The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the
Price of Oil

James K. Jackson
Specialist in International Trade and Finance
March 2, 2011
Congressional Research Service
7-5700
www.crs.gov
RL34686
CRS Report for Congress
P
repared for Members and Committees of Congress

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

Summary
Rapid changes in the price of oil and the impact of such price changes on economies around the
globe have attracted considerable attention. In mid-2008 as the price of oil rose to unprecedented
heights and then dropped sharply, the international exchange value of the dollar fell and then rose
relative to a broad basket of currencies. For some, these two events seem to indicate a cause and
effect relationship between changes in the price of oil and changes in the value of the dollar.
Despite common perceptions that there is a direct cause and effect relationship between changes
in the international exchange value of the dollar and the price of oil, an analysis of data during
recent periods indicates that changes in the price of oil are driven by changes in the demand for
oil that is different from the supply of oil, rather than changes in the value of the dollar. The rapid
increase in oil prices in early 2011 reflects rising demand for oil and other commodities and
uncertainty in global markets keyed to political turmoil in North Africa and the Middle East.
This report analyzes the relationship between the dollar and the price of oil and how the two
might interact. While the data do not support a strong cause and effect relationship between the
value of the dollar and the price of oil, there likely are various channels through which changes in
the price of oil and in the value of the dollar may be indirectly correlated. The data also indicate
that an increase in the demand for crude oil that exceeded the increase in the supply of oil and a
laggardly pace in oil production capacity likely are among the main factors behind the sharp run
up in the price of oil that occurred over the first seven months of 2008. The rise in oil prices also
affected the U.S. trade deficit. That impact lessened as the price of oil plummeted and as a drop in
economic activity reduced demand for oil imports. This report provides an assessment of the
impact a range of prices of imported oil could have on the U.S. trade deficit.

Congressional Research Service

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

Contents
Overview .................................................................................................................................... 1
The Dollar and the Price of Oil.................................................................................................... 3
Real and Nominal Oil Prices ................................................................................................. 3
Major Currencies .................................................................................................................. 5
The Price of Oil .......................................................................................................................... 9
Oil Exchanges....................................................................................................................... 9
Oil Demand and Supply ...................................................................................................... 10
The International Exchange Value of the Dollar......................................................................... 13
Capital Flows...................................................................................................................... 14
U.S. Financial Balance ........................................................................................................ 14
Foreign Exchange Market ................................................................................................... 16
The U.S. Trade Deficit ........................................................................................................ 17
Conclusions .............................................................................................................................. 19

Figures
Figure 1. Real and Nominal Crude Oil Price Indexes, 1970-2010 ................................................ 4
Figure 2. Crude Oil Real Price Index and Broad Real Dollar Index,1999-2010 ............................ 5
Figure 3. Crude Oil Real Price Index and Real Dollar/Euro Index, 1999-2010 ............................. 7
Figure 4. Crude Oil Real Price Index and Real Yen/Dollar Index, 1999-2010............................... 8
Figure 5. Crude Oil Real Price index and Real Dollar/Pound Index, 1999-2010 ........................... 8
Figure 6. Change in Oil Demand by Major Area, 2005 to 2009.................................................. 12
Figure 7. Change in Oil Supply by Major Area, 2005 to 2009.................................................... 13

Tables
Table 1. World Oil Demand and Supply, 2005-2010 .................................................................. 11
Table 2. Flow of Funds of the U.S. Economy, 1996-2010 .......................................................... 15
Table 3. Foreign Exchange Market Turnover ............................................................................. 17
Table 4. Estimates of the Impact on the U.S. Trade Deficit Associated With Various Prices
for Crude Oil and Changes in Oil Import Volumes.................................................................. 19

Contacts
Author Contact Information ...................................................................................................... 21

Congressional Research Service

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

Overview
To most observers, it seems apparent that the rise in the price of oil1 and the decline in the
exchange value of the dollar often are interconnected events, or that there is some cause and
effect relationship between the two.2 Since oil is priced in dollars, this line of reasoning goes, as
the exchange value of the dollar declines, the purchasing power of oil producers also falls, which,
in turn, prods oil producers to reduce their supplies to the market in order to push up the market
price of oil and restore their purchasing power. This line of thinking is not unreasonable,
considering various incidents, most notably 1973 and 1979, in which the price of oil rose sharply
in response to actions taken by members of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries
(OPEC)3 group of oil producers to increase the market price of oil. Indeed, OPEC’s stated
objective is to coordinate and unify petroleum policies among OPEC Countries, in order to secure
“fair and stable prices for petroleum producers; an efficient, economic and regular supply of
petroleum to consuming nations; and a fair return on capital to those investing in the industry.”
After reaching nearly $147 per barrel in August 2008, the price per barrel of oil dropped to less
than $40 per barrel by year-end 2008, before rising again through February 2011 to reach as high
as $120 per barrel at times. In response to the drop in oil prices in 2008, OPEC announced cuts in
production on three occasions: a cut of 500,000 barrels per day announced on September 1,
2008,4 a cut of 1.5 million barrels per day announced on October 25, 2008, and a cut of 2.2
million barrels per day announced on December 17, 2008. In February 2011, Saudi Arabia
increased oil production to calm market fears over political unrest in North Africa and the Middle
East, particularly concerns over the impact political turmoil on Libya could have on oil
production there.
An analysis of the data indicates that the rise and fall in oil prices that has been experienced since
2006 has not been driven primarily by a reduction in world supplies. Instead, the changes in oil
prices reflect a number of factors, including the slow-paced growth in oil production; an increase
in demand, most notably among the developing countries, that has outpaced the increase in
supply; and more recently market concerns related to political turmoil. Changes in the
international exchange value of the dollar, however, likely reflect a number of factors, including
changes in the demand for and supply of capital within the U.S. economy, the relative rate of
return on interest-sensitive assets, and expectations about the performance of the U.S. economy.
At the same time, some observers have argued that oil market speculators played an important
role in pushing up oil prices so quickly in 2008.5 A report issued on September 11, 2008, by the
Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC), however, concluded that market speculators
probably were not responsible for the rise in oil prices.6

