111-5). This was a $787 billion package
with $286 billion of tax cuts and $501 billion of spending increases that relative to what would
have happened without ARRA is estimated to have raised real GDP between 1.5% and 4.2% in
2010 but increased real GDP by a smaller amount in 2011 and will increase 2012 GDP by an even
smaller amount.9
In terms of extraordinary measures, Congress and the Bush Administration passed the Emergency
Economic Stabilization Act of 2008 (P.L. 110-343), creating the Troubled Asset Relief Program
(TARP). TARP authorized the Treasury to use up to $700 billion to directly bolster the capital
position of banks or to remove troubled assets from bank balance sheets.10
Congress was an active participant in the emergence of these policy responses and has an ongoing
interest in macroeconomic conditions. Current macroeconomic concerns include whether the
economy is in a sustained recovery, rapidly reducing unemployment, speeding a return to normal
output and employment growth, and addressing government’s long-term debt problem.
Is Sustained Economic Recovery Underway?
Evidence indicates that the economy, as measured by real GDP growth, began to recover in mid-
2009. However, the pace of growth has been slow and uneven with a pronounced deceleration
evident during 2011. During 2009 and 2010, growth had been sustained by transitory factors,
such as fiscal stimulus and the rebuilding of inventories by business. Economic growth in 2010
showed signs of being generated by more sustainable forces, but the strength of those forces
continues to be uneven, and a slowing of growth during 2011 prompted concern about the
recovery’s sustainability.
• For the second half of 2009 and through 2010 real GDP (i.e., GDP adjusted for
inflation) increased at an annualized rate of 3.0%. However, during 2011 growth
slowed to 1.6% and weak growth has continued in 2012, with real GDP growth
over the first three quarters of the year averaging only 2.0%. Growth at less than
a 2% annual rate may not be fast enough to close the “output gap” or keep the
unemployment rate from rising.11 Through 2010, much of the economy’s upward
momentum was sustained by the transitory factors of inventory increases and
fiscal stimulus. However, sustainable recovery would depend on more enduring
sources of demand such spending by consumers and businesses reviving and
providing continued momentum to the recovery. While business investment

9 See CRS Report R40104, Economic Stimulus: Issues and Policies, by Jane G. Gravelle, Thomas L. Hungerford, and
Marc Labonte.
10 For more information on TARP, see CRS Report R41427, Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP): Implementation
and Status
, by Baird Webel.
11 The output gap is a measure of the difference between actual output and the output the economy could produce if at
full employment.
Congressional Research Service
3

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

spending has been relatively brisk during the recovery, consumer spending was
relatively tepid. Weak consumer spending along with the rapidly fading effects of
fiscal stimulus and weaker growth in Europe raises concern about the
sustainability of U.S. economic recovery.12
• Credit conditions have improved, making getting loans easier for consumers and
businesses, loosening a constraint on many types of credit supported
expenditures. The Fed’s survey of senior loan officers indicates that, on net, bank
lending standards and terms continued to ease during 2012 and that the demand
for commercial and industrial loans had increased.13
• The stock market has rebounded and interest rate spreads on corporate bonds
have narrowed. The Dow Jones stock index had plunged to near 6500 in March
2009 but by mid-November 2012 had regained about 98% of its lost
capitalization. Spreads on investment-grade corporate bonds, a measure of the
lenders’ perception of risk and creditworthiness of borrowers, have fallen from a
high of 600 basis points in December 2008 to less than 100 basis points in
2012.14
• Manufacturing activity has shown steady improvement during the recovery, but
this advance seemed to have stalled since the summer of 2012. Through October
2012, output had increased 1.6% over a year earlier. Capacity utilization has risen
from a low of 64% in mid-2009 to 76% in October 2012; however, this is down
from over 77% in July. (A capacity utilization rate of 80% - 85% would be
typical for a fully recovered economy.)15
• From mid-2009 through October 2012, non-farm payroll employment has
increased by about 4 million jobs. Monthly gains have been consistently positive
since late 2010, but often not at a scale characteristic of a strong recovery. In
mid-2012, employment gains weakened with monthly gains averaging only
70,000 workers. However, since June 2012, monthly employment gains have
increased, averaging about 170,000 jobs. 16
• The housing sector has recently shown evidence of improving health. Private
new housing starts increased at an annual rate of near 900,000 units in October
2012, up from less than 400,000 units during the recession (but still far short of
the pre-recession highs of over 2 million units). Also, house prices have begun to
increase, on average, up about 4% over the first half of 2012.17

12 U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts, at
http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm.
13 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Senior Loan Officers Survey on Bank Lending Practices, August
2012, at http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/SnLoanSurvey/.
14 Spread of 600 basis points is 6%. Data on spreads found at http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/quote?ticker=
.TEDSP%3AIND.
15 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Statistical Release G.17, November 2012, at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/.
16 Bureau of Labor Statistics, Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey, November 2012, at
http://www.bls.gov/cps/.
17 U.S Census Bureau, New Residential Construction In October 2012, joint release, November 19, 2012, at
http://www.census.gov/construction/nrc/pdf/newresconst.pdf and S&P Case–Shiller 20-City Home Price Index,
available at http://www.standardandpoors.com/indices/sp-case-shiller-home-price-indices/en/us/?indexId=spusa-
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
4

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

• China, Asia’s other emerging economies, and Latin America are growing rapidly,
which is transmitting a positive growth impulse to the United States by boosting
demand for U.S. exports. Also, the dollar is very competitive from a historical
perspective, adding support to U.S. exports.
On the other hand, growth is well below the historical norm for U.S. economic recoveries as
persistent sources of economic weakness continue to dampen economic activity.
• In the third quarter of 2011, the economy had regained its pre-recession level of
output. But it took 15 quarters to accomplish this as compared with 5 quarters on
average in previous post-war recoveries. However, since potential GDP has also
continued to grow for these 15 months, the output gap at that point had only
narrowed from about 8.1% to 6.1%. Moreover, pointing to the slow pace of real
GDP growth since then, through the third quarter of 2012, there has been no
further decrease in the output gap.18
• Consumer spending, the usual engine of a strong economic recovery, remains
tepid, generally slowed by households’ ongoing need to rebuild substantial net
worth lost during the housing crisis and the recession, continued high
unemployment and underemployment, and a surge in energy prices in the first
half of 2012.
• Employment conditions, despite improvement, remain weak. The unemployment
rate, which had peaked at 10.0% in October 2009, fell slowly but steadily,
reaching 8.3% by January 2012. Since then, however, little improvement has
occurred, with the unemployment rate only slightly lower at 7.9% in October
2012.19 Moreover, until recently, a considerable share of that improvement is not
the result of workers finding jobs, but by discouraged workers leaving the ranks
of the officially unemployed by leaving the labor force. Such a high rate of
unemployment after more than three years of economic recovery is unusual and a
source of concern. Another measure of labor market conditions, the employment
to population ratio, which is not affected by changes in labor force participation,
shows a labor market that is essentially “treading water.” During the recession
that ratio fell from 63% to 58% and it has remained near that low through three
years of economic recovery.20
• The housing market, while showing signs of revival, is likely to continue to fall
short of its typical contribution to economic recoveries. Mortgage loan
foreclosures are still high, house prices are still weak in many regions, and
millions of mortgage holders are “underwater,” with the market values of their
houses below the amount of their mortgages. Beyond the direct effect on

(...continued)
cashpidff—p-us.
18 CRS calculation from Bureau of Economic analysis data for real GDP and CBO estimate of potential GDP both
available from Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED), St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank, at
http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/.
19 For the calculation of the unemployment rate, a person without a job is not counted as unemployed or in the labor
force unless he or she is actively looking for employment.
20 Bureau of Labor Statistics, Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey, November 2012,
http://www.bls.gov/cps/.
Congressional Research Service
5

