Changes in the Distribution of Income
Among Tax Filers Between 1996 and 2006: The
Role of Labor Income, Capital Income, and
Tax Policy

Thomas L. Hungerford
Specialist in Public Finance
December 29, 2011
Congressional Research Service
7-5700
www.crs.gov
R42131
CRS Report for Congress
Pr
epared for Members and Committees of Congress

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

Summary
Social scientists and philosophers have been concerned with issues surrounding the distribution of
income or income inequality for over 200 years—the economist and philosopher Adam Smith
discussed these issues as early as 1776. Academic writers have been writing on income inequality
measurement issues for at least a century. Policy makers have also long been interested in income
inequality issues; for example, the issue came up in Senate debate in 1898. Bills have been
introduced in the 112th Congress that address the issue of income inequality by affecting the
income of workers and taxpayers in different parts of the income distribution. In the second
session of the 112th, Congress will likely debate the scheduled expiration (at the end of 2012) of
the 2001 and 2003 Bush tax cuts, which could affect income inequality. This report examines
changes in income inequality among tax filers between 1996 and 2006. In particular, the role of
changes in wages, capital income, and tax policy is investigated.
Inflation-adjusted average after-tax income grew by 25% between 1996 and 2006 (the last year
for which individual income tax data is publicly available). This average increase, however,
obscures a great deal of variation. The poorest 20% of tax filers experienced a 6% reduction in
income while the top 0.1% of tax filers saw their income almost double. Tax filers in the middle
of the income distribution experienced about a 10% increase in income. Also during this period,
the proportion of income from capital increased for the top 0.1% from 64% to 70%.
Income inequality, as measured by the Gini coefficient, increased between 1996 and 2006; this is
true for both before-tax and after-tax income. Before-tax income inequality increased from 0.532
to 0.582 between 1996 and 2006—a 9% increase. After-tax income inequality increased by 11%
between 1996 and 2006. Total taxes (the individual income tax, the payroll tax, and the corporate
income tax) reduced income inequality in both 1996 and 2006. In 1996, taxes reduced income
inequality by 5%. In 2006, however, taxes reduced income inequality by less than 4%. Taxes
were more progressive and had a greater equalizing effect in 1996 than in 2006.
Three potential causes of the increase in after-tax income inequality between 1996 and 2006 are
changes in labor income (wages and salaries), changes in capital income (capital gains, dividends,
and business income), and changes in taxes. To evaluate these potential reasons for increasing
income inequality, a technique to decompose income inequality by income source is used. While
earnings inequality increased between 1996 and 2006, this was not the major source of increasing
income inequality over this period. Capital gains and dividends were a larger share of total
income in 2006 than in 1996 (especially for high-income taxpayers) and were more unequally
distributed in 2006 than in 1996. Changes in capital gains and dividends were the largest
contributor to the increase in the overall income inequality. Taxes were less progressive in 2006
than in 1996, and consequently, tax policy also contributed to the increase in income inequality
between 1996 and 2006. But overall income inequality would likely have increased even in the
absence of tax policy changes.

Congressional Research Service

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers


Contents
Changes in Income and Taxes.......................................................................................................... 3
Taxes as an Income Equalizer.......................................................................................................... 5
Changes in Income Inequality ......................................................................................................... 8
Potential Causes of Increased Income Inequality...................................................................... 9
Changes in Labor Income ................................................................................................. 10
Changes in Capital Income ............................................................................................... 10
Changes in Tax Policy....................................................................................................... 10
The Evidence........................................................................................................................... 11
Concluding Remarks ..................................................................................................................... 14

Figures
Figure 1. Percentage Change in Inflation-Adjusted Income and Taxes by Income
Category, 1996 to 2006................................................................................................................. 4
Figure 2. Lorenz Curves of After-Tax Income, 1996 and 2006....................................................... 9

Tables
Table 1. Sources of Income By Income Category, 1996 and 2006.................................................. 5
Table 2. Share of Income Received and Taxes Paid by Tax Filers in Various Income
Categories, 1996 and 2006 ........................................................................................................... 7
Table 3. Average Tax Rates, 1996 and 2006 .................................................................................... 8
Table 4. Contribution to Income Inequality of Income Sources, 1996 and 2006 .......................... 13
Table A-1. Number of Sample Observations by Income Category................................................ 15
Table B-1. Decomposition of the Gini Coefficient, 1996 and 2006 .............................................. 19

Appendixes
Appendix A. Data .......................................................................................................................... 15
Appendix B. Method ..................................................................................................................... 18

Contacts
Author Contact Information........................................................................................................... 19

Congressional Research Service

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

ocial scientists and philosophers have been concerned with issues surrounding the
distribution of income or income inequality for over 200 years—for example, the
S economist and philosopher Adam Smith discussed these issues as early as 1776.1 Academic
writers have been writing on income inequality measurement issues for at least a century.2 Policy
makers have also long been interested in income inequality issues.3 Three bills have been
introduced in the 112th Congress that address the issue of income inequality by affecting the
income of workers and taxpayers in different parts of the income distribution.4 Additionally, the
Administration has stated that one of its principles for tax reform was to observe the “Buffett
rule”—“no household making over $1 million annually should pay a smaller share of its income
in taxes than middle-class families pay.”5 In the second session of the 112th, Congress will likely
debate the scheduled expiration (at the end of 2012) of the 2001 and 2003 Bush tax cuts, which
could affect income inequality.
Arguments are offered for and against reducing income inequality. The classic argument against
rising income inequality is the rich get richer and the poor get poorer. This shift can increase
poverty, reduce well-being, and reduce social cohesion. Consequently, some researchers and
policy experts argue that reducing income inequality may reduce various social ills. Additionally,
researchers are concerned about the consequences of rising income inequality. Research has
demonstrated that large income and class disparities adversely affect health and economic well-
being.6
In contrast, other experts argue that rising inequality is nothing to worry about and point out that
average real income has been rising, so while the rich are getting richer, the poor are not
necessarily getting poorer. In addition, researchers and policy analysts argue that some income
inequality is necessary to encourage innovation and entrepreneurship—the possibility of large
rewards and high income are incentives to bear the risks. Furthermore, policy analysts have
argued that income or social mobility (i.e., movement within the income distribution) reduces
income inequality and increases well-being.7 Research has shown, however, that income mobility
is not very great and the degree of income mobility has either remained unchanged or decreased
since the1970s.8

