Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls
D. Andrew Austin
Analyst in Economic Policy
March 10, 2010
Congressional Research Service
7-5700
www.crs.gov
RL33657
CRS Report for Congress
P
repared for Members and Committees of Congress

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

Summary
Governments run deficits for several reasons. By running short-run deficits, governments can
avoid raising taxes during economic downturns, which helps households smooth consumption
over time. Running deficits can stimulate aggregate demand in the economy, thus giving
policymakers a valuable fiscal policy tool to help support macroeconomic stability. In particular,
short-run deficits may help boost economic activity when monetary policy loses its potency.
When interest rates fall to low levels during an economic downturn, banks can become reluctant
to lend when they perceive the risks of lending outweigh the gains, while fewer firms and
consumers demand new loans. In such a situation, known as a liquidity trap, a monetary authority
such as the Federal Reserve can do little to expand the money supply. Thus, while the monetary
authority can cut short-term interest rates to nearly zero—or even to zero—lower interest rates or
other monetary policy initiatives may do little to encourage new consumer spending or business
investment. During a liquidity trap situation, fiscal policy tools such as increased government
spending or tax cuts, which increase deficits, may be an important complement to monetary
policy. So-called “fresh-water” economists have questioned the logic of these fiscal policies. So-
called “salt-water” economists, who have sought to put Keynesian fiscal theories on a more
modern foundation, contend that government interventions can mitigate economic downturns.
Most professional economic forecasters find that deficits and fiscal policy measures can stimulate
economic activity when the economy operates well below its potential.
In better economic times, deficits may crowd out private investment or worsen trade deficits. But
long-run deficits may transfer economic resources from younger to older generations, allowing
older generations to enjoy anticipated benefits of future economic growth—long-run deficits may
also impose large burdens on future generations. Some have argued this allows politicians to act
opportunistically by providing benefits to current constituents while leaving future generations,
an unrepresented constituency, with substantial fiscal burdens.
Between 2007 and 2009, federal tax revenues fell by 18.0% and corporate tax revenues fell
62.7%. Government outlays rose during the recession due to “automatic stabilizer” programs such
as unemployment insurance and income support programs; federal support provided to Fannie
Mae, Freddie Mac, AIG, and other companies; and economic stimulus legislation such as the
American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 (ARRA; H.R. 1, P.L. 111-5).
Anticipation of changes in partisan control of government can motivate deficits, as current policy
makers may wish to restrict their successors’ options. Research on state and foreign governments
suggests that balanced-budget rules force governments to adjust spending and taxes sharply
during economic downturns. Budget enforcement legislation, such as the 1990 Budget
Enforcement Act (P.L. 101-508), may have helped preserve budgetary compromises between
parties, which may have contributed to a reduction in federal deficits.
Deficits can seriously harm national economies. In the short run, fiscal overstimulation leads to
inflation. In the long term, deficits either reduce capital investment, which retards economic
growth, or increase foreign borrowing, which swells the share of national income going abroad.
Governments can spend more than they collect in revenues by printing money, which causes
inflation, or by borrowing. In the long run, governments risk default and bankruptcy if they fail to
repay borrowers, at least to the extent of stabilizing the ratio of government debt to gross
domestic product. This report, updated with the assistance of Joseph McCormack, will be
modified as events warrant.
Congressional Research Service

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

Contents
Why Do Governments Run Deficits? .......................................................................................... 1
Recent Federal Policy Responses ................................................................................................ 2
Is the Deficit the Right Measure of Fiscal Policy? ................................................................. 2
Benefits and Costs of Using Deficits to Smooth Consumption..................................................... 3
Does Economic Stimulus Generate New Spending or Just Shift Spending?............................ 4
New Dimensions of Federal Economic Policy? ..................................................................... 5
Macroeconomic Demand Management: Theory and Policy ......................................................... 6
“Fresh-Water” Macroeconomics............................................................................................ 8
“Salt-Water” Macroeconomics .............................................................................................. 9
Dynamic Statistical Agnosticism and Macroeconomics Engineering...................................... 9
How Effective Has Economic Stimulus Been?..................................................................... 10
Other Considerations........................................................................................................... 11
Political Explanations................................................................................................................ 13
Intergenerational Transfers .................................................................................................. 13
The Long-Term Budget Outlook ............................................................................................... 15
Costs of Financing Deficits ................................................................................................. 16
Conclusion................................................................................................................................ 17

Figures
Figure 1. Estimated Multipliers of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act ..................... 11

Contacts
Author Contact Information ...................................................................................................... 17
Acknowledgments .................................................................................................................... 18

Congressional Research Service

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

Why Do Governments Run Deficits?
In the past half century, the federal government has run annual deficits in all but six years.1 The
FY2009 federal deficit swelled to $1.414 trillion, or nearly 10% of gross domestic product
(GDP), as the economic recession depressed federal revenues and as financial interventions and
“automatic stabilizer” income support programs increased federal spending. The size of recent
deficits has added to longstanding concerns regarding the federal government’s long-term fiscal
condition. Nonetheless, deficit finance can serve as an important policy tool. This report discusses
how deficit finance can help governments manage their economies and how large and persistent
deficits can lead to severe economic problems.
Public finance theory suggests three reasons for deficit financing by government. First,
governments can prevent sudden changes in taxes by borrowing. Second, debt finance gives
governments a powerful macroeconomic policy tool. Third, debt finance can redistribute
resources among generations.
Government borrowing can shift revenues and expenses into different time periods more easily or
more cheaply than households, which allows governments to use deficits to make taxpayers better
off by smoothing tax levels.2 The federal government can spread the cost of major capital
investments over many years by issuing debt in the form of bonds or Treasury bills. Deficit
finance can spread an especially large cost such as a major war over several generations, or even
centuries,3 and enables governments to keep taxes steady during temporary economic downturns,
thus smoothing consumption for households. Government debt that nears unsustainable levels,
however, can inject turmoil into an economy, and governments may go bankrupt if they fail to
repay what they borrow.4
Increased government spending financed by borrowing can stimulate economic activity, giving
government a fiscal policy tool to counteract recessions. A countercyclical fiscal policy, in which
taxes are cut or spending is increased, can dampen economic fluctuations and limit the depth of
economic downturns. Pro-cyclical fiscal policy, in which taxes are raised or spending is cut
during recessions, tends to amplify economic fluctuations. During economic downturns,
government revenues fall and expenditures rise as more people become eligible for
unemployment insurance and income support programs, causing deficits to increase or surpluses
to shrink. These programs are known as “automatic stabilizers” because deficit spending then
provides a countercyclical stimulus to economic activity in the short run without the need for new
legislative action.5
Finally, deficit finance can transfer the benefits of future economic growth to current generations.
Continuing real economic growth would allow future generations to experience higher standards

1 The federal government ran surpluses in FY1960, FY1969, and FY1998-FY2001. Only in FY1960, FY1999, and
FY2000 did the federal government run an on-budget surplus, which excludes off-budget surpluses that flow largely
from Social Security payroll taxes net of beneficiary payments.
2 So-called “rainy day” funds, used by many state governments, allow smoothing of tax levels without deficit finance.
3 The British government still pays interest on consol bonds issued during the Napoleonic Wars.
4 A more precise definition of fiscal sustainability is that the public debt does not grow without bound.
5 The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) computes a measure of the deficit that adjusts for business cycle effects to
allow a more meaningful comparison of short-term fiscal stance across different years.
Congressional Research Service
1

