Order Code RL31925
FCC Media Ownership Rules:
Current Status and Issues for Congress
Updated November 20, 2007
Charles B. Goldfarb
Specialist in Industrial Organization and Telecommunications Policy
Resources, Science, and Industry Division

FCC Media Ownership Rules:
Current Status and Issues for Congress
Summary
On June 2, 2003, the Federal Communications Commission (FCC or
Commission) modified five of its media ownership rules, easing restrictions on the
ownership of multiple television stations (nationally and in local markets) and on
local media cross ownership, and tightening restrictions on the ownership of multiple
radio stations in local markets. The new rules have never gone into effect. Sec. 629
of the FY2004 Consolidated Appropriations Act (P.L. 108-199) instructed the FCC
to modify its new National Television Ownership rule to allow a broadcast network
to own and operate local broadcast stations that reach, in total, at most 39% of U.S.
television households. On June 24, 2004, the United States Court of Appeals for the
Third Circuit (“Third Circuit”), in Prometheus Radio Project vs. Federal
Communications Commission
, found the FCC did not provide reasoned analysis to
support its specific local ownership limits and therefore remanded portions of the
new local ownership rules back to the FCC and extended its stay of those rules.
In June 2006, the FCC adopted a Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
seeking comment on how to address the issues raised by the Third Circuit and
initiating a statutorily-required quadrennial review of all of its media ownership
rules, but did not propose specific rule changes. In the summer of 2007, the FCC
adopted a Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking seeking comment on 34
proposals for increasing minority ownership of broadcast stations, and also released
for public comment 10 economic research studies of media ownership that it had
commissioned and peer reviews of those studies that are required by the Office of
Management and Budget. Consumers Union, Consumer Federation of America, and
Free Press submitted detailed analyses of these studies and peer reviews as well as
their own studies that rebut some of the FCC-commissioned studies.
On November 13, 2007, FCC chairman Martin announced that the only media
ownership rule he proposes to modify is the newspaper-broadcast cross-ownership
rule. He proposes that it be presumptively in the public interest, in the 20 largest
markets, for a major daily newspaper to own a single television or radio station, so
long as the television station is not among the four highest-rated stations in the
market and after the transaction there are at least eight independently owned and
operating major media voices.
S. 2332 would require the FCC, before adopting any new broadcast ownership
rule, to give 90 days notice for public comment, and to initiate, conduct, and
complete a separate rulemaking to promote the broadcast of local programming and
content. It also would require the FCC to establish an independent Panel on Women
and Minority Ownership of Broadcast Media and to conduct a full and accurate
census of the race and gender of broadcast owners.
This report will be updated as events warrant.

Contents
Overview of Current Status . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
Underlying Issues: Standard of Review and Bright Line Tests . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
Standard of Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
Bright Line Tests and the Diversity Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
Specific Media Ownership Rules . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
National Television Ownership (% Cap) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
Current Status . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
Recent History . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
Dual Network Ownership . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
Local Television Multiple Ownership . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26
Current Status . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26
Recent History . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
Local Radio Multiple Ownership . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
Current Status . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
Recent History . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31
Cross-Media Limits: Newspaper-Broadcast and Television-Radio . . . . . . . 35
Current Status . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
Recent History . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
Transferability of Ownership . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
Legislative Policy Issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41

FCC Media Ownership Rules:
Current Status and Issues for Congress
Overview of Current Status
The Federal Communications Commission (FCC or Commission) adopted an
order on June 2, 2003 that modified five of its media ownership rules and retained
two others.1 The new rules have never gone into effect. Sec. 629 of the FY2004
Consolidated Appropriations Act (P.L. 108-199) instructed the FCC to modify one
of the rules — the National Television Ownership rule. On June 24, 2004, the
United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit (Third Circuit), in Prometheus
Radio Project vs. Federal Communications Commission
, found:
The Commission’s derivation of new Cross-Media Limits, and its modification
of the numerical limits on both television and radio station ownership in local
markets, all have the same essential flaw: an unjustified assumption that media
outlets of the same type make an equal contribution to diversity and competition
in local markets. We thus remand for the Commission to justify or modify its
approach to setting numerical limits.... The stay currently in effect will continue
pending our review of the Commission’s action on remand, over which this panel
retains jurisdiction.2
The current status of the rules is as follows:
! National Television Ownership: a broadcast network may own and
operate local broadcast stations that reach, in total, up to 39% of
1 Report and Order and Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review
— Review of the Commission’s Broadcast Ownership Rules and Other Rules Adopted
Pursuant to Section 202 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996,
MB Docket 02-277; Cross-
Ownership of Broadcast Stations and Newspapers,
MM Docket 01-235; Rules and Policies
Concerning Multiple Ownership of Radio Broadcast Stations in Local Markets,
MM Docket
01-317; Definition of Radio Markets, MM Docket 00-244; Definition of Radio Markets for
Areas Not Located in an Arbitron Survey Area,
MB Docket 03-130, adopted June 2, 2003
and released July 2, 2003 (“Report and Order” or “June 2, 2003 Order”). The Report and
Order was adopted in a three to two vote. All five commissioners released statements on
June 2, 2003, the day that the Commission voted to adopt the item, and also released
statements that accompanied the July 2, 2003 release of the Report and Order. The Report
and Order was published in the Federal Register on September 5, 2003, at 68 FR 46285.
2 Prometheus Radio Project v. Federal Communications Commission, 373 F.3d 372, 435 (3rd
Circuit 2004) (Prometheus). The decision also is available at [http://www.ca3.uscourts.gov/
opinarch/033388p.pdf], viewed on November 16, 2007. For a legal perspective on the
Prometheus decision, see CRS Report RL32460, Legal Challenge to the FCC’s Media
Ownership Rules: An Overview of Prometheus Radio v. FCC
, by Kathleen Ann Ruane.

CRS-2
U.S. television households; entities that exceed the 39% cap must
divest as needed to come into compliance within two years; the FCC
may not forbear on applying the 39% cap; and the FCC is prohibited
from performing the quadrennial review of the 39% cap.3 In
calculating a network’s reach, UHF stations continue to be treated
as if they reach only 50% of the households in the market.4
! Until the FCC crafts new rules approved by the Third Circuit, the
ownership rules in effect prior to June 2, 2003 remain in effect:5
! Local Television Multiple Ownership: a company can own
two television stations in the same Designated Market Area
(“DMA”)6 if the stations’ Grade B contours7 do not overlap or
if only one is among the four highest-ranked (in terms of
audience) in the market and at least eight independent
television stations would remain in the market after the
proposed combination.8 An existing licensee of a failed,
failing, or unbuilt television station can seek a waiver of the
rule if it can demonstrate that the “in-market” buyer is the only
reasonably available entity willing and able to operate the
subject station, and that selling the station to an out-of-market
buyer would result in an artificially depressed price for the
station.9
3 This is required by the FY2004 Consolidated Appropriations Act (P.L. 108-109, 118 Stat.
3 et seq.), Section 629. The relevant FCC rule is 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(d)(1).
4 The Third Circuit concluded that challenges to the FCC’s decision to retain the 50% UHF
“discount” were moot “because reducing or eliminating the discount for UHF station
audiences would effectively raise the audience reach limit ... [which] would undermine
Congress’s specification of a precise 39% cap.” (Prometheus, 373 F.3d at 396). The
relevant FCC rule is 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(d)(2)(i).
5 “The stay currently in effect will continue pending our review of the Commission’s action
on remand, over which the panel retains jurisdiction.” (Prometheus, 373 F.3d at 435)
6 Designated Market Areas are geographic designations developed by Nielsen Media
Research. A DMA is made up of all the counties that get the preponderance of their
broadcast programming from a given television market. The Nielsen DMAs are both
complete (all counties in the United States are in a DMA) and exclusive (DMAs do not
overlap).
7 Grade B is a measure of signal intensity associated with acceptable reception. The FCC’s
rules define this contour, often a circle drawn around the transmitter site of a television
station, in such a way that 50 percent of the locations on that circle are statistically predicted
to receive a signal of Grade B intensity at least 90 per cent of the time. Although a station’s
predicted signal strength increases as one gets closer to the transmitter, there will still be
some locations within the predicted Grade B contour that do not receive a signal of Grade
B intensity.
8 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(b).
9 47 C.F.R. 73.3555 n. 7.

CRS-3
! Local Radio Multiple Ownership: the number of radio
stations that a company can own in a local market varies
according to the total number of stations in the market, as
follows: in a radio market with 45 or more full power
commercial and noncommercial radio stations, a party may
own, operate or control up to eight commercial radio stations,
not more than five of which are in the same service (AM or
FM); in a market with between 30 and 44 (inclusive) full
power commercial and noncommercial stations, a party may
own, operate, or control up to seven commercial radio
stations, not more than four of which are in the same service;
in a market with between 15 and 29 (inclusive) full power
commercial and noncommercial radio stations, a party may
own, operate, or control up to six commercial radio stations,
not more than four of which are in the same service; and in a
radio market with 14 or fewer full power commercial and
noncommercial radio stations, a party may own, operate, or
control up to five commercial radio stations, not more than
three of which are in the same service, except that a party may
not own, operate, or control more than 50% of the stations in
any market.10
! Broadcast-Newspaper Cross Ownership: common
ownership of a full-service broadcast station and a daily
newspaper is prohibited when the broadcast station’s service
contour encompasses the newspaper’s city of publication.
Combinations that pre-date 1975 are grandfathered11 and
companies may seek waiver of the rule.
! Television-Radio Cross Ownership: An entity may own up
to 2 television stations (provided it is permitted under the
Local Television Multiple Ownership rule) and up to 6 radio
stations (provided it is permitted under the Local Radio
Multiple Ownership rule) in a market where at least 20
independently owned media voices would remain post-merger.
Where entities may own a combination of 2 television stations
and 6 radio stations, the rule allows an entity alternatively to
own 1 television station and 7 radio stations. An entity may
own up to 2 television stations (as permitted under the Local
Television Multiple Ownership rule) and up to 4 radio stations
10 As explained below, the Third Circuit, in rehearing, lifted its stay of the portion of the
FCC rules that modified the methodology used to define local radio markets, and thus the
current rule language, 47 C.F.R. 73,3555(a), is as it appears in Appendix H of the Report
and Order. The statutory language and FCC rule also provide an exception to these
ownership limits whereby the FCC may permit a person or entity to own, operate, or control,
or have a cognizable interest in radio broadcast stations that exceed the limit if that will
result in an increase in the number of radio broadcast stations in operation.
11 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(d) as it existed prior to the FCC’s June 2, 2003 Order.

