.

The Bayh-Dole Act: Selected Issues in Patent
Policy and the Commercialization
of Technology

Wendy H. Schacht
Specialist in Science and Technology Policy
March 16, 2012
Congressional Research Service
7-5700
www.crs.gov
RL32076
CRS Report for Congress
Pr
epared for Members and Committees of Congress
c11173008


.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

Summary
Congressional interest in facilitating U.S. technological innovation led to the passage of P.L. 96-
517, Amendments to the Patent and Trademark Act (commonly referred to as the Bayh-Dole Act
after its two main sponsors). The act provides patent rights to certain inventions arising out of
government-sponsored research and development (R&D) to non-profit institutions and small
businesses with the expressed purpose of encouraging the commercialization of new technologies
through cooperative ventures between and among the research community, small firms, and
industry.
Patents provide an economic incentive for companies to pursue further development and
commercialization. Studies indicate that research funding accounts for approximately one-quarter
of the costs associated with bringing a new product to market. Patent ownership is seen as a way
to encourage the additional, and often substantial investment necessary for generating new goods
and services in the private sector. In an academic setting, the possession of title to inventions is
expected to provide motivation for the university to license the technology to companies for
commercialization in expectation of royalty payments.
The Bayh-Dole Act has been seen as particularly successful in meeting its objectives. However,
while the legislation provides a general framework to promote expanded utilization of the results
of federally funded research and development, questions have been raised as to the adequacy of
current arrangements. Most agree that closer cooperation among industry, government, and
academia can augment funding sources (both in the private and public sectors), increase
technology transfer, stimulate more innovation (beyond invention), lead to new products and
processes, and expand markets. However, others point out that collaboration may provide
increased opportunities for conflicts of interest, redirection of research, less openness in sharing
of scientific discovery, and a greater emphasis on applied rather than basic research. Additional
concerns have been expressed, particularly in relation to the pharmaceutical and biotechnology
industries, that the government and the public are not receiving benefits commensurate with the
federal contribution to the initial research and development.
Actual experience and cited studies suggest that companies which do not control the results of
their investments—either through ownership of patent title, exclusive license, or pricing
decisions—tend to be less likely to engage in related R&D. The importance of control over
intellectual property is reinforced by the positive effect P.L. 96-517 has had on the emergence of
new technologies and techniques generated by U.S. companies.

Congressional Research Service

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

Contents
Introduction...................................................................................................................................... 1
An Historical Perspective ................................................................................................................ 1
The Rationale............................................................................................................................. 1
The Patent System: A Brief Overview....................................................................................... 2
University-Industry Cooperation............................................................................................... 4
Small Business........................................................................................................................... 4
Bayh-Dole Act and Related Law ..................................................................................................... 6
Provisions .................................................................................................................................. 6
Implementation and Results ...................................................................................................... 8
Current Issues and Concerns.......................................................................................................... 13
Recoupment............................................................................................................................. 14
Government Rights: Royalty Free Licenses and Reporting Requirements ............................. 16
University Research................................................................................................................. 17
Biotechnology and Pharmaceuticals........................................................................................ 20
Concluding Observations............................................................................................................... 23

Contacts
Author Contact Information........................................................................................................... 24

Congressional Research Service

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

Introduction
Congressional interest in facilitating U.S. technological innovation led to the passage of P.L. 96-
517, Amendments to the Patent and Trademark Act, commonly referred to as the “Bayh-Dole
Act” after its two main sponsors former Senators Robert Dole and Birch Bayh. Under this 1980
law, as amended, title to inventions made with government support may be provided to the
contractor if that contractor is a small business, a university, or other non-profit institution. The
legislation is intended to use patent ownership as an incentive for private sector development and
commercialization of federally funded research and development (R&D). As a response to
congressional efforts to create a unified government patent policy pertaining to inventions made
with federal support, the Bayh-Dole Act promotes cooperative activities among academia, small
business, and industry leading to new products and processes for the marketplace.
This paper discusses the rationale behind the passage of P.L. 96-517, its provisions, and
implementation of the law. Observers generally agree that the Bayh-Dole Act has successfully
met its objectives. However, some experts argue that the issues associated with the law’s patent
policies should be revisited given the current R&D environment. Much of the renewed interest is
a result of the legislation’s effect on the biotechnology and pharmaceutical industries where
critics assert that the private sector is receiving benefits to the detriment of the public interest.
Other analysts, particularly in the defense arena, maintain that the existing rights maintained by
the government are too restrictive and prevent industry from meeting national needs. Many of
these issues and concerns are similar, if not identical to those addressed during the 15 to 20 years
of deliberation prior to enactment of the law. These too will be explored to provide a context for
current discussions.
An Historical Perspective
The Rationale
In the late 1970s, the United States Congress was involved in a series of legislative debates over
ways to promote private sector development and utilization of federally funded research and
development. This was soon followed by expanded congressional interest in additional means to
foster technological advancement and commercialization in industry. During the 1980s and
1990s, various initiatives resulted in laws designed to encourage increased innovation-related
activities in the business community and to remove barriers to technology development, thereby
permitting market forces to operate.1 Laws promoting cooperative R&D and/or joint ventures
involving the federal government, industry, and academia have been a cornerstone of the majority
of these efforts and include legislation that created a system to transfer technology from federal
laboratories to the private sector; implemented tax incentives for collaborative work; instituted
direct and indirect government support for increased R&D; and changed government patent
policy to provide an economic inducement for commercialization of federally funded technology,
the subject of this report.

1 For additional discussion, see CRS Report RL33528, Industrial Competitiveness and Technological Advancement:
Debate Over Government Policy
, by Wendy H. Schacht.
Congressional Research Service
1

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

P.L. 96-517, the Bayh-Dole Act, was one of the first of these initiatives. Prior to 1980, only 5% of
government owned patents were ever used in the private sector although a portion of the
intellectual property portfolio had potential for further development, application, and marketing.
The Bayh-Dole Act was constructed, in part, to address the low utilization rate of these federal
patents. The House report to accompany H.R. 6933 (the House counterpart to the Senate bill that
eventually became the Bayh-Dole Act) noted that, at the time the bill was considered, 26 different
agency policies existed regarding the use of the results of federally funded R&D. Generally the
government retained title to inventions made with government support whether the research was
performed in federal laboratories, in universities, or by individual companies. Licenses to use
government patents were then negotiated with firms either on a non-exclusive basis (meaning
additional companies could use the technology) or, more rarely, for the exclusive use by one
manufacturer. However, it was widely argued that without title (or at least an exclusive license) to
an invention and the protection it conveys, a company would not invest the additional, and often
substantial time and money necessary to commercialize a product or process for the marketplace.
In 1980, the federal expenditure for research and development totaled $55.5 billion (in constant
2000 dollars).2 The money typically was used to support research and development to meet the
mission requirements of the federal departments and agencies (e.g., defense, public health,
environmental quality) or to finance work in areas where there was an identified need for
research, primarily basic research, not being performed in the private sector. While the
government’s investment led to many new inventions that have profoundly influenced our
society, many in Congress were of the opinion that additional applications could be pursued by
the private sector if provided the proper incentives.
The intent of the new law was to replace this situation with a “single, uniform national policy
designed to cut down on bureaucracy and encourage private industry to utilize government
financed inventions through the commitment of the risk capital necessary to develop such
inventions to the point of commercial application.”3 Expanded technology commercialization was
to be accomplished by employing the patent system to augment collaboration between
universities (as well as other nonprofit institutions) and the business community to ensure that
inventions are brought to market. The Bayh-Dole Act also provides for the increased participation
of small firms in the national R&D enterprise under the assumption that these companies tend to
be more innovative than larger companies.
The Patent System: A Brief Overview
The patent system was created to promote invention and innovation. Article I, Section 8, Clause 8
of the U.S. Constitution states: “The Congress Shall Have Power ... To promote the Progress of
Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive
Right to their respective Writings and Discoveries....” Patents are widely believed to encourage
innovation by simultaneously protecting the inventor and fostering competition. They provide the
inventor with a right to exclude others, temporarily, from use of the invention without
compensation. Patents give the owner an exclusive right for 20 years (from date of filing) to
further develop the idea, commercialize a product or process, and potentially realize a return on

2 National Science Board, Science and Engineering Indicators—2006, (Washington, National Science Foundation,
2006), A4-5.
3 House Committee on the Judiciary, Report to Accompany H.R. 6933, 96th Cong., 2d Sess., H.Rept. 96-1307, Part 1, 3.
Congressional Research Service
2