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

of living than previous generations. Deficit finance provides a means of transferring some of
those gains to current generations by shifting some costs onto future generations. If deficits are
large or if future economic growth is slow, then deficit finance could lead to a deterioration of
living standards over time.
Recent Federal Policy Responses
The federal government’s response to the recent recession may reflect the aims discussed above.
The government cut some taxes and increased spending to stimulate the economy, while issuing
new debt at an accelerated pace. The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 (ARRA;
H.R. 1, P.L. 111-5) funded programs that are projected to provide $862 billion to stimulate the
economy with financial assistance, loans provided to financial firms, and increased government
spending including aid given to states.6 In 2008, tax cuts and income tax refunds under President
Bush also provided increased liquidity allowing for higher levels of consumption. The Emergency
Economic Stabilization Act of 2008 (EESA; P.L. 110-343), injected capital into key financial
markets as part of the Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP).7 The “Cash for Clunkers”
program (P.L. 111-47) was created to generate auto sales and improve fuel efficiency. Some argue
that the program helped the automobile manufacturers General Motors and Chrysler remain
viable concerns, encouraged greater sales of cars made in the United States, and prevented larger
increases in unemployment.8 ARRA extended a first-time home-buyer tax credit that provides up
to an $8,000 credit to first-time home buyers for sales occurring between January 1, 2009, and
April 30, 2010.9 While these programs stimulated home and auto sales, many suspect that they
were more effective in shifting the timing of sales rather than affecting the overall volume of
sales.10
Is the Deficit the Right Measure of Fiscal Policy?
The federal deficit is an imperfect measure of the federal government’s fiscal stance. While the
total deficit indicates the federal government’s current interaction with the U.S. economy, it does
not reflect other aspects of the government’s fiscal condition.11 First, because the federal

6 U.S. Congressional Budget Office, The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2010 to 2020, January 2010,
available at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/108xx/doc10871/01-26-Outlook.pdf, p. 98; and CRS Report RS21126, Tax
Cuts and Economic Stimulus: How Effective Are the Alternatives?
, by Jane G. Gravelle. ARRA (H.R. 1, P.L. 111-5)
also raised the federal debt limit to $12.1 trillion. The initial CBO estimate of ARRA on federal deficits was $787
billion over the 2009-2019 period.
7 CRS Report R41001, Redirecting Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) Funds to Other Uses, by Marc Labonte,
Edward V. Murphy, and Baird Webel.
8 A reorganized General Motors emerged from bankruptcy on April 30, 2009; Chrysler filed for bankruptcy and on July
10, 2009, was sold to the Italian car maker Fiat. For details, see Micheline Maynard, “A Primer on the New General
Motors,” New York Times, July 10, 2009. Michael J. De La Merced and Micheline Maynard, “Fiat Deal With Chrysler
Seals Swift 42-Day Overhaul,” New York Times, June 11, 2009, p. B4.
9 A first-time home buyer tax credit was included in the 2009 Recovery Act (P.L. 110-289, Sec. 3011[a]). ARRA
extended this credit and relaxed some requirements. The credit was again extended by the Worker, Homeownership,
and Business Assistance Act of 2009 (P.L. 111-92) to homes bought before May 1, 2010. For details, see CRS Report
R40955, An Economic Analysis of the Homebuyer Tax Credit, by Mark P. Keightley.
10 Mark Trumbull, “Extending home-buyer credit: another clunker?” Christian Science Monitor, October 29, 2009.
This issue is discussed in more detail below.
11 The total deficit combines on-budget deficits with off-budget surpluses stemming from the difference between
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
2

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

government is essentially run on a cash basis, the deficit does not fully reflect changes in future
fiscal conditions of the government.12 Second, some federal programs may create additional fiscal
exposures that federal budget concepts may not fully reflect. The budgetary cost estimates of
federal loan and loan guarantee programs omit risk adjustments, with the exception of programs
funded by the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act (EESA) such as the Troubled Assets Relief
Program (TARP).13 Some contend that risk adjustments provide a more accurate description of
the economic costs of federal credit programs. Other federal responses to financial turmoil may
have created fiscal exposures that are harder to quantify. Recent federal interventions, to the
extent that they convince private firms that the government will shoulder some costs of future
adverse events through further public interventions, may expose taxpayers and federal program
beneficiaries to other contingent costs that are difficult to quantify.
Bringing a federal budget to balance, temporarily, can occur beyond the straightforward measures
of raising taxes or decreasing spending. Governments can increase current revenues by borrowing
against future income, allowing a smaller deficit today at the expense of higher taxes or lower
public program benefits. For example, Greece met certain European Union deficit and debt rules
by selling rights to future airport fees and lottery income.14 The City of Chicago in February 2009
sold the rights to parking fee revenues for the next 75 years for a $1.15 billion lump-sum payment
that mostly funded current municipal expenses.15 Government asset sales and trades of future
income streams for lump-sum payments can improve deficit figures reported on a cash-
accounting basis, but may signal a deterioration of a government’s overall fiscal condition.
Finally, deficits are residuals resulting from spending that exceeds revenues. While policymakers
can control economic policy instruments such as taxes and spending, economic fluctuations affect
the tax base.16 For that reason, many economists rely on deficit measures that take business cycle
effects into account.
Benefits and Costs of Using Deficits to Smooth
Consumption

Helping households smooth income, according to standard public finance theory, may justify
short-run deficits. If governments were required to balance their budgets in each fiscal year, so

(...continued)
Social Security payroll taxes and benefit payments.
12 The Financial Statement of the United States has for many years included accrual accounting measures that reflect
some changes in future federal costs. Those measures, however, do not include scheduled benefits for programs such as
Social Security and Medicare, which some contend leads to underestimation of the fiscal overhang facing the federal
government. For details, see CRS Report RL33623, Long-Term Measures of Fiscal Imbalance, by D. Andrew Austin;
“Accrual Budgeting and Fiscal Policy,” OECD Journal on Budgeting, vol. 2009/1, pp. 1-29.
13 Section 123 of EESA requires that TARP costs be estimated as specified by the Federal Credit Reform Act of 1990
(P.L. 101-508, amended by P.L. 105-33) and that estimates incorporate risk adjustments. Cost estimates for other
federal loan and loan guarantee programs omit risk adjustments.
14 Louise Story, Landon Thomas Jr., and Nelson D. Schwartz, “Wall St. Helped to Mask Debt Fueling Europe’s
Crisis,” New York Times, February 14, 2010, p. A1.
15 Dan Mihalopoulos, “Company Piles Up Profits From City’s Parking Meter Deal,” New York Times, November 20,
2009, p. A29A.
16 Also see CRS Report RL31235, The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit, by Brian W. Cashell.
Congressional Research Service
3