1 CRS Report RL33521, Gasoline Prices: Causes of Volatility and Congressional Response, by Carl E. Behrens and
Carol Glover.
2 Merriman, Jane, “Weak Dollar Central to Oil Price Boom,” Reuters, September 26, 2007.
3 OPEC is comprised of Algeria, Angola, Ecuador, Indonesia, Iran, Iraq, Kuwait, Libya, Nigeria, Qatar, Saudi Arabia,
UAE, and Venezuela.
4 Reed, Stanley, “How Real is OPEC’s Production Cut?” BusinessWeek, September 11, 2008.
5 Masters, Michael W., Testimony before the Committee on Homeland Security and Governmental affairs, United
States Senate, May 20, 2008.
6 Mufson, Steven, “Speculators Did Not Raise Oil Prices, Regulator Says,” The Washington Post, September 12, 2008,
p. D1; Staff Report on Commodity Swap Dealers & Index Traders With Commission Recommendations, Commodity
Futures Trading Commission, September 2008.
Congressional Research Service
1

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

While data on exchange rates and on oil prices do not support the case for a strong cause and
effect relationship between the value of the dollar and the price of oil, there are a number of
channels through which changes in the price of oil and changes in the value of the dollar may be
indirectly correlated. In fact, an increase in the price of oil to offset the loss of purchasing power
that is associated with a depreciation in the value of the dollar can spark a chain of events that
could blunt or even nullify the rise in oil prices.
The pervasive nature of such commodities as oil, which serve as essential components in
economic growth, means that changes in the prices of those commodities affect the prices of a
broad range of goods, services, and economic activities.7 Indeed, according to the Census Bureau,
increases in the price of imported oil were a major factor in rising consumer prices in the United
States in the first six months of 2008. Similarly, rising oil prices in late 2010 and early 2011 have
pushed up the prices of other commodities. Rising consumer and commodity prices undermine
the exchange value of the dollar relative to other currencies and reduce the real incomes of
consumers, which can lead to a lower rate of economic growth. Slower economic growth, in turn,
lowers the demand for oil, thereby putting downward pressure on the price of oil, as occurred in
2009.8 Expectations about future economic growth and, therefore, about the demand for crude oil,
also can affect a broad range of investment decisions that might affect expectations about the
value of the dollar. The interaction between the price of oil and the value of the dollar is
complicated further by the way changes in the price of oil can affect the economic performance of
other nations and, therefore, have an impact on their respective currencies.9
According to Global Insight,10 a number of factors worked to put upward pressure on oil prices in
2007 and during the first half of 2008. These factors include both supply and demand issues as
well as geopolitical troubles in various countries, particularly Nigeria and Iran, that created
uncertainties in the market concerning the stability of oil supplies. A low rate of growth in oil
supplies relative to a higher rate of growth in the demand for oil has been cited as the most
important market factor behind the rise in oil prices. Saudi Arabia agreed to increase its
production of oil by 300,000 barrels per day in May 2008 and by an additional 200,000 barrels
per day in July 2008. Also, price movements in the oil market apparently were exaggerated
somewhat by trading in the oil futures market, and other producers, especially non-OPEC
producers, who had not increased their supply as had been projected. On the demand side,
continued strong growth in the demand for oil in Asia and the Middle East pushed the total
demand for oil to rise at a pace that has been faster than the rise in supplies. Demand in the
Middle East rose at double-digit rates as a result of a boom in construction and oil consumption.
In Asia, demand for oil grew rapidly in China, where the government subsidized the price of oil
to consumers and the government stockpiled oil to use as substitute for coal in the Beijing area
during the Olympics to reduce the level of air pollution.

7 CRS Report RL31608, The Effects of Oil Shocks on the Economy: A Review of the Empirical Evidence, by Marc
Labonte.
8 Clifford, Catherine, Oil at 5-month Low on Shrinking Demand. CNNMoney.com., September 5, 2008; Barr, Colin,
Why Cheaper Oil Signals Trouble. CNNMoney.com. September 4, 2008.
9 Dougherty, Carter, “Fears of European Slowdown Weaken the Euro.” The New York Times, August 9, 2008.
10 Market Analysis: Forecast Highlights, Global Insight, July 1, 2008.
Congressional Research Service
2

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

The Dollar and the Price of Oil
For many observers, there seems to be a direct cause and effect relationship between the
depreciation in the international exchange value of the dollar and the rise in the price of oil. These
observers argue that because oil is priced in dollars, a depreciation in the international exchange
value for the dollar against other major currencies erodes the purchasing power of oil producers.
The International Monetary Fund (IMF) has identified three channels through which a change in
the value of the dollar can affect a broad range of commodity prices, including the price of oil. A
change in the value of the dollar can affect commodity prices through (1) purchasing power and
cost channels; (2) asset channels in which changes in the value of the dollar affect the return on
dollar-denominated financial assets; and (3) a combination of effects, including changes in
monetary policy.11 As a result of these three effects, the IMF also estimates that among various
commodities, the linkage between changes in the value of the dollar and changes in commodity
prices is especially strong for oil and gold, because they are more suitable as a “store of value,” or
as a hedge against inflation.12 One explanation for this relationship is that oil market participants
and speculators may have adopted a rough rule of thumb over time concerning changes in the
value of the dollar and subsequent changes in the price of oil and vice versa. As a consequence
the statistical relationship between the two has been strengthened, because market participants
have acted on this informal rule. In late 2010 and early 2011, however, the rise in commodity
prices, including the price of oil, appear not to be related to the value of the dollar, since
commodity prices rose significantly in terms of all major currencies.
The past actions of OPEC oil producers may also have tended to strengthen the apparent linkage
between changes in the value of the dollar and changes in the price of oil as the producers have
acted in concert to adjust their output in order to alter the world price of oil. OPEC accounts for
just over 40% of the world output of crude oil, and the coordinated actions of its members can
affect world oil prices. In addition, one of OPEC’s stated goals is to secure a “fair and stable
price” for the oil the member countries produce; it is not unreasonable to assume that OPEC
members would respond to a loss in the purchasing power of the dollar by reducing their overall
level of production, or holding down the rate of increase in production in order to raise the market
price of oil.13
Real and Nominal Oil Prices
Figure 1 shows indexes of the nominal and real (adjusted for inflation) indexes of the price of
crude oil from 1970 to 2010. The figure shows the 1973 and 1979 price increases and the slide in
the real price of oil between 1980 and 1999. The indexes show the stark rise in real oil prices in
the 1970s as OPEC oil producers pushed up crude oil prices. Over the next decade, however, real
prices slowly moved downward to more moderate levels, due in part to an increase in crude oil
production by non-OPEC producers. Naturally, nominal prices increased in the 1970s as a result
of the rise in oil prices, but nominal prices rose at a slower pace than real prices as national