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

the initial investment. Concurrently, the process of obtaining a patent places the concept in the
public arena. As a disclosure system, the patent can, and often does, stimulate other firms or
individuals to invent “around” existing patents to provide for parallel technical developments or
meet similar market needs.4
Not everyone agrees that the patent system facilitates innovation. Critics argue that patents
provide a monopoly which induces additional social costs. Others assert that the patent system is
unnecessary due to market forces that already suffice to create an optimal level of innovation. The
desire to obtain a lead time advantage over competitors, as well as the recognition that
technologically backward firms lose out to their rivals, may well provide sufficient inducement to
invent without the need for further incentives.5 Some commentators believe that the patent system
encourages industry concentration and presents a barrier to entry in some markets and that cross
licensing between companies can result in exploitation of other markets.6 Still other observers
believe that the patent system too frequently attracts speculators who prefer to acquire and
enforce patents rather than engage in socially productive activity.7
The importance of patents varies among industrial sectors. Patents are perceived as critical in the
drug and chemical industries in part because of the ease of replicating the finished product. While
it is expensive, complicated, and time consuming to duplicate an airplane, it is relatively simple to
chemically analyze a pill and reproduce it.8 Studies have found that in many other industries the
protection offered by patents is diminished by the ability to invent around the patent and limited
by the disclosure of vital information in the patent itself.9 In the aircraft and semiconductor
industries, patents have not been the most successful mechanism for capturing the benefits of
investments. Instead, lead time and the strength of the learning curve were determined to be more
important.10 Later studies bear this out; secrecy and lead time were deemed to have greater effect
than patents in the semiconductor and related equipment industry, as well as the aerospace and
machine tool industries, among others.11
Patents can provide an economic incentive for companies to pursue further development and
commercialization. Studies indicate that research funding accounts for approximately one-quarter
of the costs associated with bringing a new product to market. According to The Economist, “A
dollar’s worth of academic invention or discover requires upwards of $10,000 of private capital to

4 For more information, see CRS Report RL32324, Federal R&D, Drug Discovery, and Pricing: Insights from the
NIH-University-Industry Relationship
, by Wendy H. Schacht.
5 Frederic M. Sherer, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance (Rand McNally & Co, 1970), 384-87.
6 John R. Thomas, “Collusion and Collective Action in the Patent System: A Proposal for Patent Bounties,” University
of Illinois Law Review,
2001, 305.
7 Ibid.
8 Federic M. Scherer, “The Economics of Human Gene Patents,” Academic Medicine, December 2002, 1350.
9 Wesley M. Cohen, Richard R. Nelson, and John P. Walsh, Protecting Their Intellectual Assets: Appropriability
Conditions and Why U.S. Manufacturing Firms Patent (or Not)
, National Bureau of Economic Research, February
2000, available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w7552.
10 Richard C. Levin, Alvin K. Klevorick, Richard R. Nelson, and Sidney G. Winter, “Appropriating the Returns for
Industrial Research and Development,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1987, printed in The Economics of
Technical Change
, Edwin Mansfield and Elizabeth Mansfield, eds., (Vermont, Edward Elgar Publishing Co., 1993),
253.
11 Protecting Their Intellectual Assets: Appropriability Conditions and Why U.S. Manufacturing Firms Patent (or Not),
Table 1.
Congressional Research Service
3

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

bring [it] to market.”12 Patent ownership is seen as a way to encourage the additional, and often
substantial investment necessary for new goods and services, particularly in the case of small
business. In an academic setting, the possession of title to inventions is expected to provide
motivation for the university to license the technology to the private sector for commercialization
in anticipation of royalty payments.
University-Industry Cooperation
Changes to the patent laws embodied in the Bayh-Dole Act had as an objective the facilitation of
collaborative ventures between and among academia, industry, and government. In 1980,
universities performed 14% of the R&D undertaken in the United States (similar to today); much
of this the fundamental research basic to technological advance.13 The work is accomplished as
part of the education process and provides training for scientists, engineers, and managers
subsequently employed by the private sector.
Universities, however, generally do not have the means of production necessary to take the results
of research and generate marketable products. Such activities are carried out by industry. Thus,
the emphasis in the Bayh-Dole Act on the promotion of cooperative efforts between academia and
the business community. By providing universities with intellectual property ownership with
which to pursue and structure collaborative ventures, the legislation is intended to encourage the
two sectors to work together to generate new goods, processes, and services for the marketplace.
Such joint work allows for shared costs, shared risks, shared facilities, and shared expertise.
Prior to World War II, industry was the primary source of funding for basic research in
universities. This financial support helped shape priorities and build relationships. However, after
the war, the federal government supplanted the private sector as the major financial contributor
and became the principal determinant of the type and direction of the research performed in
academic institutions. This situation oftentimes resulted in a disconnect between the university
and industrial communities. Because the private sector and not the government typically is
involved in commercialization, the difficulties in moving an idea from the research stage to a
marketable product or process appeared to have been compounded. Thus, efforts to encourage
increased collaboration between and among the sectors through the Bayh-Dole Act were expected
to augment the contribution of both parties to technological advancement.
Small Business
Special consideration concerning patent title was given to small businesses in part because of the
role these companies were seen as playing in the generation of new jobs and in technological
advancement. Early research supported by several federal agencies concluded that small, high
technology companies are the source of significant innovation. An often cited 1982 study
financed by the Small Business Administration determined that small firms were 2.4 times as
innovative per employees as large companies.14 Similar work performed at the time the

12 “Innovation’s Golden Goose,” The Economist (US), December 14, 2002, available at http://www.economist.com/
node/1476653?story_id=1476653.
13 National Science Board, Science and Engineering Indicators—2002 (Washington, National Science Foundation,
2002), A4-9.
14 National Science Board, Science and Engineering Indicators—1993 (Washington, National Science Foundation,
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
4

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

legislation was being considered found that firms of less than 1,000 employees were responsible
for more major innovations than large firms in the years 1953-1966 and for an equal number from
1967-1973.15 More recent research points to the contribution of small businesses to economic
growth “as measured by net new job creation....”16 According to the National Science Foundation,
“U.S. small business is closely associated with the development of new technologies in many of
the science-based industries likely to be important to future economic growth.”17
Commentators argue that small firms act as entrepreneurs and change agents, undertaking
innovative activities that stimulate the evolution of new and existing industries.18 Because these
companies often are involved in “leading-edge technical niches,” the contribution of this sector to
innovation “is most intense in new technologies.”19 Experts claim that
small firm innovators are extremely effective at producing technically important
innovations—and technically important innovations are more than twice as likely as large
firm innovations to be extremely high impact.20
Therefore, small companies appear to be dominant in certain high technology industries including
biotechnology, new materials, information technology and communications.21
However, certain caveats need to be stated particularly within the context of small business,
innovation, and technology development. Over the years, experts have argued that the
contribution of small firms to the economy is overstated. Marc Levinson, writing in Dun’s
Business Month
during the 1980s, maintained that small companies tended to produce fewer
goods than larger ones because they are less capital intensive and, on the whole, add less to the
gross national product because they offer lower salaries and often do not provide health insurance
or pension plans.22 Professors Zoltan Acs and David Audretsch argued that the relationship
between company size and innovation capacity varied by industry.23 They note that “the evidence
also suggests that there tends to be more innovative activity in industries consisting of larger and
not smaller firms.”24 One commentator claims that the

(...continued)
1993), 185.
15 National Science Board, Science Indicators—1976 (Washington, National Science Foundation, 1976), 116.
16 BJK Associates, The Influence of R&D Expenditures on New Firm Formation and Economic Growth, Small
Business Administration, Office of Advocacy, October 2002, 2, available at http://www.njit.edu/v2/News/Releases/
finalreport_10-02-02.pdf.
17 National Science Foundation, “Indicators of U.S. Small Business’s Role in R&D,” InfoBrief, NSF 10-304, March
2010, 1, available at http://www.nsf.gov/statistics/infbrief/nsf10304/nsf10304.pdf.
18 Martin A. Carree and A. Roy Thurik, “Entrepreneurship, Economic Growth and Policy,” in Handbook of
Entrepreneurship Research
, Zoltan J. Acs and David B. Audretsch, eds. (New York, Springer Press, 2003), 439.
19 CHI Research, Inc, Small Serial Innovators: The Small Firm Contribution to Technological Change, Small Business
Administration, Office of Advocacy, February 2003, 3, available at http://www.sba.gov/advo/research/rs225tot.pdf.
20 Ibid., 12.
21 CHI Research, Inc., Small Firms and Technology: Acquisitions, Inventor Movement, and Technology Transfer, Small
Business Administration, Office of Advocacy, January 2004, 4, available at http://www.sba.gov/advo/research/
rs233tot.pdf.
22 Marc Levinson, “Small Business: Myth and Reality,” Dun’s Business Month, September 1985, 32-33.
23 Zoltan J. Acs and David B. Audretsch, Innovation and Small Firms (Cambridge, The MIT Press, 1990), 50-51.
24 Ibid., 147.
Congressional Research Service
5

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

value of the innovations tended to increase with the size of the innovating firms.
Consequently, ...the interpretations that small firms are more innovative (or more efficient
innovators) than large firms because they have introduced a larger number of innovations
relative to their employment is unsound.25
Others maintain that there is no conclusive evidence that firm size affects the “success” of
R&D.26
An important factor affecting the ability of small companies to effect technological advance
appears to be the relationship between these firms and large corporations, a concept that is
reflected in the provisions of the Bayh-Dole Act:
the corporate contribution and that of the innovative entrepreneur are characteristically very
different from one another and characteristically play complementary roles. Moreover, the
contribution of the two together is superadditive, that is, the combined result is greater than
the sum of their individual contributions.27
As small firms look to larger companies for additional resources, large firms look for partners as
the new technologies developed by smaller companies look more viable.28 Small businesses tend
to be willing to take those technological risks that are not pursued by large firms and may be in a
position to quickly exploit market opportunities. However, they may need to depend on large
companies to meet large-scale manufacturing and/or market needs. In specific cases, experts note,
“an innovative disadvantage of large firms is an innovative advantage for small firms, and vice
versa, which can make collaboration between two firms of different size desirable for both
parties.”29
Bayh-Dole Act and Related Law
Provisions
In enacting P.L. 96-517, the Congress accepted the proposition that providing title to the
contractor will encourage commercialization and that this should be used to support innovation in
certain identified sectors. The law states:
It is the policy and objective of the Congress to use the patent system to promote the
utilization of inventions arising from federally-supported research or development; ...to
promote collaboration between commercial concerns and nonprofit organizations, including
universities; ...to promote the commercialization and public availability of inventions made
in the United States by United States industry and labor; [and] to ensure that the Government

