.

The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the
Economy and the Labor Market

Thomas L. Hungerford
Specialist in Public Finance
March 9, 2011
Congressional Research Service
7-5700
www.crs.gov
R41676
CRS Report for Congress
P
repared for Members and Committees of Congress
c11173008

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

Summary
In December 2010, Congress passed the Tax Relief, Unemployment Insurance Reauthorization,
and Job Creation Act of 2010 (P.L. 111-312), which among others things temporarily extended
the Emergency Unemployment Compensation (EUC08) program at an estimated cost of $56.5
billion—the eighth time EUC08 was extended. Before each vote, there were calls from some to
end the program, arguing that the Unemployment Insurance (UI) program increases
unemployment and does not stimulate the economy. It has been argued that UI subsidizes
unemployment and creates a disincentive to look for a job, thus increasing the duration of
unemployment. Some assert that this will increase the unemployment rate, reduce the production
of goods and services, and reduce economic growth. Others emphasize the traditional view that
UI and extending UI benefits during economic downturns serves as an economic stimulus, puts
money into the economy, and helps create jobs. Since unemployment is likely to remain relatively
high throughout 2011, further extensions of the EUC08 program could be considered by the 112th
Congress. This report examines the effect of the Unemployment Insurance program on the
economy and the labor market.
Total Unemployment Insurance benefit payments increase automatically during recessionary
periods as the unemployment rate increases and unemployed workers apply for benefits. Total
benefit payments decrease during economic expansions as unemployed workers return to work.
UI payments provide an automatic counter-cyclical fiscal policy expansion that dampens
fluctuations in economic activity, which is often enhanced by temporary legislation.
Consequently, the UI system is said to be part of the automatic stabilization tools of the
government that boost economic output during recessions.
But a higher level of Unemployment Insurance benefits appears to increase the duration of
unemployment spells, thus increasing unemployment. One recent study, however, suggests that
this may be mostly due to a liquidity effect (i.e., UI benefits allow unemployed workers, who
would have to reduce consumption levels without benefits, to maintain consumption levels while
unemployed), which reduces the pressure to find a new job quickly, rather than to moral hazard
(i.e., disincentive effect) and concludes that the optimal level of UI benefits could be close to its
current level. Furthermore, the UI system may reduce the duration of unemployment spells of
individuals not eligible to receive UI benefits. Overall, the various studies indicate that the UI
system has an indeterminate effect on the unemployment rate.

Congressional Research Service

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

Contents
The State of the Labor Market Since 2007................................................................................... 1
Key Features of the UI Program .................................................................................................. 4
Unemployment Insurance as an Automatic Economic Stabilizer .................................................. 6
Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Labor Market ............................................................. 7
Effect on the Duration of Unemployment .............................................................................. 8
Effect on Post-Unemployment Labor Market Outcomes ...................................................... 10
Spillover Effects on the Uninsured ...................................................................................... 10
Effect on Job Quits.............................................................................................................. 11
Effect of the Method of Financing....................................................................................... 11
Concluding Remarks................................................................................................................. 11

Figures
Figure 1. Temporary Layoffs and Permanent Job Losses, 1967-2010 ........................................... 3
Figure 2. Unemployment Rate and Long-tern Unemployment Rate, 1948-2010........................... 4

Tables
Table 1. Composition of the Unemployed.................................................................................... 2

Contacts
Author Contact Information ...................................................................................................... 12

Congressional Research Service

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

n December 2010, Congress passed the Tax Relief, Unemployment Insurance
Reauthorization, and Job Creation Act of 2010 (P.L. 111-312), which among other things
I temporarily extended the Emergency Unemployment Compensation (EUC08) program at an
estimated cost of $56.5 billion—the eighth time EUC08 was extended.1 Before each vote, there
were calls from some to end the program, arguing that the Unemployment Insurance (UI)
program increases unemployment and does not stimulate the economy. It has been argued that UI
subsidizes unemployment and creates a disincentive to look for a job, thus increasing the duration
of unemployment. This would arguably increase the unemployment rate, reduce the production of
goods and services, and reduce economic growth.2 Others assert the traditional view that UI and
extending UI benefits during economic downturns serves as an economic stimulus, puts money
into the economy, and helps create jobs.3
Outlays for UI have increased from $41.7 billion in 2008 to $159.0 billion in 2010. Since
unemployment is likely to remain relatively high throughout 2011, further extensions of the
EUC08 program could be considered by the 112th Congress with a potentially significant effect on
the budget deficit.4 This report examines the effect of the Unemployment Insurance program on
the economy and the labor market.
The State of the Labor Market Since 2007
In the Current Population Survey, the government survey used to estimate the official
unemployment rate, individuals 16 years or older are classified into one of three labor force
states: employed, unemployed, and not in the labor force (NILF). An individual without a job is
considered unemployed if he has looked for a job in the past four weeks, otherwise he is
considered not in the labor force.5 Employed and unemployed make up the labor force.
Individuals can become unemployed because they lost their job and begin searching for a new
job, because they are new to the labor force (e.g., a recent school graduate) and begin looking for