1 Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations, Cannan ed. (New York: The Modern Library, 1937).
2 For example, the Gini coefficient , which has long played a central role in the measurement of income inequality, was
developed in 1909 by the Italian statistician and sociologist Corrado Gini.
3 For example, distributional issues of wealth and income were part of Senate debate over the War Revenue Act of June
10, 1898. See Senator Richard Pettigrew, Senate debate, Congressional Record, June 10, 1898, pp. 5743-5744. More
recently, there have been at least 17 hearings or testimony devoted to aspects of income inequality in the last three
Congresses (based on a search of CQ.com).
4 The bills are the Living American Wage (LAW) Act of 2011 (H.R. 283), the Jobs Creation Act (S. 1960), and the
Income Equity Act of 2011 (H.R. 382).
5 Office of Management and Budget, Living Within Our Means and Investing in the Future, Washington, DC,
September 2011.
6 Michael Marmot, The Status Syndrome: How Social Standing Affects Our Health and Longevity (New York: Henry
Holt and Co., 2004); Richard G. Wilkinson, Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality (New York: Routledge,
1996); Robert Frank, Falling Behind: How Rising Inequality Hurts the Middle-Class (Berkeley, CA: University of
California Press, 2007); and Gopal K. Singh and Mohammad Siahpush, “Widening Socioeconomic Inequalities in US
Life Expectancy, 1980-2000,” International Journal of Epidemiology, vol. 35 (May 2006), pp. 969-979.
7 See, for example, Milton Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962), p. 171.
8 Thomas L. Hungerford, “How Income Mobility Affects Income Inequality: US Evidence in the 1980s and the 1990s,”
Journal of Income Distribution, vol. 20, no. 1 (March 2011), pp. 83-103; and Katharine Bradbury, Trends in U.S.
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
1

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

Income inequality has been increasing in the United States over the past 35 years.9 Several factors
have been identified as possibly contributing to increasing income inequality. Some researchers
have suggested the decline in unionization and a falling real minimum wage as the primary
causes.10 Others have argued that rising returns to education and skill-biased technological change
are the important factors explaining rising inequality.11 Still others argue that “winner-take-all”
markets—markets where the rewards are few but large with more and more people competing for
these rewards—have spread.12 In an elaboration of this argument, some have argued that “public
officials have rewritten the rules of American politics and the American economy in ways that
have benefited the few at the expense of the many.”13 Tax policy, especially the Tax Reform Act
of 1986, has also been identified as a possible cause for rising income inequality.14 Many analysts
agree that the likely explanation for rising income inequality is due to skill-biased technological
changes combined with a change in institutions and norms of which a falling minimum wage and
declining unionization are a part.15 Research suggests that changes in tax policy do not have much
impact on the longer-term trend or rate of change in inequality, but can have a one-time affect on
the level of income inequality.16
This report examines changes in income inequality among tax filers between 1996 and 2006.17 In
particular, the role of changes in wages, capital income, and tax policy, especially the 2001 and

(...continued)
Family Income Mobility, 1969-2006, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Working Paper No. 11-10, Boston, MA,
October 20, 2011.
9 See CRS Report RL34155, Income Inequality and the U.S. Tax System, by Thomas L. Hungerford and CRS Report
RL34434, Income Inequality, Income Mobility, and Economic Policy: U.S. Trends in the 1980s and 1990s, by Thomas
L. Hungerford.
10 See David S. Lee, “Wage Inequality in the United States During the 1980s: Rising Dispersion or Falling Minimum
Wage?,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 114, no. 3 (August 1999), pp. 977-1023; and John DiNardo, Nicole M.
Fortin, and Thomas Lemieux, “Labor Market Institutions and the Distribution of Wages, 1973-1992: A Semiparametric
Approach,” Econometrica, vol. 64, no. 5 (September 1996), pp. 1001-1044.
11 See John Bound and George Johnson, “Changes in the Structure of Wages in the 1980s: An Evaluation of Alternative
Explanations,” American Economic Review, vol. 82, no. 3 (January 1992), pp. 371-392; David H. Autor, Lawrence F.
Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney, “The Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market,” American Economic Review, papers and
proceedings, vol. 96, no. 2 (May 2006), pp. 189-194; and Thomas Lemieux, “Postsecondary Education and Increasing
Wage Inequality,” American Economic Review, papers and proceedings, vol. 96, no. 2 (May 2006), pp. 195-199.
12 Robert H. Frank and Philip J. Cook, The Winner-Take-All Society (New York: The Free Press, 1995).
13 Jacob S. Hacker and Paul Pierson, Winner-Take-All Politics (New York: Simon and Schuster, Inc., 2010).
14 See Daniel R. Feenberg and James M. Poterba, “Income Inequality and the Incomes of Very High-Income
Taxpayers: Evidence from Tax Returns,” in James M. Poterba, ed., Tax Policy and the Economy, vol. 7 (Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press, 1993); and Roger H. Gordon and Joel B. Slemrod, “Are “Real” Responses to Taxes Simply Income
Shifting Between Corporate and Personal Tax Bases?” in Joel B. Slemrod, ed., Does Atlas Shrug? The Economic
Consequences of Taxing the Rich
(New York and Cambridge, MA: Russell Sage Foundation and Harvard University
Press), pp. 240-280.
15 See, for example, Frank Levy and Peter Temin, Inequality and Institutions in 20th Century America, National Bureau
of Economic Research, Working Paper no. 13106, May 2007; and Autor, Katz, and Kearney.
16 See Joel Slemrod and Jon M. Bakija, “Growing Inequality and Decreased Tax Progressivity,” in Kevin A. Hassett
and R. Glenn Hubbard, Inequality and Tax Policy (Washington, DC: AEI Press, 2001), pp. 192-226; Levy and Temin;
Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez, “Income Inequality in the United States, 1913-1998,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics
, vol. 118, no. 1 (February 2003), pp. 1-39; and Edward M. Gramlich, Richard Kasten, and Frank
Sammartino, “Growing Inequality in the 1980s: The Role of Federal Taxes and Cash Transfers,” in Sheldon Danziger
and Peter Gottschalk, eds., Uneven Tides: Rising Inequality in America (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1993),
pp. 225-249.
17 The 2006 tax year is the most recent year for which tax data is publicly available.
Congressional Research Service
2