11 World Economic Outlook, the International Monetary Fund, April 2008. P. 46-50.
12 The IMF estimates that a 1 percent real depreciation in the value of the dollar would result in an increase of greater
than 1 percent in the price of oil over two years. Ibid., p. 50.
13 According to standard economic theory, a reduction in the market supply of a good relative to a given level of
demand will result in a higher market price for the good since the market demand would be chasing a smaller number
of goods (supply), which would tend to bid up the market price of the good.
Congressional Research Service
3



The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

governments focused economic policies on constraining inflation. Both real and nominal oil
prices began rising in 1999 as a result of an agreement signed in 1998 between OPEC members
and such non-OPEC producers as Mexico, Norway, Oman, and the Russian Federation to reduce
their supplies of oil. While OPEC’s production of crude oil declined by about 4% in 1999 from
that produced in 1998, production in 2000 increased by 6% to reach an average of 28 million
barrels per day. From 2000 to 2002, OPEC’s production of crude oil fell by about 9.5% to 25.6
million barrels per day. After 2002, OPEC’s crude oil production has increased every year,
reaching an average of 33.9 million barrels per day in 2009.
Figure 1. Real and Nominal Crude Oil Price Indexes, 1970-2010

Source: CRS, Energy Information Administration
Data for the fourth quarter of 2010 show that the real price of crude oil began rising during the
first quarter of 2009 and rose steadily throughout the period, reaching an average price of about
two-thirds of that reached during the peak period in 2008. On an annual basis, the average price
of oil, as measured by the spot price of Brent crude,14 rose from an average price of $54.42 per
barrel in 2005 to an average of $96.85 per barrel in 2008, or an increase of 78% in nominal terms.
During the same period, the dollar depreciated about 10% in real terms as measured against a
broad basket of currencies.15 From January 2008 to July 2008, the real price of oil increased by
another 38%, while the real broad dollar index depreciated by 1.7%. Relative to other major
currencies, the dollar depreciated about 7% against the Euro in real, or price adjusted terms on

14 Brent crude is the largest classification of crude oil. It is used to price two-thirds of internationally traded crude oil
supplies.
15 The broad dollar index is an index of the currencies of 26 largest U.S. trading partners weighted by the importance of
the country as a trading partner. For additional information, see Loretan, Mico, Indexes of the Foreign Exchange Value
of the Dollar, Federal Reserve Bulletin, Winter 2005. P. 1-8.
Congressional Research Service
4



The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

average from 2005 to 2008 and about 5.6% in the January to July period in 2008. Relative to the
Yen, the average value of the dollar depreciated about 15% between 2005 and 2008 in real terms,
and depreciated about 5% against the Yen in the first seven months of 2008. Against the British
Pound, the dollar depreciated about 8% in real terms between 2005 and 2008, and fell by about
3% in value in real terms in the first seven months of 2008. From 2009 through 2010, the dollar
has appreciated slightly against a broad basket of currencies in real terms and against the pound
and the euro, but depreciated against the yen in real terms.
Major Currencies
Figures 2 through 5 display indexes of the dollar relative to other currencies in real terms and an
index of the price of oil, also expressed in real terms, from the first quarter of 1999 through the
fourth quarter of 2010. Figure 2 shows the real broad dollar index, or an index of the dollar per a
unit of a grouping of 26 currencies in real terms compared with an index of the real price of crude
oil. A decline in the dollar index signifies a depreciation in the value of the dollar relative to the
broad group of other currencies. The data cast doubt on the argument that the price of oil
responded to offset the depreciation of the dollar. Compared with the currencies of the 26 largest
U.S. trading partners, the dollar has fluctuated slightly in real terms, compared with large swings
in the real price of oil.
Figure 2. Crude Oil Real Price Index and Broad Real Dollar Index,1999-2010

Source: Federal Reserve, Energy Information Administration
The devaluation of the dollar against the Euro from early 2006 to the end of 2008 led some
observers to speculate that oil producers would attempt to raise the price of oil to compensate for
the devalued purchasing power of the dollar relative to the Euro and that a devalued dollar would
be a disincentive for producers to explore and drill for new wells because of the loss of
Congressional Research Service
5

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

purchasing power. In addition, the devalued dollar makes oil cheaper for the Euro-area countries
and, therefore, oil consumption in the euro area should increase with an appreciation of the euro.
The decline in the exchange value of the dollar relative to the Euro also prompted some observers
to argue that oil should be priced in a currency other than the dollar.
Data through fourth quarter 2010, however, do not support the contention that Euro-area countries
increased their consumption of oil any faster than the United States due to the drop in the price of
oil that resulted from an appreciation of the euro relative to the dollar. Also, after some initial
adjustment, pricing oil in Euros, or some other currency, rather than in dollars would appear to
have no real effect on the demand and supply of oil in the market. Between the third quarter of
2009 and the third quarter of 2010, as the Euro generally depreciated relative to the dollar, oil
consumption of oil in Europe rose by 2.9% compared with an increase in consumption by the
United States of 4.1%. Pricing oil in dollars facilitates the smooth functioning of the oil market,
because the dollar is the most widely used currency in the world for pricing, or invoicing trade,
which facilitates the cross-border comparison of goods and services.16 Figure 3 shows an index
of crude oil prices in real terms and dollars per Euro in real terms, so that a rise in the dollar/Euro
index signifies an appreciation in the Euro relative to the dollar, or a depreciation in the value of
the dollar. The data support the argument that any loss in oil producers’ purchasing power arising
from a depreciation in the value of the dollar relative to the Euro was offset by a larger increase in
the price of oil, which may well provide an incentive to oil producers to expand their drilling and
exploration activities.