CRS-4
(as permitted under the Local Radio Multiple Ownership rule)
in markets where, post-merger, at least 10 independently
owned media voices would remain. A combination of 1
television station and 1 radio station is allowed regardless of
the number of voices remaining in the market.12
Although the Third Circuit remanded the FCC’s specific cross-media
ownership, local television multiple ownership, and local radio multiple ownership
rules, and extended the stay, it upheld many of the FCC’s findings, including
! not to retain a ban on newspaper-broadcast cross ownership;13
! to retain some limits on common ownership of different-type media
outlets;14
! to retain the restriction on owning more than one top-four television
station in a market;15
! the Commission’s new definition of local radio markets;16
! to include non-commercial stations in determining the size of local
radio markets;17
! the Commission’s restriction on the transfer of radio stations;18
! to count radio stations brokered under a Joint Sales Agreement
toward the brokering station’s permissible ownership totals;19 and
! to use numerical limits in its ownership rules (though not the
specific numerical limits adopted by the Commission).20
12 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(c) as it existed prior to the FCC’s June 2, 2003 Order. For this rule,
media “voices” include independently owned and operating full-power broadcast
television stations, broadcast radio stations, English-language newspapers (published
at least four times a week), one cable system located in the market under scrutiny,
plus any independently owned out-of-market broadcast radio stations with a
minimum share as reported by Arbitron.
13 Prometheus, 373 F.3d at 397-399.
14 Ibid., at 399-401.
15 Ibid., at 418.
16 Ibid., at 425.
17 Ibid., at 426.
18 Ibid., at 426-428.
19 Ibid., at 429-430.
20 Ibid., at 426-433.

CRS-5
Since the Third Circuit had upheld the FCC’s findings as they applied to the
methodology underlying the revised local radio ownership rules, the FCC filed a
narrowly focused petition for panel rehearing, asking the Third Circuit to reconsider
its extension of the stay of the revised Local Radio Multiple Ownership rule, arguing
that the “stay prevents the Commission from implementing regulatory changes that
this Court has upheld as a reasonable exercise of the Commission’s public interest
authority.”21 The Third Circuit approved a partial lifting of the stay:
Inasmuch as we held in our Opinion and Judgment of June 24, 2004, that certain
changes to the local radio ownership rule proposed by the Federal
Communications Commission (the “Commission”) in its Report and Order and
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 18 F.C.C.R. 13,620 (2003) — specifically,
using Arbitron Metro markets to define local markets, including noncommercial
stations in determining the size of a market, attributing stations whose
advertising is brokered under a Joint Sales Agreement to a brokering station’s
permissible ownership totals, and imposing a transfer restriction (collectively, the
“Approved Changes”) — are constitutional and/or consistent with the
Administrative Procedure Act, 5 U.S.C. Section 706(2), and Section 202(h) of
the Telecommunications Act of 1996, the foregoing motion by the Commission
is granted to the extent that it requests a partial lifting of the stay to allow the
Approved Changes to go into effect. All other aspects of the Commission’s
motion, including matters pertaining to numerical limits on local radio ownership
and AM “subcap” are hereby denied.22
Several media companies and media associations (The Tribune Company, Fox,
NBC Universal, Viacom, the National Association of Broadcasters, and the
Newspaper Association of America) formally sought appeals of the Third Circuit
decision at the Supreme Court.23 As part of their legal challenge to the Prometheus
decision, they challenged the continued viability of the spectrum scarcity rationale
that the Supreme Court relied upon in its 1969 Red Lion decision24 permitting
government regulation of broadcasters. (That Supreme Court decision permits
regulations that impose minimally intrusive restrictions on broadcasters’ First
Amendment rights on the grounds that the airwaves, which are public assets, are
scarce and thus licensees can be subject to requirements to serve in “the public
interest.”) The media companies claimed that the FCC acknowledges that the prior
cross-ownership rule and local ownership restrictions inhibit diversity of viewpoints,
that the FCC’s order confirms that broadcast channels are no longer uniquely
important sources of information, and that actions of Congress and the FCC signal
that industry conditions have changed sufficiently to justify reconsideration of
21 Prometheus Radio Project v. Federal Communications Commission, Petition of the FCC
and the United States for Panel Rehearing, August 6, 2004.
22 USCA3 Docket Sheet for 03-3388, Prometheus Radio v. FCC, 9/3/04.
23 See Tania Panczyk-Collins, “Media Group Asks Supreme Court to Hear Ownership
Case,” Communications Daily, January 31, 2005, at pp. 4-5, and also Communications
Daily
, February 2, 2005, at p. 8.
24 Red Lion Broadcasting Co, Inc. v. Federal Communications Commission, Supreme Court
of the United States, 395 U.S. 367, decided June 9, 1969.

CRS-6
whether broadcast speech deserves lesser First Amendment protection.25 On June 13,
2005, the Supreme Court declined to consider the appeals.
The FCC adopted on June 21, 2006, and released on July 24, 2006, a Further
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking that sought comment on how to address the issues
raised by the Third Circuit’s Prometheus decision.26 The Further Notice also initiated
a comprehensive quadrennial review of all of its media ownership rules, as required
by statute.27 The Further Notice did not propose any specific rules; rather, the FCC
sought comment on the following rules: the local television ownership limit, the local
radio ownership limit, the newspaper-broadcast cross-ownership ban, the radio-
television cross-ownership limit, the dual network ban, and the UHF discount on the
national television ownership limit. Two of the commissioners dissented in part
from the order adopting the Further Notice,28 criticizing the absence of specific
proposed rules and the lack of discussion of proposals to foster minority ownership.29
On November 22, 2006, the FCC announced that it had commissioned (or had
begun conducting internally) 10 economic studies as part of its review of the media
ownership rules.30 The two commissioners who had dissented in part from the order
25 Tania Panczyk-Collins, “Media Group Asks Supreme Court to Hear Ownership Case,”
Communications Daily, January 31, 2005, at p. 4.
26 In the Matter of 2006 Quadrennial Review — Review of the Commission’s Broadcast
Ownership Rules and Other Rules Adopted Pursuant to Section 202 of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996; 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of the
Commission’s Broadcast Ownership Rules and Other Rules Adopted Pursuant to Section
202 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996; Cross-Ownership of Broadcast Stations and
Newspapers; Rules and Policies Concerning Multiple Ownership of Radio Broadcast
Stations in Local Markets; Definition of Radio Markets
, MB Dockets No. 06-121 and 02-
277 and MM Dockets No. 01-235, 01-317, and 00-244, Further Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking, adopted June 21, 2006, and released July 24, 2006.
27 Section 629 of the FY2004 Consolidated Appropriations Act, P.L. 108-199, modifies the
Communications Act to instruct the FCC to perform a quadrennial review of all of its media
ownership rules, except the National Television Ownership rule.
28 “Statement of Commissioner Michael J. Copps, Concurring in Part, Dissenting in Part,”
June 21, 2006, available at [http://hraunfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DOC-
266033A3.pdf], viewed on November 6, 27, 2007, and “Statement of Commissioner
Jonathan S. Adelstein, Concurring in Part, Dissenting in Part,” June 21, 2006, available at
[http://hraunfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DOC-266033A4.pdf], viewed on
November 6, 2007.
29 In footnote 59 of the Prometheus decision, the Third Circuit had instructed the FCC to
address in its rulemaking process proposals for advancing minority and disadvantaged
businesses and for promoting diversity in broadcasting that the Minority Media and
Telecommunications Council (MMTC) had submitted in the proceeding in 2003.
(Prometheus, 373 F.3d at 421.)
30 “FCC Names Economic Studies to be Conducted as Part of Media Ownership Rules
Review,” FCC Public Notice, November 22, 2006, available at [http://hraunfoss.fcc.gov/
edocs_public/attachmatch/DOC-268606A1.pdf], viewed on November 6, 2007. The ten
studies are: (1) “How People Get News and Information,” by Nielsen Research; (2)
(continued...)

CRS-7
adopting the Further Notice each issued statements raising questions about the
transparency of the process by which the contractors were selected and the peer
review process that would be used.31 On July 31, 2007, the FCC released the 10
studies, making them available on its website, and giving the public 60 days to
submit comments (and then 15 additional days to submit reply comments).32 These
studies consist of hundred of pages of text and very large data sets. The studies then
underwent a peer review process that is required by the Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) of all influential scientific information on which a federal agency
relies in a rulemaking proceeding.33 The two dissenting commissioners issued a joint
30 (...continued)
“Ownership Structure and Robustness of Media,” by C. Anthony Bush, Kiran Duwadi, Scott
Roberts, and Andrew Wise, of the FCC; (3) “Effects of Ownership Structure and Robustness
on the Quantity and Quality of TV Programming,” by Gregory Crawford of the University
of Arizona; (4) “News Operations,” by Kenneth Lynch, Daniel Shiman, and Craig Stroup
of the FCC; (5) “Station Ownership and Programming in Radio,” by Tasneem Chipty of
CRAI; (6) “News Coverage of Cross-Owned Newspapers and Television Stations,” by
Jeffrey Milyo of the University of Missouri; (7) “Minority Ownership,” by Arie Bersteanu
and Paul Ellickson of Duke University; (8) “Minority Ownership,” by Allen Hammond of
Santa Clara University and Barbara O’Connor of the California State University at
Sacramento; (9) “Vertical Integration,” by Austin Goolsbee of the University of Chicago;
and (10) “Radio Industry Review: Trends in Ownership, Format, and Finance,” by George
Williams of the FCC.
31 “Commissioner Michael J. Copps Comments on the FCC’s Media Ownership Studies,”
FCC News, November 22, 2006, available at [http://hraunfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/
attachmatch/DOC-268611A1.pdf], viewed on November 6, 2007, and “Commissioner
Jonathan S. Adelstein Says Public Notice on Media Ownership Economic Studies is ‘Scant’
and ‘Undermines Public Confidence’,” FCC News, November 22, 2006, available at
[http://hraunfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DOC-268616A1.pdf], viewed on
November 7, 2007.
32 “FCC Seeks Comment on Research Studies on Media Ownership,” MB Docket No. 06-
121, FCC Public Notice, DA-07-3470, released July 31, 2007, available at [http://fjallfoss.
fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DA-07-3470A1.pdf], viewed on November 6, 2007. The
studies were made available at [http://www.fcc.gov/ownership/studies.html]. Subsequently,
the FCC released a public notice extending the comment period to October 22, 2007, and
the reply comment period to November 1, 2007. See, “Media Bureau Extends Filing
Deadlines for Comments on Media Ownership Studies,” MB Docket No. 06-121, FCC
Public Notice, DA-07-4097, released September 28, 2007, available at
[http://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DA-07-4097A1.pdf], viewed on
November 6, 2007.
33 The OMB requirement appears in the OMB Peer Review Bulletin, 70 Fed. Reg. 2664.
In these peer reviews, the reviewer is instructed to evaluate and comment on the theoretical
and empirical merit of the information, by considering, among other things: (1) whether the
methodology and assumptions employed are reasonable and technically correct; (2) whether
the methodology and assumptions are consistent with accepted economic theory and
econometric practices; (3) whether the data used are reasonable and of sufficient quality for
purposes of the analysis; and (4) whether the conclusions, if any, follow from the analysis.
The reviewer is instructed not to provide advice on policy or to evaluate the policy
implications of the study. The peer review is not anonymous; the reviewer will be identified
and the review will be placed in the public record. Also, the federal agency must assess
(continued...)