25 B.S. Tether, “Small and Large Firms: Sources of Unequal Innovation?,” Research Policy, November 1998, 742.
26 Charles Brown, James Hamilton, and James Medoff, Employers Large and Small, (Cambridge, Harvard University
Press, 1990), 10.
27 William J. Baumol, Education for Innovation: Entrepreneurial Breakthroughs vs. Corporate Incremental
Improvements
, NBER, June 2004, 2-3, available at http://www.nber.org/papers/10578.
28 David R. King, Jeffrey G. Covin, W. Harvey Hegarty, “Complementary Resources and the Exploitation of
Technological Innovations,” Journal of Management, August 1, 2003, 595.
29Ibid., 592.
Congressional Research Service
6

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

obtains sufficient rights in federally-supported inventions to meet the needs of the
Government and protect the public against nonuse or unreasonable use of inventions.... 30
Each nonprofit organization (including universities) or small business is permitted to elect (within
a reasonable time) to retain title to any “subject invention” made under federally funded R&D.31
[According to a recent Supreme Court decision in Stanford University v. Roche Molecular
Systems Inc., “The Bayh-Dole Act does not automatically vest title to federally funded inventions
in federal contractors or authorize contractors to unilaterally take title to such inventions.” The
Act only clarifies “the order of priority of rights between the Federal Government and a federal
contractor in a federally funded invention that already belongs to the contractor” and that certain
conditions must be met before the invention belongs to the contractor.32] The institution must
commit to commercialization within a predetermined, agreed upon, time frame. However, the
government may keep title under “exceptional circumstances when it is determined by the agency
that restriction or elimination of the right to retain title to any subject invention will better
promote the policy and objectives of this chapter.” Additionally, the government may withhold
title if the contractor “is not located in the United States or does not have a place of business
located in the United States or is subject to the control of a foreign government,” in situations
associated with national security, or when the work is related to the naval nuclear propulsion or
weapons programs of the Department of Energy.33
Certain other rights are reserved for the government to protect the public’s interests. The
government retains “a nonexclusive, nontransferable, irrevocable, paid-up license to practice or
have practiced for or on behalf of the United States any subject invention throughout the
world....” The government also retains “march-in rights” which enable the federal agency to
require the contractor (whether the organization owns the title or has an exclusive license) to
“grant a nonexclusive, partially exclusive, or exclusive license in any field of use to a responsible
applicant or applicants ...” (with due compensation) or to grant a license itself under certain
circumstances. The special situation necessary to trigger march-in rights involves a determination
that the contractor has not made efforts to commercialize within an agreed upon time frame or
that the “action is necessary to alleviate health or safety needs which are not reasonably satisfied
by the contractor....”34
The government is “authorized” to withhold public disclosure of information for a “reasonable
time” until a patent application can be made. Licensing by any contractor retaining title under this
act is restricted to companies which will manufacture substantially within the United States.
Initially, universities were limited in the time they could grant exclusive licenses for patents
derived from government sponsored R&D to large companies (five of the then 17 years of the
patent). This restriction, however, was voided by P.L. 98-620, the Trademark Clarification Act of
1984. According to S.Rept. 98-662, extending the time frame for licensing to large firms “is
particularly important with technologies such as pharmaceuticals, where long development times
and major investments are usually required prior to commercialization.”35

30 35 U.S.C. § 200.
31 35 U.S.C. § 202.
32 Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University v. Roche Molecular Systems, Inc., et al., __U.S.__(June
6, 2011).
33 35 U.S.C. § 202.
34 35 U.S.C. § 203.
35 Senate Committee on the Judiciary, Report to Accompany S. 2171, 98th Cong., 2d Sess. S.Rept. 98-662, 1984, 3.
Congressional Research Service
7

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

Most experts continue to argue that patent exclusivity is important for both large and small firms.
In a February 1983 memorandum concerning the vesting of title to inventions made under federal
funding, then President Ronald Reagan ordered all agencies to treat, as allowable by law, all
contractors regardless of size the same as prescribed in P.L. 96-517. This, however, does not have
a legislative basis. P.L. 98-620, noted above, further amended Bayh-Dole by loosening the time
limitations for both disclosure of an invention to the government agency and for the amount of
time provided within which to elect to take title. Nonprofit institutions were subsequently
permitted to assign title rights to another organization (e.g., one which markets technology) and
government-owned, contractor-operated laboratories (primarily those of the Department of
Energy) run by nonprofits were permitted to retain title to inventions made in the facility with the
exception of those dedicated to naval nuclear propulsion or weapons development. In addition,
the Federal Technology Transfer Act (P.L. 99-502) allows firms regardless of size to be awarded
patents generated under a cooperative research and development agreement (CRADA) with a
federal laboratory.36
Implementation and Results
The Bayh-Dole Act appears to have met its expressed goals of using “the patent system to
promote the utilization of inventions arising from federally-supported research or development; ...
and to promote collaboration between commercial concerns and nonprofit organizations,
including universities....”37 In one of the earliest studies of the legislation, the General Accounting
Office (now the Government Accountability Office, GAO) found agreement among university
administrators and small business representatives that P.L. 96-517 had “a significant impact on
their research and innovation efforts.”38 While noting it was not correct to generalize about
academia from the 25 universities studied, GAO did find that by 1987 all university
administrators questioned indicated that the Bayh-Dole Act had “been significant in stimulating
business sponsorship of university research, which has grown 74 percent” from FY1980 to
FY1985.39 According to the National Science Foundation (NSF), industry support for academic
research grew faster than any other funding source until FY2002. Industry financing expanded
from 3.9% of university R&D in 1980 to 7.2% in 2000, although by FY2009 industry support had
dropped to 5.8% of academic R&D. In 1980, federal financing comprised 67.5% of the total
academic undertaking; by 2000 federal support declined to 58.2% of university funding, yet
increased to 59.3% in FY2009.40 It should be noted, however, that the federal government still
remains the major source of academic research funding.

36 For additional discussion see Industrial Competitiveness and Technological Advancement: Debate Over Government
Policy
.
37 35 U.S.C. § 200.
38 U.S. General Accounting Office, Patent Policy: Recent Changes in Federal Law Considered Beneficial, RCED-87-
44, April 1987, 3.
39 Ibid., 3.
40 National Science Foundation, “Changes in Federal and Non-Federal Support for Academic R&D Over the Past Three
Decades,” InfoBrief, June 2002, available at http://www.nsf.gov, National Science Foundation, National Patterns of
R&D Resources: 2003, Special Report
, available at http://www.nsf.gov/statistics/nsf05308/pdfstart.htm, and National
Science Foundation, “Universities Report $55 Billion in Science and Engineering R&D Spending for FY2009;
Redesigned Survey to Launch in 2010. InfoBrief, NSF 10-329, 1, available at http://www.nsf.gov/statistics/infbrief/
nsf10329/nsf10329.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
8

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

The majority of the university personnel involved in the GAO study indicated that the increase in
industry support for research at universities was “directly” attributed to the patent changes in P.L.
96-517 and P.L. 98-620. Academic faculty interviews conducted by GAO found that “since
businesses knew that universities could take title to federally funded inventions, they no longer
were concerned that their research efforts could be ‘contaminated’ by federal funding with the
possibility that a federal agency could assert title rights to resulting inventions.”41 All respondents
agreed that the removal of licensing restrictions on nonprofit institutions (including universities)
by P.L. 98-620 was of vital importance in promoting industry-university interaction.42 This was
reinforced by the finding that 9 out of 10 business executives questioned identified the Bayh-Dole
Act as an “important factor” in their decisions to fund R&D in academia.43
Another GAO study published in May of 1998 reported that agency and university
representatives believed the Bayh-Dole Act was meeting its goals as articulated by the Congress
and the law had a positive impact on all involved. Academia was “receiving greater benefits from
their inventions and were transferring technology better than the government did when it retained
title to inventions.”44 In addition, the report states that the increased commercialization of
federally funded research resulting from the implementation of the act positively affected both the
federal government and the American people.45
Other experts agree. Yale President Richard Levin argued that the purpose of the Bayh-Dole Act
is to transition the results of government funded research “into practice for the benefit of
humanity” and that results indicate a “pretty emphatic positive answer that the Bayh-Dole Act has
created public benefits” with minimal costs.46 As stated in an article in The Economist, the Bayh-
Dole Act is “probably the most inspired piece of legislation to be enacted in America over the
past half-century....”47
One of the major factors in the reported success of the Bayh-Dole Act is the certainty it conveys
concerning ownership of intellectual property. The Director of Stanford University’s Office of
Technology Licensing, Katherine Ku, noted that exclusivity is what motivates firms to invest
financial and human resources in technology development.48 It provides an incentive for
universities to take the time and effort to pursue a patent and to license those patents in its
portfolio. This has led to a significant increase in academic patenting. In 1980, 390 patents were
awarded to universities;49 by 2009, the number increased to 3,088.50