16 Goldberg, Linda S., and Cedric Tille, The International Role of the Dollar and Trade Balance Adjustment, NBER
Working Paper 12495, August 2006; and Goldberg, Linda S, and Cedric Tille, Macroeconomic Interdependence and
the International Role of the Dollar
, NBER Working Paper 13820, February 2008.
Congressional Research Service
6



The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

Figure 3. Crude Oil Real Price Index and Real Dollar/Euro Index, 1999-2010

Source: Federal Reserve, Energy Information Administration
Similar trends are seen in movements in the value of the dollar relative to the Yen and the British
Pound. Figure 4 shows the index of the Yen per dollar exchange rate, expressed in real terms and
the index of the real price of crude oil. In this figure, a decline in the index indicates an
appreciation in the value of the Yen relative to the dollar, since fewer Yen are required to buy a
dollar. Figure 5 shows the index for dollars per Pounds expressed in real terms and the index for
real crude oil prices. In this case, a rise in the dollar/Pound index indicates an appreciation in the
value of the Pound, since more dollars would be required to purchase a Pound. In both cases, the
relative movement in the real prices of foreign currency against the dollar has been small relative
to the increase in the real price of crude oil since 2004.
Congressional Research Service
7





The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

Figure 4. Crude Oil Real Price Index and Real Yen/Dollar Index, 1999-2010

Source: Federal Reserve, Energy Information Administration
Figure 5. Crude Oil Real Price index and Real Dollar/Pound Index, 1999-2010

Source: Federal Reserve, Energy Information Administration
Congressional Research Service
8

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

The Price of Oil
As indicated previously, the OPEC cartel of oil producers has acted in concert on occasion to alter
the supply of oil in the market in order to affect the price of oil and, therefore, the export earnings
of its members. In practice, OPEC oil producers, or other oil producers for that matter, do not
attempt to set the price of oil directly, but attempt to alter the supply of oil in the market relative
to a given level of expected demand and then rely on the market to search out the corresponding
price. The price of oil, then, reflects the actual level of demand and supply in the market, which is
reflected in the spot, or current, market, and the price of oil is affected by expectations about
demand and supply conditions and about production capacity, reflected in the futures market. In
addition, during times of economic or political instability, investors may well trade such
commodities as oil that they calculate will generate a return on their investment that exceeds such
traditional financial investments as stocks, bonds, or government securities.
Oil Exchanges
Similar to other commodities, oil is traded on specialized commodities exchanges. Most of this
trading is conducted by licensed brokers, who act on behalf of clients to buy and sell oil on the
spot market and in the futures and options markets.17 The major futures exchanges for oil are the
Intercontinental Exchange, located in London, which acquired the International Petroleum
Exchange in 2001, and the New York Mercantile Exchange (NYMEX). The New York Exchange
states that it is the world’s largest physical commodity futures exchange. The NYMEX operates
on the bid-ask system in which buy and sell transactions are executed between floor brokers. In
this process, buyers compete with each other by bidding up prices and sellers compete by bidding
prices down. Such markets are identified as price discovery markets, because the price of the
futures contract is determined through open bids. Futures contracts are firm commitments to
make or accept delivery of a specified quantity and quality of a commodity during a specified
month in the future at a price agreed upon at the time the contract is made. In the commodities
exchanges, futures contracts are traded in standardized units in a highly visible, extremely
competitive continuous open auction. The NYMEX reports that less than 1% of all oil futures
contracts take physical delivery; the remainder are settled by cash payments.
Although relatively little physical quantities of oil change hands in futures markets, the markets
serve as important sources of information about market conditions and provide mechanisms for
determining the price of oil in the global energy market. As a result, oil prices that are determined
in the futures market are useful in at least three ways.18 First, since the futures markets are
conducted in full public view, a broad assortment of traders, including producers, commercial
users, speculators, and financial institutions, make financial and production decisions based on
the prices that are determined in the market. Second, the prices that are generated in the futures
markets are publicly available and are used as reference points for physical trades in oil. Third,
because the markets are conducted on a bid-ask system with floor brokers, the prices react
quickly to new information about the supply and demand factors that are expected to influence
the price of oil.

17 For additional information, see CRS Report RL34555, Speculation and Energy Prices: Legislative Responses, by
Mark Jickling and Lynn J. Cunningham.
18 CRS Report RS22918, Primer on Energy Derivatives and Their Regulation, by Mark Jickling.
Congressional Research Service
9

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

Futures and options contacts are used by both buyers and sellers to reduce the risks inherent in
trading commodities.19 Factors that might cause an abrupt change in supply, demand, and price
such as international politics, war, changing economic patterns, and structural changes within the
energy industry have created uncertainty about market conditions. Such uncertainty, in turn, leads
to volatility in the market and creates risk for the market participants. The futures price, then,
represents the current market opinion of what the commodity will be worth at some time in the
future. Since the future price of a commodity can not be known with any certainty, buyers and
sellers attempt to lock in prices and profit margins in advance through the use of futures and
options contracts in order to hedge, or to reduce, their risks. The purpose of the hedge is to avoid
the risk of an abrupt change in market conditions and prices that could result in major losses for
buyers and sellers.
Since the spot price and the futures market price do not have a perfect relationship, there will
always be the potential for some profit or loss. Hedging, then, reduces exposure to risk for a
buyer or a seller by shifting part of the risk associated with the market price of a commodity to
investors who are willing to accept the risk in exchange for a profit opportunity. As indicated
above, most traders do not take physical delivery of the commodities they are trading, but hope to
profit by correctly anticipating future price trends, which some observers argue has been a factor
in driving high and volatile prices. Concerns over the impact of such trading on the oil market
spurred a number of legislative proposals during the 110th Congress.20
Unlike a futures contract, an options contract conveys a right, but not an obligation, to engage in a
transaction. There are two types of options, calls and puts. A call conveys the right, but not the
obligation, to the one holding the option to purchase the underlying futures contract at a specified
price up to a certain time. A put gives the owner of the option the right, but not the obligation, to
sell the underlying futures contract at a specified price up to a certain time. A call is purchased
when investors anticipate a rise in prices and a put is bought when investors expect neutral or
falling prices. When options are used in combination with futures contracts, investors can develop
strategies that cover virtually any risk profile, time horizon, or cost consideration.
Oil Demand and Supply
The data in Table 1 show the world demand and supply of petroleum in millions of barrels a day
on average by major area from 2004 through 2009, including the first three quarters of 2010. As
indicated in Figure 6, between 2005 and 2009, the demand for oil, or consumption, among all
consumers increased by 0.8%, rising from an average of 83.65 million barrels per day in 2005 to
an average of 84.33 million barrels per day in 2009. Data for 2009 indicate that world demand for
oil fell below the average for 2008 as economic growth slowed as a consequence of the financial
crisis and the global economic recession. Over the first three quarters of 2010, however, world
demand for oil increased by 2.4%, with demand among the developed economies increasing by
1.6% and demand increasing by 3.4% among the developing economies. The developed
economies, represented by the members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD),21 accounted for about 60% of world demand for oil. As a group, these