1 EUC08 was created by the Supplemental Appropriations Act of 2008 (P.L. 110-252). This is the eighth time that
Congress has created a temporary federal program to extend unemployment insurance benefits during an economic
downturn.
2 See, for example, Alex M. Brill, Unemployment Insurance: Considerations for Extending Benefits, American
Enterprise Institute, Testimony before the Subcommittee on Income Security and Family Support of the Committee on
Ways and Means, April 10, 2008; James Sherk, Extended Unemployment Insurance Benefits: The Heritage Foundation
2010 Labor Boot Camp
, The Heritage Foundation, WebMemo no. 2759, Washington, DC, January 14, 2010,
http://www.heritage.org/Research/Labor/wm2759.cfm; and Robert Barro, “The Folly of Subsidizing Unemployment,”
The Wall Street Journal, August 30, 2010.
3 See, for example, Till von Wachter, “Unemployment Insurance and the Long-Term Effects of Layoffs,” Presentation
at the Economic Policy Institute, Washington, DC, May 25, 2010; and Andrea Orr, Extending Unemployment
Insurance is a Fiscally Responsible Thing To Do
, Economic Policy Institute, Washington, DC, May 28, 2010,
http://www.epi.org/analysis_and_opinion/entry/extending_unemployment_insurance_is_the_fiscally_responsible_thing
_to/.
4 The Blue Chip consensus forecast has the unemployment rate remaining at about 9% throughout 2011 (Blue Chip
Economic Indicators, vol. 36, no. 2 , February 10, 2011). The Federal Reserve Board forecasts that the unemployment
rate will be 8.8% to 9.0% in 2011 (minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee, January 25-26, 2011,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/fomcminutes20110126.pdf).
5 Research suggests that the unemployed are behaviorally different from individuals not in the labor force. See
Christopher J. Flinn and James J. Heckman, “Are Unemployment and Out of the Labor Force Behaviorally Distinct
Labor Force States?” Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 1, no. 1 (1983), pp. 28-42.
Congressional Research Service
1

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

a job, or because they begin looking for a job after a prolonged absence from the labor force.
How an individual becomes unemployed affects her eligibility for UI benefits.
People become unemployed for several reasons (see Table 1). Just before the onset of the 2007-
2009 recession (November 2007), about half of the unemployed were unemployed because their
job ended involuntarily through a temporary layoff (13.6%) or other employer action (36.9%)—
denoted as “job losers” in the table. By December 2010 (a year and a half after the end of the
recession), job losers accounted for over 60% of the unemployed. The share of the unemployed
who voluntarily left a job (“job leavers”) decreased from 10.6% in November 2007 to 6.3% in
December 2010. Individuals who were not in the labor force and then started looking for a job are
classified as unemployed; they are considered “reentrants” (who held a full-time job before) or
“new entrants” to the labor force. The proportion of the unemployed who are reentrants or new
entrants fell from 39% to 32% between November 2007 and December 2009.

Table 1. Composition of the Unemployed

November 2007
December 2010
Job losers
50.5
61.3
Temporary layoff
13.6
9.6
Permanent job loss
36.9
51.7
Job leavers
10.6
6.3
Reentrants 29.6
23.4
New entrants
9.3
9.0
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The proportion of the unemployed on temporary layoff has not followed the same pattern over the
2007-2009 recession as it has over previous recessions. Figure 1 displays the trend in the
proportion of the unemployed on temporary layoff (the bottom heavy line) and permanent job
losers (the top thin line). In recessions before 2000, temporary layoffs would increase
dramatically (or spike) in the recession and then rapidly decline during the subsequent recovery
(this pattern was somewhat muted during the 1990-1991 recession). During the 2007-2009
recession, there was no spike in the percentage of the unemployed on temporary layoff—the
percentage actually decreased during the recession.
Permanent job losers as a percentage of the unemployed increased to an unprecedented extent
during the 2007-2009 recession (the increase during this recession was larger than during any
previous recession after 1967). The number of unemployed experiencing a permanent job loss
increased by 217% between December 2007 and June 2009 (the official end of the recession).
Congressional Research Service
2