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

2003 tax cuts, is investigated. During this period, there were changes in the sources of income
that differed by income category and there were changes in tax policy. The years 1996 and 2006
are examined for several reasons. First, both years were at approximately similar points of the
business-cycle with moderate inflation (about 3%), a modest unemployment rate (about 5%), and
moderate economic growth (3.7% in 1996 and 2.7% in 2006). Second, 2006 was the year before
the August 2007 liquidity crunch and the onset of the severe 2007-2009 recession.18 Third, there
were major tax policy changes between these two years. Fourth, both 1996 and 2006 were three
years after the enactment of tax legislation that affected tax rates and are unlikely to be affected
by short-run behavioral responses to these changes.19
Changes in Income and Taxes
The economy grew between 1996 and 2006 with real (inflation-adjusted) gross domestic product
(GDP) increasing by 38%.20 Per capital real GDP (real GDP divided by the U.S. population)
increased by 24% between 1996 and 2006 and average inflation-adjusted after-tax income of U.S.
tax filers also increased by about 25%. Average real income before taxes increased by 20% while
the average tax payment increased by 6% (see Figure 1).21 These average growth rates, however,
do not reflect how tax filers in different parts of the income distribution fared between 1996 and
2006.
Tax filers in different parts of the income distribution fared differently between 1996 and 2006.
Figure 1 displays the percentage changes in inflation-adjusted income (before- and after-tax) and
taxes for tax filers in different income categories.22 The poorest tax filers (bottom 20%) saw
average after-tax income fall by 6% between 1996 and 2006, while those in the richest quintile
(top 20%) saw their average after-tax income rise by 38% over the same period. This rise in
income is significantly smaller than the rise in income at the top of the income distribution. The
richest 1% of tax filers experienced a 74% increase in after-tax income and the richest 0.1% (one
tax filer in a thousand) saw their after-tax income almost double (an increase of 96%).


18 During the 2007-2009 recession, income from capital fell since profit margins fell; consequently, labor’s share of
national income increased. However, by 2011, profit margins were back to their prerecession levels and labor’s share of
national income was below its 2006 level.
19 Tax rates were increased for high-income taxpayers in 1993 by the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1993
(P.L. 103-66) and tax rates were reduced by the Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001 (P.L.
107-16) and the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 (P.L. 108-27).
20 www.bea.gov
21 The data used for this analysis is described in the Appendix.
22 A tax filer’s income category is determined by equivalence-adjusted after-tax income (after-tax income divided by
the square root of family size). Tax filers are ranked by income from lowest to highest and divided into five income
categories or quintiles, each containing 20% of the tax filers. Quintile 1 contain the 20% poorest tax filers and quintile
5 contain the richest 20%.
Congressional Research Service
3

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

Figure 1. Percentage Change in Inflation-Adjusted Income and Taxes by Income
Category, 1996 to 2006
120%
100%
80%
e
60%
tag
n
ce
Per

40%
20%
0%
Total
Bottom
Second
Middle 20% Fourth 20%
Top 20%
Top 5%
Top 1%
Top 0.1%
20%
20%
-20%
After-Tax Income
Before-Tax Income
Taxes

Source: CRS analysis of 1996 and 2006 IRS Statistics of Income Public Use Files.
Taxes fell for most tax filers in the middle of the income distribution (i.e., the second, middle, and
fourth quintiles). Taxes slightly increased for tax filers in quintile 1 by about 2%; the tax increase
is due solely to a rise in payroll taxes paid. Total taxes paid by the richest 20% increased by about
15%—less than half the increase in income. The richest 0.1% of tax filers paid 33% more in taxes
in 2006 than in 1996—their taxes rose one-third as fast as their income.
Not only was there significant variation in income increases between 1996 and 2006, there were
also large differences in the composition of income among the income categories as well as
significant changes in the composition. Table 1 reports the share of income (before taxes)
received by tax filers from a variety of income sources in 1996 and 2006.23 For tax filers with
income below the 80th percentile (i.e., the bottom 80%), the major source of income is from
wages and salaries, which accounted for 82% of total income in both 1996 and 2006. The share
from capital income (that is, capital gains, dividends, and business income) was very small in
1996 (about 4%) and fell to less than 3% in 2006. The share from retirement income (from
pensions and IRAs) and other income (such as Social Security, unemployment compensation, and
interest income) increased slightly between 1996 and 2006.
The situation at the top of the income distribution is very different. For the top 20%, wages and
salaries make up a smaller share of total income (60% in 1996) and this share fell by 10

23 The data used for the analysis is described in Appendix A.
Congressional Research Service
4

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

percentage points between 1996 and 2006 to 50%. The share from capital income increased over
this period, especially from capital gains and dividends. The situation is even more different for
the top 0.1% of tax filers—wages and salaries account for about 20% of total income, with the
share falling from 23% in 1996 to less than 19% by 2006. In both years, about half of the total
income of the top 0.1% comes from capital gains and dividends; the share from capital gains and
dividends increased by 6 percentage points between 1996 and 2006.
Table 1. Sources of Income By Income Category, 1996 and 2006
Dividends
Wages and
and Capital
Business
Retirement
Other