19 A Guide to Energy Hedging. New York Mercantile Exchange.
20 Ibid.
21 For additional information about the OECD, see CRS Report RS21129, Pharmaceutical Patent Term Extensions: A
Brief Explanation
, by Wendy H. Schacht and John R. Thomas.
Congressional Research Service
10

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

developed economies decreased their demand for oil every year between 2005 and 2008. Oil
demand fell in most countries and areas in 2008 as the pace of global economic activity slowed
from the faster pace in 2007. On average, oil demand among OECD countries fell by 3.6%
between 2007 and 2008, compared with a 3.6% increase in demand among non-OECD countries
over the same period. During the 2005-2009 period, demand for oil by the developed OECD
countries fell by 7.9% and by 9.8% in the United States. Among the developing countries, oil
demand between 2005 and 2009 increased by 13.6%, led by a 23.9% increase in demand by
China, although such demand started from a low base.
Table 1. World Oil Demand and Supply, 2005-2010
(million barrels per day)

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
2010
Quarter
Annual Average
1st
2nd
3rd
4th
Petroleum (Oil) Demand







OECD









United
States
20.80 20.69 20.68 19.50 18.77 18.82 19.01 19.49 NA
Other
OECD
15.61 15.63 28.44 28.05 26.95 27.21 26.44 27.29
Total
OECD
49.66 49.34 49.59 47.87 45.72 46.03 45.45 46.78
Non-OECD









China
6.72 7.20 7.58 7.83 8.32 8.88 9.31 8.89
Former
U.S.S.R.
4.07 4.21 4.27 4.35 4.21 4.31 4.33 4.48
Other
Non-OECD
23.20 23.88 24.84 25.72 26.08 26.20 27.27 27.35
Total
Non-OECD
33.99 35.29 36.70 37.90 38.6 39.39 40.91 40.72
Total World Demand
83.65 84.62 86.29 85.78 84.33 85.42 86.36 87.50










Petroleum (Oil) Supply






OECD









United
States
8.32 8.33 8.46 8.51 9.14 9.45 9.56 9.67
Other
OECD
13.56 13.26 13.03 12.43 11.95 11.93 11.55 11.20
Total
OECD
21.88 21.59 21.48 20.95 21.09 21.38 21.11 20.87
Non-OECD









OPEC
36.09 35.83 34.39 35.71 33.87 34.45 34.65 34.84
Former
U.S.S.R.
11.77 12.16 12.61 12.53 12.91 13.12 13.16 13.20
Other
Non-OECD
14.89 15.02 16.07 16.32 16.52 16.96 17.09 17.19
Total
Non-OECD
62.75 63.01 63.06 64.56 63.30 64.53 64.90 65.23
Total World Supply
84.63 84.60 84.54 85.51 84.39 85.90 86.02 86.10










Difference (demand less supply)
-0.98 0.02 1.75 0.27 -0.05 -0.48 0.34 1.40
Congressional Research Service
11



The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

Source: International Petroleum Monthly, December, 2010. Energy Information Administration. Table 2.1.
During the 2005-2009 period, oil supplies fell by 3.6% among the developed countries, or falling
by about half as much as the demand for oil among the developed countries, effectively
increasing their demand for oil on world markets. During the same five-year period, oil supplies
among the developing countries increased by 0.9%, led by an increase in supplies by developing
countries other than OPEC countries and Russia.
Figure 7 shows that world oil supplies fell by 2.8% over the period from 2005 to 2009, or by less
than the increase in the world demand for oil. During this period, oil supplies provided by U.S.
producers increased by nearly 10%, while oil production in other developed countries fell by
3.9%. At the same time, OPEC producers decreased their supply of oil by 6.2%, mostly during
the 2008-2009 period, and oil suppliers from other developing countries increased their supplies
by 0.9%. The shortfall between the change in demand and the change in supply was met by oil
that had been held in stocks elsewhere. The rising demand likely was an important factor in
pushing up the price of oil in the market and likely affected the pricing expectations of oil brokers
and traders in the futures market.
Figure 6. Change in Oil Demand by Major Area, 2005 to 2009

Source: Energy Information Administration
Congressional Research Service
12



The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil


Figure 7. Change in Oil Supply by Major Area, 2005 to 2009

Source: Energy Information Administration
The International Exchange Value of the Dollar
Although attention has focused on the international exchange value of the dollar for many years,
the general depreciation of the dollar since 2006 has drawn particular attention. As previously
stated, some observers have argued that the rise in the price of oil has occurred in part to offset
the decline in the purchasing power of oil producers as a result of the depreciation of the dollar
against other major currencies. According to standard economic theory, the international
exchange value of the dollar is determined by a complex interplay of demand for and supply of
goods and capital within the U.S. economy and the demand for and supply of dollars in
international currency markets. While dollar-related transactions generally are independent of
those transactions that determine the market price of oil, there may be channels through which
movements in the price of oil and changes in the value of the dollar may have spillover effects.
This is especially true for the price of oil, which has a far-ranging impact on the performance of
the U.S. economy and on global flows of dollars. Over time, such a connection may have become
more stylized in the minds of some observers who may link changes in the price of oil to changes
in the value of the dollar and vice versa. Such global capital flows, in turn, are facilitated by
liberalized international capital markets and floating exchange rates, which greatly expand the
amount of capital flows between countries. These flows also have sparked growth in the
development and the use of financial instruments that are designed to ease the international trade
of currencies and to provide investors, corporations, and financial services providers with a hedge
against unpredictable changes in the value of currencies.
Congressional Research Service
13