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

Figure 1. Temporary Layoffs and Permanent Job Losses, 1967-2010
60
50
d 40
e
oy
pl
m

Une 30
of
ge
ta
n
e
rc
e
P
20
10
0
7
9
1
3
5
7
9
1
3
5
7
9
1
3
5
7
9
1
3
5
7
9
6
6
7
7
7
7
7
8
8
8
8
8
9
9
9
9
9
0
0
0
0
0
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
an-
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
J
Recession
Permanent Job Loss
Temporary Layoff

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
The absence of a spike in temporary layoffs in recessions after 1990 may help explain why recent
economic recoveries were characterized as jobless. Before 1990, after the end of a recession
temporarily laid-off workers were typically recalled to work by their former employers fairly
quickly, thus reducing the unemployment rate. Those who permanently lost their jobs would, in
most cases, eventually find a new job, thus helping to gradually reduce the unemployment rate
during a recovery. After 1990, it appears that as temporary layoffs became less important to the
rise in unemployment during the recession, recalls to former employers have had a much smaller
effect on the fall in unemployment during the recovery.
Another distinguishing characteristic of the 2007-2009 recession is the high proportion of the
unemployed who have been out of work for more than 26 weeks (see Figure 2).6 The percentage
of long-term unemployed attained a post-WWII high shortly after the end of the 2007-2009
recession (see the dashed line in Figure 2)—over 40% of the unemployed have been jobless for
26 or more weeks since July 2009. Part of this increase can be explained by the large increase in
the ratio of unemployed to job openings. Before the 2007-2009 recession there were about 1.7
unemployed workers per job opening.7 By July 2009 (the first month after the end of the

6 For more information on the long-term unemployed, see CRS Report R41179, Long-Term Unemployment and
Recessions
, by Gerald Mayer and Linda Levine.
7 The number of unemployed workers per job opening is calculated using Bureau of Labor Statistics data on the
number of unemployed (from the Employment Situation reports) and the number of job openings (from the Job
Openings and Labor Turnover Survey). Both are available at http://www.bls.gov. For more information, see Mark
deWolf and Katherine Klemmer, “Job Openings, Hires, and Separations Fall During the Recession,” Monthly Labor
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
3

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

recession), there were over 6 unemployed workers per job opening; the figure was 4.7 in
December 2010.8 During the 2001 recession and subsequent recovery, the number of unemployed
workers per job opening never surpassed 2.2.
Figure 2. Unemployment Rate and Long-tern Unemployment Rate, 1948-2010
12%
10%
8%
e
c

For
bor
La
6%
of
ge
a
nt
e
rc
e
P

4%
2%
0%
Jan-48 Jan-52 Jan-56 Jan-60 Jan-64 Jan-68 Jan-72 Jan-76 Jan-80 Jan-84 Jan-88 Jan-92 Jan-96 Jan-00 Jan-04 Jan-08
Recessions
Unemployment Rate
Long-term Unemployment Rate

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Key Features of the UI Program
The Unemployment Insurance (UI) program is a joint federal-state program that is financed by
federal and state payroll taxes.9 The program incorporates three levels of benefits:
• regular Unemployment Compensation (UC) in which the federal government
provides broad guidelines for benefits coverage and eligibility, and benefit
determination, with the specifics left to the states;

(...continued)
Review, vol. 133, no. 5 (May 2010), pp. 36-44.
8 Over the course of the 2007-2009 recession, the number of job openings fell by almost half and in December 2010
still remained about 30% below the November 2007 level.
9 For more details on financing, see CRS Report RS22077, Unemployment Compensation (UC) and the Unemployment
Trust Fund (UTF): Funding UC Benefits
, by Julie M. Whittaker.
Congressional Research Service
4