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

economic activity through lower rates of new construction, housing market
weakness has a strong negative indirect effect on the balance sheets of
households and banks. A large portion of the sharp fall in household net worth
was caused by the fall of house prices. Although the value of household’s
financial assets have bounced back since 2009, the value of their real estate assets
have not, continuing to dampen consumer spending.21
• Growth in the UK and the Euro area has been weak and fiscal austerity measures
to stem the growth of public debt have likely pushed the region back into
recession, slowing growth further. Slower growth in this region, a major U.S.
export market, has likely transmitted a contractionary impulse to the United
States, slowing the pace of the U.S. recovery in 2012 and will likely continue to
do so into 2013.22
The Shape of Economic Recovery
In the typical post-war business cycle, lower than normal growth of aggregate demand during the
recession is quickly followed by a recovery period with above normal growth of spending,
perhaps spurred by some degree of monetary and fiscal stimulus. The degree of acceleration of
growth in the first two to three years of recovery has varied across post-war business cycles, but
has been at an annual pace in a range of 4% to 8%.23 This above normal growth brings the
economy back more quickly to the pre-recession growth path, and speeds up the reentry of the
unemployed to the workforce.
Once the level of aggregate demand approaches the level of potential GDP (or full employment),
the economy returns to its pre-recession growth path, where the growth of aggregate spending is
slower because it is constrained by the growth of aggregate supply, which in recent years is
estimated to have been at an annual pace of near 3.0%. (A subsequent section of the report looks
more closely at aggregate supply.)24
There is concern, however, that this time the U.S. economy, without supporting stimulus from
policy actions, will either not return to its pre-recession growth path, perhaps remain permanently
below it, or return to the pre-crisis path but at a slower than normal pace, or worse, dip into a
second recession. Below normal growth would almost certainly translate into below normal
recovery of employment, whereas a second round of recession could increase the already high
unemployment rate. The next sections of this report discuss problems on the supply side and the
demand side of the economy that could lead to a weaker than normal recovery.

21 See Atif Miam and Amir Sufi, Consumers and the Economy, Part II: Household Debt and the Weak Recovery,
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Letter, January 18, 2011.
22 International Monetary Fund (IMF), World Economic Outlook, October 2012, at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/
weo/2012/02/index.htm.
23 Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, at http://www.bea.gov/national/index.htm#gdp.
24 The long-term growth of aggregate supply is determined by the growth in the supplies of capital and labor and on the
growth in production technology used to turn capital and labor into goods and services.
Congressional Research Service
6

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

Demand Side Problems?
Much of the vigor that occurred on the demand side of the economy in 2009 and 2010 appears to
have come from fiscal stimulus and business inventory restocking. Fiscal stimulus and inventory
rebuilding are, however, temporary sources of support of aggregate spending. Sooner or later
fiscal stimulus falls away. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) projects that fiscal stimulus
peaked in 2010, provided a smaller boost to demand in 2011, and continued to diminish in 2012.25
Inventory building is self-limiting processes that will not go on indefinitely; stock-building was
weaker during most of 2011, and despite a stronger turn in late 2011 and early 2012 inventory
growth will unlikely continue to have a major positive effect on aggregate demand.
A strong recovery of private sector demand, including consumer spending, investment spending,
and exports, is required to sustain an economic recovery that brings the economy quickly back to
its pre-recession growth path and unemployment rate. However, there are major uncertainties
about the potential medium-term strength of each of these components that could dampen
aggregate spending and constrain the economy’s ability to generate a recovery period with above
normal growth and quickly falling unemployment.
Consumption Spending
Personal consumption expenditures historically constitute the largest and most stable component
of aggregate spending in the U.S. economy. During the first three post-war decades, personal
consumption spending averaged a 62% share of GDP. However, that share rose significantly over
the next three decades, averaging about 65% in the 1980s, 67% during the 1990s, and about 70%
between 2001 and 2007. The high level of household spending reached during the 2001-2007
expansion is unlikely to reemerge during the current recovery because it was supported by an
unsustainable increase in household debt, a decrease in personal savings, ease of access to credit,
and lower energy prices.
Household Debt
In the mid-1980s, after a long period of relative stability at a scale of around 45% to 50% of GDP,
the debt level of households began to rise steadily, reaching over 100% of GDP by 2008. Such a
substantial rise in the level of household debt was sustainable so long as rising home prices and a
rising stock market continued to also increase the value of household net worth, and interest rates
remained low, mitigating any rise in the burden of debt service as a share of income.
The collapse of the housing and stock markets in 2008 and 2009 substantially decreased
household net worth, which had, by mid-2009, fallen about $16 trillion below its 2007 peak of
nearly $67 trillion.26 This near 25% fall in net worth pushed the household debt burden up
substantially. Unlike in earlier post-war recoveries, the current need of households to repair their
damaged balance sheets has induced a large diversion of current income from consumption

25 The Congressional Budget Office, The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2012 to 2020, January 2012, at
http://www.cbo.gov/publication/42905.
26 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Flow of Funds Accounts,” Table B.100, September 2012, at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/Current/z1r-5.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
7

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

spending to debt reduction.27 That above normal diversion has persisted in 2012 and is likely to
be a continuing drag on the pace of economic recovery in 2013.
A substantial rebuilding of household net worth has occurred during the recovery. Through the
second quarter of 2012, household net worth has increased by about $12 trillion from its 2009
trough, reaching about $63 trillion and recovering nearly 75% of what was lost during the
recession. This improvement has occurred largely on the asset side of the household balance sheet
and primarily for financial assets due to the rise of the stock market from its low point in early
2009.28 Traditionally, rising home equity, largely dependent on the path of house prices, has been
the major contributor to household wealth. The rapid rise of home prices during the last economic
expansion caused an equally rapid rise in home equity. Consumers borrowed against this equity to
fund current spending. With the sharp fall of home prices, home equity was reduced substantially,
erasing that source of funding. Home prices are only now beginning to rise and the housing
market is expected to remain weak for several more years, slowing the pace of households
rebuilding their net worth, and continuing to dampen consumer spending.29
In addition to diverting more personal income to saving, a continued weak labor market is likely
to dampen income growth and, in turn, slow the recovery of consumer spending.
Credit Conditions
Easy credit availability in the pre-crisis economy enabled households to readily borrow against
their rising home equity to fund added spending. Financial innovations allowed lenders to keep
interest rates low and offer liberal terms and conditions to entice households to borrow. Many
believe that credit conditions will remain tighter during the current expansion. Interest rates are
still low, but banks greatly tightened the terms and conditions of consumer loans during the crisis
and recession and have only slowly relaxed them as the recovery has proceeded. While not likely
as important a driver of higher savings as high household debt, tighter credit conditions will make
it less likely that households will exploit any increase in their home equity to fund current
spending, further constraining consumer spending relative to what occurred during the 2001-2007
economic expansion.
Personal Saving
The U.S. personal saving rate averaged about 10% of GDP consistently through the 1970s, 1980s,
and 1990s. Subsequently, the personal saving rate declined sharply, reaching a low of 1.0% by
2005.30 It is likely that the reduction of household saving was in large measure a consequence of

27 See Evan Tanner and Yassar Abdih, “Rebuilding U.S. Wealth,” Finance & Development, IMF, December 2009 at
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2009/12/tanner.htm.
28 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Flow of Funds Accounts,” Table B.100, June 2012, at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/Current/z1r-5.pdf.
29 The standard model of consumer spending used in economic analysis assumes that consumers seek to avoid large
swings in their living standards over the course of their lifetimes. Thus as incomes rise and fall both in the short and
long term, individuals are expected to vary their saving rate in order to minimize the effect on their consumption. If
consumers seek to maintain a fairly stable level of consumption over their entire lives, then the level of consumption at
any given point in their lives will depend on their current wealth and some expectation about their income over the rest
of their lives. See Annamaria Lusardi, Jonathan Skinner, and Steven Venti, “Saving Puzzles and Saving Policies in the
United States,” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 8237, April 2001.
30 See CRS Report R40647, The Fall and Rise of Household Saving, by Brian W. Cashell.
Congressional Research Service
8