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

that current spending were constrained by available cash reserves and incoming revenues, then
negative economic shocks would require spending cuts or tax increases. Public spending tends to
rise during recessions due to the effect of automatic stabilizers, while revenues fall. Thus, such
strict balanced-budget requirements would force governments to run a pro-cyclical fiscal policy,
which could either strain household budgets via tax increases or force painful cuts in public
programs. Governments can also smooth income by maintaining “rainy day” funds or sinking
funds.
Economists have studied balanced-budget requirements in state governments, as well as
budgetary restrictions used by other national governments.17 All states except Vermont have
balanced-budget requirements, though the strictness of those requirements varies. Many studies
have found that the strictness of the balanced-budget requirement affects fiscal performance.
Inman and Bohn found that tight balanced-budget rules cause states to reduce deficits by cutting
spending, whereas softer constraints have little short-term effect.18 Other researchers found that
balanced-budget rules force governments to adjust spending and taxes sharply during economic
downturns.19 Fiscal crises may put strains on states and their citizens, but may also force policy
makers to face tough fiscal decisions that would otherwise be avoided. Balanced-budget rules
also appear to hold down taxes and spending, at least in the short run. Over the longer term, both
spending and taxes adjust, although state and local governments with tight budget-balance
measures appear to spend less per capita than those with less stringent requirements.
State budget-balance rules may also complicate broader macroeconomic stabilization efforts. One
study found that reductions in state spending in 2008-2009 essentially offset federal stimulus
spending.20 Thus, according to that analysis, while federal spending prevented a steeper decline in
economic activity, it did little to counteract a fall in private sector demand.
Does Economic Stimulus Generate New Spending or Just Shift
Spending?

Deficit finance aimed at helping households smooth consumption will generate few gains if
households can smooth consumption on their own. For example, economist Robert Barro argued
that deficit spending caused by tax cuts has no fiscal effect because households save in
anticipation of future tax increases, offsetting any short-term stimulative effects. This concept is
known as Ricardian equivalence.21 The theory of Ricardian equivalence implies that only the net

17 For a review of research using U.S. state data, see James M. Poterba, “Budget Institutions and Fiscal Policy in the
U.S. States,” American Economic Review, vol. 86, no. 2 (1986), pp. 395-400. For a review of European budgetary
rules, see Giancarlo Corsetti and Nouriel Roubini, “European versus American Perspectives on Balanced-Budget
Rules,” American Economic Review, vol. 86, no. 2 (1986), pp. 408-413.
18 Henning Bohn and Robert P. Inman, “Balanced Budget Rules and Public Deficits: Evidence From the U.S. States,”
NBER Working Paper No. 5533, April 1996.
19 James M. Poterba, “State Responses to Fiscal Crises: The Effects of Budgetary Institutions and Politics,” Journal of
Political Economy
, vol. 102, no. 4 (August 1994), pp. 799-821.
20 Joshua Aizenman and Gurnain Kaur Pasricha, “On the Ease of Overstating the Fiscal Stimulus in the U.S., 2008-9”
NBER Working Paper No. 15784, February 2010, available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w15784.pdf.
21 This concept is named after David Ricardo (1772-1823), a London financier and economist engaged in debates about
the management of debts accumulated during the Napoleonic Wars. Ricardo, while providing examples pointing out
that the real burden of a stream of interest payments was essentially the same as the burden of immediate payment of
borrowing associated with those payments, was concerned that the opportunity to carry public debt could encourage
“profligacy” in government expenditure. David Ricardo, The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, 3rd ed.,
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
4

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

present value of government expenditures and taxes needed to pay for them matter, but that the
timing of taxes does not.22
Empirical research has failed to find evidence of Ricardian equivalence in its pure form, but some
research has identified some Ricardian effects in savings behavior.23 Even if a large proportion of
households face liquidity constraints that limit their ability to smooth out income fluctuations by
borrowing and saving, however, many high-net-worth households are well equipped to shift
buying power across time in response to government policies.
The overwhelming evidence of economic research and macroeconomic experience, contrary to
the predictions of Ricardian equivalence, suggests that deficit spending creates a short-term fiscal
stimulus.24 Despite the imprint that New Classical Macroeconomics, of which Ricardian
equivalence is a central tenet, has left on macroeconomic modeling, most empirical economists
believe deficits affect prices and output in the short run and recognize the usefulness of fiscal
policy as a tool for macroeconomic management, at least in some circumstances. Even if
Ricardian equivalence fails to hold in a pure form, it may help explain why economic stimulus
measures may have limited effect when households can shift purchases backwards or forwards in
time. The effects can also vary with the instrument used. For example, many contend that the
Cash for Clunkers program (P.L. 111-47) and the First-Time Homebuyers’ tax credit may have
encouraged households planning to buy either cars or homes in the medium term to shift
purchases forward in time, rather than stimulating new purchases by households that had no plans
to buy.
New Dimensions of Federal Economic Policy?
Economists typically view fiscal policy and monetary policy as the basic tools of macroeconomic
management. Congress, in conjunction with the President, controls fiscal policy by making taxing
and spending decisions, while the Federal Reserve sets monetary policy, using tools such as
reserve requirements, and open-market trading of Treasury securities to affect key short-term
interest rates. Responses to the financial crisis in late 2007 and 2008, however, included policies
that do not fit squarely into the normal framework of fiscal and monetary policy. Some
economists have referred to these initiatives as “credit policy” tools.25 Many have argued that
credit policy has developed because monetary and fiscal policy tools are ill-suited to deal with
severe liquidity problems that may emerge due to credit quality issues.26 Other economists note

(...continued)
(London: Murray, 1821), ch. 17.
22 Robert J. Barro, “Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 82, no. 6. (November-
December, 1974), pp. 1095-1117. Robert Barro assumes that public spending is fixed and any decrease in taxes on
consumers only induces households to save more to prepare for future tax increases.
23 M. Gabriella Briotti, “Economic Reactions to Public Finance Consolidation: A Survey of the Literature,” European
Central Bank Occasional Paper no. 38, October 2005.
24 Alan J. Auerbach and William G. Gale, “Activist Fiscal Policy to Stabilize Economic Activity,” working paper,
September 29, 2009, available at http://elsa.berkeley.edu/~auerbach/activistfiscal.pdf; Robert E. Hall, “By How Much
Does GDP Rise If the Government Buys More Output?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009, pp. 183-
249.
25 Marvin Goodfriend, Carnegie Mellon University and National Bureau of Economic Research, “We Need an
‘Accord’ for Federal Reserve Credit Policy,” Shadow Open Market Committee Cato Institute, April 28, 2008.
26 Claudio Borio and Haibin Zhu, “Capital Regulation, Risk-Taking and Monetary Policy; A Missing Link In The
Transmission Mechanism?” BIS Working Papers, December 2008.
Congressional Research Service
5