Salaries
Gains
Income
Income
Income
1996
82.0 1.4 2.6 6.9 7.1
Bottom 80%
2006
82.0 0.7 1.8 7.2 8.3
1996
60.2 13.4 10.2 8.5 7.8
Top 20%
2006
50.4 18.8 12.0 11.8 7.1
1996
46.9 21.1 15.1 8.7 8.2
Top 5%
2006
36.3 28.1 16.9 11.8 7.0
1996
34.4 30.8 17.7 8.2 8.9
Top 1%
2006
26.0 38.2 19.0 9.6 7.1
1996
23.0 45.8 17.9 4.2 9.1
Top 0.1%
2006
18.6 51.9 17.9 4.0 7.6
Source: CRS analysis of 1996 and 2006 IRS SOI Public Use Files.
Notes: Rows may not sum to 100% due to rounding.
The pattern of income growth displayed in Figure 1 suggests that income inequality increased
between 1996 and 2006 as the income of tax filers at the top of the income distribution pulled
away from those at the bottom. Furthermore, with changes in the composition of income,
especially among high-income tax filers, different income sources will likely have different
contributions to increasing income inequality. The role of tax policy changes is suggested by
comparing the percentage change in taxes paid to the percentage change in income for each
income category. If tax policy had not changed between 1996 and 2006, then taxes paid would
have increased by about the same percentage as before-tax income. The percentage changes in
taxes paid were generally much less than the percentage changes in before-tax income especially
for higher-income tax filers. This suggests that part of the pattern in the growth of after-tax
income is due to changes in tax policy.
Taxes as an Income Equalizer
The federal individual income tax is a graduated tax with progressively higher tax rates for each
successive tax bracket (ranging from 10% to 35% in 2006).24 But, because of various tax
preferences and the lower rates on long-term capital gains and qualified dividends, the tax rates

24 The statutory tax rates ranged from 15% to 39.6% in 1996.
Congressional Research Service
5

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

published in the tax tables may be a poor guide to the actual tax burden faced by tax filers in each
income category.25 Nonetheless, on average, the individual income tax is progressive with the
average tax rate increasing as income rises, and can be expected to reduce income inequality.26
The payroll tax that funds Social Security and Medicare has a constant 15.3% tax rate on wages
and salaries (12.4% for Social Security and 2.9% for Medicare).27 Half of the tax rate is paid by
the employee and the other half by the employer; the self-employed are responsible for the entire
amount. The tax rate for Social Security applies only to covered earnings below the maximum
taxable limit ($62,700 in 1996 and $94,200 for 2006). The payroll tax is slightly progressive
throughout the bottom 80% of the income distribution, but is regressive above that—individuals
in the top 20% of the income distribution pay a lower share of their income in payroll taxes than
the bottom 80%.28
Individual taxpayers are not directly subject to the U.S. corporate income tax, but may indirectly
bear the burden of the corporate income tax. One justification offered for lower tax rates on
capital gains and dividends is this income can be taxed twice—once under the corporate income
tax and again under the individual income tax.29 It is likely that most or all of the burden of the
corporate income tax falls on capital.
Table 2 reports the share of income (before- and after-tax) received and taxes paid by tax filers in
various income categories in 1996 and 2006. Tax filers in the bottom four income quintiles
received a smaller share of before-tax and after-tax income in 2006 than in 1996. For example,
the middle quintile (middle 20%) received 13.7% of all before-tax income in 1996 (and 14.2% of
all after-tax income) but received 12.1% in 2006 (and 12.7% of after-tax income). In contrast, the
top 20% of tax filers received 54% of all before-tax income in 1996 and 59.3% in 2006.30 The
share of before-tax income received by the top 0.1% of tax filers increased from 6.6% in 1996 to
almost 10% by 2006.

25 CRS Report RL34622, Tax Expenditures and the Federal Budget, by Thomas L. Hungerford.
26 CRS Report RL32693, Distribution of the Tax Burden Across Individuals: An Overview, by Jane G. Gravelle.
27 A temporary one-year reduction in the Social Security payroll tax (by 2 percentage points) was enacted for 2011 by
the Tax Relief, Unemployment Insurance Reauthorization, and Job Creation Act of 2010 (P.L. 111-312). The reduction
was extended for 2 months on December 23, 2011.
28 CRS Report RL33943, Increasing the Social Security Payroll Tax Base: Options and Effects on Tax Burdens, by
Thomas L. Hungerford.
29 Several recent studies estimate that most or all of the burden of the corporate income falls on labor through reduced
wages. These studies, however, have been shown to suffer from various methodological deficiencies. See CRS Report
RL34229, Corporate Tax Reform: Issues for Congress, by Jane G. Gravelle and Thomas L. Hungerford; and Jennifer
C. Gravelle, Corporate Tax Incidence: A Review of Empirical Estimates and Analysis, CBO working paper 2011-01,
June 2011, for reviews of these studies and an analysis of their deficiencies.
30 The share of after-tax income received by the top quintile similarly increased from 51.6% in 1996 to 57.2% in 2006.
Congressional Research Service
6

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

Table 2. Share of Income Received and Taxes Paid by Tax Filers in Various Income
Categories, 1996 and 2006

1996
2006
Before-Tax
After-Tax
Before-Tax
After-Tax

Income
Income Total
Taxes Income
Income Total
Taxes
Bottom
20% 3.0 3.6 0.7 2.3 2.7 0.6
Second
20% 8.3 9.1 5.3 7.4 8.1 4.5
Middle
20% 13.7 14.2 12.0 12.1 12.7 9.9
Fourth
20% 21.1 21.4 20.0 18.9 19.3 17.6
Top
20% 54.0 51.6 62.0 59.3 57.2 67.3
Top
5%
29.0 27.1 35.6 35.0 33.5 40.9
Top
1%
15.4 13.9 20.2 20.5 19.5 24.4
Top
0.1% 6.6 5.8 9.4 9.7 9.1 11.8
Gini
0.532 0.503
0.582 0.560

Coefficient
Source: CRS analysis of 1996 and 2006 IRS SOI Public Use Files.
The share of total taxes paid by tax filers in the bottom four quintiles decreased between 1996 and
2006. For example, the share paid by the middle quintile (middle 20%) fell from 12% in 1996 to
about 10% in 2006. The share paid by the richest 20% increased between 1996 and 2006 from
62% to 67%; the share paid by the richest 0.1% increased over this period from 9% to 12%. Both
the share of income received by the top 20% and the share of taxes paid by them increased
between 1996 and 2006.
The last row of Table 2 reports the Gini coefficient for before-tax and after-tax income in 1996
and 2006.31 Income inequality as measured by the Gini coefficient increased between 1996 and
2006; this is true for both before-tax and after-tax income. The before-tax income Gini coefficient
increased from 0.532 to 0.582 between 1996 and 2006—a 9% increase. The Gini coefficient for
after-tax income increased by 11% between 1996 and 2006.
Total taxes (the individual income tax, the payroll tax, and the corporate income tax) reduced
income inequality in both 1996 and 2006. In 1996, the Gini coefficient of before-tax income was
0.532 and taxes reduced it to 0.503—a 5% reduction. In 2006, however, taxes reduced the Gini
coefficient by less than 4% (from 0.582 to 0.560). Taxes appear to have had a slightly greater
equalizing effect in 1996 than in 2006.
This conclusion is further supported by information displayed in Table 3, which reports the
average tax rate (total tax paid divided by total income) of tax filers in each income category.
Between 1996 and 2006, the overall average tax rate (which includes all taxes) fell from 23% to
20%. The average tax rate fell for all income categories except for those in the bottom quintile