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

the sizable increase in household net worth associated with increased house prices and stock
prices occurring at that time. As wealth rose rapidly, it was less urgent to divert current income to
saving.
The sharp reduction of household net worth during the recent recession dramatically changed the
financial circumstances of households, reducing the use of debt-financed spending. The need to
repair household balance sheets induced households to pay down debt. The poor prospect for the
appreciation of house prices has eliminated the ability to use rising equity as a substitute for
saving.
In addition, the increase in economic uncertainty in the aftermath of the financial crisis and
recession will likely mean that over the medium term, households could continue to be more
inclined to save. As the economic decline intensified, the personal saving rate increased, climbing
from 3.5% of GDP in 2007 to 6.1% of GDP in 2009.31 However, since that point the personal
saving rate has fallen, averaging about 4.0% in the first half of 2012. The passing of the dire
financial and economic circumstances that prevailed in 2008 and 2009 has likely led to some of
the recent moderation in households’ saving behavior. A lower rate of saving enables higher rates
of consumption, but it is uncertain that continued fall of the saving rate will be a substantial
source of support for current spending by households.
Energy Prices
A 30% increase in the price of oil from October 2011 through April 2012 has likely adversely
affected household budgets and contributed to the slow rate of increase in consumer spending
over the same period.32 In the short run, the U.S. demand for energy is relatively inelastic, with
little curtailment of energy use in the face of the rising price. As households and businesses spend
more for energy, which is largely imported, they tend to spend less on domestic output, slowing
economic growth.33 Since April 2012, the price of oil appears to have stabilized, and if it remains
near the current level, the dampening effect on economic growth is likely to fade. In addition,
increasing supplies of shale gas have resulted in lower natural gas prices, which may benefit
household budgets.
Slow Recovery of Consumer Spending?
If consumer spending continues its slow paced recovery, then for the U.S. economy to return to
its normal pre-crisis growth path, an improved pace of GDP growth will have to come from other
components of aggregate demand: investment spending, net exports, or government spending.

31 U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts, Table 5.1,
http://www.bea.gov/national/nipaweb/SelectTable.asp?Selected=N.
32 U.S. Energy Information Administration, Petroleum; Weekly Spot Price, July 2012, at http://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/
hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=RCLC1&f=D.
33 Research indicates that a $10 increase in the per barrel price of oil sustained for two years is likely to reduce real
GDP growth relative to base-line by 0.2 percentage points in the first year and 0.5 percentage points in the second year.
See U.S. Energy Information Administration, Economic Effects of High Oil Prices, 2006, http://www.eia.gov/oiaf/aeo/
otheranalysis/aeo_2006analysispapers/efhop.html.
Congressional Research Service
9

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

Investment Spending
Investment spending is the third-largest component of aggregate spending, historically averaging
17% to 18% of GDP in years of near normal output growth. (Government spending is second
largest at about 20%.) Historically, the largest portion of total investment spending is business
fixed investment, its share averaging 11% to 12% of GDP in periods of normal growth. The
second component of total investment is residential investment (i.e., new housing), averaging 4%
to 5% of GDP.
Investment spending is very sensitive to economic conditions and more volatile than consumer
spending. This sensitivity is at least in part because investment projects are often postponable to a
time when economic conditions are more favorable. Its volatility makes investment spending an
important determinant of the amplitude, down and up, of the typical business cycle.34
As aggregate spending fell and credit availability tightened in 2008, investment spending quickly
weakened. As a share of real GDP, investment spending fell from about 16% in 2007 to about
11% at the economy’s trough in 2009. The sharp fall in real GDP from the second quarter of 2008
through the first quarter of 2009 was nearly fully accounted for by the sharp fall of investment
spending over this same period. With economic recovery, investment spending was a leading
source of economic growth, elevating its share of real GDP to 13.1% in 2010; it continued to
increase strongly over 2011, reaching 13.5% of real GDP. In the first half of 2012, investment
spending continued its upward trend reaching 14% of real GDP.35
In particular, the equipment and software component of nonresidential investment has been the
principal source of business spending strength and an important contributor to the pace of the
economic recovery. Equipment and software spending increased 14.6% in 2010, contributing
nearly a full percentage point to the growth of real GDP in that year. This category of business
investment spending continued to be an important source of economic growth in 2011, increasing
at an annual rate of 10.4% and contributing 0.7 percentage points to real GDP growth. However,
in the first half of 2012 investment spending on equipment and software slowed substantially,
advancing at a slower 5% annual rate.36
Typically, this same sensitivity also works in the opposite direction. Strongly rising investment
spending, responding to improving market demand, reduced uncertainty, and expanding credit
availability, often gives an above normal contribution to the rebound of aggregate spending
during the recovery phase of the business cycle.
Looking forward, however, some significant constraints on both residential and business
investment raise uncertainty about whether investment spending will continue to be a strong
contributor to economic recovery, and therefore, whether it could be a component of aggregate
spending capable of compensating for a weaker than normal recovery of spending by consumers.
The principal constraint on residential investment has been the large inventory of vacant housing,
left over from the 2002-2006 housing boom. It is estimated that the number of vacancies could be

34 Ibid., Table 1.1.5.
35 Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts, Table 1.1.5,
athttp://www.bea.gov/national/index.htm#gdp.
36 Ibid., Table 1.1.5, at http://www.bea.gov/national/index.htm#gdp.
Congressional Research Service
10

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

more than 2 million units above what would normally be expected at this stage of the business
cycle.37 As discussed above, the housing market has recently shown signs of stabilizing, and
residential investment spending has risen strongly in 2012, albeit from a very low base. On
balance new house construction is likely to remain relatively weak for the next two years while
the inventory overhang continues to be worked down.
The prospect for nonresidential investment is likely to be better than for residential investment,
but it is not clear that with economic recovery nonresidential investment will exceed its pre-crisis
level. On the supply side, capacity utilization rates have climbed back from record lows of below
70% reached during the recession, but, at about 75% currently, are still only at the lows reached
in the 1990 and the 2001 recessions and well short of the 80% to 85% that would typically
correspond to operating near or at capacity.38 On the demand side, business investment in new
plants and equipment is most often a response to the expectation of increased demand for the
products they produce. The main driver of that demand is consumer spending and, as discussed
above, that spending has been tepid, with the not unlikely prospect that it may continue to be
weak over the near term if households have made a lasting commitment to increased savings.
Stronger foreign demand could also stimulate investment spending and in theory compensate for
the weaker pull of domestic demand, but as discussed more fully below, foreign demand may also
be weak. Also, problems in the financial sector have caused sharply reduced activity in
commercial real estate, contributing to persistent weakness in business investment spending on
structures.39
In general, it seems questionable whether total investment spending would provide the offset to a
below normal contribution of consumption spending to economic growth over the near term.
Net Exports
The U.S. trade deficit (real net exports) shrank from about 6% of real GDP in 2006 to below 3%
in 2009. Since the beginning of the recession in late 2007 through the end of the contraction in
mid-2009, net exports have made a significant positive contribution to real GDP in an otherwise
declining economy. Even as economic weakness abroad caused U.S. exports to fall, imports fell
by more, providing a net positive push to current economic activity.40
The 3 percentage point swing in real net exports is, however, largely the consequence of the
severe economic weakness in the United States over this period. Since mid-2009, the deficit in
net exports has increased slightly, reaching 3.2% of real GDP in 2010, but in 2011 the deficit
decreased slightly, falling to 3.1% of real GDP; and in the first half of 2012 it again decreased
slightly to 3.0% of GDP. This relatively flat performance means that over the course of the
current recovery net exports have not had either a substantial positive or negative impact on