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

• the Extended Benefit program, which extends unemployment benefits to
unemployment workers in a state if certain adverse economic conditions exist in
that state; and
• the Emergency Unemployment Compensation (EUC08) program, which was
created by the Supplemental Appropriations Act of 2008 (P.L. 110-252) and is a
federal temporary program to extend unemployment compensation during the
recession and weak labor market.10
Over the past 40 years numerous studies have examined the effect of the Unemployment
Insurance program on the labor market. These studies have generally focused on the transitions
from one labor force state to another and how the UI program changes incentives for workers and
employers. The main features of the program that affect incentives regarding labor market
transitions are (1) eligibility based on reason for unemployment, (2) the potential duration of
benefit receipt, (3) the benefit level, and (4) the financing of the program.
Workers who have attained a minimum of wages and employment in covered work over a base
period are generally eligible for benefits if they become unemployed.11 The minimum and base
period varies among the states. Furthermore, different states have different rules regarding
workers who voluntarily leave an employer. For example, workers leaving an employer for good
cause are not disqualified from receiving benefits, but what constitutes good cause does vary
somewhat from state to state. Consequently, not all unemployed workers are eligible for UI
benefits and the proportion who are ineligible varies from state to state. In mid-December 2010,
about 14 million were unemployed and about 8.9 million people were claiming UI benefits.12
Regular UC benefits are generally payable for up to 26 weeks. Under the Extended Benefit
program, benefit receipt is automatically extended for up to an additional 13 weeks (20 weeks in
some cases) depending on the state’s economic conditions. Lastly, benefits are extended for an
additional 34 to 53 weeks under EUC08 depending on a state’s economic conditions.13
Unemployment compensation benefits are generally based on a worker’s wages in covered
employment over a base period.14 The minimum and maximum benefit level varies from state to
state, but within the minimum and maximum, most state benefit formulas yield a benefit level
that replaces about half the average weekly wage up to the maximum benefit. The maximum
weekly benefit varies from state to state—from $235 in Mississippi to $625 in Massachusetts.15

10 For further details see CRS Report RL33362, Unemployment Insurance: Programs and Benefits, by Katelin P. Isaacs
and Julie M. Whittaker; and CRS Report RL34251, Federal Programs Available to Unemployed Workers, coordinated
by Katelin P. Isaacs.
11 See U.S. Department of Labor, Employment and Training Administration, Comparison of State Unemployment
Insurance Laws
, available at http://www.unemploymentinsurance.doleta.gov.
12 The number of unemployed is reported in U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, The Employment
Situation, December 2010
, News Release, January 7, 2011; and the number claiming UI benefits is reported in U.S.
Department of Labor, Employment and Training Administration, Unemployment Insurance Weekly Claims Report,
News Release, December 30, 2010.
13 See appendix A in CRS Report RL33362, Unemployment Insurance: Programs and Benefits, by Katelin P. Isaacs
and Julie M. Whittaker for a summary of the potential duration of UC receipt.
14 See CRS Report RL33362, Unemployment Insurance: Programs and Benefits, by Katelin P. Isaacs and Julie M.
Whittaker.
15 Department of Labor, Employment and Training Administration, Significant Provisions of State Unemployment
Insurance Laws Effective January 2011, http://www.workforcesecurity.doleta.gov/unemploy/content/sigpros/2010-
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
5

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

The maximum weekly benefit is close to or less than the average weekly wage in many states,
suggesting that the wage replacement rate is less than 50% for many unemployed workers,
especially those who had higher earnings. For the U.S., the average weekly benefit is about
34.2% of the average weekly wage; this ratio varies from 25.8% in Louisiana to 53.9% in
Hawaii.16 In calculating the benefit level, all states disregard some earnings during unemployment
to provide some incentive to recipients to accept short-time or part-time employment while
searching for permanent employment. The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009
(P.L. 111-5) created Federal Additional Compensation (FAC), which provided a $25 weekly
benefit supplement to UI recipients. The authorization for the benefit supplement expired in May
2010.
The regular UC program is funded at the federal and state levels by a tax on payroll. The state
payroll tax is experience rated in that an employer’s tax rate is based on the amount of benefits
paid to former employees, up to a maximum established by state law. Because of the maximum
rate, the experience rating is said to be imperfect—the marginal tax rate does not increase as the
amount of benefits paid to former employees increases. Furthermore, the federal tax is 0.8% on
the first $7,000 of earnings ($56 per worker), which has not changed since 1983. It has been
argued that this imperfect experience rating could provide an incentive to some firms to layoff
workers.
Unemployment Insurance as an Automatic
Economic Stabilizer

Aggregate Unemployment Insurance benefit payments increase automatically during recessionary
periods as the unemployment rate increases and decreases during economic expansions. UI
payments provide an automatic counter-cyclical fiscal policy expansion that dampens fluctuations
in economic activity, which is often enhanced by temporary legislation (e.g., EUC08).
Consequently, the UI system is part of the automatic stabilization tools of the government that
boost economic activity during recessions.
Over the past 40 years, several studies have examined the impact of the UI system on the
economy. A 1991 study prepared for the Department of Labor summarized much of the early
scholarly literature.17 On average, the early studies estimate that the decline in gross domestic
product (GDP) during a recession would have been about 15% greater if the UI system had not
existed. Based on simulations using an econometric model of the U.S. economy, the authors of
the study conclude that the effect of the UI system on the economy was two-thirds as large in the
1980s as it was in the 1970s. Their simulations, however, were based only on the regular UI
program and did not consider the extended benefits program.