CRS-8
statement criticizing the shortness of the public comment period and raising
questions about the peer review process.34 On September 5, 2007, the FCC released
the peer reviews of these studies.35
On August 1, 2007, the FCC adopted and released a Second Further Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking in its media ownership proceeding,36 setting forth in detail and
seeking public comment on 34 proposals for increasing minority ownership of
broadcast stations. The Commission took this action in response to a motion filed
on August 23, 2006 by the Diversity and Competition Supporters (a coalition of
organizations representing minority and women’s communities that is often referred
to in short-hand as MMTC, for one of the member organizations, the Minority Media
and Telecommunications Council) to withdraw the Commission’s initial Further
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking. The MMTC motion claimed the Further Notice did
not meet one of the requirements of the Prometheus decision because it failed to
identify and describe minority ownership proposals that MMTC had submitted in the
proceeding in 2003.37 Footnote 59 of the Prometheus decision stated:
We also note that the Commission deferred consideration of the MMTC’s other
proposals for advancing minority and disadvantaged businesses and for
promoting diversity in broadcasting.... The Commission’s rulemaking process in
response to our remand order should address these proposals at the same time.

33 (...continued)
whether potential peer reviewers have any potential conflicts of interest.
34 “Joint Statement by FCC Commissioners Michael J. Copps and Jonathan S. Adelstein on
Release of Media Ownership Studies,” FCC News, released July 31, 2007, available at
[http://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DOC-275674A1.pdf], viewed on
November 6, 2007.
35 The peer reviews are available at [http://www.fcc.gov/mb/peer_review/peerreview.html],
viewed on November 6, 2007.
36 In the Matter of 2006 Quadrennial Regulatory Review — Review of the Commission’s
Broadcast Ownership Rules and Other Rules Adopted Pursuant to Section 202 of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996; 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of the
Commission’s Broadcast Ownership Rules and Other Rules Adopted Pursuant to Section
202 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996; Cross-Ownership of Broadcast Stations and
Newspapers; Rules and Policies Concerning Multiple Ownership of Radio Broadcast
Stations in Local Markets; Definition of Radio Markets; Ways to Further Section 257
Mandate and to Build on Earlier Studies
, MB Dockets Nos. 06-121, 02-277, and 04-228 and
MM Docket Nos. 01-235, 01-317, and 00-244, Second Further Notice of Proposed Rule
Making, adopted and released August 1, 2007.
37 As part of its review of the local television rule, in its 2003 order the FCC had repealed
the Failed Station Solicitation Rule (FSSR) (47 C.F.R. 73.3555 n. 7), which required a
waiver applicant to provide notice of the sale to potential out-of-market buyers before it
could sell the failed, failing, or unbuilt television station to an in-market buyer. In its
Prometheus decision, the Third Circuit found that the FCC’s repeal of the FSSR without any
discussion of the effect of its decision on minority television station ownership, “amounts
to arbitrary and capricious rulemaking,” and remanded the decision. (Prometheus, 373 F.3d
at 421.)

CRS-9
The two commissioners who had earlier dissented in part once again dissented in
part, claiming that the 60 day comment period was too short.38
On October 22, 2007, Consumers Union, Consumer Federation of America, and
Free Press (Consumer Commenters) submitted to the FCC very detailed comments
on the 10 FCC-commissioned media ownership studies.39 The Consumer
Commenters identify a number of alleged specification errors — some raised by the
peer reviewers, some by the Consumer Commenters themselves — in the major
statistical studies commissioned by the FCC, and then present statistical results from
re-running the models in those studies, applying the same empirical data to models
revised to correct for the specification errors. These revised models yield very
different statistical results that, according to the Consumer Commenters, demonstrate
that loosening the media ownership rules would not be in the public interest.40
On November 8, 2007, Senator Dorgan introduced S. 2332, which would
modify Section 202 of the 1996 Telecommunications Act by adding three provisions
that would (1) require the FCC to publish in the Federal Register any proposal to
modify, revise, or amend any of its regulations related to broadcast ownership at least
90 days before voting to add the proposal, providing at least 60 days for public
38 “Joint Statement of Commissioner Michael J. Copps and Commissioner Jonathan A.
Adelstein Approving in Part, Dissenting in Part,” FCC-07-136, released August 1, 2007,
available at [http://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/FCC-07-136A2.pdf], viewed
on November 6, 2007.
39 In the Matter of 2006 Quadrennial Regulatory Review — Review of the Commission’s
Broadcast Ownership Rules and Other Rules Adopted Pursuant to Section 202 of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996; 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review; Cross-Ownership of
Broadcast Stations and Newspapers; Rules and Policies Concerning Multiple Ownership
of Radio Broadcast Stations in Local Markets; Definition of Radio Markets; Ways to
Further Section 257 Mandate and to Build on Earlier Studies,
MB Docket Nos. 06-121, 02-
277, and 04-228 and MM Docket Nos. 01-235, 01-317, and 00-244, Further Comments of
Consumers Union, Consumer Federation of America, and Free Press, October 22, 2007.
40 The Consumer Commenters’ submission also includes a weblink [http://www.fcc.gov/
ownership/materials/newly-released/newspaperbroadcast061506.pdf] to a 27-page internal
FCC memorandum by then-FCC chief economist Leslie M. Marx, dated June 15, 2006 and
entitled “Summary of Ideas on Newspaper-Broadcast Cross-Ownership,” which they
obtained through a freedom of information act request and which they allege demonstrates
that the FCC’s process for commissioning media ownership studies was biased. The
opening sentence of the memorandum states: “This document is an attempt to share some
thoughts and ideas I have about how the FCC can approach relaxing newspaper-broadcast
cross-ownership restrictions.” At p. 14, the memorandum states: “In this section I discuss
some studies that might provide valuable inputs to support a relaxation of newspaper-
broadcast cross-ownership limits.” (footnote omitted). Although Ms. Marx was no longer
the chief economist when the FCC announced that it had commissioned the 10 media
ownership studies (an August 21, 2006 FCC News Release announced that Michelle P.
Connolly had been named FCC chief economist), several of the studies suggested in Ms.
Marx’s memorandum were among those later commissioned by the FCC. The memorandum
lists a number of media ownership-related hypotheses that are of interest to policy makers
and thus might merit analysis, but it also lists for each a finding that would support
loosening the cross-ownership limits, thus suggesting a preferred outcome. The
memorandum also provides a list of possible authors for the studies.

CRS-10
comment and 30 days for reply comments; (2) require the FCC to initiate, conduct,
and complete a separate rulemaking proceeding to promote the broadcast of local
programming and content by broadcasters, including radio and television broadcast
stations, and newspapers, before voting on any change in the broadcast and
newspaper ownership rules, and require the FCC to conduct a study to determine the
overall impact of television station duopolies and newspaper-broadcast cross-
ownership on the quantity and quality of local news, public affairs, local news media
jobs, and local cultural programming at the market level; and (3) establish an
independent Panel on Women and Minority Ownership of Broadcast Media to make
recommendations to the FCC for specific Commission rules to increase the
representation of women and minorities in the ownership of broadcast media, and
require the FCC to conduct a full and accurate census of the race and gender of
individuals holding a controlling interest in broadcast station licenses, provide the
results of the census to the Panel, study the impact of media market concentration on
the representation of women and minorities in the ownership of broadcast media, and
act on the Panel’s recommendations before voting on any changes in its broadcast
and newspaper ownership rules.
On November 13, 2007, FCC chairman Martin announced that the only media
ownership rule he proposes to modify is the newspaper-broadcast cross-ownership
rule.41 He proposes that it be presumptively in the public interest, in the 20 largest
local markets (DMAs), for a major daily newspaper to own a single television or
radio station, so long as the television station is not among the four highest-rated
stations in the market and after the transaction there are at least eight independently
owned and operating major media voices. In all other situations, any newspaper-
broadcast cross-ownership would be presumptively not in the public interest.
In any situation, the Commission would be required to make a public interest
finding and, in so doing, consider, among other factors: whether the cross-ownership
will increase the amount of local news disseminated through the affected media
outlets in the combination; whether each affected media outlet in the combination
will exercise its own independent news judgment; the level of concentration in the
DMA; and the financial condition of the newspaper, and if the newspaper is in
distress, the owner’s commitment to invest significantly in newsroom operations.
Thus, under the proposed rule, a newspaper-broadcast combination in a top 20
market could be rejected by the Commission and a newspaper-broadcast combination
in a smaller market could be approved. Commissioners Copps and Adelstein issued
a joint statement criticizing and opposing Chairman Martin’s proposal,42 claiming
that the “proposal could repeal the ban in every market in America, not just the top
twenty.”
41 “Chairman Kevin J. Martin Proposes Revision to the Newspaper/Broadcast Cross-
Ownership Rule,” FCC News Release, November 13, 2007, available at [http://hraunfoss.
fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DOC-278113A1.pdf], viewed on November 19, 2007.
42 “Joint Statement by Commissioners Copps and Adelstein on Chairman Martin’s Cross-
Ownership Proposal,” FCC News Release, November 13, 2007, available at [http://hraun
foss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DOC-278142A1.pdf], viewed on November 19,
2007.