37 U.S. Census Bureau, Housing Vacancies and Home Ownership, at http://www.census.gov/hhes/www/housing/hvs/
historic/.
38 Data for capacity utilization are available at Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Industrial
Production and Capacity Utilization
, Table G17, http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/.
39 Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts, Table 1.1.5, at http://www.bea.gov/national/
index.htm#gdp.
40 Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts, Table 1.1.6, at
http://www.bea.gov/iTable/iTable.cfm?ReqID=9&step=1.
Congressional Research Service
11

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

economic growth. This neutral pattern makes it uncertain that net exports can be expected to
boost aggregate spending sufficiently to offset weak consumption over the medium term and help
assure a sustained recovery at a pace that steadily reduces unemployment.
Boosting U.S. Net Exports Through a Rebalancing of Global Spending
Increasing U.S. net exports to any degree requires that the trade deficit continues to decrease. For
that to happen, trade surpluses of the rest of the world with the United States must also decrease.
To achieve this adjustment of trade flows, a sizable rebalancing of domestic and external demand
on the part of the deficit and surplus economies would need to occur.41
Because a trade deficit is a consequence of an economy spending more than it produces,
rebalancing in this circumstance requires a decrease of domestic spending and increase of
domestic saving. In contrast, for overseas trade partners, because a trade surplus is a consequence
of an economy spending less than it produces, rebalancing in this circumstance requires an
increase of trade partner domestic spending and decrease in trade partner domestic saving.
This rebalancing of spending will put pressure on the dollar to depreciate and foreign currencies
to appreciate. A fall in the value of the dollar relative to the currencies of the surplus countries
causes the price of foreign goods to rise for U.S. buyers and the price of U.S. goods to fall for
foreign buyers. This change in the relative price of foreign versus domestic goods will cause the
net exports of the United States to rise, giving the boost in spending needed to potentially offset
reduced consumption spending. The change in relative prices would also cause the net exports of
surplus countries to fall as more of current output is absorbed by increased domestic spending.
In the United States, as discussed above, some measure of rebalancing seems to be occurring, as
evidenced by the increase in the personal saving rate above its pre-recession low. Although there
are good reasons to expect this increase to be sustained, there is the possibility that households
would eventually revert to their pre-crisis low saving patterns. However, even if household saving
remains higher, it is likely that any significant increase in the overall U.S. national saving rate
would also require an increase in government saving via smaller federal budget deficits.
Large U.S. budget deficits over the near term are providing a needed boost to weak aggregate
spending during the early stages of an economic recovery. With the strengthening of private
spending as the recovery matures, large government budget deficits would fade away, causing
government saving to rise. What puts this fading away of budget deficits in doubt over the long
term is the prospect of having to fund the obligations attached to the rising demand of an aging
U.S. population for healthcare, Social Security, and other entitlements. Without policy actions to
address these long-term demands, it is not clear how the long-term budget deficits will fall.
Effective global rebalancing arguably also involves sizable adjustments by the largest surplus
economies—Germany, Japan, and China. However, there are significant potential constraints on
how substantially each of these three economies can “save less and spend more,” perhaps limiting

41 On global rebalancing, see for example, Olivier Blanchard, “Sustaining Global Recovery,” International Monetary
Fund, September 2009, “Rebalancing,” The Economist, March 31, 2010, at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/
2009/09/index.htm, and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Vice-chairman Donald L. Kohn, Speech
“Global Imbalances,” May 11, 2010, at http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/kohn20100511a.htm.
Congressional Research Service
12

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

any sizable appreciation of their currencies relative to the dollar, and any associated boost in U.S.
net exports.
The inability of Germany to move its exchange rate independently from the other Euro area
economies reduces its flexibility of adjustment. In addition, the effects of the 2008-2009
recession have left limited room for further fiscal expansion and small ability to lower the
household saving rate. In addition, the ongoing sovereign debt crisis in the euro area has
dampened growth prospects in Germany, likely weakening the demand for U.S. exports. While its
level of debt is not high, recent German policy actions have stressed fiscal consolidation, tending
to increase saving and dampen spending.42 Japan, which does have a very high level of public
debt, has little to no room for fiscal expansion and a poor prospect of boosting household
spending. Moreover, both Germany and Japan, faced with substantial near-term economic
weakness in the aftermath of the global recession, may take steps to avoid the dampening of their
net exports that a sizable appreciation of the exchange rate would cause.
China has the largest bilateral trade surplus with the United States and therefore has the potential
to have a large impact on U.S. export sales and through that a significant positive impulse on the
pace of the U.S. economic recovery. Also, economic growth has remained relatively strong in
China through the recent global financial crisis and recession, and aggregate demand is expected
to be strong through the next two to three years. What is uncertain, however, is whether a greater
share of this spending will be domestic demand, particularly consumption spending by Chinese
households.
The very high rate of saving by Chinese households is thought to be a precautionary measure to
compensate for a lack of social insurance. It likely also reflects limited access to consumer credit.
The difficulty for the near-term task of sustaining economic recovery is that even if policy actions
are taken to remove these constraints on consumer spending, households are likely to only
gradually change their pattern of consumption and not provide a sharp near-term boost to
domestic spending.
Also, a closer look at the sources of increase in China’s domestic saving over the last decade
reveals that the principal contributor to that growth was Chinese companies, not households.
Therefore, changing the saving practices of Chinese companies is likely to be an important aspect
of any large increase in China’s saving rate. It is argued by some that Chinese companies retain
too large a share of their earnings. Better access to credit and changes in the governance rules of
Chinese business would likely reduce the business saving rate. But, as with households, even if
such policy initiatives are forthcoming, the change in the business saving rate is likely to emerge
only gradually.43

42 OECD, Restoring Public Finances, Country Notes: Germany, 2010, at http://www.oecd.org/gov/
budgetingandpublicexpenditures/47840777.pdf.
43 Of course, for these reforms to translate into a shift in China’s trade balance, that nation must be willing to allow its’
exchange rate to rise relative to the dollar, causing a decrease in the price of foreign goods relative to domestic goods,
and exerting downward pressure on China’s trade surplus. From July 2005 to February 2009, China abandoned its
dollar peg, allowing the yuan to appreciate by 28% (on a real trade-weighted basis). However, faced with weakening
export sales due to the global financial crisis China for the last 10 months has re-pegged the yuan to the dollar. China’s
export-led growth model, relying on a high saving rate (to keep internal demand low) and a low exchange rate pegged
to the dollar (to keep external demand high), has been very successful and, despite the possible advantages of reforms
to boost domestic demand, it is uncertain whether China would move substantially away from this model.
Congressional Research Service
13

