ȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱ
ȱ
ȱ ǯȱ ȱ
ȱȱȱȱ¢ȱ
ȱǯȱȱ
ȱȱȱȱ
¢ȱŘŞǰȱŘŖŖşȱ
ȱȱȱ
ŝȬśŝŖŖȱ
ǯǯȱ
řŚŚşŚȱ
ȱȱȱ
Pr
epared for Members and Committees of Congress
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
¢ȱ
The foreign tax credit alleviates the double-taxation that would result if U.S. investors’ overseas
income were to be taxed by both the United States and a foreign country. U.S. taxpayers credit
foreign taxes paid against U.S. taxes they would otherwise owe, and in doing so concede that the
country where income is earned has the primary right to tax that income. But the United States
retains the primary right to tax U.S.-source income, placing a limit on the foreign tax credit:
foreign taxes can only offset the part of a U.S. taxpayer’s U.S. tax that falls on foreign source
income. It is this limit to which the American Jobs Creation Act of 2004 (P.L. 108-357, Jobs Act)
applied. To calculate the limit, a firm separates its revenue and costs, for tax purposes, into those
having a foreign source and those having a U.S. source. Foreign taxes can offset U.S. tax on
revenue “sourced” abroad; in effect, foreign-source income is exempt from U.S. tax for firms
whose foreign tax credits exceed the limit (firms with “excess credits”). But because deductions
allocated abroad reduce U.S. tax, the effect is the same as if deductions allocated to foreign
sources can not be claimed for U.S. tax purposes.
If a U.S. firm has foreign investments, current law requires at least part of the U.S. interest to be
allocated to foreign sources based on the theory that debt is fungible—that regardless of where
funds are borrowed, they support a firm’s worldwide investment. But multinational firms have
argued that if part of domestic interest is allocated abroad, part of foreign interest should be
allocated to the United States, which would reduce U.S. tax. (Some critics have suggested,
however, that granting multinationals tax benefits through interest allocation revisions should be
accompanied by restrictions on the benefit of deferral, which allows taxes.)
This worldwide allocation rule was adopted in the Jobs Act, but has not yet been implemented.
The Jobs Act called for implementation starting in 2009, while P.L. 110-289 has subsequently
delayed implementation until 2011. Other bills introduced in the 110th Congress, including H.R.
3920, H.R. 5720, H.R. 6049, and H.R. 7060, would have also delayed or repealed the
implementation of the worldwide interest allocation rule.
The analysis here suggests that current law’s interest allocation rules are likely imperfectly
structured to achieve the objective of the foreign tax credit limit and that worldwide allocation of
interest as enacted by the Jobs Act, while losing revenue, would probably be more consistent with
the basic objective of the foreign tax credit limit. Tax planning techniques however, could
undermine this objective and cause further revenue loss. And, like the foreign tax credit limit
itself, allocation rules contribute to tax distortions which may be heightened with worldwide
allocation. Further, an expansion of the bank “subgroup” elections contained in the Jobs Act may
not be consistent with the general objective of worldwide allocation of interest. Although the Jobs
Act contains anti-abuse rules, these subgroup elections may permit firms to avoid the impact of
the interest allocation rules. This report will be updated as legislative events warrant.
ȱȱȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
ȱ
Function and Mechanisms of the U.S. Foreign Tax Credit ............................................................. 1
Deferral ..................................................................................................................................... 2
Foreign Tax Credit Limitation................................................................................................... 2
Interest Allocation Rules ................................................................................................................. 3
“Worldwide” Allocation............................................................................................................ 4
The Advantages of Worldwide Allocation ................................................................................ 4
Disadvantages of Worldwide Allocation................................................................................... 4
Administrative Complications ............................................................................................ 4
Tax Planning ....................................................................................................................... 5
Economic Efficiency........................................................................................................... 5
Interest Rate Differentials ................................................................................................... 6
Subgroup Elections.......................................................................................................................... 7
Conclusion....................................................................................................................................... 7
¡ȱ
Appendix. Effects of Alternative Allocation Rules ......................................................................... 8
ȱ
Author Contact Information .......................................................................................................... 13
ȱȱȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
he American Jobs Creation Act of 2004 (P.L. 108-357; the Jobs Act) contained a number
of provisions related to the taxation of multi-national corporations. Among these
provisions were more generous rules for multinationals to use in allocating interest
T expense for purposes of the U.S. foreign tax credit. This rule is referred to as the
“worldwide” allocation of interest and it is the subject of this report. The act’s changes
are due to take effect for tax years beginning after December 31, 2008. The implementation was,
subsequently, delayed until tax years beginning after December 31, 2010, by P.L. 110-289. Other
proposals introduced in the 110th Congress, including H.R. 5720, H.R. 6049, H.R. 3920, and H.R.
7060, would have also delayed or repealed the worldwide interest allocation rule.