CRS-11
In the interim, the Commission continues to consider waiver requests from
media companies that wish to do transactions that do not meet the rules currently in
place43 and to make determinations on requests for the extension of temporary
waivers that have expired.
However, the fate of the sale of one company that has a number of waivers may
be affected by the FCC actions relating to the newspaper-broadcast cross-ownership
rule.44 The Tribune Company has accepted a buy-out proposal by Sam Zell that
would use an S-corporation Employee Stock Ownership Plan (ESOP) to purchase the
Tribune Company. That corporate structure would avoid paying corporate income
taxes and make it less onerous for the new firm to carry the more than $8 billion in
additional debt required to make it private. Under the agreement, the ESOP will end
up with at least majority ownership of the company, though Sam Zell will have stock
warrants that can be exchanged for up to 40% of the shares.45
Tribune has enjoyed a grandfathered cross-ownership exemption in Chicago,
where it owns the Chicago Tribune, a radio station (WGN-AM 720), and a television
station (WGN-TV, channel 9). It also has waivers for its newspaper-television
combination in New York City, Los Angeles, Hartford, CT, and South Florida. But
none of those waivers would extend to new owners of the broadcast properties, so the
new Tribune owners would have to obtain their own waivers to keep all of the assets
intact. Tribune therefore petitioned for temporary waivers until the FCC can
complete its formal rulemaking process to resolve the cross-ownership debate.
Tribune argued that it is unfair to hold up the transaction while the rules are under
review; if the rules changed later, it could sell newspapers or television stations to
comply at that time.
If the transaction is not completed by December 31, 2007, key provisions in the
merger and loan agreement would make the deal more expensive both for Mr. Zell
and for Tribune. Thus there has been great pressure on the FCC to approve the
waiver petitions in a timely fashion. There appears to be more support at the FCC
for the Tribune waivers than for Chairman Martin’s proposed newspaper-broadcast
cross-ownership rule change, in part because some critics of his proposed loosening
of the rule are supporters of ESOPs. Mr. Martin therefore has been accused of
attempting to tie the vote on the waiver petitions to a vote on his cross-ownership
proposal, which could result in delays that would keep the transaction from being
finalized by December 31. In their joint statement criticizing Chairman Martin’s
43 See, for example, Brigitte Greenberg and Tania Panczyk-Collins, “Ferree Sees Issues That
Could Interest the Supreme Court,” Communications Daily, July 1, 2004, at pp. 1-4.
44 See, for example, Phil Rosenthal and Michael Oneal, “FCC plan clouds deal for
Tribune,” Chicago Tribune, October 19, 2007, available at [http://www.chicagotribune.
com/business/chi-fri_tribune_1019oct19,0,5524717.story], viewed on November 19, 2007.
45 See, Corey Rosen, “An ESOP for the Tribune Company? Things to Know is Assessing
the Transaction,” The National Center for Employee Ownership (NCEO), April 2007,
available at [http://www.nceo.org/library/tribune-esop.html], viewed on November 19, 2007.

CRS-12
proposed rule change,46 commissioners Copps and Adelstein claimed that the
chairman “has refused to act on Tribune’s waiver requests that would permit the
transaction to close. Let us be clear: it is improper to hold the Tribune hostage in
order to force a vote on media ownership before the end of the year.”
The Tribune is not the only media company that has sought a waiver of the
cross-ownership rule. Other examples of waiver petitions include:
! News Corp., which already had been granted a permanent waiver of
the rules to allow it to own both WNYW(TV) and The New York
Post
, and a temporary waiver of the rules to allow it to own both
WWOR-TV and The New York Post, in the New York market, filed
a petition asking the Commission to modify the permanent waiver
to also include common ownership of WWOR-TV or, at a minimum
to extend the temporary waiver with regard to WWOR-TV pending
conclusion of the remand of the 2002 biennial review proceeding.47
That petition was incorporated into the unopposed application to
transfer a number of broadcast licenses from K. Rupert Murdoch to
Fox Entertainment Group. In approving the ownership transfer, the
FCC maintained the permanent waiver to permit the continued
ownership of WNYW(TV) and The New York Post, but only granted
a 24-month temporary waiver of the rule to permit the continued
ownership of WWOR-TV and The New York Post.48
! Media General purchased WBTW, a Florence, SC, television station
in March 2000 and then purchased the Florence Morning News
newspaper in August 2000. FCC rules do not require a broadcast
licensee that purchases a newspaper in its local broadcast market to
seek a waiver of the newspaper-broadcast cross-ownership rule until
the next license renewal cycle. Thus, as part of its license renewal
application for WBTW, in 2004 Media General sought a permanent
waiver of the newspaper-broadcast cross-ownership rule to allow it
to own both that station and the Morning News.49 The FCC has not
yet ruled on the permanent waiver request, but under Sec. 307(c)(3)
of the Communications Act pending any final decision on a license
renewal application the “Commission shall continue such license in
46 See footnote 42 above.
47 In the Matter of Fox Television Stations and the News Corporation Limited, Request for
Waiver of the Newspaper-Broadcast Cross-Ownership Rule Relating to WNYW(TV),
WWOR-TV, and the New York Post
, Petition for Modification of Permanent Waiver,
September 22, 2004.
48 In the Matter of K. Rupert Murdoch (Transferor) and Fox Entertainment Group
(Transferee) Applications for Transfer of Control of Fox Television Stations, Inc.
File No.
BTCCT-20050819AAF, et. al., Memorandum Opinion and Order, adopted August 15, 2006
and released October 6, 2006, at para. 8.
49 “Holding On,” Broadcasting & Cable, August 23, 2004, at p. 17.

CRS-13
effect.”50 Thus, although it is Commission policy not to renew the
license for which a waiver request has not been resolved, the license
remains in effect.
Although the Commission continues to consider waiver applications and extend
existing permanent or temporary waivers, the Third Circuit’s remand and extended
stay of the FCC rules nonetheless appear to have retarded merger activity in the
media sector until final rules are approved by the courts.51

To date, S. 2332, discussed earlier, has been the only legislation introduced in
the 110th Congress that directly addresses the FCC’s media ownership rules. But the
three major policy goals of competition, diversity, and localism that the media
ownership rules are intended to foster might be affected by other legislative
proposals. For example, H.R. 600 and H.R. 3003 each would amend the Internal
Revenue Code of 1986 to provide for a deferral of tax on capital gains from the sale
of telecommunications businesses in specific circumstances or to create a tax credit
and other incentives with the goal of promoting diversity of ownership in
telecommunications businesses. Also, S. 1675 and H.R. 2802 would eliminate
existing statutory minimum distance separation requirements for low power FM radio
stations, thereby significantly increasing the number of such stations that could
broadcast programming. H.R. 983 would prohibit satellite radio providers from
providing services that are locally differentiated or that result in programming being
delivered to consumers in one geographic market that is different from the
programming that is delivered to consumers in any other geographic market.
Underlying Issues:
Standard of Review and Bright Line Tests
In 2001-2003, the Commission had to revisit several of its broadcast ownership
rules as a result of rulings by the U.S. Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia
Circuit (“D.C. Circuit”) that the Commission had failed to provide sufficient
justification for specific thresholds incorporated into its National Television
Ownership and Local Television Multiple Ownership rules.52 In addition, pursuant
50 47 U.S.C. §307(c)(3).
51 For example, Mark Fratrik, vice president of BIA Financial Network, reportedly stated
that “Until the ownership rules are finally resolved, television station sales activity will
continue to be weak.” See Communications Daily, August 18, 2004, at pp. 10-11. More
recently, an analyst for Deutsche Bank reportedly has claimed that the Hearst Corp.’s recent
decision to take Hearst-Argyle private may have been motivated by uncertainty about its
ability to obtain regulatory approval for the purchase of broadcast stations that would create
duopolies in local markets. See Josh Wein, “Ownership Rules May Have Spurred Hearst
Bid for TV Group,” Communications Daily, August 29, 2007, at pp. 5-6.
52 Fox Television Stations, Inc. v. Federal Communications Commission, 280 F.3d 1027,
1044 (D.C. Cir. 2002) (“Fox Television”), rehearing granted, 293 F.3d (D.C. Cir. 2002)
(“Fox Television Re-Hearing”) (addressing the National Television Ownership rule) and
Sinclair Broadcast Group, Inc. v. Federal Communications Commission, 284 F.3d 148
(continued...)

CRS-14
to Section 202(h) of the 1996 Act, the FCC had to conduct a biennial review of all
of its broadcast ownership rules and repeal or modify any regulation it determined
to be no longer in the public interest.53
The FCC’s 2002 Biennial Review was initiated on September 12, 2002;54 review
of the Commission’s broadcast-newspaper cross-ownership rule and waiver policy
was initiated on September 13, 2001;55 and review of the Commission’s local radio
ownership rule and radio market definition rule was initiated on November 8, 2001.56
The FCC sought comment on whether each specific rule continued to serve the
Commission’s goals of diversity, competition, and localism — and if the rule served
some purposes while disserving others, whether the balance of the effects argued for
maintaining, modifying, or eliminating the rule.57
In its rulemaking, the Commission raised two fundamental administrative issues
that have potentially significant policy implications. First, what is the relevant
standard for reviewing existing ownership rules? And second, what are the
advantages and disadvantages of using bright line tests vs. case-by-case evaluations
when reviewing proposed ownership transactions that would increase media
concentration?
Standard of Review
There has been some controversy surrounding the standard to be used in
reaching a public interest determination about the existing rules. The D.C. Circuit,
in Fox Television, stated “Section 202(h) carries with it a presumption in favor of
52 (...continued)
(D.C. Circuit) (“Sinclair”) (addressing the Local Television Ownership rule).
53 The 1996 Act, § 202(h), as in effect at the time the FCC undertook its rulemaking, stated:
“The Commission shall review its rules adopted pursuant to this section and all of its
ownership rules biennially as part of its regulatory reform review under section 11 of the
Communications Act of 1934 and shall determine whether any of such rules are necessary
in the public interest as the result of competition. The Commission shall repeal or modify
any regulation it determines to be no longer in the public interest.” Subsequently, Congress
passed the FY2004 Consolidated Appropriations Act (P.L. 108-199), Sec. 29 of which
changes the biennial review to a quadrennial review.
54 Notice of Proposed Rule Making, 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of the
Commission’s Broadcast Ownership Rules and Other Rules Adopted Pursuant to Section
202 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996
, MB Docket No. 02-277, released September
23, 2002.
55 Order and Notice of Proposed Rule Making, Cross-Ownership of Broadcast Stations and
Newspapers,
MM Docket No. 01-235 and Newspaper/Radio Cross-Ownership Waiver
Policy
, MB Docket No. 96-197, released September 20, 2001.
56 Notice of Proposed Rule Making and Further Notice of Proposed Rule Making, Rules and
Policies Concerning Multiple Ownership of Radio Broadcast Stations in Local Market,
MM
Docket No. 01-317 and Definition of Radio Markets, MM Docket No. 00-244, released
November 9, 2001.
57 See, e.g., 67 FR 65751, ¶ 75.