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

Even with a successful rebalancing, it is unlikely that China alone can propel a boost in U.S. net
exports sufficient to offset weak domestic demand and pace economic recovery. China’s global
trade surplus is estimated to be about 10% of GDP. However, China is only about one-third the
size of the U.S. economy. Therefore, if China’s trade were only with the United States, it would
have to reduce its trade surplus by 3% of GDP to affect a 1 percentage point reduction of the U.S.
trade deficit. But since, in fact, only about 16% of China’s trade is with the United States, it
would take a 15 percentage point change in China’s trade balance (moving from a surplus equal
to 10% of GDP to a deficit equal to 5% of GDP) to reduce the U.S. trade deficit by 1 percentage
point. (This assumes that the fall of China’s trade surplus is not offset by an increase of other
trading partners surpluses.)
Other emerging Asian economies also run trade surpluses, and adding these to the calculation
makes the relative scale of rebalancing needed to achieve a given amount of improvement in the
U.S trade deficit more feasible. However, all of emerging Asia is only about half the size of the
U.S. economy. Therefore, if the U.S. share of the whole region’s trade is similar to China’s,
emerging Asia would need to accomplish a sizable 7 percentage point change in its trade balance
to generate a 1 percentage point change in the U.S. trade balance. As with China, for a reduction
of the trade surpluses of other emerging Asian economies to happen quickly, their currencies will
need to appreciate against the dollar.
All in all, there are reasons to doubt whether U.S. net exports can increase over the near term at a
pace sufficient to fully compensate for the prospect of slower than normal growth of other
components of U.S. domestic spending.
Supply Side Problems?
The supply side of the economy governs its capacity for producing goods and services. That
capacity is a function of the economy’s supplies of labor and capital and the level of technology
used to turn labor and capital into the output of goods and services. In the short run, the potential
supplies of these productive factors are relatively fixed and will determine the economy’s
potential output. In periods of economic slack, rising aggregate demand can increase the
economy’s output and employment up to the level of potential output, which corresponds with
full employment.
In the long run, as the supplies of capital and labor and the level of technology increase, the level
of potential output also increases. Over time the steady rise of potential output will define the
economy’s long-term growth path (called the “trend” growth rate). When aggregate demand is
below potential output the economy can grow faster than trend growth, but when the level of
aggregate demand reaches the level of potential output, further growth of output will be
constrained to the trend growth rate.
Typically the long-run growth path is thought to be relatively stable and not greatly affected by
recessions and the associated short-term fluctuations in aggregate demand. Over the post-war
period, the average annual growth rate of potential output for the United States has been 3.4%;
however, since the 1970s it has averaged closer to 3.0%.44

44 CBO, Key Assumptions in Projecting Potential Output, August 2012, at http://www.cbo.gov/publication/43541.
Congressional Research Service
14

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

An analysis by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) examines the question of whether output
will return to its pre-crisis trend.45 It examines the medium-term and long-run paths of output
after 88 banking crises over the past four decades in a wide range of countries (including both
advanced and developing economies). A key conclusion was that seven years after the crisis,
output had declined relative to trend by nearly 10% for the average country. But there was
considerable variation of outcomes across crisis episodes.
In other words, such crises not only reduce actual output, but also may reduce potential output
(the economy’s structural and institutional capacity to produce output). In this circumstance, the
economy could return to its trend growth rate, but there is unlikely to be a rebound period of
above normal growth to quickly return the economy to its pre-crisis potential output and growth
path and, in turn, quickly reduce unemployment. This failure to return to the pre-crisis potential
output means that the economy bears the burden of a permanent output loss and the large initial
increase in the unemployment rate caused by the crisis could persist even as the economy is
growing at its trend rate.
The IMF analysis suggests that the reduction of the post-crisis growth path is likely to be the
consequence of decreases of approximately equal size in the employment rate, the capital-labor
ratio, and productivity. The adverse effect of the financial crisis on the employment rate is
thought to arise from an increase in the “structural unemployment rate,” hampering the post-crisis
economy’s ability to accomplish the needed reallocation of labor from sectors that have
contracted permanently to sectors that are expanding.
Because the aftermath of the crisis will likely involve sizable changes in the composition of the
economy, it likely also increases the mismatch between the skills of the unemployed and the skills
demanded in the post-crisis labor market—job vacancies go unfilled for lack of a worker with
sufficient skills for the job.46 Also, labor force participation rates may fall if the crisis is severe
enough to substantially increase the numbers of the long-term unemployed, some of whom may
become discouraged from searching for a new job. A crisis-induced fall of house prices and a
rising incidence of mortgages with negative equity will also discourage the geographic mobility
of workers who are unable to sell their houses.
The adverse impact of a financial crisis on capital accumulation is likely the combined outcome
of several factors. Decreased demand for products and heightened uncertainty of potential return
dampens the incentive to invest. In addition, the financial crisis could impede the process of
financial intermediation for up to several years, as weakened balance sheets, lower collateral
values, and elevated risk premiums slow the flow of credit and elevate the real cost of borrowing.
The dampening effect on productivity may occur as higher risk premiums and a generally more
cautious approach to spending by businesses diminish the willingness and ability to finance

45 P. Kannan, A. Scott, and M. Terrones, “From Recession to Recovery: How Soon and How Strong?,” in World
Economic Outlook, April 2009, pp. 103-138. International Monetary Fund. Also see Davide Furceri and Annabelle
Mourougane, The Effect of Financial Crisis on Potential Output: New Empirical Evidence from OECD Countries,
OECD Economics Department, Working Paper no. 699, May 2009.
46 Employment in construction, financial services, and some types of manufacturing may remain depressed for some
time, requiring some who lose their jobs in those sectors to seek employment in other sectors. See also CRS Report
R41785, The Increase in Unemployment Since 2007: Is It Cyclical or Structural?, by Linda Levine, which suggests that
most of current U.S. unemployment is cyclical.
Congressional Research Service
15

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

relatively high-risk projects. Expenditures on research and development are typically pro-cyclical
and likely to be sharply reduced in times of crisis.
Productivity tends to recover quickly after recessions and thus allows the economy to resume
growth at the pre-crisis trend rate. However, the capital and employment losses tend to endure
and keep the economy on a lower growth path.
Has the recent financial crisis caused a reduction in the potential output of the U.S. economy and
placed it on a lower trend growth path? It is difficult to make a concurrent determination because
potential output is not directly observable, and can only be imputed from the economy’s actual
post-crisis performance. A clear determination of any such permanent output loss is some years in
the future.
Although the IMF study gives reasons why the financial crisis possibly could have adversely
affected the economy’s supply side, the study also finds that there can be some significant
mitigating factors that could be particularly relevant for the U.S. economy. First, a high pre-crisis
investment share is a good predictor of a large potential output loss. This is a reflection of the
high sensitivity of investment to the negative effects of a financial crisis. For the United States
there was no sharp increase in investment spending above trend as measured as a share of GDP
for the three years prior to the financial crisis, averaging near a typical 16% of GDP.47
Second, the IMF study also found that those economies that aggressively apply stimulative fiscal
and monetary policies during the crisis tend to have smaller medium-term output losses. As
already discussed, the United States has applied quickly and substantially stimulative polices in
response to the financial crisis.
Third, countries with fewer labor market rigidities suffered smaller medium-term output losses.
U.S. labor markets, as compared with other advanced economies, are relatively free of labor
market rigidities, though as mentioned declining house prices may have reduced mobility of some
workers who own their own homes.
The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) currently projects U.S. potential output to increase at an
annual average rate of 2.2% for the 2011-2016 period, slightly below the 2.4% pace of the 2002-
2010 period. CBO’s projected rate of growth of potential output is well below the post-war
average of 3.3%. Slower growth of potential GDP is largely the consequence of a projection of
significantly slower labor force growth than during the post-war period in the coming decades.
Most of the slow down in labor force growth is related to long-term demographic changes forced
by an aging population; however, a protracted recession with growing numbers of long-term
unemployed and discouraged workers has also contributed to this labor force dynamic.48
Policy Responses to Increase the Pace of Economic Recovery
The momentum of the current economic recovery has been assisted by injections of fiscal and
monetary stimulus. But with substantial economic slack remaining and with unemployment still

47Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts, Table 1.1.6, at
http://www.bea.gov/iTable/iTable.cfm?ReqID=9&step=1.
48 The Congressional Budget Office, Budget and Economic Outlook: An Update, August 2012, Table 2-3, at
http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=12316.
Congressional Research Service
16