41 Patent Policy: Recent Changes in Federal Law Considered Beneficial, 20-21.
42 Ibid., 16.
43 Ibid., 23.
44 U.S. General Accounting Office, Technology Transfer: Administration of the Bayh-Dole Act by Research
Universities
, RCED-98-126, May 1998, 2.
45 Ibid., 15.
46 National Academy of Sciences, Board on Science, Technology, and Economic Policy, Workshop on Academic IP:
Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on Commercialization and Research
, April 17, 2001 [transcript], 261-
262, available at http://www.nas.edu.
47 Innovation’s Golden Goose.
48 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on Commercialization and Research, 9.
49 Science and Engineering Indicators—1993, 430.
50 National Science Board, Science and Engineering Indicators, 2012 (Washington, National Science Foundation,
2010), Appendix table 5-48, available at http://www.nsf.gov/statistics/seind12/append/c5/at05-48.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
9

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

Academia has become a major source of innovation for local and regional economic
development. In the latest survey (FY2010) performed by the Association of University
Technology Managers (AUTM), universities identified a total of 657 new products that were
marketed as a result of academic R&D. In addition, the survey indicated the creation of more than
651 new companies to commercialize university research with 5,362 new licenses/options granted
primarily to small businesses. Since 1980, more than 8,107 new firms have been established to
develop and market academic R&D, with “3,657 startups still operating as of the end of
FY2010.”51
Many of the start-up businesses created from university R&D were associated with just seven
schools including the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT), the University of California,
California Tech, the University of Minnesota, the Johns Hopkins University, the University of
Utah, and the University of Virginia.52 While only a few universities earn large returns from
licensing,53 studies indicated that licensing by the University of California system generates $91
million in net licensing income annually with Columbia University receiving approximately $80
million and Florida State University $45 million.54 A recent report found that “without accounting
for product substitution effects, …over the period 1996 to 2007, university licensing agreements
based on product sales contributed at least $47 billion and as much as $187 billion to the U.S.
GDP.”55
However, several analysts argue that “Bayh-Dole was only one of a number of important factors
behind the rise of university patenting and licensing activity.”56 In a study of the technology
transfer and patenting activities of the University of California, Stanford University, and
Columbia University, Professor David Mowery and his colleagues concluded that increased
federal funding for basic biomedical research, expanded research in biotechnology, specific court
rulings, and government policies augmenting what can be patented all contributed to the rise in
academic intellectual property activities. According to their assessment, the Bayh-Dole Act had
“little impact on the content of academic research.” The pursuit of patenting and licensing at
universities has expanded because of changes in biomedical and biotechnology R&D, not because
of the act.57 Later work by Professor Mowery follows this approach, arguing that “the emphasis
on the Bayh-Dole Act as a catalyst to these interactions [increased university-industry cooperation

51 Association of University Technology Managers, AUTM U.S. Licensing Activity Survey Highlights: FY2010,
available at http://www.autm.net/AM/Template.cfm?Section=FY_2010_Licensing_Survey&Template=
/CM/ContentDisplay.cfm&ContentID=6874.
52 Goldie Blumenstyk, “Income From University Licenses on Patents Exceeded $1-Billion,” The Chronicle of Higher
Education
, March 22, 2002.
53 Harun Bulut and GianCarlo Moschini, U.S. Universities’ Net Returns from Patenting and Licensing: A Quantile
Regression Analysis
, Iowa State University Working Paper-06-WP 432, September 2006, 2, available at
http://www.card.iastate.edu.
54 Gregory K. Sobolski, John H. Barton, Ezekiel J. Emanuel, “Technology Licensing, Lessons From the US
Experience,” Journal of the American Medical Association, December 28, 2005, 3138.
55 David Roessner, Jennifer Bond, Sumiye Okubo, and Mark Planting, The Economic Impact of Licensed
Commercialized Inventions Originating in University Research, 1996-2007
, Final Report to the Biotechnology Industry
Organization, September 3, 2009, 32, available at http://www.bio.org/ip/techtransfer/
BIO_final_report_9_3_09_rev_2.pdf.
56 David C. Mowery, Richard R. Nelson, Bhaven N. Sampat, and Arvids A. Ziedonis, “The Growth of Patenting and
Licensing by U.S. Universities: An Assessment of the Effects of the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980,” Research Policy 30,
2001, 99.
57 Ibid., 100.
Congressional Research Service
10

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

and technology transfer] also seems somewhat misplaced, ignoring as it does the long history,
extending to at least the earliest decades of the 20th century, of collaboration and knowledge flows
between universities and industry in the United States.”58
Some experts criticize this assessment and point out that the act had the most significant impact
on universities that were not actively engaged in patenting prior to its passage.59 Proponents of
this position argue that as a result of the Bayh-Dole Act, in part, “university patenting increased
particularly rapidly during the second half of the 1980s and early 1990s.”60 This growth in
patenting has been concentrated in “middle-tier” schools, not just the top research universities.61
Researchers who take this position suggest that the Mowery et al. study focused solely on
universities that were previously involved in patenting and licensing and may not have fully
considered patent problems that existed before the legislation was implemented. According to
critics of the study, the analysts also failed to take into account changes in the venture capital
industry that promoted the development of start-up companies to commercialize the results of
university R&D.62
Other research questions the effect of increased university licensing on U.S. innovation. A study
by Bhavan Sampat suggests that while the Bayh-Dole Act augmented patent and licensing by
universities, these activities are just “one of many channels through which universities make
economic contributions and in most industries less important contributions than those made by
placing scientific and technological information in the public domain.”63 This author’s work
indicates that “there is little evidence that increased university patenting and licensing has
facilitated increased technology transfer or any meaningful growth in the economic contributions
of universities.”64
However, commentators argue that the provisions of the Bayh-Dole Act provide incentives to take
university inventions and develop them into products for the marketplace.65 University
technology generally is in the early stage and not yet ready for commercialization, requiring
additional funding and the involvement of faculty to move the idea into a marketable product.66

58 David C. Mowery, The Bayh-Dole Act and High-Technology Entrepreneurship in U.S. Universities: Chicken, Egg,
or Something Else?
, paper prepared for the Eller Center conference on “Entrepreneurship Education and Technology
Transfer,” University of Arizona, January 21-22, 2005, available at http://entrepreneurship.eller.arizona.edu/docs/
conferences/2005/colloquium/D_Mowery.pdf.
59 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on Commercialization and Research, 17.
60 Science and Engineering Indicators—1993, 152.
61 Ibid., 152 and Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on Commercialization and
Research
, 57-58.
62 Ashley J. Stevens, “Is Bayh-Dole Under Siege Again?” Technology Access Report, July 2001. See also Lori Turk-
Bicakci and Steven Brint, “University-Industry Collaboration: Patterns of Growth for Low- and Middle-Level
Performers,” Higher Education, January 2005, 61-89.
63 Bhavan N. Sampat, “Patenting and US Academic Research in the 20th Century: The World Before and After Bayh-
Dole,” Research Policy, July 2006, 773.
64 Ibid.
65 Marie Thursby, Jerry Thursby, and Emmanuel Dechenaux, Shirking, Shelving, and Sharing Risk: The Role of
University License Contracts
, April 9, 2004, National Bureau of Economic Research, available at http://www.nber.org/
~confer/2004/entf04/thursby.pdf.
66 Jerry G. Thursby and Marie C. Thursby, University Licensing Under Bayh-Dole: What are the Issues and Evidence?,
May 2003, available at http://opensource.mit.edu/papers/Thursby.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
11

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

While most universities do not receive large amounts of funds as a result of licensing their
technologies, it
is clear from the evidence ... that faculty involvement in the further development of
university technologies is an important element in getting those technologies to market.
Mechanisms to ensure such efforts are an important element of commercialization regardless
of whether those mechanisms included licensing by universities.67
In addition, Professor Scott Shane observes:
Because universities exploit their inventions primarily through the licensing of technology,
and licensing is not equally effective across all technologies ... the incentive to become more
commercially focused led universities to concentrate their patenting in fields in which
knowledge is transferred effectively through licensing.68
While the effects of the Bayh-Dole Act on the small business sector have not been as extensively
studied, the results appear similar. All eight small business owners interviewed by GAO for its
1987 study indicated that the patent changes had a significant beneficial effect on research,
development, and innovation in their firms.69 Perhaps most illustrative of the influence of the
Bayh-Dole Act on small business is the biotechnology industry. According to Dr. Bernadine
Healy, the former Director of the National Institutes of Health (NIH), P.L. 96-517 was responsible
for the development and growth of the biotechnology sector.70 The biotechnology industry
primarily is composed of small firms that are developing technologies and techniques derived
from R&D funded by NIH. Many of these companies have been established by NIH alumni or
university professors previously supported by NIH grants. In Senate testimony delivered on
August 1, 2001, Dr. Marie Freire, then Director of the Office of Technology Transfer at NIH,
stated that “[i]t is widely recognized that the Bayh-Dole Act and the Federal Technology Transfer
Act continue to contribute to the global leadership of the U.S. biomedical enterprise....” An
industry that was in its infancy when the Bayh-Dole Act was passed, by the end of 2009 1,699
biotechnology firms generated annual sales of $48.2 billion.71 The number of U.S. biotechnology
patents granted has increased from 619 in 1985 to 4,853 in 2010.72
The value of the Bayh-Dole Act might be reflected in state efforts to promote industry-university
cooperation based on the contributions of these activities to local economic growth. As Mark
Myers, retired Senior Vice-President of Xerox, told a meeting of the National Academy of
Sciences, “[t]he role of the research university is growing ever important as an economic force in
our economy....”73 In a report by Battelle for the Biotechnology Industry Organization (BIO),