The Jobs Act’s interest allocation provision was designed to correct what some argue was an
imperfection in the design of the foreign tax credit rules. In general, the tax code places a limit on
the foreign tax credit. To calculate the limit, firms are required to separate interest and other
expenses according to source—foreign or domestic. Because of effects detailed below, the more
interest that is assigned to domestic sources, the more foreign tax credits a firm can claim and the
lower its U.S. tax liability. Some believed that the prior law’s approach unduly left taxpayers
exposed to double taxation of foreign-source income.1 The Jobs Act addressed this perceived
flaw.
The analysis here indicates that worldwide allocation rules, while losing revenue, would likely be
better aligned with the objective of the foreign tax credit. Tax planning techniques could
undermine this objective—and lead to increased revenue loss and efficiency costs.
The act contained another relevant modification to the interest allocation rules, that would
increase a firm’s creditable taxes. Specifically, the provision expands the subgroup election for
banks to include other financial intermediaries, including insurance companies—which allows for
the separate calculation of interest allocation. This provision could insulate some firms from a
portion of the interest allocation rules, and it is at odds with the theory underlying the act’s other
provisions.
ȱȱȱȱȱǯǯȱȱ¡ȱ
ȱ
The United States—in principle—taxes its resident corporations and individuals on their
worldwide income, regardless of where it is earned, under the residence rule. The foreign tax
credit and deferral, are the key structural pieces of the U.S. taxation of foreign-source income.
The foreign tax credit provisions generally permit U.S. taxpayers to credit foreign taxes they pay
against U.S. taxes they would otherwise owe—on a dollar-for-dollar basis. For example, a U.S.
corporation chartered in North Dakota is potentially subject to U.S. tax on income it earns outside
the United States. Concurrently, however, the foreign countries where the income is earned
generally tax that income, even if it is earned by a foreign (U.S. in this case) investor, under the
source principle. In the absence of the foreign tax credit, this income would potentially face
double-taxation and possibly very high tax rates.
1 U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, General Explanation of Tax Legislation Enacted in the 108th Congress,
JCS-5-05, May 2005 (Washington: GPO, 2005).
ȱȱȱ
ŗȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
The foreign tax credit, however, generally alleviates the possibility of double-taxation of foreign-
source income. With the credit, the U.S. concedes that the country where income is earned has the
primary right to tax that income and collect the tax revenue that it generates.2 This results in the
U.S. collecting only the U.S. tax due after paying foreign taxes—if positive. As such, the foreign
tax credit helps to define the U.S. tax jurisdiction and it is not a tax expenditure favoring selected
groups. While theoretically straight-forward, overlapping jurisdictions introduce numerous
complications. To better understand interest allocation rules, it is useful to first examine two key
structural pieces: deferral and the foreign tax credit limitation.
ȱ
As noted above, deferral is one of the key structural pieces of the U.S. taxation of foreign-source
income. U.S.-owned firms can conduct their foreign operations through foreign chartered
subsidiaries. Unlike U.S. chartered firms, these foreign-chartered corporations are generally taxed
only on income earned in the United States. Thus, where a U.S. parent firm invests abroad
through a foreign chartered subsidiary, U.S. taxes do not apply to its foreign income, as long as
the income is reinvested abroad.3 U.S. taxes are, in other words, deferred or postponed. Because
of discounting, firms view the cost of taxes paid in the future as less than an identical amount
paid in the present. U.S. taxes do apply when the income is repatriated to the U.S. parent firm as
intra-firm dividends.
Foreign tax credits can be claimed with respect to U.S. tax on dividends received from foreign
subsidiaries. In addition to the direct credit, “indirect” foreign tax credits can be claimed by a
U.S. parent firm for foreign taxes paid by the subsidiary during the time the income was tax-
deferred.4
ȱ¡ȱȱȱ
As noted above, the U.S. concedes that the country where income is earned has the primary right
to tax that income and collect the tax revenue that it generates. The U.S. retains, however, the
primary right to tax U.S. source-income. In order to protect its domestic tax base, the U.S.
imposes a limitation on the foreign tax credit.5 In effect, the tax code only allows foreign tax
credits to offset the U.S. tax on foreign source-income. Any foreign taxes paid in excess of the
limit become “excess credits” and can be carried back one year and carried forward up to 10
years.6
The foreign tax credit and its mechanics can be understood clearly by looking at the tax rate on
foreign income that is produced by the foreign tax credit. With the foreign tax credit and its
2 That is, the resident principle is subordinate to the source principle when the two are asserted by different
jurisdictions.
3 Income received under Subpart F rules, which are aimed at sheltering activities, is not eligible for deferral.
4 While the U.S. parent can claim indirect foreign tax credits with respect to dividends, the dividends are also “grossed
up” by the amount of the foreign tax before they are included in the parent’s taxable income. Thus, a parent’s taxable
dividend from foreign sources is 1/(1-t), where t is the foreign tax rate.