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

stubbornly high, would further stimulus by monetary and fiscal policy be warranted to sustain
economic recovery?
Fiscal Policy Actions Taken During the Recovery
In 2010, many economists argued that another dose of fiscal stimulus was warranted because the
effects of the first stimulus package were beginning to fade, and because of evidence that private
spending lacked sufficient vigor to sustain a healthy recovery.49 In this situation, the risk of not
applying further fiscal stimulus could be several years of sub-normal growth, or worse, dipping
into a second recession.
In response to concerns that the recovery was faltering, Congress passed and President Obama
signed in December 2010 the Tax Relief, Unemployment Insurance Reauthorization, and Job
Creation Act of 2010 (P.L. 111-312). The essential features of that measure were an extension for
two years of the “Bush” tax cuts, a 2 percentage point cut in the payroll tax during 2011, a 13-
month extension of unemployment benefits, and allowance for more rapid expensing of business
investment in 2011. The CBO estimated that the direct stimulative effect of these revenue and
spending changes as measured by the increase in the federal budget deficit would be
approximately $374 billion in 2011 and $422 billion in 2012.50
A major counterforce to federal stimulus policies has been contraction of spending by state and
local governments. Direct expenditures by state and local governments decreased 1.8% in 2010
3.4%% in 2011, and 1.6% during the first half of 2012, having the effect of subtracting from real
GDP growth 0.2 percentage points in 2010, 0.3 percentage points in 2011, and 0.2 percentage
points in first half of 2012.51
Evaluating the Case for Fiscal Stimulus
Fiscal stimulus is not without its critics. The case against more fiscal stimulus comes in three
forms, used separately or in combination: one, no further stimulus is needed; two, fiscal stimulus
does not work; and three, stimulus increases the budget deficit, makes the U.S. long-term debt
problem worse, and dampens economic growth.52

49 Lawrence H. Summers, “Reflections on Fiscal Policy and Economic Strategy,” Speech at the Johns Hopkins School
of Advanced International Studies, May 24, 2010, at http://www.whitehouse.gov/administration/eop/nec/speeches/
fiscal-policy-economic-strategy. Other economists have also concluded that further stimulus is called for. See, for
example, Brad DeLong “The Worst -of-Both-Worlds Fiscal Policy,” June 18, 2010, http://delong.typepad.com/sdj/
2010/06/worst-of-both-worlds-fiscal-policy.html; and “The Case for More Stimulus” Interview with William Gale of
the Brookings Institution, June 2010, at http://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2010/06/the-case-for-more-
stimulus/57776/.
50 Congressional Budget Office, CBO Estimate of Changes in Revenue and Direct Spending for the Tax Relief,
Unemployment Insurance Reauthorization, and Job Creation Act of 2010, at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/120xx/
doc12020/sa4753.pdf.
51 Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts, Tables 1.1.1 and
1.1.2, at http://www.bea.gov/iTable/iTable.cfm?ReqID=9&step=1.
52 See for example, Derek Thompson, “The Case Against More Stimulus,” The Atlantic, June 2010, at
http://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2010/06/the-case-against-more-stimulus/57774/, and “Here’s Why Fiscal
Stimulus Won’t Work,” The Atlantic, February 2010, at http://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2010/02/heres-
why-government-stimulus-does-not-work/36466/.
Congressional Research Service
17

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

In regard to the need for stimulus, the U.S. economy does have strong recuperative powers and it
is possible that private spending and economic growth will soon surge without further fiscal
stimulus. Events such as improved consumer confidence, lower energy prices, a more normal
flow of credit, or faster growth in the rest of the world could separately or in combination induce
stronger spending by households and businesses. However, given the severity of the recent
recession and, as outlined above, given the current weakness of private spending and the several
economic obstacles that households and businesses will probably continue to face over the near
term, there remains a significant risk of sub-normal growth for the next several years.
In regard to the ability of fiscal stimulus to boost output and employment, some economists argue
that fiscal stimulus only shifts spending, it does not increase spending. In this view, when people
see the government running a budget deficit, they anticipate that the government will need to
increase taxes in the future to pay off the debt. This anticipation causes households and
businesses to increase their current savings to pay for the higher taxes. The increase in saving
tends to offset the stimulative effect of the budget deficit.53 There is little empirical support for
this theory, however. Mainstream economic analysis indicates that in circumstances like the
present, in which the economy’s output is likely constrained by insufficient demand, fiscal
stimulus can raise the level of output and employment.54
In regard to the long-term debt problem, it is often pointed out that for an economy operating
close to potential output, government borrowing to finance budget deficits will draw down the
pool of national saving, leaving less available to support private capital investment. Private
investment by business and households in education, housing, research and development, and
capital equipment that would have otherwise occurred is in theory “crowded out” through higher
interest rates bid up by government borrowing. If budget deficits divert national saving from
private investment, other things equal, future productivity and income growth may be slowed.
However, the U.S. economy is currently operating well short of capacity and market interest rates
are generally at or near historical lows, making the risk of such “crowding out” occurring and
damaging future economic growth not seem immediate.55 Another variant of this argument
against fiscal stimulus maintains that by increasing public debt, fiscal stimulus undermines
household and business confidence and causes them to postpone current spending. In this view,
contrary to mainstream economic thinking, shrinking the deficit would, by improving confidence,
actually stimulate current spending by consumers and business.56

53 This theory is called “Ricardian equivalence.” It is named after the nineteenth-century economist David Ricardo who
first made the argument. For further discussion see N. Gregory Mankiw, Principles of Economics (Ft. Worth, Dryden
Press, 1998), p. 556, and Robert J. Barro, “Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?” Journal of Political Economy, vol.
82, no. 6. (November-December, 1974), pp. 1095-1117.
54 See CRS Report RL31235, The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit, by Brian W. Cashell; Alan J. Auerbach and
William G. Gale, “Activist Fiscal Policy to Stabilize Economic Activity,” working paper, September 29, 2009,
available at http://elsa.berkeley.edu/~auerbach/activistfiscal.pdf; and Robert E. Hall, “By How Much Does GDP Rise If
the Government Buys More Output?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, fall 2009, pp. 183- 250. On the probable
simulative impact of alternative fiscal measures see CBO, Policies for Increasing Economic Growth and Employment,
March 2010, at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/112xx/doc11255/02-23-Employment_Testimony.pdf, and J. Bradford
DeLong and Lawrence H. Summers, “Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy,” The Brookings Institution, March 2012.
55 For discussion of the long-term debt issue, see President Obama’s National Commission on Fiscal Responsibility and
Reform
, at http://www.fiscalcommission.gov/.
56 For further discussion of this issue, see CRS Report R41849, Can Contractionary Fiscal Policy Be Expansionary?,
by Jane G. Gravelle and Thomas L. Hungerford.
Congressional Research Service
18