67 Ibid.
68 Scott Shane, “Encouraging University Entrepreneurship? The Effect of the Bayh-Dole Act on University Patenting in
the United States,” Journal of Business Venturing, 2004, 128.
69 Patent Policy: Recent Changes in Federal Law Considered Beneficial, 4.
70 House Committee on the Judiciary, Biotechnology Development and Patent Law, 102d Cong., 1st Sess., November
20, 1991, 48.
71 Ernst & Young, Beyond Borders, Global Biotechnology Report 2010, 59, available at http://www.ey.com/
Publication/vwLUAssets/Beyond_borders_2010/$FILE/Beyond_borders_2010.pdf.
72 Science and Engineering Indicators, 2010, Appendix table 6-58, available at http://www.nsf.gov/statistics/seind10/
appendix.htm and Science and Engineering Indicators, 2012, Appendix table 6-60, available at http://www.nsf.gov/
statistics/seind12/append/c6/at06-60.pdf.
73 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on Commercialization and Research, 255.
Congressional Research Service
12

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

analysts found that there are biotechnology-related initiatives in 44 states, including many that
involve cooperative efforts between academia and the private sector. In 2008, 28 states and Puerto
Rico had specific programs to facilitate industry-university collaboration in the biotechnology
arena. Pre-seed and seed fund programs have been established in 25 states and Puerto Rico while
19 states have venture capital initiatives to invest in biotechnology R&D.74 State laws also have
been changed to allow universities to become equity partners in start up firms designed to
commercialize academic R&D.75 Later analysis indicates that by 2010, 42 states support
initiatives to assist in the commercialization of new technologies in the bioscience arena.76
Current Issues and Concerns
While the Bayh-Dole Act provides a general framework to promote expanded utilization of the
results of federally funded research and development, questions have been raised as to the
adequacy of current arrangements. Most experts agree that closer cooperation among
government, industry, and academia can augment funding sources (both in the private and public
sectors), increase technology transfer, stimulate more innovation (beyond invention), lead to new
products and processes, and expand markets. However, others point out that cooperation may
provide an increased opportunity for conflict of interest, redirection of research, less openness in
sharing of scientific discovery, and a greater emphasis on applied rather than basic research.
The successes of the Bayh-Dole Act and the visibility of the results of its implementation have
generated certain concerns, many of which are associated with the role of the university in
research, as well as biomedical and biotechnology R&D, particularly as related to the availability
and cost of pharmaceuticals. Several of these issues are discussed below. However, it is important
to place the Bayh-Dole Act in context. The law is one significant factor in expanded industry,
university, small business collaboration, but not the only one. Therefore, it may be difficult to
assess what concerns are the direct result of the Bayh-Dole Act and which arise from the overall
research environment. The rising costs associated with the performance of research and
development, the availability of venture capital, increased R&D outsourcing by large firms, and
expanded federal funding for biomedical research all contribute to increased interaction among
the parties. Additional legislative initiatives including the research and experimentation tax credit,
the National Cooperative Research Act, the small business technology transfer program, the
advanced technology program, and cooperative R&D agreements established by the Stevenson-
Wydler Technology Innovation Act all facilitate joint R&D activities leading to the
commercialization of new technologies for the marketplace.77

74 Battelle Technology Partnership Practice, Technology, Talent and Capital: State Bioscience Initiatives 2008,
Biotechnology Industries Organization, June 2008, available at http://bio.org/local/battelle2008/
State_Bioscience_Initiatives_2008.pdf.
75 Battelle Technology Partnership Practice and SSTI, Laboratories of Innovation: State Bioscience Initiatives 2004,
June 2004, 27-29, available at http://www.washingtonlifescience.com/econ_dev_reports/
OregonBioscienceInitiatives2004.pdf.
76 Peter M. Pellerito and George Goodno, “Successful State Initiatives That Encourage Bioscience Industry Growth,”
Biotechnology Industry Organization, February 9, 2012, available at http://www.bio.org/node/5771.
77 For additional information, see CRS Report RL33526, Cooperative R&D: Federal Efforts to Promote Industrial
Competitiveness
, by Wendy H. Schacht, and CRS Report RL33528, Industrial Competitiveness and Technological
Advancement: Debate Over Government Policy
, by Wendy H. Schacht.
Congressional Research Service
13

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

Recoupment
Over the years, several legislators have suggested that the government “recoup” its investments
from firms using federally supported research and development after profits are generated. This is
particularly true in the area of pharmaceuticals.78 Such arguments are similar to those that were
identified and considered as part of the original legislative debate over patent policy and
cooperative R&D. The concept of recoupment is based upon the argument that the government
should be reimbursed for research and development expenses provided to a contractor if the
resulting product is brought to the market and generates profits. Proponents of this approach also
maintained that providing the contractor with a limited time monopoly on the results of federally
funded R&D through assignment of patent rights should be balanced by compensation for the
government’s initial investment. In the debate over related legislation, then-Senator Robert Dole
stated on the floor of the Senate on April 23, 1980, the provision for recoupment was intended to
insure that “the Government’s investment, paid for by the taxpayers of this country, is returned to
the Federal coffer.”79 During the same debate, Senator Birch Bayh argued that a payback
provision means that, “in the final analysis, the taxpayer will not be out the cost of the research
and they also will have the benefit of the product.”80
Such suggestions are based on several factors. In addition to funding research performed by
individual companies, under certain circumstances, the government furnishes the private sector
ownership of the intellectual property resulting from this public investment. Patent protection
gives firms monopoly rights on these innovations for a specified amount of time. By providing
patent protection to the results of federally-funded research, a company receives an individual
benefit based upon public investments. Thus, proponents of recoupment assert that the monopoly
power of patents should be modified by this “public subsidization” They contend that the public
has a right to a return on its investment. However, it is argued that “this right is not preserved
under the patent system, which ascribes solely to the patent holder all proprietary rights and
interests in the patented product or process.”81
To date, Congress has weighed these issues and decided that, in the case of patent and technology
policies, the benefits to the Nation brought about by increased innovation are paramount. The
passage of the Bayh-Dole Act represented a determination that, with respect to certain types of
organizations, the economic incentive to realize a return on investment provided by a patent is
necessary to stimulate companies to provide the often substantial financial commitment to turn
federally-funded R&D into marketable technologies and techniques. This is suggestive of the idea
that the promise of a large return on investment “is precisely the tool sanctioned by the
Constitution to promote the progress of science.”82 The decision was based on several
determinations deriving from the rationale for federal support of basic research, the importance of
technological progress to the Nation, and the critical role of private sector commercialization in
technological advancement.

78 For a more detailed discussion of this issue in the pharmaceutical arena, see CRS Report RL32324, Federal R&D,
Drug Discovery, and Pricing: Insights from the NIH-University-Industry Relationship
, by Wendy H. Schacht.
79 U.S. Congress, Congressional Record, April 23, 1980, S739.
80 Ibid., S743.
81 Steven R. Salbu, “Aids and Drug Pricing: In Search of a Policy,” Washington University Law Quarterly, Fall 1993,
5-20.
82 Evan Ackiron, “Patents for Critical Pharmaceuticals: The AZT Case,” American Journal of Law and Medicine, 1991,
18.
Congressional Research Service
14

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

Federal support for basic research is founded, in large part, on the understanding that the rate of
return to society as a whole generated by investments in research is significantly larger than the
benefits that can be captured by any one firm performing it.83 It has been estimated that the
returns to society generated by investments in basic research are approximately twice those to the
company performing the work. Government support reflects a consensus that basic research is the
foundation for many innovations, but that incentives for private sector financial commitments are
dampened by the fact that spending for R&D runs a high risk of failure. Even results of fruitful
R&D often are exploited by other domestic and foreign companies, thus resulting in
underinvestment in research by the private sector. The returns from basic research are generally
long term, sometimes not marketable, and not always evident.
It is now widely accepted that “from one-third to one-half of all [U.S.] growth has come from
technical progress, and that it is the principal driving force for long-term economic growth and
the increased standards of living of modern industrial societies.”84 Technological advancement
can clearly contribute to the resolution of those national problems which are amenable to
technological solutions. Such progress is achieved through innovation, the process by which
industry provides new and improved products, processes, and services. An invention becomes an
innovation when it has been integrated into the economy such that the knowledge created results
in a new or improved good or service that can be sold in the marketplace or is applied to
production to increase productivity and quality. It is only through commercialization, a function
of the business sector, that a significant stimulus to economic growth occurs. Thus, there is
congressional interest in accelerating development and commercialization activities in the private
sector through the Bayh-Dole Act as well as other legislation.
Actual experience and cited studies suggest that companies which do not control the results of
their investments—either through ownership of patent title, exclusive license, or pricing
decisions—tend to be less likely to engage in related R&D. This likelihood is reflected in the
provisions of the Bayh-Dole Act (as well as other laws). Providing universities, nonprofit
institutions, and small businesses with title to patents arising from federally-funded R&D offers
an incentive for cooperative work and commercial application. Royalties derived from intellectual
property rights provide the academic community an alternative way to support further research
and the business sector a means to obtain a return on their financial contribution to the endeavor.
While the idea of recoupment was considered by the Congress in hearings on the legislation, it
was rejected as an unnecessary obstacle, one which would be perceived as an additional burden to
working with the government. It was thought to be particularly difficult to administer.85 Instead,
Congress accepted as satisfactory the anticipated payback to the country through increased
revenues from taxes on profits, new jobs created, improved productivity, and economic growth.
For example, as discussed above, from 1980, when the Bayh-Dole Act was passed, through 2010,