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

that over the longer term, financial regulation and consumer credit protection policies may also
have important macroeconomic implications.
To avert a wider panic, the Federal Reserve set up facilities that loan funds to a broad assortment
of private companies using a wide range of assets as collateral for longer terms, leading to a
dramatic expansion of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet. In addition, in 2008, the federal
government took on risky assets as part of financial interventions involving the Treasury
Department and the Federal Reserve. In March 2008, as part of the arranged sale of the collapsing
investment bank Bear Stearns to JP Morgan Chase, the federal government agreed to absorb
certain Bear Stearns assets into the Maiden Lane I special purpose vehicle.27 The federal takeover
of mortgage giants Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in September 2008 also required substantial
government resources. The federal bailout of the insurer AIG resulted in the creation of the
Maiden Lane II and III vehicles. Treasury officials have contended that supporting AIG avoided
the collapse of other major financial firms and helped stabilize credit markets. 28
New Federal Reserve loan facilities that provide liquidity to financial markets could expose the
federal government to more risk than traditional monetary policy mechanisms. Medium-term
collateralized lending through Fed liquidity facilities can provide economic relief to cash-
constrained, yet solvent, companies. Federal Reserve facilities generally impose a “haircut” on
loans, which depends on the type of collateral. For example, an asset with a par value of $100
might be assessed a 15% haircut, so that a borrowing firm could obtain an $85 loan. While the
Federal Reserve is mandated to avoid credit risks and has implemented conservative loan
collateral requirements, a severe financial disruption could impose costs on the Federal Reserve.
For instance, if assets posted as collateral dropped sharply in value, the Federal Reserve could
suffer losses. While the Federal Reserve is not part of the federal budget, net earnings of the
Federal Reserve are transferred to the U.S. Treasury Department; capital losses on the Federal
Reserve’s balance sheet might also be transmitted to the federal government. Federal Reserve
system earnings transferred to the U.S. Treasury, according to OMB estimates, are expected to
reach $77 billion in FY2010.
Macroeconomic Demand Management: Theory and
Policy

Keynesian economic theories, which call for governments to engage in active demand
management through fiscal policy, had enormous influence in post-World War II economic
policy. Governments, according to Keynesian theories, can influence economic activity through
policies that affect investment and savings (IS) and liquidity and the money supply (LM).29 Fiscal
policy can influence investment and savings through government consumption and taxation.
Monetary policy can affect the money supply and short-term interest rates, which can encourage
investment. The IS-LM model, which describes the effects of fiscal and monetary policies,

27 The New York Federal Reserve Bank’s back door opens onto Maiden Lane in lower Manhattan.
28 U.S. Department of Treasury, “Remarks by Secretary Henry M. Paulson, Jr. on Financial Rescue Package and
Economic Update,” press release, November 12, 2008, http://www.ustreas.gov/.
29 The IS-LM interpretation of John Maynard Keynes’s economic theories was developed by John Hicks. See John R.
Hicks, “Mr. Keynes and the ‘Classics’: A Suggested Interpretation,” Econometrica 5 (1937), pp. 147-59.
Congressional Research Service
6

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

remains a widely used applied macroeconomics policy tool, even as academic research has
focused on more mathematically sophisticated modeling approaches.
When interest rates fall to low levels during an economic downturn, banks can become reluctant
to lend because they perceive the risks of lending outweigh the gains, while fewer firms and
consumers demand new loans. In such a situation, known as a liquidity trap, a monetary authority
such as the Federal Reserve can do little to expand the money supply. Thus, while the monetary
authority can cut short-term interest rates to nearly zero—or even to zero—lower interest rates or
other monetary policy initiatives may do little to encourage new consumer spending or business
investment. Some monetary policy rules of thumb might in a severe recession indicate that short-
term nominal interest rates should be negative. But a monetary authority cannot induce negative
nominal interest rates because firms and households guarantee themselves a zero nominal return
by simply holding cash.30 When a central bank faces a zero lower bound (ZLB) on interest rates,
fiscal policy tools such as increased government spending or tax cuts, which increase deficits,
may be a necessary complement to monetary policy.31 Some recent research suggests that fiscal
stimulus is more effective when the zero lower bound applies.32
In better economic times, government spending becomes a less effective means of stimulating
economic activity and can elbow out private consumption and investment or worsen trade
deficits. When the economy is not below its potential, fiscal policy expansions are likely to lead
to higher inflation or a displacement of private consumption and investment. When fiscal policy
becomes less effective, though, monetary policy can be more effective in either encouraging or
restraining economic activity.
In the 1970s, Keynesian theories began to face intense intellectual challenges.33 The modern
debate over Keynesian demand management and fiscal policy eventually precipitated into a
division between the so-called “salt-water” and “fresh-water” schools of thought. Salt-water
macroeconomics is often associated with the coast-proximate departments of economics at
Berkeley, Harvard, MIT, UCLA, and Yale, while fresh-water macroeconomics is often associated
with the lake-proximate Universities of Chicago, Minnesota, and Rochester.34 These differences
in views about the proper role of macroeconomic policy have become more prominent during the
recent economic recession.

30 The Taylor rule relates a short-term interest rate target to current inflation, a target inflation rate, and the level of
economic slack in the economy, measured by the gap between actual and potential GDP. See John B. Taylor,
“Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 39 (1993),
pp. 195-215.
31 Managing monetary policy can become more challenging when a central bank faces the ZLB. When economic
activity becomes so weak that the price level falls, causing deflation, then those who hold cash enjoy a positive real rate
of return, which the real value of debts increases. Consumers who expect deflation to continue may wish to delay
purchases, further reducing aggregate demand. A central bank may seek to reverse those deflationary expectations by
committing to policies that would help increase the price level. The credibility of a central bank may play an important
role in the success of such policies.
32 Lawrence Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo, “When is the Government Spending Multiplier
Large?” paper presented at the Allied Social Sciences Association meetings, January 4, 2010.
33 Arjo Klamer, Conversations with Economists (Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield , 1984).
34 These departments of economics are not monolithically divided along fresh- versus-salt-water lines, and mostly
comprise economists with diverse views.
Congressional Research Service
7

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

“Fresh-Water” Macroeconomics
Fresh-water economists are typically skeptical of the government’s ability to improve economic
performance. Fresh-water economists, critical of Keynesian theories, view recessions not as
reflections of market instability, but as the result of the emergence of new economic structures or
the responses to external shocks. This school of thought, often called the New Classical
Macroeconomics, argues that market forces naturally balance labor supply and demand and lead
to economic efficiency. According to some economists, the actions by the private sector are more
effective and efficient at changing market forces than the government’s response, which allows
for a faster rebound from downward-trending economic forces. During the 1970s some
Keynesian economists had argued that demand management policies could exploit an observed
inverse relationship between unemployment rates and inflation, known as the Phillips curve.
Policymakers who tried to reduce unemployment by tolerating higher inflation rates saw the
Phillips curve break down, as slow economic growth and persistent inflation rates—termed
“stagflation”—led to wide unhappiness with macroeconomic conditions.
While the joint appearance of inflation and high unemployment confounded many Keynesian
economists, research in New Classical Macroeconomics argued that firms and households simply
learned to anticipate inflation and developed inflationary expectations. Thus, the microeconomic
responses of families and companies would counteract efforts of macroeconomic policymakers to
exploit the Phillips curve relationship, which then resulted in high inflation rates without any
persistent gains in employment levels. Prominent New Classical Macroeconomists argued,
therefore, that monetary policy authorities should stick to simple, predictable rules.35
New Classical Macroeconomists also argued that microeconomic decisions of households and
firms could undermine the effectiveness of fiscal policy. Further they believe in the flexibility of
prices and wages throughout the economy. The Ricardian Equivalence view, as noted above,
assumes households respond to tax cuts by saving funds to finance subsequent tax increases. This
view, which assumes households can easily borrow and lend to shift buying power across time
periods, has had mixed empirical support.
New Classical Macroeconomics research typically assumes that individuals have strong
forecasting abilities. Rational expectations, a central tenet of New Classical Macroeconomics,
presumes that firms and families are not systematically wrong when they form their economic
plans. In particular, the rational expectations assumption implies that households and businesses
foresee the consequences of changes in government policies and act in their own best interests in
response, although economic agents may make mistakes because of changing circumstances and
uncertainty. In many economic models, the combination of rational expectations with other
technical assumptions, such as no-bubble conditions, often results in strong efficiency
properties—meaning that resources are not wasted, productive equipment is not idle, costs are
minimized, and firms produce a mix of goods that match what consumers want.36 The New
Classical Macroeconomics critique of Keynesian demand management policies has relied on
models that combine neoclassical micro-foundations for macroeconomics (meaning that
households make consumption decisions to maximize their long-term well-being) and the