(...continued)
2019/January2011.pdf.
16 See Department of Labor, Employment and Training Administration, Unemployment Insurance Data Summary, 3rd
Quarter 2010, http://www.workforcesecurity.doleta.gov/unemploy/content/data_stats/datasum10/DataSum_2010_3.pdf.
17 Bruce H. Dunson, S. Charles Maurice, and Gerald P. Dwyer, The Cyclical Effects of the Unemployment Insurance
(UI) Program: Final Report
, Department of Labor, Unemployment Insurance Occasional Paper 91-3, Washington, DC,
1991.
Congressional Research Service
6

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

Subsequent studies reach different conclusions. In a study using a different econometric model,
Lawrence Chimerine, Theodore Black, and Lester Coffey find that the GDP declines during
recessions would have been 17% deeper in the absence of the UI program.18 They further find
that the stabilizing effectiveness of UI has not diminished since the 1970s.
In a more recent study, Wayne Vroman examines the stabilization role of the UI program during
the 2007-2009 recession using a third econometric model.19 He finds that the UI program (regular
and extended) closed 18.3% of the GDP shortfall caused by the recession. He also finds that the
extended benefits through the Extended Benefits program and EUC08 played an important role in
this stabilization effect.
Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Labor
Market

Changes in the rates of transition between the labor force states will affect the unemployment
rate, and the UI system can affect these transition rates. Many analysts have focused solely on the
behavior of individuals. For example, in his 1976 Nobel lecture, Milton Friedman argued that the
natural rate of unemployment was increasing, due, in part, to unemployment insurance reducing
the incentive of the unemployed to seek work.20 This suggests that the effects of the UI program
fall on workers or on the supply-side of the labor market. Other scholars have suggested some of
the features of UI financing can also affect employers or the demand-side of the labor market.
On the supply-side of the labor market, the standard economic model used to analyze the effect of
UI is the job search model. The model postulates that an unemployed worker searches for a job
and accepts a job offer if the wage offered exceeds her reservation wage. The reservation wage is
the lowest wage an unemployed worker is willing to accept and is influenced by income received
while unemployed (e.g., public assistance, unemployment compensation, asset income, and
access to credit) and by income of other family members. An individual’s efforts looking for a job
affect the rate at which job offers arrive and the wage rate offered. The receipt of UI benefits
tends to increase the reservation wage, which in turn can decrease the probability that a wage
offer will exceed the reservation wage, and it could reduce job search effort. The state of the
economy can affect the rate at which wage offers are received and affect job search effort.
Through these effects, UI benefits are said to have an disincentive effect on a worker’s job search
and thus increase the duration of unemployment (the length of time unemployed). This duration
effect is often cited as an example of moral hazard—that insuring a worker against the income
loss due to unemployment actually increases unemployment. For example, Jonathan Gruber

18 Lawrence Chimerine, Theodore S. Black, and Lester Coffey, Unemployment Insurance as an Economic Stabilizer:
Evidence of Effectiveness Over Three Decades
, Department of Labor, Unemployment Insurance Occasional Paper 99-
8, Washington, DC, 1999.
19 Wayne Vroman, The Role of Unemployment Insurance as an Automatic Stabilizer During a Recession, Department
of Labor, ETAOP 2010-10, Washington, DC, November 16, 2010.
20 Milton Friedman, “Nobel Lecture: Inflation and Unemployment,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 85, no. 3
(1977), pp. 451-472.
Congressional Research Service
7

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

observes that “UI has a significant moral hazard cost in terms of subsidizing unproductive
leisure.”21
Effect on the Duration of Unemployment
Many of the studies examining the effect of UI benefits on the duration of unemployment focus
on the rate at which individuals leave unemployment.22 Furthermore, most studies use
administrative UI data, which have accurate data on the level of UI benefits, the previous wage
rate, and the length of time benefits are received. The studies generally find that a 10% increase in
UI benefits (measured as the ratio of the benefit payment to the wage before unemployment and
called the replacement rate) leads to an increase in the duration of unemployment by 0.5 to 1.5
weeks.23 Work by Alan Krueger and Andreas Mueller suggests that the reason for the lengthened
unemployment spell is due to the inverse relationship between time spent looking for a job and UI
benefit generosity.24
The potential duration of UI receipt may also affect the length of time unemployed. A few studies
have examined how extended benefits affect the duration of unemployment, and all report that
extending the potential duration in which a recipient can collect UI benefits increases the amount
of time the average recipient receives benefits.25 There is no consensus on the magnitude of the
impact, however, with some suggesting a 13-week extension of benefits increases unemployment
by one week and others suggesting up to a 2.5-week increase. Rob Valletta and Katherine Kuang,
however, find that unemployment durations after December 2007 increased similarly for both
unemployed workers receiving UI benefits and those unemployed ineligible for UI benefits.26
This suggests that extended UI and EUC08 may have had a limited impact on lengthening the
duration of unemployment spells in the 2007-2009 recession.
Many unemployment spells begin with the worker being laid off because of slack demand for the
employer’s output. In the past, many laid-off workers were recalled by their former employer
after receiving UI benefits for a period of time. Research suggests that the recall expectations of
UI recipients affects their job search behavior and thus the likelihood of finding a new job. For