5 In the absence of a limit, foreign countries could, in theory, divert tax revenue from the U.S. by simply raising their
taxes on U.S. investors—without fear of placing additional burdens on the U.S. firms themselves.
6 Firms whose foreign taxes exceed the limit are said to be in an excess credit position.
ȱȱȱ
Řȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
limitations, a U.S. investor pays total taxes (U.S. plus foreign taxes) on foreign income at an
average rate equal to the higher of the U.S. pre-credit tax rate or the foreign tax rate. For example,
if a firm pays U.S. tax at a 35% rate and the foreign tax rate is 10%, its total tax on foreign
income would consist of the 10% foreign tax plus the 25% of U.S. tax that remains after the 10%
offset by the foreign tax credit.7 If, instead, the foreign tax rate is 50%, the firm could offset all of
its U.S. tax on foreign income with the foreign tax credit, and would pay only foreign taxes—at a
50% rate.8
If a firm is in an excess credit position—its foreign taxes exceed U.S. tax on foreign-source
income—the sourcing of income and deductions matters. Under the foreign tax credit limitation,
maximum creditable foreign taxes are limited to the amount of U.S. pre-credit tax falling on
foreign source income rather than domestic-source income. It follows that if, for example, an item
of revenue is determined to have a foreign rather than U.S. source, then the maximum foreign tax
credit is increased because foreign income and the share of U.S. pre-credit tax falling on foreign
income is increased. The reverse is true with deductions; a deduction allocated to foreign rather
than U.S. sources reduces foreign income and U.S. pre-credit tax on foreign income; it reduces
creditable foreign taxes and increases after-credit U.S. tax.
ȱȱȱ
Whether an expense is deducted from foreign or U.S. income matters for tax purposes. The tax
code, therefore, contains rules for allocating deductions between foreign and U.S. sources. In the
case of interest expense, the rules generally are based on the approach that money is fungible and
that interest expense is properly attributable to all business activities and property of a taxpayer,
regardless of any specific purpose for incurring an obligation on which interest is paid. For
example, a U.S. parent company might borrow in the U.S. and use the funds to increase its equity
stake in a foreign subsidiary, which uses those borrowed funds to make its own investments.
Conversely, a U.S. firm could borrow domestically to finance domestic investment—investment
that might otherwise have been financed through repatriated earnings. In this case, domestic
borrowing may support both domestic and foreign investment.9
While it is beyond the scope of this report to determine if the fungibility of debt is a reasonable
assumption, except to recognize that it underlies both the current interest allocation rules and
those enacted by the Jobs Act, some facts on each side are worth noting. First, in favor of
fungibility, corporations are legal entities, and not economic ones. As a result corporate
boundaries can be easily manipulated for financial gain. Conversely, the existence of cross-
jurisdictional interest rate differentials suggest that fungibility may not hold between all
jurisdictions.
Current law applies the fungibility principle in a manner sometimes referred to as “waters edge”
allocation. Under this system, foreign subsidiaries are not explicitly included in the allocation.
This has two implications for the allocation formula. First, only a domestic parent’s equity stake
in its foreign subsidiary is counted as an asset—excluding the foreign subsidiary’s assets financed
by debt. The parent’s assets, in contrast, are all included in the calculation—whether financed by
7 Thus, the total tax rate is 35%—10% plus 25%.
8 These relationships assume a uniform definition of taxable income in the U.S. and foreign countries.
9 This implies a fungibility of equity, i.e. the subsidiary’s retained earnings support investment at home and abroad.
ȱȱȱ
řȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
equity or debt. Secondly, the subsidiary’s interest expense is automatically allocated to foreign
sources. This occurs since the subsidiary’s interest expense reduces dividend payments to the
parent, which are all allocated to foreign sources.
ȃ Ȅȱȱ
An alternative to the “waters edge” allocation is a “worldwide” allocation regime, such as enacted
by the Jobs Act.10 Under a “worldwide” allocation, the borrowing of foreign subsidiaries would
be taken into account. This change would have two effects, which combined, increase the foreign
tax credit limit of multinationals and therefore decrease after-credit U.S. taxes. The first effect
involves including interest of the foreign subsidiary. By allocating a portion of foreign debt to
domestic use, this reduces foreign source deductions, increases foreign source income, increases
the foreign tax credit limit and reduces U.S. tax liability. The second effect involves counting
foreign subsidiary, debt financed assets as part of the worldwide asset base of the parent
company. Taken in isolation, this would allocate more interest to foreign sources and raise U.S.
tax liability. Mathematically, however, the first effect dominates—so tax liability is reduced under
worldwide allocation.