31 The Gini coefficient is a measure of income inequality that varies between 0 and 1. A Gini coefficient value of 0
indicates that income is evenly distributed throughout the income distribution (i.e., everyone has the same income)
while a value of 1 indicates perfect income inequality (i.e., one person has all the income).
Congressional Research Service
7

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

(bottom 20%). The primary reason for the slight increase for the bottom quintile was an increase
in the average payroll tax rate. Between 1996 and 2006, the tax system became flatter in that the
difference between the lowest and highest average tax rates decreased. The average tax rate for
tax filers in the top 0.1% fell by about 25% (from almost 33% to under 25%). The last row of
Table 3 reports the Suits index, which is a measure of the progressivity of the tax system.32 The
Suits index for all taxes fell from 0.135 in 1996 to 0.125 in 2006. In other words, while the tax
system remained progressive, it was less progressive in 2006 than in 1996.
Table 3. Average Tax Rates, 1996 and 2006
1996 2006
Total 23.03
20.26
Bottom 20%
5.24
5.68
Second 20%
14.80
12.50
Middle 20%
20.20
16.51
Fourth 20%
21.87
18.88
Top 20%
26.43
23.00
Top 5%
28.23
23.68
Top 1%
30.30
24.16
Top 0.1%
32.72
24.77
Suits Index
0.135
0.125
Source: CRS analysis of 1996 and 2006 IRS SOI Public Use Files.
Changes in Income Inequality
Income inequality increased between 1996 and 2006. Figure 2 presents a graphical representation
of the increase in income inequality. The figure displays the Lorenz curves of after-tax income in
1996 and 2006. The Lorenz curve is way of characterizing an income distribution and shows the
percentage of income accruing to a particular proportion of the population who have been ranked
by income from smallest to largest. For example, if the Lorenz curve were the straight line shown
in the figure, then10% of income (a 0.1 income share) accrues to the poorest 10% of the
population (a 0.1 population share), 20% of income accrues to the poorest 20%, and so on. This
would be a case of perfect income equality (with a Gini coefficient of 0). The further the Lorenz
curve is below the diagonal line, the more unequally income is distributed (i.e., less income is
received by those in the lower parts of the income distribution in relation to their share of the
population and more income is received by the rich than their share of the population). If two
Lorenz curves do not intersect, then it can be said that one income distribution is unambiguously
more equal than another.33 The 2006 Lorenz curve is further from the diagonal line than the 1996

32 The Suits index is a measure of tax progressivity that varies between −1 (completely regressive) and +1 (completely
progressive). A tax is progressive if the average tax rate increases with income. See Daniel B. Suits, “Measurement of
Tax Progressivity,” American Economic Review, vol. 67, no. 4 (September 1977), pp. 747-752.
33 In this case, all common measures of income inequality that respect certain desirable properties (including the Gini
coefficient) will indicate that income inequality is higher in one distribution than in the other. See Stephen P. Jenkins
and Philippe Van Kerm, “The Measurement of Economic Inequality,” in Oxford Handbook on Economic Inequality,
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
8

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

Lorenz curve. Furthermore, the two Lorenz curves do not intersect, consequently, after-tax
income was more unequally distributed in 2006 than in 1996.
Figure 2. Lorenz Curves of After-Tax Income, 1996 and 2006
1
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
e
e Shar 0.5
com
In
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
1
Population Share
1996
2006

Source: CRS analysis of 1996 and 2006 IRS SOI Public Use Files.
Potential Causes of Increased Income Inequality
Three potential causes of the increase in after-tax income inequality between 1996 and 2006 are
examined in the analysis. The three are changes in labor income (wages and salaries), changes in
capital income (capital gains, dividends, and business income), and changes in taxes. These are
not the only potential reasons for changes in income inequality, but all are commonly cited as
reasons by many observers.34 Furthermore, these three reasons are not mutually exclusive—a
change in labor or capital income could also affect the amount of taxes paid, which affects
observed inequality.

(...continued)
ed. Wierma Salverda, Brian Nolan, and Timothy M. Smeeding (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009), pp. 40-70.
34 Congressional Budget Office, Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007, October
2011.
Congressional Research Service
9

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

Changes in Labor Income
Earnings inequality has been increasing since at least the late-1960s.35 Part of this has been
attributed to increased salaries paid to CEOs, managers, financial professionals, and athletes,
which is estimated to account for 70% of the increase in the share of income going to the richest
Americans.36 Such changes in the earnings distribution have been described by some as a move
toward a winner-take-all reward structure.37 This explanation would primarily affect those at the
top of the income distribution. Skill-biased technological change could also affect earnings in the
upper part of the earnings distribution. Other explanations for rising earnings inequality would
affect different parts of the income distribution. A declining real minimum wage could affect
lower income tax filers (the inflation-adjusted minimum wage fell from $6.57 per hour in 1996 to
$5.57 per hour in 2006) and declining unionization could affect tax filers in the middle of the
earnings distribution. Increasing earnings inequality has been identified as the main suspect
behind rising income inequality, since a large share of total income is from earnings.
Changes in Capital Income
Capital income has generally been concentrated among higher-income tax filers. Capital income
can be capital gains, dividends, and business income from partnerships and S corporations. The
number of partnerships and S corporations has steadily increased between 1996 and 2006. The
number of partnerships increased by 1.2 million over this period and the number of S
corporations increased by 1.6 million.38 Income from these types of businesses is reported on
individual tax filer’s tax returns and is not subject to the corporate income tax. An increasing
share of income for high-income tax filers comes from capital income, which could be part of the
explanation for the rising income of this group of tax filers and rising income inequality.
Changes in Tax Policy
The major tax change between 1996 and 2006 was enactment of the 2001 and 2003 Bush tax cuts,
which reduced taxes especially for higher-income tax filers. These tax cuts involved reduced tax
rates, the introduction of the 10% tax bracket (which reduced taxes for all taxpayers), reduced the
tax rates on long-term capital gains and qualified dividends, and other changes.39 In 1996, long-
term capital gains were taxed at 28% (15% for lower-income taxpayers) and all dividends were
taxed as ordinary income. By 2006, long-term capital gains and qualified dividends were taxed at
15% (5% for lower-income taxpayers). Tax policy changes that affect progressivity will affect
after-tax income inequality.40