83 Edwin Mansfield, “Social Returns From R&D: Findings, Methods, and Limitations,” Research/Technology
Management
, November-December 1991, 24.
84 Gregory Tassey, The Economics of R&D Policy (Connecticut, Quorum Books, 1997), 54. See also: Edwin Mansfield,
“Intellectual Property Rights, Technological Change, and Economic Growth,” in: Intellectual Property Rights and
Capital Formation in the Next Decade
, eds. Charls E. Walker and Mark A. Bloomfield (New York, University Press of
America, 1988), 5.
85 For example see U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Science and Technology, Government Patent Policy,
Hearings, September 23, 27, 28, 29, and October 1, 1976, 94th Cong. 2nd sess., 1976; United States Senate, Select
Committee on Small Business, Government Patent Policies, Hearings, December 19, 20, and 21, 1977, 95th Cong. 1st
sess., 1978; and U.S. Senate, Committee on Commerce, Science, and Transportation, Patent Policy, Hearings, July 23
and 27, and October 25, 1979, 96th Cong. 1st sess., 1979.
Congressional Research Service
15

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

8,107 new spin-off companies were created, and, in 2010 alone, 657 new products were
introduced into the market by these firms. The emergence of the biotechnology industry and the
development of new therapeutics to improve health care are other prominent indications of such
benefits. To date, these benefits have been considered more important than the initial cost of the
technology to the government or any potential unfair advantage.
Government Rights: Royalty Free Licenses and
Reporting Requirements

As discussed above, the government retains certain rights under the Bayh-Dole Act to protect the
public interest. The act states that the government is provided a “nonexclusive, nontransferable,
irrevocable, paid-up license to practice or have practiced for or on behalf of the United States any
subject invention throughout the world....” This license, commonly known as a “royalty free
license,” has been the subject of some discussion including whether or not this permits
government purchasers to obtain discounts on products developed from federally funded R&D,
particularly pharmaceuticals. A July 2003 GAO report addressed this issue and concluded that the
license entitles the government to practice or have practiced the invention on the government’s
behalf, but “does not give the federal government the far broader right to purchase, ‘off the shelf’
and royalty free (i.e. at a discounted price), products that happen to incorporate a federally funded
invention when they are not produced under the government’s license.”86 The study goes on to
say that rights in one patent do not “automatically” permit rights in subsequent, related patents.87
Because the government apparently holds few licenses on the biomedical products it purchases
(generally through the Veteran’s Administration and the Department of Defense),88 federal
officials indicated that procurement costs were best reduced by use of the Federal Supply
Schedule and national contracts.89 Government licenses are used primarily in the performance of
research in the biomedical area.90
A related issue is that of tracking the government’s interest in patents resulting from federally
funded research and development. In an August 1999 study, GAO noted that federal contractors
and grantees were not meeting the reporting requirements associated with the Bayh-Dole Act,
making it difficult to identify and assess what licenses the government retained, among other
things.91 Two years later, in a follow-up report, GAO stated that four of the five agencies had
taken steps to insure improved compliance with the law including several new monitoring
systems, although more needed to be done.92 Of particular interest is iEdison, created by the NIH,
which electronically tracks federal inventions and is used by other agencies in addition to NIH.93

86 General Accounting Office, Technology Transfer: Agencies’ Rights to Federally Sponsored Biomedical Inventions,
GAO-03-536, July 2003, 7.
87 Ibid., 8.
88 Ibid.
89 Ibid., 12.
90 Ibid., 10.
91 General Accounting Office, Technology Transfer: Reporting Requirements for Federally Sponsored Inventions Need
Revision
, August 1999, GAO/RCED-99-242, 2.
92 General Accounting Office, Intellectual Property: Federal Agency Efforts in Transferring and Reporting New
Technology
, October 2002, GAO-03-47, 29.
93 Ibid., 33.
Congressional Research Service
16

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

University Research
A question often posed is whether or not patent ownership rights provided by P.L. 96-517 have
interfered with the traditional operating procedures of academia. A fear is that private sector
funding of university R&D has led to conflicts of interest by scientists performing the research,
particularly when academics have equity positions in the relevant companies. There are concerns
that industry agendas will distort or supplant the basic research and educational responsibilities of
academia. Complaints have also been expressed that the free exchange of ideas and scientific
discovery are constrained as a result of both the university and the business community’s interest
in protecting their competitive positions.
The issue of conflict of interest is a complex one particularly when trying to determine what
direct role the Bayh-Dole Act has in generating such concerns and what are the results of other
factors that have lead to increased industrial funding of university research. As noted above, laws
that provide tax incentives for private sector financing of university basic research and facilitate
technology transfer and cooperative R&D among government, industry, and academia, as well as
changes in the way companies obtain the basic research necessary for product development shape
the environment within which academic research is pursued. Thus, as argued by Katherine Ku, it
is necessary to evaluate criticisms of the Bayh-Dole Act and to understand that the success of the
law has made many in government uncomfortable despite the clear guidelines for technology
transfer it established.94
Senior Research Scholar Mildred Cho and her coauthors assert that the Bayh-Dole Act
has created opportunities for conflict of interest for university faculty members because
academic-industry partnerships can offer direct financial rewards to individual faculty
members in the form of consulting fees, royalties, and equity in companies while
simultaneously funding these faculty members’ research.95
This, it is argued, has resulted in situations where the researcher’s ties to private sector interests
may not be evident and may adversely affect “the quality, outcome, and dissemination of
research.”96 Other studies indicate that obligations to industry “pose a threat to scientific
integrity.”97 Some commentators maintain that private sector funded research tends to generate
conclusions favorable to industry; however, the factor that is primarily associated with the
withholding or delay of information is the involvement of the scientist in bringing his research to
market in a product, not the industrial financing itself.98
Data collected by Professor David Blumenthal and his colleagues also support the assessment that
involvement in commercialization activities is related to delays in publication.99 This study

94 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on Commercialization and Research, 98,
100-101.
95 Mildred K. Cho, Ryo Shohara, Anna Schissel, and Drummond Rennie, “Policies on Faculty Conflicts of Interest at
U.S. Universities,” Journal of the American Medical Association, November 1, 2000.
96 Ibid.
97 Justin E. Bekelman, Yan Li, and Cary P. Gross, “Scope and Impact of Financial Conflicts of Interest in Biomedical
Research: A Systematic Review,” Journal of the American Medical Association, January 22/January 29, 2003.
98 Ibid.
99 David Blumenthal, Eric G. Campbell, Melissa S. Anderson, Nancyanne Causino, and Karen Seashore Louis,
“Withholding Research Results in Academic Life,” Journal of the American Medical Association, April 16, 1997,
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
17

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

indicated that approximately 20% of life science researchers delayed publication of their studies
more than six months at least once for reasons associated with patents and commercialization
considerations. Almost 9% of faculty refused to share research or materials with other university
scientists in the past three years. However, the authors conclude that “withholding of research
results is not a widespread phenomenon among life-science researchers.”100 A survey of industry-
university research centers by Professor Wesley Cohen and his colleagues found that over half of
the centers permitted firms to request publication delays and 35% of the institutions allowed
researchers to delete information prior to publication. At those centers with a mission to improve
industrial products and processes, 63% allowed publication delays and 54% permitted the
deletion of information.101
Delays in publication and the free flow of information from academia, according to Professor
Richard Florida, “may well discourage or even impede the advancement of knowledge, which
retards the efficient pursuit of scientific progress, in turn slowing innovation in industry.”102
Professor Florida also points to concerns over the increasing number of academic institutions
taking equity positions in and/or incubating spin-off companies. These actions “simply tend to
distract the university from its core missions of conducting research and generating talent.”
Florida concludes that publication delays and greater secrecy in the research process resulting
from implementation of the Bayh-Dole Act have shifted the university away from the pursuit of
its traditional goals.
Other experts, including Robert Barchi, Provost of the University of Pennsylvania, maintain that
the Bayh-Dole Act has not generated a significant set of issues concerning conflicts of interest
and publication delays primarily because of the importance of academic freedom to the faculty.103
Publications are the basis for promotion and tenure and methods to respect reasonable intellectual
property protection have been established. Similarly, as noted by Professor Pam Samuelson,
conflicts of interest would jeopardize tenure thus regulations are in place to instruct faculty what
is required of them.104 Research conducted by Professors Pierre Azoulay, Waverly Ding, and Toby
Stuart indicates that
patenting is often accompanied by a flurry of publication activity ... academic scientists who
patent are more productive than otherwise equivalent scientists that are not listed as
inventors on patents, but that publication quality appears relatively similar in the two
groups.105