ȱȱȱ ȱȱ
One can argue that worldwide allocation more accurately limits the foreign tax credit to income
that is attributable to a foreign source, as long as borrowed funds are fungible. Briefly, this
perspective results as follows: if it is true that borrowing in one location finances investment in all
locations equally; then it is true that borrowing domestically or abroad should not alter the share
of income earned domestically or abroad. Remembering that the purpose of the foreign tax credit
limitation is to protect the U.S. tax base, while minimizing double-taxation of foreign-source
income, it then follows that location of borrowing should not affect the maximum creditable
foreign taxes. Under current law, the limitation can be affected by shifting the borrowing location.
ȱȱ ȱȱ
While worldwide allocation would achieve a more accurate foreign tax credit limitation, there are
also some complications and disadvantages to such an approach, including administrative
complications, tax planning complications, and increases in investment distortions (even though
U.S. revenue is lost). Also, if interest rates vary across jurisdictions, it isn’t clear whether
fungibility of borrowing is pervasive and that worldwide allocation of interest is completely
appropriate to achieving the goal of limiting the foreign tax credit to income that is attributable to
a foreign source.
ȱȱ
One obvious disadvantage of worldwide allocation is that it would require foreign subsidiaries,
which are not always wholly owned by U.S. firms, to classify their assets and borrowing for U.S.
10 The interest allocation provisions of the Jobs Act become effective for taxable years beginning after December 31,
2008.
ȱȱȱ
Śȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
tax purposes as having a U.S. or foreign location. This change would complicate both IRS tax
administration and firm compliance.
¡ȱȱ
A second issue with worldwide allocation is the possibility that firms could artificially increase
their gross foreign assets to eliminate any interest allocation. Under worldwide allocation, there
are no decreases in the foreign tax credit limit if the foreign subsidiary has a debt to asset ratio as
high or higher than the parent company. However, if firms could borrow and redeposit funds, they
could increase their debt to gross asset ratios. For example, suppose a parent company has $100
million in assets and its subsidiary also has $100 million in assets, with only $50 million in debt
attributable to the parent company. Under both current and pending law, half of the debt ($25
million) would be allocated to the subsidiary. This allocation is consistent with the worldwide
fungibility of debt. Suppose, however, that the subsidiary could borrow $100 million and
redeposit the $100 million in a bank account, then no allocation would occur. The subsidiary
would now have $200 million in gross assets, two-thirds of the total, gross debt would be $150
million and $50 million would be allocated to domestic uses.
The possibility of borrowing is one reason to restrain the allocation to a non-negative one;
otherwise this technique could be used, at the extreme, to further reduce U.S. tax liability and to
render the foreign tax credit limit meaningless.
While this discussion outlines a possible tax planning technique; firms may not choose to use it
and that transaction costs could reduce the value of the technique. It does illustrate that at an
extreme, tax planning could eliminate the allocation rules entirely. It is possible that other
methods could be used to prevent such abuses, but they would likely be complex and add to the
administrative complications, mentioned above.
ȱ¢ȱ
Another worldwide allocation issue concerns economic efficiency. As noted above, the purpose of
the foreign tax credit limit is not to ensure the efficient allocation of resources; rather, it is
concerned with protecting the U.S. tax base. The impact of worldwide allocation on the ability of
the economy to efficiently allocate investment and borrowing among different locations, however,
can be viewed as one cost of fine-tuning the foreign tax credit limitation. In some respects,
worldwide allocation might create greater distortions in the allocation of debt and equity capital,
relative to the non-tax allocation.
First, worldwide allocation magnifies tax-based incentives to borrow abroad—an important
consideration if debt is not fungible, as assumed. Allocating interest on the worldwide basis of
aggregate capital stock, for purposes of the foreign tax credit limit, effectively reduces borrowing
in the U.S. and increases it abroad. In effect, any savings can be calculated by multiplying the
foreign tax rate times the interest shifted abroad. For example, if the interest rate were 10 percent
and the foreign tax rate 40 percent, a $100 dollar shift in debt from the U.S. to a foreign locale
would save the company $4. If there were no allocation rules, however, then the shift in debt
abroad would lead to a larger interest deduction abroad, but a smaller foreign tax credit limit,
because the flow of dividends is net of interest costs. In this case, the benefit of shifting is the
difference in the tax rates. Continuing our example, the foreign tax rate is 40 percent and the U.S.
tax rate is 35 percent, so that the savings is only $0.50 (0.05 times the interest). The current
ȱȱȱ
śȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
system is in between these two cases; the allocation of domestic interest does mean that a shift in
the debt abroad has an effect in reducing the foreign tax credit limitation, but not the effect that
would occur with no allocation rules.
Similarly, the degree to which equity investment is discouraged in the high tax countries (a
general efficiency problem with international taxation), while minimized when there is no
allocation rule at all, is likely to be larger with the worldwide allocation system than with the
current allocation system.
The efficiency effects of shifting both debt and equity abroad simultaneously would be more
complex and depend upon the level of debt by the parent firm and other factors. In some cases,
the current allocation rules cause more distortions and in some cases they reduce distortions.