35 Wojciech Kopczuk, Emmanuel Saez, and Jae Song, “Earnings Inequality and Mobility in the United States: Evidence
from Social Security Data Since 1937,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 125, no. 1 (February 2010), pp. 91-128.
36 Jon Bakija, Adam Cole, and Bradley T. Heim, Jobs and Income Growth of Top Earners and the Causes of Changing
Income Inequality: Evidence from U.S. Tax Return Data
, Williams College, Working Paper, November 2010.
37 Robert H. Frank and Philip J. Cook, The Winner-Take-All Society (New York: The Free Press, 1995).
38 Internal Revenue Services, Statistics of Income, available at www.irs.gov.
39 For more details, see CRS Report R42020, The 2001 and 2003 Bush Tax Cuts and Deficit Reduction, by Thomas L.
Hungerford.
40 Thomas L. Hungerford, “The Redistributive Effect of Selected Federal Transfer and Tax Provisions,” Public Finance
Review
, vol. 38, no. 4 (July 2010), pp. 450-472; and Kinam Kim and Peter J. Lambert, “Redistributive Effect of U.S.
Taxes and Public Transfers, 1994-2004,” Public Finance Review, vol. 37, no. 1 (January 2009), pp. 3-26.
Congressional Research Service
10

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

The Evidence
To evaluate these potential reasons for increasing income inequality, a well-known technique to
decompose the Gini coefficient by income source is used.41 The technique to decompose the Gini
coefficient allows for an examination of how a change in a particular source of income will affect
income inequality as measured by the Gini coefficient. The results of the decomposition for 1996
and 2006 are reported in Table 4.
The results displayed in Table 4 report the contribution to income inequality (the Gini coefficient)
from eight income sources (taxes are considered as a negative income source). After-tax income
inequality increased between 1996 and 2006 as reflected in the increase of the Gini coefficient
from 0.503 in 1996 to 0.560 in 2006—an increase of 0.057 (see the last row of the table). In the
panels for 1996 and 2006, four numbers are reported for each income source. The first number is
the income source’s share in total income, which sums to 100% over all income sources.42 The
second number is the income source’s contribution to the overall Gini coefficient; the sum of this
number over all the income sources is equal to the Gini coefficient. The third number reported in
each panel is the income source’s percentage contribution to the overall Gini coefficient, which
sums to 100% over all the income sources. Lastly, the percentage change in the overall Gini
coefficient due to a 1% across-the-board increase in the income source is shown. For example, if
wages and salaries of all tax filers had been 1% larger in 1996, then the overall Gini coefficient
would have been 0.09% lower (see the fourth column in the panel for 1996).
The first row of Table 4 reports the results for wages and salaries. Between 1996 and 2006,
wages and salaries as a share of total after-tax income fell from 91% to about 80%, though this is
still the largest income source. Wages and salaries also make the largest contribution to the Gini
coefficient, but this contribution has declined between 1996 and 2006 (from 82% in 1996 to 66%
in 2006).43 A 1% across-the-board increase in 1996 wage and salaries would have reduced the
Gini coefficient by 0.09%, but a similar 1% increase in 2006 would have reduced the overall Gini
coefficient by 0.14%—an across-the-board increase in wages and salaries would have had a
greater equalizing effect in 2006 than in 1996 (i.e., reducing the Gini coefficient). These results
suggest that while earnings inequality increased between 1996 and 2006, this was not the major
source of increasing income inequality over this period.
Capital income is income from capital gains, dividends, and income reported in the 1040 form
schedules C (business income), E (primarily partnerships and S corporations), and F (farm
income). The results are reported on the third and fourth rows of Table 4. Business income
includes the income reported on the three schedules of the 1040 form. Capital gains, dividends,
and business income were all a larger share of total income in 2006 than in 1996. Furthermore,
capital income, especially capital gains and dividends, made a larger contribution to the overall
Gini coefficient in 2006 than in 1996. Changes in capital gains and dividends was the largest
contributor to the increase in the overall Gini coefficient. The disequalizing effect of capital gains

41 The technique is developed and described in Robert I. Lerman and Shlomo Yitzhaki, “Income Inequality Effects by
Income Source: A New Approach and Applications to the United States,” Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 67,
no. 1 (1985), pp. 151-156. See Appendix B for more details of the decomposition.
42 Since taxes are negative for most tax filers, they account for a negative share of total after-tax income.
43 Although the contribution of wages and salaries to the overall Gini decreased between 1996 and 2006, earnings
inequality increased between these two years.
Congressional Research Service
11

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

and dividends increased between 1996 and 2006 (from 0.08% to 0.10%) while the disequalizing
effect of business income remained essentially unchanged.
Taxes reduce after-tax income and can be thought of as negative income, which is why taxes
account for a negative share of total income (see the next to last row of Table 4). The share of
taxes in income was less negative in 2006 than in 1996 (−25% in 2006 compared to −30% in
1996); that is, taxes were less important in after-tax income in 2006 than in 1996. One likely
reason for this was the enactment of the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts. Another likely reason is the
increase in income from capital gains and dividends, which are largely received by higher-income
tax filers, that were taxed at a lower rate in 2006 than in 1996 (the lower rates were enacted in the
2003 tax cut). Taxes has a greater effect on reducing the overall Gini coefficient in 1996 than in
2006—the percentage contribution of taxes to the Gini coefficient changed from −37% to −30%
between 1996 and 2006. The equalizing effect of taxes (from a 1% proportionate increase in
taxes) was greater in 1996 than in 2006.
Changes in interest income, social insurance income (Social Security and unemployment
compensation), and other income had a negligible effect on the increase in income inequality
between 1996 and 2006. Changes in retirement income, however, did contribute to the increase in
the Gini coefficient. Between 1996 and 2006, retirement income became a larger share of total
income (10% in 1996 and 12.4% in 2006) and became more disequalizing.
Congressional Research Service
12