21 Jonathan Gruber, Public Finance and Public Policy, 2nd ed. (New York: Worth, 2007), p. 395.
22 Technically, these studies employ “hazard” models that estimate the effects of characteristics of the individual, the
economy, and UI benefits on the hazard rate—the probability of leaving unemployment at a point in time given being
unemployed up to that time.
23 See, for example, Raj Chetty, “Moral Hazard versus Liquidity and Optimal Unemployment Insurance,” Journal of
Political Economy
, vol. 116, no. 2 (2008), pp. 173-234; Bruce D. Meyer, “Unemployment Insurance and
Unemployment Spells,” Econometrica, vol. 58, no. 4 (July 1990), pp. 757-782; and Gary Solon, “Work Incentive
Effects of Taxing Unemployment Benefits,” Econometrica, vol. 53, no. 2 (March 1985), pp. 295-306.
24 Alan B. Krueger and Andreas Mueller, “Job Search and Unemployment Insurance: New Evidence from Time Use
Data,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 94, no. 3-4 (April 2010), pp. 298-307. Since UI receipt is not recorded in the
data, Krueger and Mueller had to infer UI eligibility based on the reason for unemployment and part-time/full-time
status on the previous job, which could affect their finding.
25 See Lawrence F. Katz and Bruce D. Meyer, “The Impact of the Potential Duration of Unemployment Benefits on the
Duration of Unemployment,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 41, no. 1 (February 1990), pp. 45-72; David Card and
Phillip B. Levine, “Extended Benefits and the Duration of UI Spells: Evidence from the New Jersey Extended Benefit
Program,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 78 (2000), pp. 107-138; and Stepan Jurajda and Frederick J. Tannery,
“Unemployment Durations and Extended Unemployment Benefits in Local Labor Markets,” Industrial and Labor
Relations Review
, vol. 56, no. 2 (January 2003), pp. 324-348.
26 Rob Valletta and Katherine Kuang, “Extended Unemployment and UI Benefits,” FRBSF Economic Letter, no. 2010-
12, April 19, 2010.
Congressional Research Service
8

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

example, Lawrence Katz and Bruce Meyer found that those expecting to be recalled were much
less likely to find a new job than those who had no recall expectations.27 Furthermore, those
expecting to be recalled were much more likely to leave unemployment by being recalled by their
former employer. Unemployment due to temporary layoffs, however, now appears to be less
significant than in the past. Since the recovery of the 2007-2009 recession could be characterized
as a jobless recovery like the previous two recessions, recall by a former employer may be
unlikely and unemployment durations could remain long.28
A job loss is accompanied by earnings loss and a reduction of income. Jonathan Gruber estimated
that in the absence of unemployment compensation, the consumption of the unemployed would
fall by 22% because of reduced income.29 This potential fall in consumption is over three times
the actual fall in consumption of the unemployed with unemployment compensation (6.8%).30
Gruber uses his research findings and calculates that the socially optimal replacement rate for UI
benefits would probably be considerably less than the average replacement rate of individuals in
his sample (42.6%) under what he considers plausible values of individuals’ attitudes toward risk.
Subsequent research, however, suggests that the values for risk attitudes considered plausible by
Gruber are probably too low.31 Consequently, the optimal UI replacement rate (the ratio of the
benefit payment to the wage before unemployment) may be closer to the average of 43%.
One of the possible reasons for the large consumption smoothing effect of UI is the unemployed
are liquidity constrained—that is, they do not have access to assets, loans, or other income to help
smooth their consumption over bad times. Furthermore, this could be an alternate explanation for
the effect UI benefits have on the duration of unemployment. The primary explanation is usually
one of moral hazard—the “price” of leisure is reduced so individuals work less and increase their
leisure.32 Raj Chetty examined the role of these two alternatives in explaining why UI benefits
increase the length of time unemployed.33 He finds that a 10% increase in the UI benefit would
decrease the conditional probability of leaving unemployment by 5.3% (lengthen an
unemployment spell by about one week). He further estimates that the liquidity effect accounts
for about 60% of the UI effect on lengthening unemployment durations. This result has
implications for the effect of the UI program on social welfare. Chetty concludes that UI benefits
have a welfare-enhancing consumption smoothing effect (i.e., allows the unemployed to maintain