Overall, the best system for minimizing the distortions in both the allocation of borrowing and
equity investment is to have no allocation rules at all. Nevertheless, if the parent tends to do most
of the borrowing (which may occur for a variety of non-tax reasons), having no allocation rules
could cause a significant loss of U.S. revenue compared to both the current system and to the
worldwide approach. That is, some efficiency cost is necessary to protect the U.S. tax base. In
both cases, however, partial allocation rules are less distortionary than full allocation rules. The
rules are less clear with respect to investment shifts that occur simultaneously with debt shift.
These issues become more complicated when considering multiple country investments. Since
firms are generally not required to calculate separate foreign tax credit limits for different
countries, firms can use excess credits from one country—a high tax country—to shelter income
from a low tax country from U.S. tax. Accordingly, even if a firm is in an excess credit position
and makes interest allocations, it will still be faced with an incentive to invest in low-tax
countries. Moreover, it is difficult to make precise judgements about economic efficiency when
the tax system is not efficient in other ways, such as with deferral. Nevertheless it is interesting
that there are cases where a change in the allocation rules that lowers taxes of multinational
corporations can magnify distortions.
ȱȱȱ
A final complication relating to interest allocation rules is the possibility of interest rate
differentials. In a perfect world with completely mobile capital, such interest rate differentials
would not occur. However, if the domestic savers prefer investing in particular locations or there
are differences in risk across locations, such differentials may arise. In particular, if foreign
interest rates are higher than U.S. rates, worldwide allocation rules will have a larger effect
increasing the foreign tax credit limit than would be the case where interest rates are identical.
It is difficult to ascertain how these interest rate differentials should influence the allocation
process. Certainly, the presence of interest rate differentials suggests that the very presumption of
fungibility is in question, and also suggests that the presumed standard that justifies worldwide
allocation—equal debt-to-equity ratios—may not be the case. While beyond the scope of this
paper, this area may need further exploration.
ȱȱȱ
Ŝȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
ȱȱ
Along with allowing firms to allocate interest expense on the basis of worldwide groups, the Jobs
Act contained an additional related change. Current law contains a subgroup election for firms
that are banks. The act expands this election to a wider range of financial intermediaries,
including finance companies and insurance firms. Such an election could, potentially, reduce the
amount of interest a worldwide group is required to allocate to foreign sources. For example, a
firm that has a financial subsidiary which conducts genuine financial intermediation could
arrange to have a portion of the non-financial part of the firms’ borrowing undertaken by the
subsidiary. If the financial subsidiary’s assets are principally located in the U.S., borrowing
through the subsidiary could be insulated from allocation rules. More directly stated, firms could
distribute their borrowing among related subsidiaries to minimize foreign allocations of interest.
The act does contain anti-abuse provisions whose apparent intent is to limit such arrangements.
Nonetheless, it remains to be seen if the anti-abuse provisions will be effective in limiting such
arrangements.
As mentioned above, the Jobs Act contains a number of rules intended to limit the extent to which
the expansion of the bank group election can be used to avoid interest allocation. For example,
the act would limit the extent to which a subgroup member can increase the portion of its
earnings it pays to the parent as dividends. This rule is, presumably, designed to limit the means
by which a subgroup can borrow and subsequently transmit debt to its parent. If the subgroup is
new, however, the rules for calculating average dividends are confined to the subgroups’ years in
existence, which may provide a mechanism for avoiding the limitation.
In short, the act’s subgroup election provision appears to present potential opportunities for firms
to avoid the allocation of interest according to the fungibility principle. Unlike the act’s other
changes in the allocation rules (discussed above), this feature of the bill appears to move the
system away from the “theoretically pure” foreign tax credit limitation under the assumption of
fungibility.
ȱ
The analysis in this report suggests that there are benefits and disadvantages to worldwide
allocation of interest enacted by the Jobs Act. If debt is fungible, worldwide allocation is the most
accurate method of ensuring that the U.S. foreign tax credit is used for its intended purpose:
allowing the foreign tax credit to offset the full share of U.S. pre-credit tax that falls on foreign
source income. Absent additional rules, however, opportunities for tax planning may limit the
achievement of this objective. Also, like the foreign tax credit limit itself, allocation rules tend to
contribute to the distortions that discourage equity investment abroad. Adopting worldwide
allocation rules could, in several ways, increase these distortions relative to current law. While the
distortions created by current law can be viewed as a cost of collecting taxes—since they increase
U.S. revenue—and potential increased distortion associated with worldwide rules cannot since
they decrease U.S. revenue.
Finally, the subgroup election provision in the Jobs Act does not appear consistent with the
general objective of the foreign tax credit limit or the act’s own worldwide allocation regime.
This subgroup election may permit firms to reduce the current domestic interest allocation costs,
while achieving foreign interest allocation benefits.