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

Table 4. Contribution to Income Inequality of Income Sources, 1996 and 2006
1996
2006
Percentage
Percentage
Change in Gini
Change in
from 1%
Gini from 1%
Percentage
Increase in
Percentage
Increase in
Income
Share of Total
Contribution
Contribution
Income
Share of Total
Contribution
Contribution
Income
Source
Income
to Gini
to Gini
Source
Income
to Gini
to Gini
Source
Wages and
91.1 0.412 81.9 −0.092
79.3 0.368 65.8 −0.135
Salaries
Interest
5.4 0.033 6.6 0.012 4.0 0.029 5.2 0.012
Income
Dividends and
10.3 0.092 18.3 0.080 14.3 0.138 24.7 0.104
Capital Gains
Business
8.7 0.077 15.4 0.067 9.8 0.092 16.3 0.065
Income
Social
3.8 0.016 3.1 −0.008
5.0 0.016 2.8 −0.023
Insurance
Income
Retirement
10.1 0.056 11.2 0.012 12.4 0.081 14.5 0.021
Income
Other
Income
0.5 0.002 0.5 0.000 0.6 0.004 0.7 0.001
Taxes
−29.9
−0.186
−37.0
−0.071
−25.4
−0.168
−30.0
−0.046
Total
100.0 0.503 100.0 0.000 100.0 0.560 100.0 0.000
Source: CRS analysis of 1996 and 2006 IRS SOI Public Use Files.
CRS-13

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

Concluding Remarks
Inflation-adjusted after-tax income grew by 25% between 1996 and 2006 for tax filers. This
income growth, however, was not equally shared throughout the income distribution. Inflation-
adjusted income actually fell for those in the bottom income quintile (the poorest 20% of tax
filers) and almost doubled for the richest 0.1% of tax filers. Consequently, income inequality
increased between 1996 and 2006. This was true for both before-tax and after-tax income.
The U.S. system is progressive in that the average tax rate increases as income increases, which
tends to decrease inequality of after-tax income. In the decade between 1996 and 2006, however,
there was a relatively large decrease in average tax rates for tax filers at the top of the income
distribution. Consequently, the tax system in 2006 was less progressive than in 1996.
It has been argued that changes in wages and salaries, capital income, and taxes were the major
contributors to the increase in income inequality. Earnings inequality has been increasing over the
past three decades, and the share of income from capital has increased for high-income tax filers.
Furthermore, the 2001 and 2003 Bush tax cuts, while reducing taxes for almost all tax filers,
reduced taxes for high-income tax filers to a greater extent than for lower-income tax filers.
Changes in income from capital gains and dividends were the single largest contributor to rising
income inequality between 1996 and 2006. Changes in tax policy also made a significant
contribution to the increase in income inequality, but even in the absence of tax policy changes
income inequality would likely have increased. Although earning inequality increased between
1996 and 2006, changes in wages and salaries appear to have had little effect on the increase in
overall income inequality.
Congressional Research Service
14

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

Appendix A. Data
The sources of data are the 1996 and 2006 Internal Revenue Service (IRS) Statistics of Income
(SOI) Public Use Files. The Public Use Files are nationally representative samples of tax returns
for the 1996 and 2006 tax years. To protect the identity of individual tax filers while preserving
the character of the data, the IRS made changes to the data. Consequently, while reliable
aggregate information can be obtained, individual tax filer records in the data may or may not
contain information from just one tax return. The unit of analysis is the tax return for a tax filer
(which may be a married couple), and IRS-provided sample weights are used throughout the
analysis. The 1996 analysis sample contains information for 105,232 tax filers (representing
107.1 million tax filers). The 2006 analysis sample contains 135,817 tax filers (representing 124.0
million tax filers). The numbers of sample observations in each income category are reported in
Table A-1.
Table A-1. Number of Sample Observations by Income Category
Income Category
1996
2006
Bottom 20%
12,337
15,073
Second 20%
9,241
11,299
Middle 20%
9,892
12,507
Fourth 20%
11,164
13,488
Top 20%
62,596
83,450
Top 5%
50,443
65,138
Top 1%
37,043
43,391
Top 0.1%
19,591
11,707
Source: CRS analysis of 1996 and 2006 IRS SOI Public Use Files.

U.S. taxes from all sources should be included in an analysis of the effective tax burden and this
analysis considers the individual income tax, the corporate income tax, and the payroll tax.44 But
three issues need to be addressed regarding the burden of the corporate income tax.45 The first
issue is the question of who actually bears the burden of the corporate income tax. Several recent
studies estimate that most or all of the burden of the corporate income falls on labor through
reduced wages. These studies, however, have been shown to suffer from various methodological
deficiencies.46 The evidence suggests that most or all of the burden of the corporate income tax
falls on owners of capital.47 In the analysis, it is assumed that 100% of the corporate income tax

44 See CBO, Average Federal Tax Rates in 2007, June 2010.
45 In addressing these issues, various assumptions need to be made regarding the burden of the corporate income tax. In
cases where different decisions regarding assumptions could be made, the one that would “bias” against finding a
Buffett rule result was chosen.
46 See CRS Report RL34229, Corporate Tax Reform: Issues for Congress, by Jane G. Gravelle and Thomas L.
Hungerford; and Jennifer C. Gravelle, Corporate Tax Incidence: A Review of Empirical Estimates and Analysis, CBO
working paper 2011-01, June 2011, for reviews of these studies and an analysis of their deficiencies.
47 Ibid.
Congressional Research Service
15