35 Finn E. Kydland and Edward C. Prescott, “Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans,” The
Journal of Political Economy
, vol. 85, no. 3 (June 1977), pp. 473-492.
36 These Ramsey-type models, in which infinitely lived households choose consumption paths over an infinite time
horizon, incorporate other conditions and assumptions as well.
Congressional Research Service
8

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

assumption that economic agents are foresighted, even when faced with complex dynamic
decisions.
“Salt-Water” Macroeconomics
Salt-water economists tend to see recessions as evidence of economic instability that governments
can mitigate to allow steadier economic growth.37 More recent “salt-water” research sets older
Keynesian theories upon more modern foundations, while emphasizing that the structure of labor
markets may create wage rigidities. For example, the price of soybeans may change by the
millisecond, but the wages of employees do not. Wage rigidities may lead to involuntary
unemployment or excess capacity during economic downturns, and thus provide a role for
traditional Keynesian demand management.38
Salt-water economists contend that individuals and firms, for various reasons, may have trouble
lifting the economy out of a recession.39 Federal fiscal policy actions and the Federal Reserve
monetary policies, in this view, can help stabilize the economy and mitigate recessions. The Great
Depression of the 1930s, according to salt-water economists, demonstrates that the American
economy could remain persistently below its potential despite individual efforts by households
and firms. If households are unwilling to spend because they fear continuing economic weakness,
then firms may cut investment in the face of weak demand, generating a self-enforcing
recessionary cycle. Falling prices, rather than adjusting the balance between supply and demand,
may give households further reason to delay consumption. Government fiscal stimulus, salt-water
economists claim, can restore market balance by temporarily replacing private consumption and
investment with government outlays, thus providing the demand to help push the economy back
to its full potential. Deficit spending can be used to increase aggregate demand in the economy,
causing output and prices to increase. When the economy is running below its potential level of
output, expansionary fiscal policies such as deficits stimulate economic activity, bringing idle
economic capacity back into use and pushing the economy back toward its full potential.
If the economy is running near its full potential, expansionary fiscal policies can lead to inflation,
may displace private economic activity, and could cause large trade deficits. Running government
surpluses reduces aggregate demand in the economy and helps restrain inflation.
Dynamic Statistical Agnosticism and Macroeconomics Engineering
While fresh- and salt-water research has increased the technical sophistication of academic
macroeconomic models, some contend that more atheoretical approaches that focus on the
statistical dynamics of large economies may be more useful for policy analysis.40 Moreover,

37 Peter T. Kilborn, “'Fresh Water’ Economists Gain,” The New York Times, July 23, 1988.
38 For a critique of fresh-water macroeconomics, see Robert J. Gordon, “Is Modern Macro or 1978-era Macro More
Relevant to the Understanding of the Current Economic Crisis?” Northwestern University working paper, September
12, 2009, available at http://faculty-web.at.northwestern.edu/economics/gordon/GRU_Combined_090909.pdf.
39 William White, “Modern Macroeconomics Is On The Wrong Track” Finance & Development, December 2009.
40 Christopher A. Sims, “Policy Analysis with Econometric Models,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1
(1982), pp. 107-164. For a review of recent research that combines some limited assumptions about the structure of the
economy with dynamic statistical approaches (structural autoregressive vector regressions), see Alan J. Auerbach and
William G. Gale, “Activist Fiscal Policy to Stabilize Economic Activity,” working paper, September 29, 2009; Robert
E. Hall, “By How Much Does GDP Rise If the Government Buys More Output?” Brookings Papers on Economic
(continued...)
Congressional Research Service
9

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

models used by central banks and commercial economic forecasters often have a more pragmatic
foundation than leading academic macroeconomic models. Such models can predict effects of a
policy change, such as inflation, when given an accurate assessment of current conditions. Some
see such applied economic models as a form of engineering, in contrast to the more scientific
concerns of academic researchers.41 While applied models used by the Federal Reserve, CBO,
private forecasters, and major central banks, which generally rest on Keynesian foundations, may
work reasonably well in normal circumstances, they might function less well in unusual
circumstances where microeconomic responses of households and firms diverge from Keynesian
assumptions.42 New Classical models, while highly influential in academic research, have not yet
achieved wide use in forecasting and policy analysis.43
How Effective Has Economic Stimulus Been?
ARRA was passed in February 2009 with the aim of stimulating economic growth by increasing
government spending on certain programs and by cutting some taxes. The effectiveness of
economic stimulus is often measured using estimates of multipliers, which calculate the
cumulative effect of an extra dollar of government spending on overall economic activity.44
According to CBO estimates, some recent programs have increased GDP by as much as $2.50 per
dollar of stimulus spending, while others may have increased growth by as little as 20 cents per
stimulus dollar. When tax breaks or transfer payments are saved rather than spent, multipliers are
smaller.45 Some economists would argue that during times of a liquidity trap, when monetary
policy loses potency, spending multipliers are higher. Households that are liquidity constrained
are more likely to spend one-time cash payments, yielding a high spending multiplier. For
households that are not liquidity constrained, one-time payments are more likely to be saved,
rather than spent. The expenditure multiplier is higher when the economy is operating below full
potential.46 When the economy operates at its full potential government spending is more likely to
crowd out private consumption.
Figure 1 shows CBO estimates of multipliers associated with government spending programs
funded by ARRA. Direct purchases by the government or transfer payments to state and local
governments and to individuals generated the highest multipliers, while one-time payments had a
relatively low multiplier in comparison to other forms of government spending. The multiplier for
payments to retirees is even weaker because members of older generations may not face financial
constraints such as those facing younger generations who often have higher levels of debt.