ȱȱȱ
ŝȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
¡ǯ ȱȱȱȱȱ
This appendix derives the allocation rules that most accurately support the foreign tax credit
limitation—the rules that most accurately limit creditable foreign taxes to U.S. tax on foreign-
source income. While this ideal rule is one under which the location of borrowing does not affect
the foreign tax credit limit for U.S. tax purposes, taxpayers could still change their overall (that is,
foreign and U.S. combined) tax liability by switching the location of borrowing. The appendix
continues by showing how the incentive to borrow abroad is affected by allocation rules. The
discussion concludes with an analysis of how the allocation rules affect investment.
ȱȱȱȱ
The shape that accurate allocation rules take depends, crucially, upon the assumption of debt
fungibility. As noted in the text, it is unclear whether fungibility accurately represents real world
experiences. Since both current and enacted law both make this assumption, however, fungibility
will be assumed—that debt supports investment in all locations, regardless of the borrowing
locale.
With the assumption of fungibility, a shift in the location of borrowing should not shift the
location of investment. Further, since investment produces income, a shift in the location of
borrowing should not alter the proportion of income earned at home or abroad. Thus, for the
foreign tax credit limit to be accurate, a firm should not be able to affect the limit by shifting its
location of borrowing.
ȱȱȱ ȱȱȱȱ
Assume a multinational’s U.S. tax liability can be expressed as:
(1) U.S. Tax = t(Y + D/(1 - tf) - iBd) - tD/(1 - tf);
where t is the U.S. tax rate, Y is U.S.-source income before interest deductions, D is dividends
from a foreign subsidiary, tf is the foreign tax rate, i is the interest rate, and Bd is domestic
borrowing. The equation’s first term represents the tax on worldwide income, with dividends
grossed up to a pre-foreign tax basis, while the second term is the foreign tax credit, which is
limited to the U.S. tax on grossed up dividends. The foreign tax credit is also limited to actual
foreign taxes paid (or deemed paid, in the case of dividends). As a result, changing the base of the
foreign tax credit only has an effect when a company is in an “excess credit” position—where the
foreign tax rate is greater than the U.S. rate.
For this analysis, foreign subsidiary dividends are defined in terms of foreign earnings and other
elements as:
(2) Yf = D + R + iBf + tf(Yf - iBf);
where Yf is foreign earnings before deducting interest, R is retained earnings, and Bf is borrowing
by the foreign subsidiary. In all cases, the amounts would be scaled back for a subsidiary that isn’t
wholly owned (e.g., if a subsidiary is 90 percent owned, then all three values would be multiplied
ȱȱȱ
Şȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
by 0.9). Foreign earnings are the sum of dividends, retained earnings, interest payments, and
foreign taxes. Therefore:
(3) D/(1 - tf) = Yf - R/(1 - tf) - iBf .
Thus, equation (1) can be rewritten:
(4) U.S. Tax - t(Y + Yf - R/(1 - tf) - iBf - iBd) - t(Yf - R/(1 - tf) - iBf).
For a firm in an excess credit position, the limitation, L, is the last term:
(5) L = t(Yf - R/(1 - tf) - iBf).
In this world, without allocation rules that require the allocation of domestic interest to foreign
sources, the taxpayer could increase the limitation—and reduce their taxes—by shifting
borrowing to their subsidiary (by reducing iBf and increasing iBd by equal amounts). Clearly, if
fungibility is assumed, requiring no allocation rules does not result in an effective limitation.
ȱȱȱ¢ȱȱ DZȱȱȱ
For the limitation to be unaffected by the location of borrowing, geographic-specific borrowing
cannot be a parameter in equation (5). That is, neither Bf nor Bd can appear in the equation. This
condition is satisfied, incompletely, by replacing the term iBf in the equation with iBT. In this
formulation, the limitation could be unaffected by the borrowing location with an allocation rule
allocating all borrowing costs to foreign income, or, alternatively, to domestic income. Clearly,
this is at odds with the assumption of fungibility. That is, if a firm has both foreign and domestic
investment supported by borrowing, some portion of the interest on total borrowing must be
allocated to foreign sources and that proportion must be independent of the borrowing locale.
Thus, assuming fungibility, an accurate limitation can be written as:
(6) L = t(Yf - R/(1 - tf) - iABT);
where A is the portion of interest allocated to foreign sources. Fungibility requires that “A”
cannot be an arbitrarily chosen fraction (50%, for example), and that only the location of assets
defines “A”. Thus:
(7) A = Kf/KT.
The ideal limitation can, therefore, be defined as:
(8) L* = t(Yf - R/(1 - tf) - i((Kf/KT)BT)).
Next, we compare the current law’s allocation and the Jobs Act’s rules to this ideal formula.