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

Capital Flows
Capital inflows also help bridge the gap in the United States between the amount of credit
demanded and the domestic supply of funds. A shortfall in the domestic supply of credit relative
to domestic demands for those funds tends to raise domestic interest rates and draws in capital
from abroad. Those inflows, in turn, help to keep U.S. interest rates below the level they likely
would reach without the inflows. The necessity to attract capital inflows, however, has
complicated the conduct of economic policy. As the Federal Reserve has lowered interest rates on
credit in order to stimulate economic activity and stem a slowdown in the economy, the lower
interest rates have blunted capital inflows as foreign investors have sought assets in other markets
where relative interest rates are higher.
Capital inflows, however, do allow the United States to spend beyond its means, including
financing its trade deficit, because foreigners have been willing to lend to the United States in the
form of exchanging goods, represented by U.S. imports, for such U.S. assets as stocks, bonds, and
U.S. Treasury securities. Such inflows put upward pressure on the dollar, because demand for
U.S. assets, such as financial securities, translates into demand for the dollar, since U.S. securities
are denominated in dollars. As demand for the dollar rises or falls according to overall demand
for dollar-denominated assets, the value of the dollar changes. These exchange rate changes, in
turn, have secondary effects on the prices of U.S. and foreign goods, which tend to alter the U.S.
trade balance. In addition, an increase in the U.S. rate of inflation tends to undermine the value of
the dollar relative to other currencies, which tends to shift demand from the dollar to other
currencies. At times, foreign governments have intervened in international capital markets to
acquire the dollar directly or to acquire Treasury securities in order to strengthen the value of the
dollar against particular currencies.
U.S. Financial Balance
The most common way of measuring capital inflows is through the U.S. balance of payments
accounts. According to standard economic theory, macroeconomic developments in the U.S.
economy are the major driving forces behind the magnitudes of capital flows, because the
macroeconomic factors determine the overall demand for and supply of credit in the economy.
Naturally, these macroeconomic conditions can be affected by changes in the price of oil, or by
changes in macroeconomic policies. To the extent that changes in the price of oil alter the basic
savings-investment relationship in the economy, such price changes could have long-lasting
impact on the economy and on the trade balance.
One way of viewing the interaction between capital inflows and the domestic demand and supply
of funds is through the domestic flow of funds accounts. These accounts measure financial flows
across sectors of the economy, tracking funds as they move from those sectors that supply the
capital through intermediaries to sectors that use the capital to acquire physical and financial
assets.22 Table 2 shows the major accounts in the net flow of funds in the U.S. economy from
1996 through the third quarter of 2010 The net flows show the overall financial position by
sector, whether that sector is a net supplier or a net user of financial capital in the economy. Since

22 Teplin, Albert M., The U.S. Flows of Funds Accounts and Their Uses, Federal Reserve Bulletin, July 2001, pp. 431-
441.
Congressional Research Service
14

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

the demand for funds in the economy as a whole must equal the supply of funds, a deficit in one
sector must be offset by a surplus in another sector.
Table 2. Flow of Funds of the U.S. Economy, 1996-2010
(billions of dollars)
Government
State and
Year Households
Businesses
Total
Local
Federal
ROW
1996 175.2 19.8
-196.8
-1.2
-195.6
137.9
1997 47.4 -18.3
-116.6
-47.5
-69.1
219.6
1998
128.0
-45.7 64.8 48.8 16.0
75.0
1999 -132.7 -62.6
115.3
9.9
105.4
231.7
2000
-371.0
-82.9 252.5 54.5 198.0
476.3
2001
-494.4
-82.9 233.4 35.4 198.0
485.4
2002 -304.0 8.7
-382.6
-95.6
-287.0
501.7
2003 -79.3 30.3
-546.3
-70.4
-476.4
529.4
2004 -67.9 136.8
-468.1
-33.0
-436.1
530.0
2005 -466.5 -44.8
-373.1
7.3
-380.4
712.1
2006 -512.2 -231.1
-188.9
76.1
-265.0
807.4
2007 70.5 -285.1
-345.0
-1.7
-343.3
638.5
2008 619.1 -1,003.1
-914.9
-137.3
-777.6
583.9
2009 273.8 211.9
-1,399.9
-85.1
-1,314.8
215.9
2010 I
392.5
262.0
-1,445.1
-39.5
-1,405.6
138.7
2010 II
1,091.0
12.6
-1,814.9
-48.4
-1,766.5
146.3
2010 III
252.7
181.9
-1,079.3
14.8
-1,094.1
259.4
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States,
Flows and Outstandings Third Quarter 2010, December 9, 2010.
Note: Negative values indicate a net inflow of funds, or that the demand for funds in that sector was greater
than the supply of funds provided by that sector.
Generally, the household sector, or individuals, provides funds to the economy, because
individuals save part of their income, while the business sector uses those funds to invest in plant
and equipment that, in turn, serve as the building blocks for the production of additional goods
and services. The government sector (the combination of federal, state, and local governments)
can be either a net supplier of funds or a net user, depending on whether the sector is running a
surplus or a deficit, respectively. The interplay within the economy between saving and
investment, or the supply and uses of funds, tends to affect domestic interest rates, which move to
equate the demand and supply of funds. Shifts in the interest rate also tend to attract capital from
abroad, denoted by the rest of the world (ROW).
From 1999 until late in 2006, the household sector was dissaving, as individuals spent more than
they earned. Part of this dissaving was offset by the government sector, which experienced a
surplus from 1998 to 2001. As a result of the large household dissaving, however, the economy as
Congressional Research Service
15