(...continued)
Activity, Fall 2009, pp. 183-249.
41 N. Gregory Mankiw, “The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer,” working paper, Harvard University, May
2006, available at http://www.economics.harvard.edu/files/faculty/40_Macroeconomist_as_Scientist.pdf. Mankiw was
President George W. Bush’s Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisors and is currently a professor of economics
at Harvard University.
42 Some applied revenue estimation models are Ramsey-type rather than Keynesian models.
43 Mankiw, op. cit.
44 Robert J. Barro and Charles J. Redlick, “Stimulus Spending Doesn't Work,” The Wall Street Journal, October 1,
2009.
45 U.S. Congressional Budget Office, Estimated Impact of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act on
Employment and Economic Output as of September 2009
, November 2009.
46 John F. Cogan, Tobias Cwik, John B. Taylor, and Volker Wieland, “New Keynesian versus Old Keynesian
Government Spending Multipliers,” February 2009.
Congressional Research Service
10

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

Corporate tax provisions generated the lowest multiplier. The extension of the First-Time
Homebuyer Credit also had a very weak multiplier effect. Some economists contend that these
purchases came at the expense of future purchases, where consumers took advantage of tax
credits by acting now instead of opting to delay consumption.47
Figure 1. Estimated Multipliers of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act
Range of Estimated Government Multiplier Effects of Selected Programs
Transfer Payments to State and Local Governments for
Infrastructure
Federal Purchases of Goods and Services
Transfer Payments to Individuals
Other Transfer Payments to State and Local Governments
Two-Year Tax Cuts for Lower- and Middle-Income People
One-Time Payments to Retirees
Extension of First-Time Homebuyer Credit
One-Year Tax Cut for Higher-Income People
Corporate Tax Provisions Primarily Affecting Cash Flow
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0

Source: Congressional Budget Office, Estimated Impact of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act on
Employment and Economic Output as of September 2009, available at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/106xx/
doc10682/11-30-ARRA.pdf.
Notes: Includes projections by CBO or JCT as having the total budget $5 billion or more over the 2009-2019
period. Certain provisions with lower total costs were included if the costs in the 2009-2011 period were large.
Some elements have different multipliers, by CBO’s estimates; in those cases the elements are listed with the
multiplier used for the majority of the 2009-2019 budgetary cost. Major provisions as identified above are
provided by the JCT, Estimated Budget Effects of the Revenue Provisions Contained in the Conference Agreement for
H.R. 1, JCX-19-09 (February 12, 2009), available at http://www.jct.gov/x-19-09.pdf.
The output multiplier is the cumulative impact on real gross domestic product over several quarters for each
dollar of spending or reduction in tax revenues.
Other Considerations
Using deficit finance to expand government spending and federal aid during economic downturns
is only sustainable if governments run surpluses during economic expansions to repay debt or

47 U.S. Congressional Budget Office, Estimated Impact of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act on
Employment and Economic Output as of September 2009
, November 2009, available at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/
106xx/doc10682/11-30-ARRA.pdf.
Congressional Research Service
11

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

accumulate reserves, or stabilize the debt to GDP ratio. Running surpluses during normal
economic conditions may strengthen a government’s capacity to manage its economy, not only by
reducing public debt levels, but also by enhancing its reputation for fiscal prudence, which may
widen its policy options in the event of a subsequent downturn.48 Critics of deficit finance and
active fiscal policy, however, argue that policy makers are more willing to increase government
spending when economic growth slows than to cut spending when growth accelerates.49
In addition, designing fiscal policy is a slow and deliberative process, whereas economic
downturns can emerge suddenly and are difficult to predict. Because economic shocks affect
spending patterns with substantial lags, economic conditions may have changed significantly
before new federal spending actually reaches the public. Few economists believe that large
changes in fiscal policy designed to counterbalance short-term economic downturns can be timed
precisely, although many economists believe fiscal policy is an important tool during prolonged
periods of slow or negative growth. Effects of severe economic downturns, however, often persist
so that timing issues become less important. In particular, unemployment rates, widely considered
a lagging economic indicator, may remain high well after other signs of economic growth appear.
While government spending can stimulate economic growth when private consumption is weak,
excessive government spending can hinder growth. When the costs of financing government
spending exceed its benefits, economic well-being is reduced. This can occur in one of two ways.
First, it can raise interest rates and crowd out public consumption. Second, it can fail to improve
GDP and generate higher levels of debt than before.50
While government spending can stimulate economic growth when private consumption is weak,
excessive government spending can hinder growth. When the cost of financing government
spending exceeds its benefits, economic well-being is reduced. While some government programs
provide benefits that private markets cannot easily supply, taxes that fund government operations
can distort economic incentives. Other government programs might fail to generate benefits that
balance their costs to taxpayers. Thus, reducing some types of government spending might lead to
higher levels of economic growth. One study using a panel of Organization for Economic Co-
operation and Development (OECD) countries found government spending had sizeable negative
effects on profits and business investments.51 The size of the government sector in the United
States is much smaller than most large OECD member states.
The effectiveness of aggressive fiscal policies, such as running deficits, also depends on the
perception of investors that a government is solvent. If investors who might buy government
bonds view a government’s long-term fiscal situation as unsustainable and doubt that the
government has the financial or political means to address its fiscal situation, then increased
deficit spending may well lead to large interest rate increases that may overwhelm any positive
stimulative effect.

48 This often referred to as creating “policy-space,” or more colloquially as “reloading the fiscal cannon.” See Olivier
Blanchard, Giovanni Dell’Ariccia and Paolo Mauro, “Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy,” IMF Staff Position Note,
SPN/10/03, 12 February 2010.
49 Milton Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom (Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press, 1962), pp. 75-84.
50 CRS Report R40770, Economic Effects of a Budget Deficit Exceeding $1 Trillion, by Marc Labonte.
51 Alberto Alesina, Silvia Ardagna, Roberto Perotti, and Fabio Schiantarelli, “Fiscal Policy, Profits, and Investment,”
American Economic Review, vol. 92, no. 3 (June 2002), pp. 571-589.
Congressional Research Service
12

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

Political Explanations
The political business cycle literature provides a theory of economic fluctuations based on
politicians’ desire to maximize their chances of reelection. Early versions of political business
cycle models presumed politicians could fool myopic voters by pumping up government spending
before elections.52 More sophisticated versions assume voters are rational and not myopic, but are
unable to distinguish between sustainable prosperity based on policy and administrative
competence from temporary prosperity based on deficit spending.53 Drazen reviewed the
literature and found strong evidence that voters react to economic conditions, but weak evidence
that macroeconomic policy is manipulated to sway elections.54
The alternation of partisan control of government may explain a persistent tendency towards
deficit spending. Several articles in the economics of politics literature, such as Alesina and
Tabellini or Persson and Svensson, contend the government of the day can constrain its
successors’ choices by running budget deficits.55 If a successor government has different spending
priorities, the current government may be tempted to influence future fiscal policies by using debt
to change the incentives and constraints facing future decision makers. Such policies are highly
unlikely to be as economically efficient as a more consistent fiscal policy. Some argue that budget
enforcement legislation, such as pay-as-you-go requirements and discretionary budget caps, may
help provide political underpinnings to a more consistent fiscal policy. Some budget analysts
contend that mechanisms created by the 1990 Budget Enforcement Act (P.L. 101-508) led to more
sustainable fiscal policies. European Union fiscal rules on public deficits and debt-to-GDP ratios,
however, may not have led to sustainable fiscal policies in some countries.56
Intergenerational Transfers
Political considerations may also affect how the benefits and costs of government programs are
allocated among generations. Political leaders might seek to please their current constituents by
increasing government spending; however, this shifts fiscal burdens onto unborn taxpayers and
younger cohorts, whose lower voting participation rates may leave them with a weaker voice in
policy discussions. This will hold true because individuals will favor fiscal policy that increases
their lifetime wealth.57 Leaving future taxpayers to pay for higher spending today simply transfers