ȱȱȱ¢ȱȱ DZȱȱ ȱȱȱȱȱ
As noted in the text, current law requires part of domestic borrowing to be allocated to foreign
sources. However, because the subsidiary’s own interest payments reduce repatriated earnings
and not domestic-source income, all the subsidiary’s borrowing costs are automatically allocated
to foreign sources. Thus the parameter BT in the ideal limitation, equation (8), above, is replaced
ȱȱȱ
şȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
by Bd. In addition, not all the subsidiaries’ assets are included in the allocation rule, A—only the
parent’s equity stake in the subsidiary is included. Thus,
(9) A = (Kf - Bf)/(KT - Bf) and
(10) L = t(Yf - R/(1 - tf) - iBf - i((Kf - Bf)/(KT - BF))Bd),
and since Bd = BT - Bf,
(11) L = t(Yf - R/(1 - tf) - iBf - i((Kf - Bf)/(KT - BF))(BT - Bf)).
Given that the limitation is, clearly, dependent on the location of borrowing—i.e. the respective
values of Bf and Bd, current law violates the principle of fungibility. That is, a taxpayer can
increase or decrease the limitation by shifting the borrowing location. While a full discussion of
this topic is in the following section, below, note for now that dL/dBf > 0 and that a taxpayer can
increase their limitation by shifting borrowing from domestic to foreign locations.
Given current law violates the principle of fungibility, let’s turn to the JOBS Act’s rules. As noted
in the text, all assets of the subsidiary are included in the allocation formula. Thus, equation (7) is
unchanged. Additionally, the interest expense of the subsidiary is also subject to allocation—both
Bd, as in equation (9), and Bf are multiplied by A. This can be accomplished by allocating part of
domestic interest to foreign sources and part of foreign interest to domestic sources—since
foreign borrowing has already been netted out of the dividend. Thus, the limitation equation can
be expressed as:
(12) L = t(Yf - R/(1 - tf) - iBf - iBd(Kf/KT) + iBf(Kd/KT)).
This simplifies to:
(13) L = L* = t(Yf - R/(1 - tf) - i((Kf/KT)BT)),
which is the ideal limitation formula, equation (8). As it is consistent with fungibility, the value of
the limitation is independent of the location of borrowing, and it is proportional to the location of
investment.
ȱȱ ȱȱ
In order to examine the effects of tax regimes on borrowing locale, we depart from the base
model by adding foreign taxes. To simplify the analysis, we assume a single tax rate applies to
both dividends and retained earnings. This analysis assumes that foreign tax authorities do not
make allocation adjustments. Thus the total tax paid by a company can be expressed as:
(14) Total Tax = t(Y + Yf - R/(1 - tf) - iBT) - t(Yf - R/((1-tf) -
iBf - i((BT - Bf)(Kf - Bf)/(KT - Bf)) + tf(Yf - iBf)
where tf is the foreign tax rate.
This rule can be contrasted with the circumstances where there is no allocation rule in place:
(15) Total Tax = t(Y + Yf - R/(1 - tf) - iBT) - t(Yf - R/((1-tf) - iBf) + tf(Yf - iBf)
ȱȱȱ
ŗŖȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
and the worldwide allocation rule, contained in the Jobs Act:
(16) Total Tax = t(Y + Yf - R/(1 - tf) - iBT) - t(Yf - R/((1-tf) - i(Kf/KT)BT) + tf(Yf - iBf).
Totally differentiating equation (14) gives us the effect of shifting a small amount of debt from
domestic to foreign use, under current law, as:
(17) Change in Tax = -tfi + ti(KT - Kf)* (KT - BT) * Change in Foreign Debt
(KT - Bf) (KT - Bf).
When there is no allocation rule, the result is:
(18) Change in Tax = (-tfi + ti) * Change in Foreign Debt,
and finally, with worldwide allocation:
(19) Change in Tax = -tfi * Change in Foreign Debt.
Note that the largest incentive to borrow abroad occurs with the worldwide allocation, and the
smallest incentive occurs with no allocation rules. Without allocation rules, the savings from
shifting debt abroad is the difference between the tax savings from the foreign deduction and the
tax savings from the domestic deduction. With worldwide allocation, worldwide interest is
allocated the same way regardless of where it originates, so that the only effects that multiply the
expression ti, each one less than one, that dilute but do not eliminate the effect of the foreign tax
credit limit. The first term is the direct effect from allocating domestic interest and the second is
the effect of using net rather than gross foreign assets in the allocation formula.
ȱȱ¢ȱȱ
Next, let us consider the effect of allocation rules on equity investment. To do so, we change the
notation slightly to reflect the idea that gross income is the return on capital multiplied by the
capital stock.11 Under current law, the total tax of a firm can be expressed as:
(20) Total Tax = t(rKd + rfKf - R/(1 - tf) - iBT) - t(rfKf - R/(1 - tf) - iBf
-i(BT - Bf)(Kf - Bf)/(KT - Bf)) + tf(rfKf - iBf)
where r is the return on U.S. capital and rf is the return to foreign capital, both on a before-tax
basis.