(...continued)
1224.
100 Ibid.
101 Wesley M. Cohen, Richard Florida, Lucien Randazzese, and John Walsh, “Industry and the Academy: Uneasy
Partners in the Cause of Technological Advance,” in: Challenges to Research Universities, eds. Linda R. Cohen,
Wesley Cohen, Roger Noll, William Rogerson, and Albert Teich (Washington, The Brookings Press, 1998), 188-189.
102 Richard Florida, “The Role of the University: Leveraging Talent, Not Technology,” Issues in Science and
Technology
, Summer 1999.
103 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on Commercialization and Research,19-
20.
104 Ibid., 193.
105 Pierre Axoulay, Waverly Ding, and Toby Stuart, The Impact of Academic Patenting on the Rate, Quality, and
Direction of (Public) Research
, National Bureau of Economic Research, January 2006, available at
http://www.nber.org/papers/w11917.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
18

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

In response to these issues, many universities have hired professional technology managers to
work with faculty and to address patents. Universities with extensive research capabilities and
resources were the first to create offices of technology transfer; after passage of the Bayh-Dole
Act these offices were established with much greater frequency.106 These university technology
transfer offices have established guidelines to cover industry-university relationships, with
education and publication remaining academic priorities.107 The financial rewards derived from
patenting often are only a small portion of the total amount of R&D funding for academic
institutions and what substantial money does flow into individual institutions tends to be the
result of one “blockbuster” patent. University technology managers report that the major reason
for patent licensing is commercialization, not profit, particularly since the cost of a patent, which
can run approximately $10,000, is so high.108 While the Bayh-Dole Act focused universities on
“commercially relevant technologies and closer ties between research and technological
development,”109 the costs of patenting are such that “most university licensing offices barely
break even.”110
University limitations on outside research, expeditious publication obligations mandated for
certain federally-funded R&D, and conflict of interest provisions also help to preserve a balance
between federal policies like the Bayh-Dole Act that promote industry-university cooperation and
concerns over excessive control of the research environment by the business community. For
example, NIH requires grant recipients to publish the results of their government funded R&D.
This is augmented by tax code regulations necessitating prompt dissemination of actual research
results in order for a university or research institution to retain its tax exempt status. NIH also has
policies and guidelines promoting the availability of patents arising from federal funding for use
by other scientists for research purposes without acquisition of a license.111
Critics argue that the Bayh-Dole Act is distorting the traditional role of the university to the
detriment of future technological development. Professor Florida maintained that because
universities are seen as “engines” of growth, they focus on applied rather than fundamental
research. This has lead to unrealistic national and local policies and practices that encourage the
commercialization of academic research while ignoring the real value of universities as the
“nation’s primary source of knowledge creation and talent.”112 Mildred Cho also asserted that
university research is “skewed” toward marketable products and not basic research.113 Studies by
researchers Dianne Rahm and Robert P. Morgan et. al. indicated the greater the faculty interaction
with industry the more the applied research.114 According to an article in Fortune magazine, the

106 Everett Rogers, Jing Yin, and Joern Hoffmann, “Assessing the Effectiveness of Technology Transfer Offices at U.S.
Research Universities,” Journal of the Association of University Technology Managers, v. XII, 2000, available at
http://www.autm.net.
107 Technology Transfer: Administration of the Bayh-Dole Act by Research Universities.
108 Ann M. Thayer, “University Technology Moves to Market via Patenting, Licensing,: Chemical and Engineering
News
, August 24, 1992, 17-18. See also: Jerry G. Thursby and Marie C. Thursby, “Intellectual Property: University
Licensing and the Bayh-Dole Act,” Science, August 22, 2003, 1052.
109 Science and Engineering Indicators—2002, 5-54.
110 Lita Nelson, “Increase of Intellectual Property Licensing at Universities Stems from Changes in Funding and
Legislation,” MIT Tech Talk, August 26, 1998, available at http://web.mit.edu.
111 Policies available at http://www.nih.gov.
112 The Role of the University: Leveraging Talent, Not Technology.
113 Eric Niller, “Biotech & Health: Report Fails to Address the Downside of Academic-Industry Collaborations,” Wall
Street Journal (Europe)
, August 6, 2001, 17.
114 Industry and the Academy: Uneasy Partners in the Cause of Technological Advance, 186.
Congressional Research Service
19

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

Bayh-Dole Act has had “unintended consequences” in that “universities have evolved from public
trusts into something closer to venture capital firms. What used to be a scientific community of
free and open debate now often seems like a litigation scrum of data-hoarding and suspicion.”115
Other experts disagree. A study of 3,400 faculty at six major research institutions by Professors
Jerry Thursby and Marie Thursby found that “the basic/applied split in research did not change
over the period 1983-1999 even though licensing had increased by a factor greater than 10.”116
Data collected by the National Science Foundation appear to support this assessment. According
to NSF, in 1980, basic research comprised 66.6% of academic R&D endeavors while applied
research and development were 33.4% of the total. In 2009, the percent of academic R&D
expenditures devoted to basic research increased to 74.6% while applied research and
development declined to 25.4% of the total.117
Commentators claim that the Bayh-Dole Act encourages the type of research that is attractive to
faculty. James Severson, President of the Cornell Research Foundation, testified before the House
Committee on the Judiciary that
Today, the protection and commercialization of academic research is one way for
universities to attract, retain, and reward talented faculty who wish to see the results of their
research programs benefit society. A commitment to the protection of research results is
important for universities to develop closer ties to companies, and to attract additional funds
to support research programs.118
As noted by Terry Young, Assistant Vice Chancellor for Technology Transfer at Texas A&M
University, the act requires funds generated by licensing to be used for future education and
research necessary to “deliver ‘real world’ products to the public.”119 Assessing the legislation,
the Biotechnology Industries Association, contends that “without the Bayh-Dole Act, few
licensing agreements would be executed between private companies and federally supported
research institutions, and the enormous investment our government makes in medical research
would be wasted.”120
Biotechnology and Pharmaceuticals
Many of the current concerns about the Bayh-Dole Act primarily arise out of its application to the
biotechnology and pharmaceutical industries. Congressional interest in providing lower cost
drugs, particularly to seniors, has focused attention on the role the act has had on the development
of new pharmaceuticals for the marketplace. Certain critics maintain that the price of many
therapeutics derived from federally funded R&D are excessive considering the government’s

115 Clifton Leaf, “The Law of Unintended Consequences,” Fortune, September 19, 2005, 252.
116 University Licensing Under Bayh-Dole: What are the Issues and Evidence?
117 Universities Report $55 Billion in Science and Engineering R&D Spending for FY2009; Redesigned Survey to
Launch in 2010,
1.
118 House Committee on the Judiciary, Subcommittee on Courts and Intellectual Property, Hearings on Gene Patents
and Other Genomic Inventions
, July 13, 2000, available at http://www.house.gov/judiciary/seve0713.htm.
119 U.S. Department of Commerce, Technology Administration, Innovation in America: University R&D, June 11,
2002, available at http://www.ta.doc.gov/reports.
120 Biotechnology Industry Organization, Testimony on Bayh-Dole and Technology Transfer Before the President’s
Council on Science and Technology, Office of Science and Technology Policy
, April 11, 2002, available at
http://www.bio.org.
Congressional Research Service
20

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

financial contribution.121 Others argue that the Bayh-Dole Act does not significantly affect
pharmaceutical prices and point to a July 2001 study by NIH that found only four of the 47 FDA
approved drugs generating $500 million a year were developed in part with NIH funded
technologies.122 Although the government generally does not directly support pharmaceutical
research aimed at product development,123 legislative attempts have been made to require cost
controls or recoupment on drugs generated, in part, with federal funds. This is in sharp contrast to
congressional and executive branch efforts, particularly in the defense arena, to make it easier for
firms to acquire and utilize intellectual property associated with federally financed R&D.124
Overall support for biological and medical sciences has grown significantly since the passage of
the Bayh-Dole Act. As measured in constant 2000 dollars, total (federal and non-federal)
spending for academic R&D in these areas has increased from $4.6 billion in 1980 to $22.1
billion in 2008.125 Funding for university R&D in the life science, particularly biological and
medical sciences, comprises by far the largest portion of academic research support. In 2008,
52.1% of total R&D expenditures at academic institutions went to finance the medical and
biological sciences. When the Bayh-Dole Act was passed in 1980, 40.5% of the research
spending at universities was in these areas.126 Expanded support for university R&D in this arena
appears to be important in relation to findings by the late Professor Edwin Mansfield showing
that academic research was particularly significant in the development of new products and
processes in the pharmaceutical and medical device industries.127
Interest and activity in the biomedical and biotechnology sectors has sparked some concern over
the effects of the Bayh-Dole Act on research in these areas. According to information provided by
the Boston Consulting Group, in the years between 1990 and 1999, new gene patents granted
increased from about 400 to 2,800 while the number granted to universities expanded from 55%
to 73% during that time period.128 Another study “estimated that in the U.S. over 3,000 new
DNA-related patents have issued every year since 1998, and more than 40,000 such patents have
been granted.”129 Similarly, the number of U.S. biotechnology patents granted continues to