CRS-15
repealing or modifying the ownership rules.”58 Further, in response to petitions for
rehearing, the D.C. Circuit stated “[T]he statute is clear that a regulation should be
retained only insofar as it is necessary in, not merely consonant with, the public
interest.”59 But in the same decision, the D.C. Circuit stated that “[t]he Court’s
decision did not turn at all upon interpreting ‘necessary in the public interest’ to mean
more than ‘in the public interest’” and added “we think it better to leave unresolved
precisely what § 202(h) means when it instructs the Commission first to determine
whether a rule is ‘necessary in the public interest’ but then to ‘repeal or modify’ the
rule if it is simply ‘no longer in the public interest.’”60
In its June 2, 2003 Order, the Commission majority took this language to mean
that the Commission must overcome a high burden to retain any ownership rule.
Responding to a question from Senator McCain in the June 4, 2003 Senate
Commerce Committee hearing, then-chairman Powell stated that the D.C. Circuit
interprets the act to be “biased toward deregulation” and added that for the
Commission to be in concert with that interpretation it “cannot re-regulate.” In
response to a question from Senator Dorgan, Commissioner Abernathy stated that the
D.C. Circuit’s interpretation directs the Commission to minimize regulation as
competition develops, not to regulate to maximize the number of voices.
At that same hearing, all five commissioners and several Senators agreed that
it would be useful for Congress to provide both the Court and the Commission
guidance on the standard to use for reviewing ownership rules and on whether the act
allows the Commission to re-regulate broadcast ownership.61
Subsequently, in its Prometheus decision, the Third Circuit found:
While we acknowledge that § 202(h) was enacted in the context of deregulatory
amendments (the 1996 Act) to the Communications Act, see Fox I, 280 F.3d at
1033; Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 159, we do not accept that the “repeal or modify in
the public interest” instruction must therefore operate only as a one-way ratchet,
i.e., the Commission can use the review process only to eliminate then-extant
regulations. For starters, this ignores both “modify” and the requirement that the
Commission act “in the public interest.” ...
Rather than “upending” the reasoned analysis requirement that under the APA
ordinarily applies to an agency’s decision to promulgate new regulations (or
modify or repeal existing regulations), see State Farm, 463 U.S. at 43, § 202(h)
extends this requirement to the Commission’s decision to retain its existing
regulations. This interpretation avoids a crabbed reading of the statute under
which we would have to infer, without express language, that Congress intended
58 280 F.3d at 1048.
59 293 F.3d 539.
60 293 F.3d 540.
61 In markup of two bills introduced during the 108th Congress, amendments were added
that would have clarified that in its periodic review of ownership rules, the FCC is
authorized to re-regulate as well as deregulate. But neither of those bills was enacted.

CRS-16
to curtail the Commission’s rulemaking authority to contravene “traditional
administrative law principles.”62
Bright Line Tests and the Diversity Index
In its June 2, 2003 Order, the FCC reviewed the advantages and disadvantages
of implementing bright line rules that incorporate specific limits on the number of
media outlets a company can own in a local market, without regard to the market-
specific share of the post-merger company vs. implementing flexible, yet quantifiable
rules that would allow for case-by-case reviews that more readily take into account
market-specific or company-specific market shares and characteristics.
The Commission chose the bright line approach, in large part because it
identified regulatory certainty as an important policy goal in addition to the three
traditional goals of diversity, competition, and localism.63 The Commission stated:
Any benefit to precision of a case-by-case review is outweighed, in our view, by
the harm caused by a lack of regulatory certainty to the affected firms and to the
capital markets that fund the growth and innovation in the media industry.
Companies seeking to enter or exit the media market or seeking to grow larger
or smaller will all benefit from clear rules in making business plans and
investment decisions. Clear structural rules permit planning of financial
transactions, ease application processing, and minimize regulatory costs.64
It concluded that the adoption of bright line rules rather than case-by-case analysis
provides certainty to outcomes, conserves resources, reduces administrative delays,
lowers transactions costs, increases transparency of process, and ensures consistency
in decisions, all of which foster capital investment in broadcasting. The Commission
conceded that bright line rules preclude a certain amount of flexibility.
It is not clear how the Commission would weigh the goal of regulatory certainty
vis-a-vis the traditional goals of diversity, competition, and localism, if the former
were to be in conflict with one or more of the latter. On one hand, the Commission
stated that it would continue to have discretion to review particular cases, and would
have an obligation to take a hard look both at waiver requests (where a bright line
ownership limit would proscribe a particular transaction) and at petitions to deny a
license transfer (where a bright line ownership limit would allow a particular
transaction). At the same time, however, it suggested it would not look favorably
upon some petitions:
Bright lines provide the certainty and predictability needed for companies to
make business plans and for capital markets to make investments in the growth
and innovation in media markets. Conversely, case-by-case review of even
below-cap mergers on diversity grounds would lead to uncertainty and
62 Prometheus, 373 F.3d at 394 (emphasis in original).
63 Report and Order at ¶ 80-85. In the section on Policy Goals, there are four subsections
— Diversity, Competition, Localism, and Regulatory Certainty.
64 Ibid., at ¶ 83, footnote omitted.

CRS-17
undermine our efforts to encourage growth in broadcast services. Accordingly,
petitioners should not use the petition to deny process to relitigate the issues
resolved in this proceeding.65
Once it determined that a bright line test is preferable to case-by-case review,
the Commission created bright line tests for its media cross ownership and local
ownership rules by constructing a “Diversity Index” that it used as the basis for
setting the threshold ownership limits in its new rules.66 The Diversity Index is
intended to measure “viewpoint concentration” and thereby identify “at risk” markets
where limits on media ownership should be retained. It is constructed by
! identifying all the local media voices in a market.
! assigning a diversity “market share” to each of those voices by first
assigning different weights to each of the media categories based on
an Arbitron study of the sources consumers use for local news and
information — television, 33.8%; radio, 24.9%; newspapers, 28.8%,
and Internet, 12.5% — and then assigning each media outlet within
a media category the same weight (so that, for example, if there were
three radio stations in a market each one would be assigned a market
share of 8.3%). If a single entity owns more than one media outlet
in a market, for example if it owns both a television station and a
radio station, then its diversity market share would be the sum of the
two individual market shares.
! adding up the sum of the squares of each of the diversity market
shares to yield a Diversity Index value.
A larger Diversity Index value denotes greater viewpoint concentration (less diversity
of viewpoints). The Commission calculated the Diversity Index for a sample of
large, medium, and small markets, as well as the Diversity Index for those markets
if certain mergers were allowed to occur (for example, a television station purchasing
a newspaper or a television station purchasing a radio station) to determine which
markets were “at risk” for significant loss of diversity if particular ownership
combinations were allowed. It concluded that in markets with three or fewer
television stations there was significant danger of loss of viewpoint diversity if a
television station were allowed to combine with a newspaper or a radio station and
therefore maintained the cross ownership ban in those markets. It also concluded that
certain combinations would unduly harm viewpoint diversity in markets with four to
eight television stations and therefore set certain cross ownership restrictions in those
markets as well.67 The Commission also used the Diversity Index as the basis for
setting its limits on local television multiple ownership.68
65 Ibid., at ¶ 453, fn. 980.
66 Ibid., at ¶¶ 391-481.
67 These limits are discussed in the sections on the specific rules below.
68 See Report and Order at ¶¶ 192 ff.

CRS-18
The Commission stated that its Diversity Index was “inspired by” the
Herfindahl-Hirschmann Index (HHI)69 used by the Department of Justice and Federal
Trade Commission to identify those proposed mergers that, based on historical
merger experience, might have a deleterious effect on competition in the affected
markets and therefore merit additional scrutiny. (Proposed mergers that would result
in markets exceeding the HHI threshold levels automatically trigger further review.)
Analogously, the Diversity Index is intended to identify those markets in which
additional concentration in media ownership might have a deleterious effect on
viewpoint diversity in the affected market. The Diversity Index, like the HHI, is
calculated by squaring the market shares of each market participant. But there are
three significant differences between these two indices and how they are applied.
First, the HHI is calculated using the actual market shares of the providers in the
market under consideration. If one or more providers have large market shares, the
HHI is very large because that market share figure is squared. In contrast, the
Diversity Index is calculated using the assumption that every provider within a media
category (for example, newspapers or television stations) has equal diversity market
share. Thus, in the New York City market the New York Times and the Nowy
Dziennik-Polish Daily News are accorded the same weight; the local CBS television
station and the Dutchess Community College television station (in suburban New
York) are accorded the same weight. On a purely mathematical basis, the assumption
of equal diversity impact minimizes the sum of the squared market shares, thus
minimizing the size of the Diversity Index and providing the lowest possible estimate
of viewpoint concentration.
Second, the antitrust agencies apply the HHI directly to the proposed merger,
on a case-by-case basis, to determine if further scrutiny is merited. The actual market
shares of each of the market participants are calculated — and squared — and the
resulting HHI is compared to threshold levels to determine if additional scrutiny is
required. In contrast, the FCC does not intend to apply the Diversity Index to any
specific proposed change in media ownership. Rather, it used the Diversity Index
(calculated for sample markets by assuming that each media outlet within the same
media category, for example, television stations, has the same “diversity market
share”) as the basis for setting the maximum number (or combination) of media
outlets that any provider could own in a market. A proposed media merger then
would be approved or disapproved based on the number (or combination) of media
outlets the post-merger company would have in the market, regardless of its actual
post-merger diversity market share.70
Third, the threshold levels of the HHI that trigger antitrust agency scrutiny were
based on many years of Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission
experience reviewing mergers and a body of economic literature about the
relationship between market structure and market conduct. The FCC used those HHI
69 Ibid., at ¶ 396.
70 As indicated earlier, although the Commission maintained processes for firms that would
not meet a bright line test to seek a waiver and for interested parties that wanted to challenge
a merger that met a bright line test to file a petition to deny a license transfer, it stated that
it would not look favorably upon some petitions.