52 William D. Nordhaus, “The Political Business Cycle,” Review of Economic Studies, vol. 42, no. 2 (April 1975), pp.
169-190.
53 Kenneth Rogoff, “Equilibrium Political Business Cycles,” American Economic Review, vol. 80, no.1 (1990), pp. 21-
36.
54 Allan Drazen, “The Political Business Cycle After 25 Years,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, vol. 15 (2000), pp.
75-117.
55 Alberto Alesina and Guido Tabellini, “A Positive Theory of Fiscal Deficits and Government Debt,” Review of
Economic Studies
, vol. 57, July 1990, pp. 403-414; Torsten Persson and Lars E. O. Svensson, “Why a Stubborn
Conservative Would Run a Deficit: Policy with Time-Inconsistent Preferences,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol.
104 (May 1989), pp. 325-345.
56 The European Union’s Growth and Stability Pact was created as part of negotiations leading to the 1992 Maastricht
Treaty. See Anthony Annett, Jörg Decressin, and Michael Deppler, “Reforming the Stability and Growth Pact,” IMF
Discussion Paper, February 2005, available at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/pdp/2005/pdp02.pdf.
57 Alex Cukierman and Allan H. Meltzer, “A Political Theory of Government Debt and Deficits in a Neo-Ricardian
Framework,” American Economic Review, vol. 79, no. 4 (September 1989).
Congressional Research Service
13

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

the burden to future generations as opposed to focusing on deficit reduction or actual solutions to
higher costs.58 Public debt then becomes a tool used to transfer wealth between generations.
One explanation of persistent deficits is that future generations do not vote, and young citizens
usually vote less often than older citizens. Generations now alive face a temptation to pass on the
costs of programs that benefit themselves to following generations that have no say. Some
shifting of resources to older generations is seen by some as justified on the basis of equity. To the
extent that technological change leads to greater prosperity over time, future generations will
have access to higher standards of living. To the extent that population growth increases the size
of the economy, the burden of financing pay-as-you-go retirement systems is reduced. If some of
those gains are shifted from younger to older generations, then incomes and levels of well-being
would be more equal among generations. Furthermore, in this view, a fiscal policy that shifts
some resources from younger to older generations can raise living standards of all following
generations by transferring a portion of the benefits of future economic growth into the present.
A simple example illustrates this possibility.59 Consider an economy with a fixed population
divided among age-specific cohorts. For the sake of simplicity, suppose individuals live 75 years.
Also assume that income of each cohort is the same, arrives from a source outside the economy,
and grows 3% per year. Consider a fiscal policy that causes each age-specific cohort (except the
oldest) to transfer 2% of its income to the one-year-older cohort. All transfers, except for the
oldest and youngest cohorts, cancel out. The youngest cohort gets 98% of its pre-transfer income,
and the oldest gets 102% of its pre-transfer income. Although the loss to the youngest cohort and
gain to the oldest cohort balance out for each year, each individual born after the start of the plan
gains because of economic growth (so long as the economy’s interest rate is below 3% per year).
With a 3% growth rate over 74 years, income increases by 891%. Therefore, the gain in buying
power per dollar of income in present value terms for a cohort born after the start of the policy is
74
⎛1.03 ⎞
1.02*
- (.98)



⎝ 1+r
where r is the real interest rate. So long as the real interest rate is less than 3%, which is true for
long-term historical real rates of return for U.S. Treasury bills, the policy of shifting resources to
older generations makes all generations better off.60 This highly simplified example shares the
same basic structure as pay-as-you-go social insurance programs, in which young workers pay
contributions that are more or less immediately used to pay benefits to older retirees.61

58 Andrew Samwick, Dartmouth College, “How to Advise on Fiscal Policy,” Vox Baby, July 6, 2007, available at
http://voxbaby.blogspot.com/2007/07/how-to-advise-on-fiscal-policy.html.
59 This example is closely related to the overlapping generations model. For a comprehensive exposition and analysis
see David Gale, “Pure Exchange Equilibrium of Dynamic Economic Models,” Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 5
(1973), pp. 12-36.
60 Goetzmann and Ibbotson found that the real rate of return on U.S. Treasury bills from 1924-2004 was less than 1%
per year. See Table II in William N. Goetzmann and Roger G. Ibbotson, “History and the Equity Risk Premium,” Yale
School of Management working paper, October 2005, available at http://econ.ucsb.edu/conferences/equity05/papers/
Goetzmann.pdf.
61 For a defense of pay-as-you-go financing, see Peter Diamond, “Social Security,” American Economic Review, vol.
94, no.1 (March 2004), pp. 1-24.
Congressional Research Service
14

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

Raising current standards of living by shifting resources from younger to older generations has its
limits. The example above relies on the assumption that the policy continues indefinitely into the
future. With a finite ending point this policy would be unsustainable because some young cohorts
near that end point would be made worse off and would be unwilling to give up resources.
The current fiscal policies’ paths of entitlement spending of the United States imply that large
transfers will be made to the baby-boom generation from younger generations.62 Computations by
Auerbach, Gokhale, and Kotlikoff indicate that future generations will pay much more in taxes
than they will receive from the government.63 In 2000, Gokhale and others estimated that a
newborn male in 1998 would pay $142,500 more in taxes than what he would receive from the
government; the corresponding estimate for a newborn female was $71,300.64 Due to increased
federal deficits, the introduction of Medicare Part D, and falling tax revenues due to the recent
economic recession, those estimates would be higher for current newborns. Despite the projected
magnitude of these intergenerational transfers, younger generations might not be worse off than
their parents if the economy grew at a sufficiently swift pace.
These generational transfers are largely driven by the growth in the number of beneficiaries of
entitlement programs relative to the work force, as well as by rapid increases in health care costs.
The possibility that some future generation may eliminate fiscal policies that it perceives will
lower its standard of living introduces political risk into social insurance programs funded by a
pay-as-you-go mechanism.65 If a generation anticipates that a younger generation will stop
contributing to a pay-as-you-go social insurance program, then it may decide to end the program
itself. A generation whose descendants are unwilling to finance its benefits would have little to
gain, apart from altruistic impulses, by continuing its contributions.66
The Long-Term Budget Outlook
While the recent economic recession and past policy choices have led to large deficits in FY2008
and FY2009, the divergence between government revenues and expenditures is projected to grow.
The “fiscal gap,” the estimated magnitude of revenue increases or spending decreases necessary
to stabilize the ratio of public debt to GDP over a given time horizon, is one measure of that
divergence. 67 According to CBO extended baseline projections, the “fiscal gap” between
government revenues and spending over the next 25 years may be as high as 2.1% of GDP or a