27 Lawrence F. Katz and Bruce D. Meyer, “Unemployment Insurance, Recall Expectations, and Unemployment
Outcomes,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 105, no. 4 (November 1990), pp. 973-1002.
28 For more information on jobless recoveries, see CRS Report R40798, Unemployment and Employment Trends
Before and After the End of Recessions
, by Linda Levine.
29 Jonathan Gruber, “The Consumption Smoothing Benefits of Unemployment Insurance,” American Economic
Review
, vol. 87, no. 1 (March 1997), pp. 192-205.
30 This is consistent with two recent studies showing that UI and the temporary expansion enacted in ARRA were very
effective in reducing poverty among unemployed workers. See Wayne Vroman, “The Great Recession, Unemployment
Insurance and Poverty,” presented at conference on Reducing Poverty and Economic Distress after ARRA,
Washington, DC, January 15, 2010 (revised April 2010); and Arloc Sherman, Despite Deep Recession and High
Unemployment, Government Efforts—Including the Recovery Act—Prevented Poverty from Rising in 2009, New
Census Data Show
, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, Washington, DC, January 5, 2011.
31 Robert B. Barsky, F. Thomas Juster, and Miles S. Kimball, et al., “Preference Parameters and Behavioral
Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement Study,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol.
112, no. 2 (May 1997), pp. 537-579.
32 In economic terms, UI induces a substitution effect by distorting the relative price of leisure and consumption, thus
reducing the incentive to look for a job.
33 Raj Chetty, “Moral Hazard versus Liquidity and Optimal Unemployment Insurance,” Journal of Political Economy,
vol. 116, no. 2 (2008), pp. 173-234.
Congressional Research Service
9

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

consumption levels) and a welfare-reducing moral hazard effect (i.e., work disincentive effect)
and suggests that a replacement rate of 50% is near to the optimal economic welfare enhancing
level.34
Effect on Post-Unemployment Labor Market Outcomes
The receipt of UI benefits allows unemployed workers additional leeway in their search for new
employment. Consequently, it could reasonably be expected that the quality of the new
employment would be positively affected by the receipt of UI benefits. Few studies, however,
have examined this possible effect; two post-unemployment outcomes have been examined: the
post-unemployment wage and the duration of the post-unemployment job.
While not definitive, research has suggested that UI benefits have a positive effect on post-
unemployment wages. Ronald Ehrenberg and Ronald Oaxaca found that the receipt of UI had a
positive effect on the post-unemployment wages of older workers but not younger workers (i.e.,
under 25 years of age).35 John Addison and McKinley Blackburn also find a positive effect on
post-unemployment wages, but the effect is not statistically different from zero.36
One study examined the effect of UI benefits on the duration of the post-unemployment job.
Mario Centeno estimates that a 10% increase in UI benefits increases the duration of subsequent
employment by about two weeks.37
These results are consistent with the argument that UI increases labor productivity and facilitates
the efficient allocation of resources. In a model of the U.S. economy, Daron Acemoglu and
Robert Shimer show UI may encourage workers to seek higher productivity jobs and encourage
firms to create these jobs.38 They further show that these positive effects of UI benefits outweigh
the standard moral hazard costs (i.e., lengthened unemployment duration). They suggest “that a
decrease in the generosity of UI from its current U.S. level would not only decrease welfare but
also reduce the level of output.”39
Spillover Effects on the Uninsured
Most of the studies examining the effects of the UI program have limited the focus to insured
individuals—unemployed workers receiving UI benefits or workers who would be potentially
eligible to receive benefits if they were to become unemployed. Theoretical models of the labor
market suggest that the effects of the UI program could spill over and affect unemployed workers

34 Ibid., p. 221.
35 Ronald G. Ehrenberg and Ronald L. Oaxaca, “Unemployment Insurance, Duration of Unemployment, and
Subsequent Wage Gain,” American Economic Review, vol. 66, no. 5 (December 1976), pp. 754-766.
36 John T. Addison and McKinley L. Blackburn, “The Effects of Unemployment Insurance on Postunemployment
Earnings,” Labour Economics, vol. 7, no. 1 (January 2000), pp. 21-53.
37 Mario Centeno, “The Match Quality Gains from Unemployment Insurance,” Journal of Human Resources, vol. 39,
no. 3 (Summer 2004), pp. 839-863.
38 Daron Acemoglu and Robert Shimer, “Productivity Gains from Unemployment Insurance,” European Economic
Review
, vol. 44 (2000), pp. 1195-1224.
39 Ibid., p. 1196.
Congressional Research Service
10