CRS-19
trigger points as the starting point for scrutinizing viewpoint concentration, but
without a historical record or body of literature demonstrating that the same trigger
points for economic concentration are applicable to viewpoint concentration.
In Prometheus, the Third Circuit did not question the concept of a Diversity
Index or of bright line rules. It did
not object in principle to the Commission’s reliance on the Department of Justice
and Federal Trade Commission’s antitrust formula, the Herfindahl-Hirschmann
Index (“HHI”), as its starting point for measuring diversity in local markets.71
Moreover, the Third Circuit found that the Commission’s decision to retain a
numerical limits approach to radio station ownership regulation is “rational and in
the public interest.”72 (In the case of the Commission’s Local Cross Ownership and
Local Television Multiple Ownership rules, it did not explicitly conclude that the
numerical limits approach was rational and in the public interest, but did frame its
remand of the numerical limits adopted in terms of the specific limits chosen, not of
the concept of numerical limits.)
However, the Third Circuit found that the FCC’s methodology for converting
the HHI to a measure for diversity in local markets was irrational and inconsistent.
Specifically, the Third Circuit found
[the Commission’s] decision to count the Internet as a source of viewpoint
diversity, while discounting cable, was not rational.73
The Commission’s decision to assign equal market shares to outlets within a
media type does not jibe with the Commission’s decision to assign relative
weights to the different media type themselves, about which it said “we have no
reason to believe that all media are of equal importance.” Order ¶ 409; see also
Id.
¶ 445. (“Not all voices, however, speak with the same volume.”) It also
negates the Commission’s proffered rationale for using the HHI formula in the
first place — to allow it to measure the actual loss of diversity from
consolidation by taking into account the actual “diversity importance” of the
merging parties, something it could not do with a simple “voices” test. Id. ¶
396.74
Although the Commission is entitled to deference in deciding where to draw the
line between acceptable and unacceptable increases in markets’ Diversity Index
scores, we do not affirm the seemingly inconsistent manner in which the line was
71 Prometheus, 373 F.3d at 402-403.
72 Ibid., at 431.
73 Ibid., at 405. The Court found it inconsistent that the FCC chose not to include cable
television as an alternative local news and information voice because most of that news was
actually provided by the local television broadcast stations carried on the cable systems and
yet chose to include the Internet as a significant alternative local news and information voice
despite the fact that most local news and information found on the Internet is on the websites
of the local television stations and newspapers. (Ibid., at 406.)
74 Ibid., at 408.

CRS-20
drawn.... [T]he Cross-Media Limits allow some combinations where the
increases in Diversity Index scores were generally higher than for other
combinations that were not allowed.75
In remanding the rules, the Court has given the Commission the opportunity “to
justify or modify its approach to setting numerical limits.”76
Then-chairman Powell reportedly stated in an interview after the Court decision
was released,
It may not be possible to line-draw. Part of me says maybe the best answer is to
evaluate on a case-by-case basis. The commission may end up getting more
pushed in that direction.77
Given that the Third Circuit did not challenge the concept of using a Diversity Index
to set specific numerical limits, however, it is not apparent that the Third Circuit has
indicated any preference for a case-by-case approach rather than a bright line rule.
The task of implementing bright line rules that can withstand court review may
be challenging, but that may have more to do with the inherent complexity and
ambiguity of measuring viewpoint diversity consistently across heterogeneous
geographic markets than in constraints placed by the courts. As indicated above, the
Third Circuit identified three problems with the existing rules: (1) the inconsistent
treatment of cable television and the Internet; (2) the assignment of equal weight to
all media outlets within a media category rather than actual market shares; and (3)
allowing some combinations where the increases in Diversity Index scores were
generally higher than for other combinations that were not allowed. In remand, the
Commission should be able to modify its Diversity Index to treat cable television and
the Internet the same or to provide empirical evidence for why they should be treated
differently. Similarly, the Commission should be able to construct a Diversity Index
using actual market share data (though admittedly that would be a more difficult task
and might generate challenges to the market share figures). It may prove to be
difficult, however, to construct bright line media ownership limits — in terms of the
specific number of media outlets that a single entity could own in a market — that
all are based on a consistent application of the Diversity Index (the Third Circuit’s
third concern).
The Commission potentially could get around this problem in several ways,
though these might be construed as case-by-case solutions. For example, the
Commission could set its bright line rules in terms of specific Diversity Index levels
(prohibiting any consolidation that would result in a Diversity Index that exceeded
a particular level) rather than using the Diversity Index to identify media ownership
levels that are bright lines. Alternatively, the Commission could use the Diversity
Index to identify media ownership limits that are bright lines in the sense that they
75 Ibid., at 411.
76 Ibid., at 435.
77 Frank Ahrens, “Powell Calls Rejection of Media Rules a Disappointment,” Washington
Post
, June 29, 2004, at pp. E1 and E5.

CRS-21
trigger further scrutiny, but also explicitly identify further criteria that would be used
to evaluate proposed consolidations that yield Diversity Index levels within a range
of “potential concern.” For example, it might construct a multi-part rule that would
allow all proposed license transfers that would result in a market-wide Diversity
Index below 1000 and an increase in the Diversity Index of less than 200; trigger
further scrutiny (of explicitly identified diversity criteria) for any proposed license
transfer that would result in a Diversity Index between 1000 and 1800 or result in an
increase in the Diversity Index of between 200 and 400; and prohibit any proposed
license transfer that would result in a Diversity Index that exceeded 1800 or that
increased by more than 400.78
Specific Media Ownership Rules
National Television Ownership (% Cap)
Current Status.
In practice, the National Television Ownership rule applies to the major
broadcast networks, limiting them to ownership and operation of local broadcast
stations that reach, in total, the prescribed percentage of U.S. television households.
Section 629 of the FY2004 Consolidated Appropriations Act (P.L. 108-199, 118 Stat.
3 et seq.) instructs the FCC to modify its National Television Ownership rule by
setting a 39% cap,79 requires entities that exceed the 39% cap to divest as needed to
come into compliance within two years, prohibits the FCC from forbearing on
application of the 39% cap,80 requires the FCC to review its rules every four years
instead of two years, and excludes the 39% cap from that periodic review.
When calculating the total audience reached by an entity’s stations, the so-
called “UHF discount” is applied — audiences of UHF stations are given only half-
weight. For example, if an entity owns a UHF station in a market with an audience
of two million households, that audience would only be counted as one million
households when calculating the entity’s market reach.
78 The Diversity Index levels used in this example are intended to be descriptive only and
should not be construed as endorsement by CRS of any particular approach. If it were to
choose to construct a rule of this sort, the FCC would have to provide an empirical basis for
the threshold levels in its rules.
79 By setting the cap at 39%, two entities — Viacom (CBS) and News Corp. (Fox) — that
had recently acquired stations that gave them total national audience reach of approximately
39% and 38% respectively did not have to divest themselves of any of their stations.
80 Section 10 of the Communication Act of 1934 (47 U.S.C. 160) allows the FCC to forbear
from applying some regulations and provisions to a telecommunications carrier,
telecommunications service, or class of telecommunications services under certain
conditions. It is unlikely that this section of the act would apply to broadcast stations, in any
case, because broadcasters are not telecommunications carriers and broadcasting is not a
telecommunications service.

CRS-22
The National Television Ownership rule and the UHF discount were not
immediately affected by the appeal of the FCC’s June 2, 2003 Order. In deciding that
appeal in Prometheus, the Third Circuit found that
Because the Commission is under a statutory directive to modify the national
television ownership cap to 39%, challenges to the Commission’s decision to
raise the cap to 45% are moot.81
Although the 2004 Consolidated Appropriations Act did not expressly mention
the UHF discount, challenges to the Commission’s decision to retain it are
likewise moot.82
But the UHF discount portion of the FCC’s June 2, 2003 National Television
Ownership rule included a section stating that when the transition to digital television
is complete, the UHF discount would be eliminated for those stations owned by the
four largest broadcast networks.83 This section presumably would be moot, based on
the following language in the Prometheus decision requiring the rules adopted in the
FCC’s biennial review proceeding to adhere to the 39% cap mandated by Congress:
because reducing or eliminating the discount for UHF station audiences would
effectively raise the audience reach limit, we cannot entertain challenges to
Commission’s decision to retain the 50% UHF discount. Any relief we granted
on these claims would undermine Congress’s specification of a precise 39%
cap.84
At the same time, the Third Circuit, aware that the FCC has sought public comment
on its authority going forward to modify or eliminate the UHF discount through a
proceeding that is outside the proscribed quadrennial review,85 stated that
we do not intend our decision to foreclose the Commission’s consideration of its
regulation defining the UHF discount outside the context of Section 202(h) [the
mandatory quadrennial review of ownership rules that Congress has prohibited
the FCC from performing on the National Television Ownership rule].86
Recent History.
The FCC has limited the national ownership reach of television broadcast
stations since 1941, modifying its rules several times since then. In 1984, the
81 Prometheus, 373 F.3d at 396.
82 Ibid., at 396.
83 Report and Order at ¶ 591.
84 Prometheus, 373 F.3d at 396.
85 “Media Bureau Seeks Additional Comment on UHF Discount in Light of Recent
Legislation Affecting National Television Ownership Cap,” FCC Media Bureau Public
Notice, DA 04-320, MB Docket No. 02-277, February 19, 2004. The deadline for receipt
of reply comments was March 29, 2004; the Commission has not yet taken any action
relating to issues for which comment was sought in the Public Notice.
86 Prometheus, 373 F.3d at 397.

CRS-23
Commission repealed its rule, and instituted a six-year transitional ownership limit
of 12 television stations nationwide. In 1985, on reconsideration, the Commission
affirmed its conclusion, but eliminated the sunset provision, retaining the 12-station
limit and, in addition, prohibiting an entity from reaching more than 25% of the
country’s television households through the stations it owned.87
In 1996, the Commission adopted a 35% cap in response to the directive in the
1996 Telecommunications Act to raise the cap from 25% to 35% and to eliminate the
rule that any entity could not own more than 12 stations nationwide.88 The
Commission subsequently affirmed the 35% cap as part of the 1998 biennial review
of media ownership rules.89 This decision was challenged by several broadcast
networks and in 2002 the D.C. Circuit, in Fox Stations, remanded the rule to the
Commission on the grounds that the Commission had failed to provide a justification
for the 35% level.90
In its June 2, 2003 Order, the Commission modified its National Television
Ownership rule91 by increasing the maximum aggregate national audience reach of
an entity owning multiple television stations from 35% to 45%. In addition to
increasing the cap, the Commission retained the UHF discount. This discount
initially was implemented because UHF signals tend to have a smaller geographic
reach than, and are of inferior quality to, VHF signals. The Commission explicitly
retained the UHF discount, finding that UHF stations continue to face a technical and
market disadvantage.92
In the Report and Order, the Commission determined that a national television
ownership rule is not relevant to its competition goal in the three relevant economic
markets it investigated: the national television advertising market, the national
program acquisition market, and the local video delivery market.93 But it determined
that a national television ownership rule is needed to protect localism by allowing a
body of network affiliates to negotiate collectively with the broadcast networks on
network programming decisions.94 It found that the 35% level did not strike the right
balance of promoting localism and preserving free over-the-air television for several
reasons:
87 Report and Order at ¶ 502.
88 Implementation of Sections 202(c)(1) and 202(e) of the Telecommunications Act of 1996
(National Broadcast Television Ownership and Dual Network Operations),
11 FCC Rcd
12374 (1996).
89 1998 Biennial Review Report, 15 FCC Rcd 11072-75 ¶¶ 25-30.
90 See Fox Television Stations, Inc. v. Federal Communications Commission, 280 F.3rd
1027 (DC Cir. 2002).
91 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(d)(1), previously 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(e)(1).
92 Report and Order at ¶ 586.
93 Report and Order at ¶ 508-509.
94 Ibid., at ¶ 501.