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

The Short-Term and Long-Term Fiscal Problems
Because the United States faces two macroeconomic problems, two policy responses are,
arguably, appropriate: a short-term policy to sustain a cyclical recovery of economic growth and a
long-term policy to trim government debt. Conceptually there is no necessary tradeoff between
these two objectives. They can be mutually reinforcing: a credible commitment to dealing with
the long-term debt problem allays investor uncertainty and increases the near-term incentive to
spend, while effectively dealing with the short-term problem of weak aggregate demand puts the
economy on a stronger growth path, which boosts tax revenue and eases the long-term debt
problem.
Once the short-term problem of weak demand is solved and the economy has returned to a normal
growth path, the appropriate policy response for an economy with a looming debt crisis is
arguably fiscal consolidation—cutting deficits. Such a policy is thought to have the benefits of
low and stable interest rates, a less fragile financial system, improved investment prospects, and
possibly faster long-term growth.
To address the government’s long-term fiscal problem, Congress passed on August 2, 2011, the
Budget Control Act of 2011 (P.L. 112-25). The Budget Control Act (BCA) sets caps on
discretionary spending. It also created the Congressional Joint Select Committee on Deficit
Reduction, whose task was to propose further policy changes that would lead to $1.5 trillion in
further deficit reduction over 10 years. The joint committee was unable to reach an agreement on
how to achieve further deficit reduction. In the absence of an agreement, the BCA established a
process for automatic spending reduction. The CBO estimates that the fiscal restraint caused by
the expiration of provisions of the 2010 tax act and from enactment of the BCA will decrease real
GDP in 2013 by between 1.5% and 3.5%.57
The Impending “Fiscal Cliff”
Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke, speaking at an April 2012 press conference, warned about the likely
adverse effect on the economic recovery of the “fiscal cliff” the economy could face in January
2013.58 The fiscal cliff refers to the confluence of various spending cuts and tax rate increases that
are scheduled to occur at the beginning of the new year unless policies are changed. The
scheduled fiscal events include the end of the extension of the Bush tax cuts, the need for
adjustment of the alternative minimum tax (AMT), the end of the Social Security payroll tax cut,
reductions in Medicare reimbursement payments, and spending cuts mandated by the
“sequestration” process of the 2011 BCA.59 Incorporating these policy changes into its most
recent projections for the economy, the CBO estimates that this degree of fiscal tightening will
lead to real GDP contracting by 0.5% between the fourth quarter of 2012 and the fourth quarter of

57 For more information on the BCA, see CRS Report R41965, The Budget Control Act of 2011, by Bill Heniff Jr.,
Elizabeth Rybicki, and Shannon M. Mahan; and the Congressional Budget Office, Budget and Economic Outlook: An
Update
, August 2011, p. 38, at http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=12316.
58 Board of Govenors of the Federal Reserve System, Press Conference, at http://www.federalreserve.gov/mediacenter/
files/FOMCpresconf20120425.pdf.
59 For more information, see CRS Report R42362, The Federal Budget: Issues for FY2013 and Beyond, by Mindy R.
Levit, and CRS Report R42485, An Overview of Tax Provisions Expiring in 2012, by Margot L. Crandall-Hollick.
Congressional Research Service
19

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

2013 and the unemployment rate rising to about 9% in the second half of 2013. These economic
conditions would likely be judged as a recession.60
Monetary Policy Actions Taken During the Recovery
On November 3, 2010, the Fed announced that it would provide more monetary stimulus by
means of the purchase an additional $600 billion of Treasury securities at a pace of about $75
billion per month, and continue the practice of replacing maturing securities with Treasury
security purchases. When this second round of monetary stimulus (sometimes referred to as
“quantitative easing 2” or QE2)61 was completed in June 2011, the Fed had increased the size of
its balance sheet to more than $2.5 trillion. The maturity lengths of the securities purchased were
mostly between 2½ and 10 years.62
The Fed argued at that time that a second dose of monetary stimulus was needed because
economic growth is decelerating and much of what economic momentum existed was being
provided by the transitory factors of inventory adjustment and fiscal stimulus. In the second half
of 2010, growth slowed to around 2%, a pace barely fast enough to keep the unemployment rate
from rising. Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke indicated that of particular concern was the substantial
increase in the share of the long-term unemployed (workers who have been without work for six
months or more). Such long-term unemployment tends to convert temporary cyclical
unemployment into more intractable structural unemployment. In addition, the lingering
economic slack in the economy had added to deflationary pressure. Measures of core inflation
had been decelerating during 2010, reaching a low of only slightly above 1%. A continuous
decline in the price level is troublesome because in a weak or contracting economy it can lead to a
damaging, self-reinforcing, downward spiral of prices and economic activity. Deflation
exacerbated the economy’s decline during the Great Depression.63
To support a stronger recovery, the Fed announced on September 21, 2011, that it would purchase
by the end of June 2012 $400 billion of Treasury securities with remaining maturities of 6 years
to 30 years and to sell an equal amount of Treasury securities with remaining maturities of 3 years
or less.64 In June 2012, the Fed announced that it would extend this program through the end of
2012. This program does not expand the size of the Fed’s balance sheet. Rather, by changing the
composition of its asset holdings toward longer maturities, the Fed is attempting to put downward
pressure on longer-term interest rates and increase monetary policy’s stimulative effect on
economic activity.65

60 CBO, The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2012 to 2022, August 2012, at http://www.cbo.gov/
publication/43539. See also CRS Report R42700, The “Fiscal Cliff”: Macroeconomic Consequences of Tax Increases
and Spending Cuts
, by Jane G. Gravelle.
61 On the policy of quantitative easing, see CRS Report R41540, Quantitative Easing and the Growth in the Federal
Reserve’s Balance Sheet
, by Marc Labonte; and CRS Report RL30354, Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve:
Current Policy and Conditions
, by Marc Labonte.
62Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Federal Open Market Committee, http://www.federalreserve.gov/
monetarypolicy/fomccalendars.htm.
63 For further discussion of deflation, see CRS Report R40512, Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and
Policy Responses
, by Craig K. Elwell.
64 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, September 2011, at http://www.federalreserve.gov/
newsevents/press/monetary/20110921a.htm.
65 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, June 2012, at http://www.federalreserve.gov/
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
20

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

On September 13, 2012, the Fed announced a third round of quantitative easing, or QE3. Pointing
to slow economic growth and an unemployment rate that has not improved since the beginning of
the year, the Fed expressed concern that “without further policy accommodation, economic
growth might not be strong enough to generate sustained improvement in labor market
conditions.”66 QE3 will increase policy accommodation by purchasing additional agency
mortgaged-backed securities at a pace of $40 billion per month, which together with its “maturity
extension program” to increase the average maturity of its asset holdings as announced in June,
will increase the Fed’s holdings of long-term assets by about $85 billion per month through the
end of 2012. Moreover, in a significant change from the earlier rounds of quantitative easing, the
QE3 mortgage-backed security purchases are open-ended, meaning that the Fed is committing to
continuing the program until labor market conditions improve. The Fed also gave further
“forward guidance” by announcing that it intends to keep the federal funds interest rates at
“exceptionally low levels” through mid-2015.
Evaluating the Case for Monetary Stimulus
The Fed’s recent policy initiatives to provide sucessive rounds of monetary stimulus have been
criticized. One concern is an increased risk of inflation. Such a large increase in bank reserves
could also lead to a rapid increase in the overall money supply through the “money multiplier”
effect, which in normal times might generate inflation. At present, the sizable degree of slack in
the economy and banks’ heightened tendency to hold reserves rather than lend them out keeps the
risk of inflation low.
As noted above, one of the reasons for initiating a second round of monetary stimulus in late 2010
was to counter an incipient deflation problem, which is accomplished by policies that exert
upward pressure on the level of prices, that is, policies that generate some degree of inflation. The
Fed’s second round of monetary stimulus seems to have reduced the deflation risk.
Also, some of the recent increase in broad measures of inflation, such as the consumer price index
(CPI), is due to the sharp rise in oil and other commodity prices in the first half of 2011 and again
in early 2012. However, such inflation effects are most often temporary and not a source of
persistent inflationary pressure. The “core CPI,” a measure of inflation that does not include
volatile food and energy prices, has remained low. Other indicators also suggest that inflation is
likely to remain subdued. First, wages, which are generally the most important determinant of
unit production costs, have been stable. Second, longer-term inflationary expectations, as
measured by the yields on long-term securities, have not risen appreciably.
However, when the economy returns to more normal conditions, reserves would likely need to be
removed to avoid excessive upward pressure on prices. The likely unprecedented scale of the
reserves that might need to be drained from the economy has raised concerns about whether the
Fed could effectively provide the degree of restraint needed to keep inflation under control.
A second criticism of the Fed’s monetary stimulus during the recovery is that it is depreciating the
dollar. Although influencing the exchange rate is not a stated goal of the Fed’s policy, standard