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

who are not covered by the program.40 One study has empirically examined this issue and finds
that a 10% increase in the UI benefit leads to about a one week reduction in the unemployment
spell of an uninsured unemployed worker.41 One possible explanation for this finding is the
chances an uninsured unemployed worker finds a job may increase as the insured unemployed
reduce their effort searching for a new job.
Effect on Job Quits
Individuals quitting a job without good cause may be ineligible to receive UI benefits for part or
all of their unemployment spell. Some studies have examined the effect of the UI program on
workers’ quit behavior. In a study examining this feature of the UI program, Gary Solon found
that the disqualification of quitters from receiving UI benefits has no discernable impact on quit
rates.42
Effect of the Method of Financing
The UI program is financed primarily by a payroll tax on employers.43 At the state level, the tax is
experience rated, but the experience rating is imperfect and the tax does not increase uniformly as
the number of compensated unemployed rises. This feature of financing can provide an incentive
to firms to hoard workers (i.e., hold an excess inventory of workers) in good times and
temporarily lay them off during economic downturns. Using data from the 1980s, David Card and
Phillip Levine find a negative correlation between the degree of experience rating and the rate of
temporary layoffs.44 They further find that increases in the degree of experience rating are
associated with a dampening of seasonal fluctuations in temporary layoffs.
Temporary layoffs generally increase dramatically over the course of a recession. During the
2007-2009 recession, however, the proportion of the unemployed on temporary layoff actually
decreased slightly (from 12.6% in December 2007 to 11.8% in June 2009). It is possible that the
role of imperfect experience rating in increasing unemployment may be somewhat less important
now than it has been in the past.
Concluding Remarks
Evidence is mounting that the labor market behaved differently during and after the 2007-2009
recession from recessions before 1990. The percentage of unemployed on temporary layoffs did
not spike in the recent recession while the percentage with permanent job losses greatly

40 See, for example, James W. Albrecht and Bo Axell, “An Equilibrium Model of Search Unemployment,” Journal of
Political Economy
, vol. 92, no. 5 (1984), pp. 824-840.
41 Phillip B. Levine, “Spillover Effects Between the Insured and Uninsured Unemployed,” Industrial and Labor
Relations Review
, vol. 47, no. 1 (October 1993), pp. 73-86.
42 Gary Solon, “The Effects of Unemployment Insurance Eligibility Rules on Job Quitting Behavior,” Journal of
Human Resources
, vol. 19, no. 1 (Winter 1984), pp. 118-126.
43 For more details, see CRS Report RL33362, Unemployment Insurance: Programs and Benefits, by Katelin P. Isaacs
and Julie M. Whittaker.
44 David Card and Phillip B. Levine, “Unemployment Insurance Taxes and the Cyclical and Seasonal Properties of
Unemployment,” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 53 (January 1994), pp. 1-29.
Congressional Research Service
11

.
The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on the Economy and the Labor Market

increased. Furthermore, the proportion of the labor force who have been unemployed for 26
weeks or more has reached a post-WWII high. Some analysts have suggested that the UI system
has contributed to the current labor market problems of unemployed workers and high
unemployment rates.
The UI system is part of the automatic stabilization tools of the government that boost economic
output and employment during recessions. But a higher level of Unemployment Insurance
benefits appears to increase the duration of unemployment spells, thus increasing unemployment.
One recent study, however, suggests that this may be mostly due to a liquidity effect (i.e., UI
benefits allow unemployed workers, who would have to reduce consumption levels without
benefits, to maintain consumption levels while unemployed), which reduces the pressure to find a
new job quickly, rather than to moral hazard (i.e., disincentive effect) and concludes that the
optimal level of UI benefits could be close to its current level. Furthermore, the UI system may
reduce the duration of unemployment spells of individuals not eligible to receive UI benefits.
Research also suggests that it is possible the UI program increases productivity by allowing
unemployed workers the opportunity to search for and find high productivity jobs. Overall, the
various studies indicate that the UI system has an indeterminate effect on the unemployment rate.

Author Contact Information

Thomas L. Hungerford

Specialist in Public Finance
thungerford@crs.loc.gov, 7-6422


Congressional Research Service
12