CRS-24
! the 35% cap did not have any meaningful effect on the negotiating
power between individual networks and their affiliates with respect
to program-by-program preemption levels;95
! the broadcast network owned-and-operated stations served their
local communities better with respect to local news production.
Network-owned stations aired more local news programming, and
higher quality local news programming, than did affiliates.96
! the public interest is served by regulations that encourage the
networks to keep expensive programming, such as sports, on free,
over-the-air television.97
Opponents of increasing the cap from 35% to 45% had argued that:
! locally owned and operated stations are more likely to be responsive
to local needs and interests than network owned and operated
stations (for example, they are more likely to preempt network
programming when non-network programming of special local
interest, such as a local sports event, is available or when network
programming does not meet community standards);
! if there are fewer independently owned and operated affiliates, they
will be under much greater pressure from the networks not to pre-
empt network programming even if programming of special local
interest is available;
! some broadcast networks that also own cable networks have refused
to give local cable systems permission to retransmit their local
broadcast stations’ signals unless they also carried the integrated
company’s cable networks; if these broadcast networks could own
95 One measure of the relative balance of negotiating strength between networks and
affiliates is the rate at which affiliates preempt network programming to show alternative
programming. The Commission found that there was no difference in the preemption rates
among those network affiliates affiliated to networks whose audience reach was less than
the 35 percent cap and those network affiliates affiliated to the two networks whose
audience reach exceeded the 35 percent cap. Report and Order at ¶ 558.
96 Report and Order at ¶ 575-576.
97 The broadcast networks had claimed in their comments that broadcast networks are less
profitable than local broadcast stations, so to help broadcast networks compete against cable
networks for rights to expensive sports programming (and keep such programming free to
the public), the networks must be able to own and operate more local broadcast stations.
The dissenting FCC commissioners questioned broadcast network needs given the record
$9.4 billion in advertising revenues for the 2003-2004 season, an increase of 13%, they
contracted for in the four-day “up-front” market in May of this year. (See Steve McClellan,
“Extraordinary: Fast and furious, network advertisers spend record $9.4B,” Broadcasting
& Cable
, May 26, 2003.)

CRS-25
and operate additional local broadcast stations, they could extend
this practice to those stations.
In its Report and Order, the Commission did not provide quantitative analysis
in support of adoption of the 45% cap. It explained that the available data
demonstrated no difference in behavior between the two networks that reach just
under 40% of national television households and the other networks that reach fewer
than 35% of national television households. At the same time, the Commission
found that preserving a balance of power between the broadcast television networks
and their affiliates serves local needs by ensuring that affiliates can play a meaningful
role in selecting programming suitable for their communities. The 45% cap thus
represented the balancing of competing interests.98 At the June 4, 2003 Senate
Commerce Committee hearing, Chairman Powell reflected that while the
Commission believes its order provides a justification for the 45% cap, given the
very high standard set by the Court he could not have total confidence the
Commission’s rule would survive judicial review and that if Congress believed a
specific percentage cap is “inviolate,” it should codify that percentage in the act.
Some parties have called for elimination of the UHF discount. They claim that
the UHF discount in effect raises the current cap to as high as 70% and if retained
while the cap was increased to 45% would raise the effective cap to as high as 90%.99
The provision in the Balanced Budget Act of 1997 relating to digital television
requires all analog television stations, both those on the VHF band and those on the
UHF band, to convert to digital transmission by December 31, 2006 unless certain
conditions are not met. When the digital transition is complete, both VHF and UHF
stations will have the same transmission capabilities and therefore UHF stations will
no longer be at a disadvantage with respect to audience reach. The Commission’s
decision took this into account by ruling that when the transition to digital television
is complete, the UHF discount would be eliminated for the stations owned by the
four largest broadcast networks.100 It chose to retain the UHF discount in other
situations because it believes the discount could foster creation of additional
broadcast networks. But as mentioned above, although the Third Circuit’s
Prometheus decision maintained the UHF discount, it also did not foreclose the
Commission from reviewing that discount outside the scope of the biennial review
of ownership rules.
Dual Network Ownership
In its June 2, 2003 Order, the FCC retained the existing Dual Network
Ownership rule, which prohibits the four major networks — ABC, CBS, Fox, and
98 Report and Order at ¶ 501.
99 The dissenting FCC commissioners stated that the Commission’s new cross-ownership
and television ownership rules do not provide a 50% discount for UHF stations and that this
inconsistent weighting of UHF in different rules cannot be justified.
100 Report and Order at ¶ 591.

CRS-26
NBC — from merging with one another.101 The Commission found that the rule
continues to be necessary to promote competition in the national television
advertising and program acquisition markets, and that the rule promotes localism by
preserving the balance of negotiating power between networks and affiliates.
In 2001, as part of its previous biennial review of media ownership rules, the
FCC had modified this rule to allow the four major networks to own, operate,
maintain, or control broadcast networks other than the four majors. With this change,
Viacom, the owner of CBS, was allowed to purchase UPN, and NBC was able to
purchase Telemundo, the second largest Spanish-language network in the U.S.
At the June 4, 2003 Senate Commerce Committee hearing, Commissioner
Adelstein stated that while he supported retention of the prohibition on mergers
among the four major broadcast networks, he dissented from the rule because the
Commission should have expanded it to provide a similar merger prohibition on
Spanish language broadcast networks, which are currently experiencing
consolidation.
Local Television Multiple Ownership
Current Status.
As a result of the Third Circuit’s Prometheus decision remanding and extending
its stay of the Local Television Multiple Ownership rule that the FCC adopted on
June 2, 2003, the rule currently in place is the one the FCC adopted in 1999,
sometimes referred to as the “TV duopoly” rule. Under this rule, an entity can own
two television stations in the same Designated Market Area (DMA) only if the
following requirements are met:
! either the Grade B contours of the stations do not overlap,
! or (a) at least one of the stations is not ranked among the four
highest-ranked stations in the DMA, and (b) at least eight
independently owned and operating commercial or non-commercial
full-power broadcast television stations would remain in the DMA
after the proposed combination were consummated.102 This second
option is sometimes referred to as the “top four ranked/eight voices
test.”
The rule also includes a standard for approving a waiver of the ownership limits
where a proposed combination involves at least one station that is failed, failing, or
101 The rule “permits broadcast networks to provide multiple program streams (program
networks) simultaneously within local markets, and prohibits only a merger between or
among [the four major networks].” 67 FR 65751 at ¶ 156.
102 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(b); Local TV Ownership Report and Order, 14 FCC Rcd at 12907-
08, ¶ 8.

CRS-27
unbuilt.103 For each type of waiver, the waiver applicant must demonstrate that the
“in-market” buyer is the only reasonably available entity willing and able to operate
the subject station, and that selling the station to an out-of-market buyer would result
in an artificially depressed price for the station.104 Any combination formed as a
result of a failed, failing, or unbuilt station waiver may be transferred together only
if the combination meets the Local Television Multiple Ownership rule or one of the
three waiver standards at the time of transfer.105
Recent History.
The FCC adopted a rule prohibiting common ownership of two television
stations with intersecting Grade B contours in 1964. In the 1996
Telecommunications Act, Congress directed the Commission to “conduct a
rulemaking proceeding to determine whether to retain, modify, or eliminate its
limitations on the number of television stations that a person or entity may own,
operate, or control, or have a cognizable interest in, within the same television
market.”106 In 1999, the Commission performed a review and modified the rule,
creating the television duopoly rule that is in effect today. In 2002, that local
ownership rule was remanded to the Commission by the D.C. Circuit,107 which ruled
that the Commission failed to justify why it only included TV stations among the
voices in the voice test, excluding other media.
The FCC modified the rule in its June 2, 2003 Order, to set the following
ownership limits:108
! In markets with five or more TV stations, a company may own two
TV stations, but only one of these stations can be among the top four
in ratings;
103 A “failed” station is one that has been dark for at least four months or is involved in
court-supervised involuntary bankruptcy or involuntary insolvency proceedings. Under the
standard for “failing” stations, a waiver is presumed to be in the public interest if the
applicant satisfies each of the following criteria: (1) one of the merging stations has had all-
day audience share of 4% or lower; (2) the financial condition of one of the merging stations
is poor; (3) and the merger will produce public interest benefits. Under the standard for
“unbuilt” stations, a waiver is presumed to be in the public interest if an applicant meets
each of the following criteria: (1) the combination will result in the construction of an
authorized but as yet unbuilt station; and (2) the permittee has made reasonable efforts to
construct, and has been unable to do so. (47 C.F.R. 73.3555, Note 7 (1) and Local Television
Ownership Report
, 14 FCC Rcd at 12941 ¶ 86.
104 47 C.F.R. 73.3555, Note 7.
105 Local TV Ownership Report and Order, 14 FCC Rcd at 12938-41 ¶¶ 77, 81, 86.
106 1996 Act, § 202(c)(2).
107 See Sinclair Broadcast Group, Inc. v. Federal Communications Commission, 284 F.3rd
148 (DC Cir. 2002)
108 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(b).

CRS-28
! In markets with 18 or more stations, a company may own three TV
stations, but only one of these stations can be among the top four in
ratings;
! In deciding how many stations are in the market, both commercial
and non-commercial TV stations are counted;
! There is an eased waiver process for markets with 11 or fewer TV
stations in which two top-four stations seek to merge.109 The FCC
will evaluate on a case-by-case basis whether such stations would
better serve their local communities together rather than separately.
! Under the waiver standard that applies for all markets, the FCC will
consider permitting otherwise banned two-station combinations or
three-station combinations if one station is “failed, failing, or
unbuilt.” The standard is liberalized by removing the requirement
that an applicant for such a waiver “demonstrate that it has tried and
failed to secure an out-of-market buyer for the failed station.”
In its June 2, 2003 Order, the Commission determined that the 1999 Television
Duopoly rule could not be justified based on diversity or competition grounds.110 It
found that Americans rely on a variety of media outlets, not just broadcast television,
for news and information. In addition, it determined that the prior rule could not be
justified as necessary to promote competition because it failed to reflect the
significant competition now faced by local broadcasters from cable and satellite TV
services.
The Commission concluded that the new rule permits television combinations
that are proven to enhance competition in local markets111 and to facilitate the
transition to digital television112 through economic efficiencies. It determined that
the new rule’s continued ban on mergers among the top-four stations will have the
109 In markets with 11 or fewer stations, the FCC will consider waivers of the “top-four”
restriction if the proposed combination meets one or more of the following criteria: reduces
a “significant competitive disparity between the merging stations and the dominant station”
in the market; facilitates the stations’ transition from analog to digital broadcasting;
produces such public interest benefits as more news and local programming; involves a UHF
station or two; or the stations’ outer, or “grade B,” signals do not overlap and have not been
carried, via direct broadcast satellite or cable, to any of the same geographic areas within
the past year. See Report and Order at ¶ 221-232. Combinations achieved by waiver of the
“top-four” restriction, however, could not be transferred or assigned to another party without
obtaining another waiver. LIN Television lobbyist Greg Schmidt reportedly criticizes this
requirement for a second waiver, claiming that television owners will lose one of the major
justifications for expending capital to buy and improve a second station if the return on that
investment cannot be recouped by selling the stations as a pair. See Bill McConnell, “FCC
Does the Waive,” Broadcasting & Cable, July 7, 2003, at p. 1.
110 Report and Order at ¶ 133.
111 Ibid., at ¶ 147.
112 Ibid., at ¶ 148.