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

falls on capital income (dividends and capital gains), which mostly affects high-income taxpayers
(almost 60% of all capital gains and dividends are received by taxpayers with income over $1
million).
Second, not all of this income is taxed at the corporate level. The Internal Revenue Service (IRS)
reports that a substantial proportion of capital gains and losses (short-term and long-term)
reported by taxpayers are passthrough gains or losses (that is, the income is not reported on any
corporate tax form and passes directly to individual taxpayers to report on their individual income
tax form), gains or losses from the sale of government bonds, and other assets never taxed at the
corporate level.48 For example, hedge funds are generally organized as partnerships. Under
current tax law, a partnership does not pay income taxes; instead gains and losses flow through to
the partners who include it on their income tax returns.
The income from the partnership is often taxed as capital gains or qualified dividends at reduced
tax rates (i.e., 15%). Essentially, if the partnership earns long-term capital gains or qualified
dividends, the income flows through to the partners as long-term capital gains or qualified
dividends and is taxed accordingly—the income is not recharacterized (e.g., from capital gains to
ordinary income) as it passes through from the partnership to the individual partners. Some
partners receive partnership interests in exchange for contributions of capital (that is,
investments) and are referred to as limited partners; some partners receive partnership interests in
exchange for services (carried interests) and these are general partners who actively manage the
partnership.49 Most of this income is taxed at the reduced long-term capital gains rate and is not
taxed at the corporate level.50 It is estimated that 53.6% (1996) and 37.4% (2006) of net capital
gains are taxed at the U.S. corporate level as well as the individual level (such as corporate stock,
mutual funds, and capital gains distributions).51 It is also assumed that all dividends are taxed at
both the corporate and individual levels.
The third issue concerns the corporate tax rate. The statutory corporate tax rate in 2010 was
39.2%, which includes federal and state corporate taxes. However, several studies estimate the
effective corporate tax rate is between 22.2% and 27.1%.52 After subtracting out the state
corporate tax rate from the highest estimate, it is assumed that the effective corporate tax rate is
24.2%.
Taxes attributed to tax filers that is not directly paid by them (that is, the employer’s contribution
of the payroll tax and corporate taxes) is also imputed to the tax filer as income. Total income
includes income from all sources reported on the 1040 form including tax-exempt interest and

48 Janette Wilson and Pearson Liddell, “Sales of Capital Assets Reported on Individual Tax Returns, 2007,” Statistics of
Income Bulletin
, Winter 2010, pp. 75-104.
49 See CRS Report RS22689, Taxation of Hedge Fund and Private Equity Managers, by Mark Jickling and Donald J.
Marples; and CRS Report RS22717, Taxation of Private Equity and Hedge Fund Partnerships: Characterization of
Carried Interest
, by Donald J. Marples.
50 About 45% of net capital gains are from passthrough net gains or a transaction involving partnership, S corporation,
and estate or trust interests. It is unknown how much of this was from the sale of corporate equities.
51 The results are virtually unchanged if it is assumed that 100% of net capital gains are taxed at both the corporate and
individual levels.
52 CRS Report R41743, International Corporate Tax Rate Comparisons and Policy Implications, by Jane G. Gravelle.
Congressional Research Service
16

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

Social Security benefits that are excluded from adjusted gross income as well as the imputed
taxes. Income is adjusted for inflation (converted to 2010 constant dollars) using the CPI-U-RS.53

53 The CPI-U-RS provides historical estimates of the consumer price index using the current method rather than the
methods in place in a particular year. See www.bls.gov/cpi/cpirsdc.htm.
Congressional Research Service
17

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

Appendix B. Method
The decomposition of the Gini coefficient by income source applied the method developed by
Robert Lerman and Shlomo Yitzhaki.54 The contribution of each income source (k=1 ... K) to the
overall Gini coefficient depends on (1) how important the income source is to total income (Sk),
(2) how the income source is distributed (Gk), and (3) how the income source is correlated with
total income (Rk). The overall Gini coeffienct (G) can be written as:
G = ∑ S ×G × R
k
k
k
If Sk, Gk, or Rk are close to zero, then the particular income source does not make a significant
contribution to income inequality. Furthermore, how an income source’s contribution to
inequality changes over time depends on how the three components change over time. For
example, although inequality of wages and salaries increased between 1996 and 2006, the
contribution of wages and salaries to overall inequality decreased because wages and salaries
were a smaller share of total income in 2006 than in 1996 (that is, Sk decreased between 1996 and
2006 from 91.1% to 79.3%).
The estimates of the decomposition are reported in Table B-1. In the panel for each year, the three
components for each income source are displayed as well as the income source’s contribution to
the overall Gini coefficient (which is also reported in Table 4). Sk multiplied by 100 is the share
of total income reported in Table 4.

54 Robert I. Lerman and Shlomo Yitzhaki, “Income Inequality Effects by Income Source: A New Approach and
Applications to the United States,” Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 67, no. 1 (1985), pp. 151-156.
Congressional Research Service
18

Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers

Table B-1. Decomposition of the Gini Coefficient, 1996 and 2006
1996
2006
Income
Source
Sk
Gk
Rk
Sk×Gk×Rk
Sk
Gk
Rk
Sk×Gk×Rk
Wages and
0.911 0.562 0.804 0.412 0.793 0.587 0.791 0.368
Salaries
Interest
0.054 0.923 0.668 0.033 0.040 0.949 0.770 0.029
Income
Dividends
0.103 1.067 0.838 0.092 0.143 1.075 0.901 0.138
and Capital
Gains
Business
0.087 1.459 0.608 0.077 0.098 1.450 0.642 0.092
Income
Social
0.038 0.908 0.445 0.016 0.050 0.867 0.356 0.016
Insurance
Income
Retirement
0.101 0.917 0.612 0.056 0.124 0.915 0.715 0.081
Income
Other
0.005 0.892 0.592 0.002 0.006 1.353 0.505 0.004
Income
Taxes
-0.299 -0.664 -0.937 -0.186 -0.254 -0.712 -0.929 -0.168
Source: CRS analysis of 1996 and 2006 IRS SOI Public Use Files.
Notes: Estimated using Stata package written by Philippe Van Kerm, sgini—Generalized Gini and Concentration
coefficients (with factor decomposition) in Stata
, v1.1, CEPS/INSTEAD, February 2010.

Author Contact Information

Thomas L. Hungerford

Specialist in Public Finance
thungerford@crs.loc.gov, 7-6422


Congressional Research Service
19