62 Laurence J. Kotlikoff and Scott Burns, The Coming Generational Storm (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2004).
63 Alan J. Auerbach, Jagadeesh Gokhale, and Laurence J. Kotlikoff, “The 1995 Budget and Health Care Reform: A
Generational Perspective,” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, issue QI, 1994, pp. 20-30.
64 Jagadeesh Gokhale, Benjamin Page, Joan Potter, and John Sturrock, “Generational Accounts for the United States:
An Update
,” CBO Technical Paper Series, 2000.
65 John B. Shoven and Sita N. Slavov, “Political Risk versus Market Risk in Social Security,” April 2006, NBER
Working Paper No. W12135, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=896208.
66 Altruistic impulses play an important role in many questions concerning intergenerational transfers. For an overview
of recent research on the subject, see L.-A. Gérard-Varet, S.-C. Kolm and J. Mercier-Ythier (eds.), Handbook of the
Economics of Giving, Reciprocity and Altruism
, vol. 1, (Amsterdam: North Holland, 2006).
67 For a discussion of the relationship between the fiscal gap, generational accounting, accrual accounting, and other
ways of accounting for government, see Alan J. Auerbach, William G. Gale, Peter R. Orszag, and Samara Potter,
“Budget Blues: The Fiscal Outlook and Options for Reform,” in Henry Aaron, James Lindsay, and Pietro Nivola, eds.,
Agenda for the Nation (Washington: Brookings Institution, 2003), pp. 109-143.
Congressional Research Service
15

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

total of an additional $7.1 trillion in debt over the next decade.68 CBO’s alternative fiscal
scenario, which many analysts believe gives a more realistic approximation of future policy, puts
the 25-year fiscal gap even higher at 5.4% of GDP.69 Over longer horizons, the fiscal gap is
projected to become wider still. The CBO extended baseline projects the 75-year fiscal gap at
3.2% of GDP, while the alternative scenario puts it at 8.1% of GDP.70 The growing fiscal gap
signals that younger and unborn generations may bear larger fiscal burdens, which could hinder
their ability to achieve a higher standard of living than their parents. Without significant changes
in fiscal policy, future generations will face the need to adjust tax rates, or government spending
levels, or both, in major ways in order to avoid default.71
Costs of Financing Deficits
A government that runs deficits and is unwilling to raise taxes or cut spending faces three choices.
First, domestic borrowing can be increased at the cost of crowding out domestic investment.
Second, a government can borrow from foreign investors and governments. Borrowing from the
rest of the world prevents deficits from crowding out investment. That is, foreign investors can
provide financial resources now in exchange for future interest payments and profits. As foreign
investors accumulate larger portfolios of stocks, bonds, and other assets, the flow of interest
payments, dividends, and repatriated profits abroad increases as well. Third, a central government
can print money to reduce the real value of debt denominated in domestic currency.
All three options have unpleasant consequences. While fiscal imbalances may gradually build
over time, the consequences of unsustainable fiscal policies may arrive suddenly. Simple supply
and demand theory implies that a smaller supply of savings for private investment will lead to
higher interest rates and lower growth in private capital stocks. Lower stocks of private capital
threaten economic growth, and slower economic growth translates into lower average living
standards in the future. Borrowing from the rest of the world permits higher levels of investment
and faster growth at the cost of sending a higher fraction of earnings abroad. If foreigners lend
capital by purchasing stocks and bonds rather than by building auto plants, for example, they may
decide suddenly someday to take their investments elsewhere. This could strain domestic and
international financial systems, thus constricting firms’ and households’ access to capital.
Foreign investment in the United States plays an important role between balancing domestic
supply and demand of capital. For instance, China held 22.8% of the United States’ debt as of
September 2009.72 The financial crisis and economic downturn, however, have sharply reduced
the demand by foreign investors.73As the share of the federal debt held by foreign entities has

68 U.S. Congressional Budget Office, The Budget and Economic Outlook, An Update, August 2009, available at
http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/105xx/doc10521/08-25-BudgetUpdate.pdf.
69 The CBO baseline assumes that all expiring tax cuts will not be extended and that discretionary spending remains at
its current level. The alternative fiscal scenario extends expiring tax cuts and uses Congress’s past behavior as an
indicator of future actions to predict future spending levels.
70 U.S. Congressional Budget Office, Long Term Budget Outlook, June 2009, available at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/
102xx/doc10297/06-25-LTBO.pdf.
71 Alan J. Auerbach and William G. Gale, “An Update on the Economic and Fiscal Crises: 2009 and Beyond,” working
paper, September 2009.
72 U.S. Treasury, Major Foreign Holders of Treasury Securities, November 17, 2009, available at
http://www.ustreas.gov/tic/mfh.txt.
73 CRS Report RL32462, Foreign Investment in U.S. Securities, by James K. Jackson.
Congressional Research Service
16

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

grown, so has concern about possible consequences. While the risk of a sudden or coordinated
sale of U.S. Treasury securities is low, the large foreign holdings of U.S. debt may introduce new
contingencies that could complicate financial and foreign policy.
Finally, inflation caused by printing money distorts the flow of information generated by the price
system and disrupts financial markets. Investors, who wish to avoid capital losses in real terms,
typically demand higher nominal interest rates when they see signs of inflation. During the 1970s,
the real value of the federal debt fell sharply as inflation accelerated. While inflation in the past
has helped ease the burden of federal debt, bringing inflation under control can be costly. Many
economists believe that the restrictive monetary policies needed to squeeze rapid inflation out of
an economy would require substantial economic disruption, at least in the short run. Moreover, in
the current fiscal environment, inflation might not be an effective means of reducing the value of
federal debt for two reasons. First, some Treasury securities are now indexed for inflation.
Second, much of the fiscal imbalance facing the federal government is linked to the implicit cost
of funding scheduled benefits for large entitlement programs such as Medicare and Social
Security, rather than accumulated federal debt.
Reducing government deficits can improve economic performance in at least three ways. First,
paying off government debt increases the supply of investment funds available for domestic
investment. Second, paying off government debt held by foreign governments or investors
reduces the amount of interest payments going abroad. Alternatively, paying off debt held by
domestic investors gives them the opportunity to rebalance their portfolios by buying foreign
assets, which offsets some of the flow of dividends and profits going abroad, or by buying
domestic assets that otherwise would have been bought by foreign investors. Third, scaling down
the federal debt decreases the temptation to reduce its real value by printing money, lessening the
possibility of a major acceleration in inflation. Finally, most economists believe reducing
government borrowing lowers interest rates, which in turn encourages investment and growth.
Conclusion
Some economists disagree on the effects of government’s ability to smooth economic recessions.
The ability of governments to run deficits can help avoid short-term fiscal crises caused by
adverse economic shocks. Long-term deficits can be used to allow older generations to enjoy
some of the anticipated fruits of future economic growth. A government can sustain a debt
indefinitely, so long as the size of the debt relative to the size of the economy does not grow
without bound. Maintaining a large debt requires large interest payments and can retard economic
growth. Thus deficits can serve as a useful tool of economic management in the short run, but
also can cause substantial economic damage to the economy over the long term.
Author Contact Information

D. Andrew Austin

Analyst in Economic Policy
aaustin@crs.loc.gov, 7-6552

Congressional Research Service
17

Running Deficits: Positives and Pitfalls

Acknowledgments
Joseph R. McCormack assisted with the March 2010 update of this report.

Congressional Research Service
18