(...continued)
newsevents/press/monetary/20120620a.htm.
66 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, September 13, 2012, at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20120913a.htm.
Congressional Research Service
21

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

macroeconomic theory would predict, all else equal, that a by-product of monetary stimulus
would be a depreciation of the dollar (assuming other countries do not similarly alter their
monetary policy in response). A weaker dollar would add to the stimulative effect of monetary
stimulus on total spending in the United States by increasing exports and decreasing imports.
However, countries such as Germany, Japan, and China that have relied on net exports to propel
their economic growth are resistant to a depreciating dollar and have criticized the Fed’s actions.
As it turns out, the dollar depreciation that has occurred over the last year is, arguably, not the
result of Fed actions, but a correction from the appreciation of the dollar in late 2008 and 2009
that was caused by a flight to safety by foreign investors during the financial crisis. At that time, a
strong global demand for relatively safe U.S. Treasury securities bid up the dollar’s exchange
rate. As financial panic receded, the demand for safety abated, and the dollar depreciated to its
pre-crisis level.
A third criticism is that monetary stimulus will have little impact on real economic activity. In the
current economic environment, with badly weakened household and business balance sheets
placing a premium on improving liquidity, it is difficult for monetary policy to get “traction,”
stimulating the broader economy by pumping reserves into the banking system. For this reason,
the stimulus to the real economy from the Fed’s successive rounds of quantitative easing have not
been expected to be a “cure-all” for sustaining economic recovery. Moreover, how effective
monetary stimulus has been is difficult to judge because there is no ready “counterfactual” state
of the economy from which to judge its impact on output and employment. Nevertheless,
estimates are possible. Using statistical economic models that incorporate past relations between
financial conditions and the economy, it is possible to estimate the impact of monetary stimulus
on the economy. For example, one recent study found that the first two rounds of quantitative
easing may have increased output by 3% and increased employment by more than 2 million
jobs.67 Other studies have found comparable effects.68
A Lesson from the Great Depression
One of the important lessons from the Great Depression is to avoid a hasty withdrawal of fiscal
and monetary stimulus in a fragile economy still recovering from a sharp economic decline.
Beginning in 1933, the U.S. economy rebounded from its sharp fall into what has become known
as the Great Depression. From 1933 to 1936, supported by expansionary fiscal and monetary
policies, the U.S. economy grew briskly at an average rate of 9.0% and unemployment fell from
25% to 14%. Economic output had nearly returned to its level in 1929, but the economy was still
well short of full recovery. But in 1937, the recovery halted and the economy tipped into a second
recession. Most economists believe that the second dip into recession was caused by an
unfortunate premature switch to contractionary monetary and fiscal policies in a still-fragile
recovering economy.

67 Hess Chung, Jean-Phillippe Laforte, David Reifschender, and John C. Williams, “Have We Underestimated the
Likelihood and Severity of Zero Lower Bound Events,” Journal of Money Credit and Banking, February 2012, pp. 47-
82.
68 See for example, Jeffrey C. Fuher and Giovanni P. Olivei, “The Estimated Macroeconomic Effects of the Federal
Reserve’s Large-Scale Treasury Purchase Program,” Public Policy Briefs, April 2011, Federal Reserve Bank of
Boston; and Micheal Kiley “The Aggregate Demand Effects of Short-Term and Long-Term Interest Rates,” Finance
and Economics Discussion Series
2012-54, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington DC.
Congressional Research Service
22

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

On the monetary side, in 1936, the Federal Reserve began to worry about inflation. After several
years of relatively loose monetary policy, the U.S. banking system had built up large quantities of
reserves in excess of legal reserve requirements. The Fed feared, despite little overt evidence of a
problem, that should the banks begin to lend these excess reserves, it could lead to an
overexpansion of credit and generate an inflationary surge. In an attempt to sop up those excess
reserves, the Fed raised the banks’ reserve requirements three times during 1936. However, banks
were still nervous about the financial panics of the early 1930s and uncertain about the durability
of the economic recovery, and consequently wanted to hold excess reserves as a cushion. In
response to the higher reserve requirements erasing that cushion, the banks worked to rebuild it
by reducing lending, leading to a contraction of credit-supported spending.
On the fiscal side, by 1936, following several years of large budget deficits, the federal
government had a strong urge to declare victory and get back to normal policy—specifically,
balancing the government budget. The veterans’ bonus that was paid in 1936 was not renewed in
1937; in addition, Social Security taxes were collected for the first time in 1937. The overall
effect was a fiscal contraction equal to about 3% of GDP.
The double hit of contractionary monetary and fiscal policy in an economy that had still not
reached the point in which private demand was capable of fully sustaining economic growth led
to a recession. In 1938, GDP fell 4.5% and the unemployment rate increased to 19%.69
Economic policy quickly changed course and recovery resumed in the second half of 1938, but
the policy error added about two years to the Great Depression, which ended with the step-up in
war-time government spending in 1941.
The euro zone countries appear to be re-learning this policy lesson from the Great Depression, at
considerable economic cost. Their attempt to impose austerity measures to combat growing
government debt, while still in the mist of economic recovery, has pushed the region back into
recession.
Economic Projections
Given the unusually large deterioration of the balance sheets of households and businesses, the
possible reduction of the U.S. economy’s level of potential output, the weakened state of the
global economy, and uncertainty about fiscal policy, projections of the U.S. economy’s near-term
path carry a higher than normal degree of uncertainty. During 2012, most economic forecasters
have steadily trimmed their growth projections as it became ever more evident that the economy
seemed to be only “treading water,” particularity in labor markets. Nevertheless, most forecasters
expect the U.S. economic recovery to continue, albeit at a distressingly slow pace.
• In its September 2012 meeting, the Fed’s Open Market Committee projected real
GDP in 2012 to advance in a range between 1.7% to 2.0% (down from a range of
1.9% to 2.4% in its June meeting) and in 2013 advance in a range between 2.5%
to 3.0% (changed from a range of 2.2% to 2.8% in its June meeting). The

69 For further discussion of the recession of 1937, see Christina D. Romer, “The Nation in Depression,” Journal of
Economic Perspectives 7
(spring 1993), pp. 19-39; Milton Friedman and Anna D. Schwartz, A Monetary History of the
United States, 1867-1960
(Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1963); Francois R. Velde, “The Recession of
1937—A Cautionary Tale,” Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, fourth quarter 2009, pp. 16-36.
Congressional Research Service
23

Economic Recovery: Sustaining U.S. Economic Growth in a Post-Crisis Economy

unemployment rate is projected to be in a range between 8.0% to 8.2% in 2012
(unchanged from its June meeting) and 7.6% to 7.9% in 2013 (compared with a
range of 7.5% to 8.0% in the June meeting).70
• The IMF’s October 2012 projection sees real GDP in the United States increasing
2.2% in 2012 and 2.1% in 2013. (The forecast for 2013 is down 0.1% percentage
points from its July 2012 projection though the forecast for 2012 has been
revised up by 0.1 percentage points.) Globally, the IMF expects an unbalanced
recovery to persist into 2013, with growth of real output in the advanced
economies to average 1.5% compared with growth in the emerging developing
economies averaging 5.6%.71
• Global Insight, an economic forecasting company, projected in August 2012 that
real GDP will advance 2.1% in 2012 and decelerate to 1.8% in 2013. The
company projects the unemployment rate will be 8.0% and 7.7% in 2012 and
2013, respectively.72

Author Contact Information

Craig K. Elwell

Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
celwell@crs.loc.gov, 7-7757



70 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Minutes of September 2012 FOMC Meeting, Projection
Materials, at http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomccalendars.htm.
71 International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, October 2012, Table 1.1, at http://www.imf.org/external/
pubs/ft/weo/2012/02/index.htm.
72 Global Insight, U.S. Economic Outlook, August 2012.
Congressional Research Service
24