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

a whole experienced a gap between domestic saving and investment that was filled with large
capital inflows. Those inflows were particularly large in nominal terms from 2000 to 2008, as
household dissaving continued and as government sector surpluses turned to historically large
deficits in nominal terms. Such inflows kept interest rates below the level they would have
reached without the inflows, but they put added pressure on the international exchange value of
the dollar during that period.
In 2008 and 2009, capital inflows fell sharply, reflecting the global financial crisis and economic
recession and the associated drop in international trade. This drop in capital inflows reflected a
shift by households from dissaving to saving as concerns over the economy, with an attendant
large loss in personal wealth, spurred households to pare back their consumption expenditures
and to increase their personal savings. The business sector also shifted from a net supplier of
funds in 2007 to a net consumer of funds as investments declined, again reflecting tight credit
conditions and the drop in the rate of economic growth in the economy in 2008 and 2009. Both
the federal government and state and local governments experienced a deterioration in their
accounts as these sectors of the economy experienced large net deficits, reflecting the slowing
rate of growth in the U.S. economy. The decrease in capital inflows combined with the slowing
rate of economic growth and concerns about the stability of the financial services sector likely
placed downward pressure on the exchange value of the dollar, or a devaluation of the dollar.
Foreign Exchange Market
International factors also affect the value of the dollar. The dollar is heavily traded in financial
markets around the globe and, at times, plays the role of a global currency. Disruptions in this role
have important implications for the United States and for the smooth functioning of the
international financial system. This prominent role means that the exchange value of the dollar
often acts as a mechanism for transmitting economic and political news and events across
national borders, including expectations about the performance of the economy and concerns
about the impact of such supply factors as the rise in the price of oil. While such a role helps
facilitate a broad range of international economic and financial activities, it also means that the
dollar’s exchange value can vary greatly on a daily or weekly basis as it is buffeted by
international events.
A triennial survey of the world’s leading central banks conducted by the Bank for International
Settlements in April 2010 indicates that the daily trading of foreign currencies through traditional
foreign exchange markets23 totals about $4 trillion, up from the $3.3 trillion reported in the
previous survey conducted in 2007, as indicated in Table 3. In addition to the traditional foreign
exchange market, the over-the-counter (OTC)24 foreign exchange derivatives market reported that
daily turnover of interest rate and non-traditional foreign exchange derivatives contracts reached
$2.1 trillion in April 2010 The combined amount of $6.1 trillion for daily foreign exchange
trading in the traditional and OTC markets is more than three times the annual amount of U.S.
exports of goods and services. The data also indicate that 85% of the global foreign exchange

23 Traditional foreign exchange markets are organized exchanges which trade primarily in foreign exchange futures and
options contracts where the terms and condition of the contracts are standardized.
24 The over-the-counter foreign exchange derivatives market is an informal market consisting of dealers who custom-
tailor agreements to meet the specific needs regarding maturity, payments intervals or other terms that allow the
contracts to meet specific requirements for risk.
Congressional Research Service
16

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

turnover is in U.S. dollars, slightly lower than the 85.6% share reported in a similar survey
conducted in 2007.25
Table 3. Foreign Exchange Market Turnover
(Daily averages in April of the year indicated, billions of U.S. dollars)

1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010
Foreign Exchange Market Turnover
Instrument






Spot
transactions
494 568 386 631
1,005
1,490
Outright
forwards
97 128 130 209 362 475
Foreign exchange swaps
546
734
656
954
1,714
1,765
Reporting
gaps
53 61 28 107 129 NA
Total
“traditional”
turnover
1,190 1,527 1,239 1,934 3,324 3,981
Over the Counter Derivatives Market Turnover
Foreign exchange instruments

97
87
140
291
NA
Interest rate instruments

265
489
1,025
1,686
2,083
Reporting
gaps
13 19 55 113 NA
Total
OTC
turnover
375 575
1,220
1,990
2,083
Total market turnover
1,190 1,865 1,775 3,100 5,300 6,064
United States






Foreign
exchange
turnover
244 351 254 461 664 817
OTC
derivatives
turnover
90 135 355 607 659
Total

244 441 389 816
1,271
1,506
Source: Triennial Central Bank Survey: Foreign Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity in 2010. Bank for
International Settlement, September 2010.
The U.S. Trade Deficit
Rising oil prices add to the Nation’s trade deficit and boost the rate of change in wholesale and
consumer prices, as long as the oil price increases are not offset by actions by the Federal Reserve
to tighten the money supply.26 According to data published by the Census Bureau of the
Department of Commerce,27 the prices of petroleum products over the past year have varied
considerably, at times rising faster than the change in demand for those products. As a result, the
price increases of imported energy-related petroleum products worsened the U.S. trade deficit in

25 Triennial Central Bank Survey: Foreign Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity in 2010. Bank for International
Settlement, September 2010. pp. 1-2. A copy of the report is available at http://www.bis.org/publ/rpfx07.pdf
26 Consumer Price Index: January 2011, The Bureau of Labor Statistics. P. 1.
27 Census Bureau, Department of Commerce. Report FT900, U.S. International Trade in Goods and Services, February
11, 2011. Table 17. The report and supporting tables are available at http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/Press-
Release/current_press_release/ftdpress.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
17

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

2006,- 2008 and again in 2010. This rising cost of oil added an estimated $120 billion in 2008 and
$80 billion in 2010.28
Changes in oil prices also affect the cost of a broad range of goods, services, and economic
activities and the changes can affect the real discretionary incomes of consumers, which has an
impact on the rate of economic growth. A lower rate of economic growth, as was experienced in
late 2008 and in 2009, reduces demand for oil and the price of oil falls to equate supply and
demand, assuming that the supply of oil remains constant. The trade deficit also represents a
transfer of wealth from the United States to the oil producers. This transfer of wealth reduces the
real discretionary incomes of U.S. consumers. To the extent that the additional accumulation of
wealth abroad is returned to the United States as payments for additional U.S. exports or to
acquire such assets as securities or U.S. businesses, some of the negative effects could be
mitigated. The data in Table 4 provide estimates of the impact different prices for imported crude
oil could have on the annual U.S. trade deficit. The table also provides estimates for the increase
in the trade deficit if the amount, or the volume, of imported oil declined by 3% or rose by 3% on
an annual basis, as a result of changes in the demand for oil.
According to the Census Bureau, the United States imported 4.28 billion barrels of energy-related
petroleum products in 2010. Energy-related petroleum products is a term used by the Census
Bureau that includes crude oil, petroleum preparations, and liquefied propane and butane gas.
Crude oil comprises the largest share by far within this broad category of energy-related imports.
At an average price of $74.66 per barrel, imported petroleum products cost $323 billion dollars in
2010. After subtracting U.S. exports of petroleum products, the U.S. trade deficit in petroleum
products was $265 billion, or 41% of the total trade deficit in 2010 of $646 billion. At an average
price of $80 per barrel in 2011 and assuming that the amount, or the volume, of petroleum
products the United States imports does not change, the U.S. trade deficit in oil in 2011 would
increase by $18 billion over the deficit recorded in 2010. At an average price of $100 per barrel in
2011, the cost of imported petroleum would add $104 billion to the annual trade deficit.
Naturally, should import volumes decrease as a result of greater energy conservation or a lower
rate of economic growth, the addition to the annual trade deficit would be less. If import volumes
fell by 3% at a time when the average price of imported petroleum products was $100 per barrel,
the addition to the annual trade deficit would be $91 billion. Should import volumes increase by
3% and oil prices rise, the deficit would increase as well.