121 See CRS Report RL32324, Federal R&D, Drug Discovery, and Pricing: Insights from the NIH-University-Industry
Relationship
, by Wendy H. Schacht.
122 Department of Health and Human Services, National Institutes of Health , NIH Response to the Conference Report
Request for a Plan to Ensure Taxpayers’ Interests are Protected
, July 2001, available at http://www.nih.gov/news/
070101wyden.htm.
123 See CRS Report RL30913, Pharmaceutical Research and Development: A Description and Analysis of the Process,
by Richard E. Rowberg.
124 See House Committee on Government Reform, Subcommittee on Technology and Procurement Policy, Toward
Greater Public-Private Collaboration in Research and Development: How the Treatment of Intellectual Property
Rights is Minimizing Innovation in the Federal Government
, hearings, July 17, 2001, available at
http://www.house.gov/reform.
125 Science and Engineering Indicators, 2010, Appendix table 5-6, available at http://www.nsf.gov/statistics/seind10/
append/c5/at05-06.pdf.
126 Ibid.
127 Edwin Mansfield, “Academic Research and Industrial Innovation: An Update of Empirical Findings,” Research
Policy
, 1998, 773-776.
128 Hamilton Moses, III and Joseph B. Martin, “Academic Relationships with Industry,” Journal of the American
Medical Association
, February 21, 2001, 933.
129 Timothy Caulfield, Robert M. Cook-Deegan, F. Scott Kieff, and John P. Walsh, Evidence and Anecdotes: An
Analysis of Human Gene Patenting Controversies
, Nature Biotechnology, September 2006, available at
http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC2701726/.
Congressional Research Service
21

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

grow.130 The focus on intellectual property has led critics to charge that the Bayh-Dole Act
encourages the patenting of fundamental research which, in turn, prevents further biomedical
innovation. Law professors Rebecca Eisenberg and Arti Rai argue that due to the legislation,
“proprietary claims have increasingly moved upstream from the end products themselves to the
ground-breaking discoveries that made them possible in the first place.”131 While patents are
designed to spur innovation, Rai and Eisenberg maintain that certain patents hinder the process.
From their perspective, by permitting universities to patent discoveries made under federal
funding, the Bayh-Dole Act “draws no distinction between inventions that lead directly to
commercial products and fundamental advances that enable further scientific studies.”132 These
basic innovations are generally known as “research tools.”
Eisenberg and Professor Richard Nelson argue that ownership of research tools may “impose
significant transaction costs” that result in delayed innovation and possible future litigation.133 It
also can stand in the way of research by others:
Broad claims on early discoveries that are fundamental to emerging fields of knowledge are
particularly worrisome in light of the great value, demonstrated time and again in history of
science and technology, of having many independent minds at work trying to advance a
field. Public science has flourished by permitting scientists to challenge and build upon the
work of rivals.134
Similar concerns were expressed by Harold Varmus, President of Memorial Sloan-Kettering and
former Director of NIH. In July 2000 prepared testimony, he spoke to being “troubled by
widespread tendencies to seek protection of intellectual property increasingly early in the process
that ultimately leads to products of obvious commercial value, because such practices can have
detrimental effects on science and its delivery of health benefits.”135 While the Bayh-Dole Act and
scientific advances have helped generate a dynamic biotechnology industry, there have been
changes that “are not always consistent with the best interests of science.”136
However, as Varmus and others acknowledge, the remedies to this situation are not necessarily
associated with the Bayh-Dole Act. Yale’s Richard Levin noted that while some research should
be kept in the public domain, including research tools, the fact that it is privatized is not the result
of the Bayh-Dole Act, but rather the result of patent law made by the courts and the Congress.
Therefore, he believes that changes to the act are not the appropriate means to address the
issues.137 Other experts agree that “many of the issues that are identified today as negative
consequences of Bayh-Dole can be traced to the institutional polices [of universities] structured to
optimize institutional benefits and income, rather than to the Act itself.”138

130 Science and Engineering Indicators, 2010, Appendix table 6-58.
131 Arti K. Rai and Rebecca S. Eisenberg, “Bayh-Dole Reform and the Progress of Biomedicine,” American Scientist,
January- February 2003, 52.
132 Ibid.
133 Rebecca S. Eisenberg and Richard R. Nelson, “Public vs. Proprietary Science: A Fruitful Tension?,” Daedalus,
Spring 2002.
134 Ibid.
135 Hearings on Gene Patents and Other Genomic Inventions.
136 Ibid.
137 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on Commercialization and Research, 262.
138 Sara Boettiger and Alan B. Bennet, “Bayh-Dole: If We Knew Then What We Know Now,” Nature Biotechnology,
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
22

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

Current law, as reaffirmed by court decisions, permits the patenting of research tools. However,
there have been efforts to encourage the widespread availability of these tools. Marie Freire
testified that the value to society is greatest if the research tools are easily available for use in
research. She asserted that there is a need to balance commercial interests with public interests.139
To achieve this balance, NIH has developed guidelines for universities and companies receiving
federal funding that make clear research tools are to be made available to other scientists under
reasonable terms.140 In addition, the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office recently made changes in
the guidelines used to determine the patentability of biotechnology discoveries.
Studies by Professors John Walsh, Ashish Arora, Wesley Cohen, and Charlene Cho found that
although there are now more patents associated with biomedical research, and on more
fundamental work, there is little evidence that work has been curtailed due to intellectual property
issues associated with research tools.141 Scientists are able to continue their research by
“licensing, inventing around patents, going offshore, the development and use of public databases
and research tools, court challenges, and simply using the technology without a license (i.e.,
infringement).” According to the authors, private sector owners of patents permitted such
infringement in academia (with the exception of those associated with diagnostic tests in clinical
trials) “partly because it can increase the value of the patented technology.”
Concluding Observations
The discussion surrounding changes to the patent laws in the 1980s, and the debate over
technology transfer since the late 1970s, acknowledged many of the issues currently being
explored. As a result of expressed concerns, certain safeguards were built into the activities
authorized by the Bayh-Dole Act. As discussed previously, march-in rights, the government’s
retention of an irrevocable license to patents generated under federally funded R&D, publication
requirements, and commercialization schedules, among other things, all are incorporated into the
process to protect the public interest. While there is a potential for creating an “unfair” advantage
for one company over another, this is balanced against the need for new technologies and
techniques and their contribution to the well-being of the Nation.
Despite arguments that title should remain in the public sector where it is accessible to all
interested parties, the earlier lack of exclusivity appeared to interfere with the further
development and commercialization of federally funded R&D. During the 1980s, Congress
determined that the dispensation of patent rights to universities, small businesses, and nonprofit
institutions and cooperative efforts took precedence, projecting the greater good generated by new
products and processes that improve the country’s health and welfare. Lawmakers anticipated the
economic benefits through increased revenues from profits, wages, and salaries. The government
receives a significant payback through taxes on profits and society benefits from new jobs created

(...continued)
2006, available at http://www.nature.com/nbt/journal/v24/n3/full/nbt0306-320.html.
139 Senate Committee on Appropriations, Subcommittee on Labor, Health and Human Services, Education and Related
Agencies, Hearings, August 1, 2001.
140 Available on the NIH website at http://www.nih.gov.
141 John P. Walsh, Ashish Arora, Wesley M. Cohen, “Working Through the Patent Problem,” Science, February 14,
2003, 1021 and John P. Walsh, Charlene Cho, and Wesley Cohen, “View for the Bench: Patents and Material
Transfers,” Science, September 23, 2005, 2002-2003.
Congressional Research Service
23

.
The Bayh-Dole Act: Issues in Patent Policy and the Commercialization of Technology

and expanded productivity. The importance of patent ownership has been reinforced by the
positive effects studies have demonstrated P.L. 96-517 is reported to have had on the emergence
of new technologies and new techniques generated by American companies.
There remain areas of concern, as discussed above, that Congress may decide to pursue. Some
argue, particularly with respect to pharmaceuticals and biotechnology, that under the Bayh-Dole
Act companies are receiving too many benefits at the expense of the public. Others, particularly
in the defense arena, assert that the existing rights retained by the government under the act are
too restrictive and are an impediment to meeting federal needs. But the impact of the legislation is
still seen as significant. As summed up by Howard Bremer, who was patent counsel to the
Wisconsin Alumni Research Foundation from 1960 through 1988:
One important factor, which is often overlooked, is that the success was achieved without
cost to the taxpayer. In other words, no separate appropriation of government funds was
needed to establish or manage the effort. In fact, it has been estimated that the economic
benefits flowing from the universities’ licensing activities adds about $41 billion to the
United States economy.
Significant as that dollar amount is, it should not be overlooked that university inventions,
arising, as most of them do, from basic research, have led to many products which have or
exhibit the capability of saving lives or of improving the lives, safety and health of the
citizens of the United States and around the world. In that context their contribution to
society is immeasurable.142


Author Contact Information

Wendy H. Schacht

Specialist in Science and Technology Policy
wschacht@crs.loc.gov, 7-7066



142 Howard Bremer, “The First Two Decades of the Bayh-Dole Act as Public Policy,” National Association of State
Universities and Land-Grant Colleges
, November 11, 2001, available at http://www.nasulgc.org.
Congressional Research Service
24