This rule can be contrasted with the circumstances where there is no allocation rule at all:
(21) Total Tax = t(rKd + rfKf - R/(1 - tf) - iBT) - t(rfKf - R/(1 - tf) - iBf) + tf(rfKf - iBf)
and the Jobs Act rule, with worldwide allocation:
11 For completeness, one would need to make a similar adjustment to retained earnings. In this analysis, however,
retained earnings cancels out.
ȱȱȱ
ŗŗȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
(22) Total Tax = t(rKd + rfKf - R/(1 - tf) - iBT) - t(rfKf - R/(1 - tf) - (iBTKf/KT))
+ tf(rfKf - iBf).
In order to isolate the tax effect, consider the case where the pretax returns are equal—in practice
they will not equal after the consideration of tax rules. Further, consider the case where very
small, but slightly, different taxes are added to this, previously, case without taxes.
Next, we totally differentiating equations (20)-(22) with respect to Kf, which holds the firm’s total
capital stock fixed.
The change in the tax liability under current law with a reallocation of capital is:
(23) Change in Tax = ((tf - t)r + ti( Bd )) * Change in Foreign Capital
(KT - Bf*).
When there are no allocation rules:
(24) Change in Tax = (tf - t)r * Change in Foreign Capital,
and under worldwide allocation rules:
(25) Change in Tax = ((tf - t) + ti BT ) * Change in Foreign Capital.
KT
In all three cases, the tax systems discourage investment abroad, due to the high tax country.
Allocation rules magnify this effect because the adjustment to the foreign tax credit limit
increases with larger shares of the capital stock located abroad. In this case, however, the
worldwide allocation rule will further discourage investment abroad because of a more powerful
effect on the allocation rule. As a result, worldwide allocation is likely to be less efficient than
domestic interest allocation with respect to disincentives for equity investment.12
ȱȱȱȱ¢ȱȱȱ¢ȱ
Finally, we consider the effects on investment abroad that are financed by both debt and equity.
Assume that the debt to asset ratio of the subsidiary is fixed, and that the total assets and debt of
the parent and subsidiary are also fixed.
To consider the effects on equity investment, we again adjust our notation to reflect idea that
gross income is the return on capital multiplied by the capital stock.
The equations from the previous section are modified to allow borrowing to change when the
capital stock is altered. In examining the change in taxes for a given change in foreign assets, the
tax effects of the change in foreign debt are incorporated. It is assumed that Bf bears a constant
relationship of Kf. If the initial ratio of foreign debt to foreign assets is defined as the constant a,
then Bf - aKf, and a change in Bf is equal to a times the change in Kf. That assumption, along with
the preceding assumption, allows the following derivations.
12 This only holds true in the most likely case—when the foreign debt to asset ratio falls below the domestic debt to
asset ratio.
ȱȱȱ
ŗŘȱ
ȱȱ¡ȱȂȱȱȱȱ
ȱ
Under current law the effect of the change in tax can be expressed as:
(26) Change in Tax = ((tf - t)® - iBf/Kf + ti [(BT - Bf)/(KT - Bf)][(-tiBf)/(Kf)]
[((KT - Kf)/(KT - Bf)) + ((KT - Kf)(BT - Bf))/(KT - BF)2]
* Change in Foreign Capital,
without an allocation rule:
(27) Change in Tax = (tf - t)® - iBf/Kf) * Change in Foreign Capital,
and with worldwide allocation:
(28) Change in Tax = (tf - t)® - iBf/Kf) + ti[(BT/KT) - (Bf/Kf)]
* Change in Foreign Capital.
Again, in all three cases, the tax systems discourage investment abroad, due to the high tax
country, although this effect is moderated by the deduction for debt financed investment. The
worldwide allocation rule—when debt to asset ratios are lower abroad than in the United States—
would discourage investment to a lesser amount than equity investment. This moderation of effect
results from a small allocation being made as some of the U.S. interest is shifted abroad. Since the
worldwide allocation rule would not apply when foreign debt to equity ratios are higher, the
worldwide allocation rule would either further discourage investment abroad or have no effect. In
contrast, the current allocation rule may either encourage or discourage investment abroad. The
first term is unchanged from the previous section, and reflects the effect of allocating more
existing domestic interest abroad as the capital stock increases. The second term reflects the fact
that some interest has shifted abroad and would not be allocated. If domestic debt is small relative
to foreign debt, then the current allocation rule would, simultaneously, raise U.S. revenue and
discourage foreign investment in high tax jurisdictions.
ȱȱȱ
Jane G. Gravelle
Donald J. Marples
Senior Specialist in Economic Policy
Specialist in Public Finance
jgravelle@crs.loc.gov, 7-7829
dmarples@crs.loc.gov, 7-3739
ȱȱȱ
ŗřȱ