28 For additional information, see CRS Report RS22204, U.S. Trade Deficit and the Impact of Changing Oil Prices, by
James K. Jackson.
Congressional Research Service
18

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

Table 4. Estimates of the Impact on the U.S. Trade Deficit Associated With Various
Prices for Crude Oil and Changes in Oil Import Volumes
2010
2011

(Actual values)
Estimated values

Quantity
Value
Price per barrel
(billions of
(billions of
barrels)
dollars)
Price per barrel

$74.66
$70.00 $80.00
$90.00
$100.00
Crude
oil
imports
3.38
$252.18
$236.44 $270.22 $303.99 $337.77
Total energy-related Petroleum
4.28
$323.63
$299.49 $342.28 $385.06 $427.85
Products imports
Change in trade deficit (in $billions) $-24.16 $18.65 $61.43 $104.22







With 3 percent reduction in import volumes
Crude
oil
imports


$229.35 $262.11 $294.87 $327.64
Total energy-related Petroleum Products imports
$290.51 $332.01 $373.51 $415.01
Change in trade deficit (in $billions)
$-33.12 $8.38
$49.88
$91.38







With 3 percent increase in import volumes
Crude
oil
imports


$243.53 $278.32 $313.11 $347.90
Total energy-related Petroleum Products imports
$308.48 $352.55 $396.61 $440.68
Change in trade deficit (in $billions) $-15.15 $28.92 $72.98 $117.05
Source: U.S. International Trade in Goods and Services February 2011, Census Bureau. Estimates developed by
CRS.
Conclusions
Despite common perceptions that there is a direct cause and effect relationship between changes
in the international exchange value of the dollar and the price of oil, an analysis of recent data
indicates that the rise in the price of oil is being driven by an increase in demand that is exceeding
the increase in supply and by political turmoil in North Africa and the Middle East. Attempts by
oil producers to raise the market price of oil in order to offset the loss of purchasing power of a
depreciating dollar likely would find those efforts blunted partially or in whole by the
repercussions of the rise in oil prices. Increases in oil prices tend to push up prices among a broad
range of goods, services, and economic activities due to the ubiquitous presence of oil as a source
of energy. In addition, higher relative rates of inflation tend to undermine the exchange value of
the dollar relative to other currencies, devaluing the dollar relative to other currencies and
reducing the purchasing power of the dollar. Domestically, rising commodity prices reduce real
incomes and lower the overall level of consumption. In turn, lower consumption reduces
economic growth, which would tend to reduce the demand for oil and lead ultimately to a lower
market price for oil.
Congressional Research Service
19

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

The relationship between the dollar and the price of oil is complicated by the impact the price of
oil can have on the rate of inflation and the rate of economic growth in the United States, the rate
of economic growth and the rate of inflation in other countries, and effects on foreign currencies.
For instance, rising oil prices not only raise the price of energy in the United States, but in
countries around the globe. Rising prices, in turn, tend to undermine the purchasing power of
national currencies. Depending on the level of domestic dependency on foreign oil, the impact of
changes in oil prices can vary. Concerns over rising prices in Europe and the prospect of slowing
economic growth in the Euro zone countries have tended to push down the exchange value of the
Euro relative to the dollar.29
Upward pressure on the market price of crude oil also can come from market participants and
investors who are bidding up the price of oil in an effort to invest in commodities that they
calculate will generate a rate of return that exceeds that of traditional financial investments. With
demand for crude oil rising faster than supplies, it is difficult for the market to determine what the
future price of crude oil might be, which provides a climate that is susceptible to speculation,
although there is no clear evidence that such speculation has been a major factor in the rise in
crude oil prices since 2006.
Over the long run, a sustained increase in the price of energy imports could permanently alter the
composition of the nation’s merchandise trade deficit. Some of the impact of higher oil prices,
however, could be offset if some of the dollars are returned to the U.S. economy through
increased purchases of U.S. goods and services or through purchases of such other assets as
securities of U.S. businesses. Some of the return in dollars likely will come through sovereign
wealth funds (SWFs), or funds controlled and managed by foreign governments, as foreign
exchange reserves boost the dollar holdings of such funds. Such investments likely will add to
concerns about the national security implications of foreign acquisitions of U.S. firms, especially
by foreign governments, and to concerns about the growing share of outstanding U.S. Treasury
securities that are owned by foreigners. Over the long run it is possible for the economy to adjust
to the higher prices of energy imports by improving its energy efficiency, finding alternative
sources of energy, or searching out additional supplies of energy. Increased pressure is already
being applied to Congress to assist in this process.
The sharp rise in prices of energy imports experienced since mid-2010 is increasing the U.S. rate
of inflation and could have a slightly negative impact on the rate of economic growth in 2011.
This could pose a number of policy issues for Congress. A slowdown in the rate of economic
growth in the United States will lessen the demand for energy imports and could help restrain the
prices of energy imports, but likely put additional pressure on the budgets at the state, local, and
federal levels of government. An important factor will be the length of political turmoil in North
Africa and the Middle East and the potential impact Atlantic hurricanes have on the production of
crude oil in the Gulf of Mexico. Most immediately, higher prices for energy imports will worsen
the nation’s merchandise trade deficit, add to inflationary pressures, and have a disproportionate
impact on the energy-intensive sectors of the economy and on households on fixed incomes.
For Congress, the increase in the nation’s merchandise trade deficit could add to existing
inflationary pressures and complicate efforts to stimulate the economy should the rate of
economic growth slow down. In particular, Congress, through its direct role in making economic
policy and its oversight role over the Federal Reserve, could face the dilemma of rising inflation,

29 Dougherty, Fears of European Slowdown Weaken the Euro.
Congressional Research Service
20

The U.S. Trade Deficit, the Dollar, and the Price of Oil

which generally is treated by raising interest rates to tighten credit, and a slowing rate of
economic growth, which is usually addressed by lowering interest rates to stimulate investment. A
sharp rise in the trade deficit could also add to pressures for Congress to examine the causes of
the deficit and to address the underlying factors that are generating that deficit. In addition, the
rise in prices of energy imports could add to concerns about the nation’s reliance on foreign
supplies for energy imports and capital inflows and add impetus to examining the nation’s energy
strategy.

Author Contact Information

James K. Jackson

Specialist in International Trade and Finance
jjackson@crs.loc.gov, 7-7751


Congressional Research Service
21