CRS-29
effect of preserving viewpoint diversity in local markets.113 The record showed that
the top four stations each typically produce an independent local newscast. The
Commission also concluded that because viewpoint diversity is fostered when there
are multiple independently owned media outlets, the rules also advance the goal of
promoting the widest dissemination of viewpoints.

The proponents of retaining the old rule argued that the rule safeguarded the
number of independent local news voices in the market, given that broadcast
television is the primary source of local news for Americans; that cable and satellite
companies provide virtually no local news; and that radio news is not a substitute for
television news. They also claimed that the rule protected against a combination
attaining market power in the local television advertising market.
Proponents of replacing the old rule with a rule requiring a case-by-case review
of proposed mergers claimed that only such an approach could accurately weigh the
diversity impact of the individual television stations in a specific market to make
informed case-by-case public interest determinations about a proposed merger. But
opponents of a case-by-case approach claimed it would not allow firms to plan
mergers with regulatory certainty.
Many aspects of the FCC’s 2003 Local Television Multiple Ownership rule
were appealed. In its Prometheus decision, the Third Circuit found:
! limiting local television station ownership is not duplicative of
antitrust regulation;114
! media other than broadcast television may contribute to viewpoint
diversity in local markets;115
! consolidation can improve local programming;116 and
! the Commission’s decision to retain the restriction on owning more
than one of the top-four television stations in a market is supported
by record evidence.117
But the Third Circuit remanded:
! the specific numerical limits on television station ownership in local
markets, because the record evidence does not support reliance on
an assumption of all stations having an equal market share and the
113 Ibid., at ¶ 196-200.
114 Prometheus, 373 F.3d at 413.
115 Ibid., at 414.
116 Ibid., at 415.
117 Ibid., at 416.

CRS-30
Commission provided no reasonable explanation for its decision to
disregard actual market shares;118 and
! the repeal of the requirement in its waiver standard that the applicant
demonstrate that the “in-market” buyer is the only reasonably
available entity willing and able to operate the subject station,
because the Commission failed to address the original purpose of the
requirement — to ensure that qualified minority broadcasters had a
fair chance to learn that certain financially troubled, and
consequently more affordable, stations were for sale.119
Local Radio Multiple Ownership
Current Status.
The ownership limits currently in place are those that the Commission adopted
in 1996 to codify the language in Section 202(b)(1) of the 1996 Act, but, as a result
of the Third Circuit agreeing in rehearing to lift the portion of its stay relating to the
FCC’s new methodology for defining local radio markets, those markets are defined
using that new methodology. Specifically, the current rules provide that:
! in a radio market with 45 or more full power commercial and
noncommercial radio stations, a party may own, operate, or control
up to eight commercial radio stations, not more than five of which
are in the same service (AM or FM);
! in a radio market with between 30 and 44 (inclusive) full power
commercial and noncommercial radio stations, a party may own,
operate, or control up to seven commercial radio stations, not more
than four of which are in the same service (AM or FM);
! in a radio market with between 15 and 29 (inclusive) full power
commercial and noncommercial radio stations, a party may own,
operate, or control up to six commercial radio stations, not more
than four of which are in the same service (AM or FM);
! in a radio market with 14 or fewer full power commercial and
noncommercial radio stations, a party may own, operate, or control
up to five commercial radio stations, not more than three of which
are in the same service (AM or FM), except that a party may not
own, operate, or control more than 50 percent of the stations in such
market.120
118 Ibid., at 418-419.
119 Ibid., at 420-421.
120 Section 202(b) also provides that the Commission may permit a party to exceed these
limits “if the Commission determines that [it] will result in an increase in the number of
radio broadcast stations in operation.” 1996 Act, § 202(b)(2), 110 Stat. at 10-11.

CRS-31
These numerical limits are applied to geographic markets that are defined
according to Arbitron rating boundaries, which are based on market factors rather
than on the signal transmission contours that previously were used to define
markets.121 Since Arbitron boundaries do not cover small radio markets, the FCC
adopted a notice of proposed rule making to determine how to define geographic
markets in those small markets for which there are no Arbitron market definitions
and adopted procedures (involving a modified version of the FCC’s historic signal
transmission contour rule) to follow during the interim.122
Also, under current rules, when a “brokering” station has a Joint Sales
Agreement (JSA) with a “brokered” station — typically this authorizes one station
acting as a broker to sell advertising time for the brokered station in return for a fee
— the brokered stations counts toward the number of stations the brokering licensee
may own in a local market.123
The FCC, however, has discontinued following its old policy of “flagging”
public notices of proposed radio station transactions that, based on an initial analysis
by the staff, would result in one entity controlling 50% or more of the advertising
revenues in the relevant Arbitron radio market or two entities controlling 70% or
more of the advertising revenues in the market.124 Previously, those flagged
transactions were subject to further competitive analysis.125
Most observers believe that the overall effect of these changes will be to reduce
radio merger opportunities.126
Recent History.
Until 1992, entities were prohibited from owning two same-service (AM or FM)
radio stations whose signal contours overlapped. In 1992, the FCC relaxed the Local
Radio Multiple Ownership rule by establishing numerical limits on radio station
ownership based on the total number of commercial radio stations in a market.
121 Report and Order at ¶ 239.
122 Ibid., at ¶ 239.
123 Ibid., at ¶ 239.
124 See Application of Shareholders of AMFM, Inc. (Transferor) and Clear Channel
Communication, Inc. (Transferee)
, 15 FCC Rcd 16062, 16066 ¶ 7 n. 10 (2000).
125 The scope of that analysis is embodied in the interim policy set forth in the FCC’s Local
Radio Ownership Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
, 16 FCC Rcd at 19894-97 ¶¶ 84-89.
126 At the July 8, 2003 Senate Commerce Committee hearing on radio consolidation, Lewis
Dickey, Jr., Chairman, President, and CEO of Cumulus Broadcasting, Inc., and Alex
Kolobielski, President and CEO of First Media Radio, testified that the new methodology
for defining radio markets would restrict opportunities for acquisitions and therefore harm
competition. Mr. Dickey claimed that it would restrict radio groups from growing as large
as market leader Clear Channel was able to grow under the old methodology and thus would
deny competitors the opportunity to compete on an equal footing. Mr. Kolobielski claimed
that it would not allow small companies to put together clusters of stations in small markets
to exploit economies of scale.

CRS-32
Under the 1992 rules, an entity could own 2 AM and 2 FM radio stations in markets
with 15 or more commercial radio stations, and three radio stations (of which no
more than 2 could be AM or FM stations) in smaller markets. The 1992 rule also
imposed an audience share limit on radio station combinations in the larger market.127
In the 1996 Telecommunications Act, Congress directed the Commission to
revise those numerical limits to provide the limits that are in place today.128 The act
also repealed national limits on radio station ownership.129
In its June 2, 2003 Order, the Commission retained the numerical limits in the
1996 Act, finding that those numerical ownership limits continue to be needed to
promote competition among local radio stations;130 that competitive radio markets
ensure that local stations are responsive to local listener needs and tastes; and that the
rule, by guaranteeing a substantial number of independent radio voices, also will
promote viewpoint diversity among local radio owners.
The Commission did, however, make several changes to the then-current rules:
! It replaced its complex signal contour methodology for defining
local radio geographic markets with a market-based approach using
Arbitron rating boundaries.131
! It modified its market definition methodology to include non-
commercial as well as commercial radio stations in its count of
stations in a market.132
! It counted stations brokered under a Joint Sales Agreement toward
the brokering station’s permissible ownership totals as long as (1)
the brokering entity owns or has an attributable interest in one or
more stations in the local market, and (2) the joint advertising sales
amount to more than 15% of the brokered station’s advertising time
per week.
! It grandfathered existing radio combinations that would not meet the
limits under the new market definitions, but prohibited the future
transfer or sale of these grandfathered combinations except to certain
“eligible entities” that qualify as small businesses.
127 See 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(a)(1) (1995).
128 1996 Act, § 202(b).
129 Ibid., § 202(a).
130 Report and Order at ¶ 239.
131 Report and Order at ¶ 239. It also adopted a notice of proposed rule making to determine
how to define geographic markets in those small markets for which there are no Arbitron
market definitions and adopted procedures to follow during the interim.
132 Ibid., at ¶ 239.

CRS-33
! It eliminated its policy of (a) “flagging” those radio station
transactions that, based on an initial analysis by the staff, would
result in one entity controlling 50% or more of the radio advertising
revenues in the relevant Arbitron radio market or two entities
controlling 70% or more of such advertising revenues; (b)
conducting further competitive review of the flagged transaction;
and (c) inviting interested parties to file comments addressing the
competitive impact of the proposed merger.133
In the FCC’s rulemaking proceeding, the proponents of retaining the old
ownership limits as is or eliminating them entirely argued that the rule — and the
resultant consolidation in the industry — had turned around the industry financially,
from one in which more than half the radio stations were losing money to one that
is very profitable and attracting an increasing share of the total advertising market.
They also claimed that the number of program formats has increased.
The proponents of modifying the rule to tighten ownership limits claimed that
the rule had led to both horizontal and vertical consolidation (for example, ownership
of concert promotion companies, concert venues) that has resulted in anticompetitive
behavior by the large vertically integrated companies that has reduced competition
in the radio, advertising, music, and concert markets, reduced program format
diversity, and reduced local programming. The dissenting FCC commissioners
claimed that elimination of the “50/70 screen” takes away the opportunity for the
Commission to undertake case-by-case reviews of mergers that, though they meet the
bright line test, do not meet a market screen that is a good predictor of potential
market power in the advertising market.
In its rulemaking proceeding, the Commission found the overlapping signal
contour methodology used to define radio markets had yielded several anomalous
situations with very expansive geographic market definitions that included distant
stations and therefore allowed concentration to occur in more narrowly — but also
more accurately — defined markets. For example, under the market definition
methodology, a single entity was able to own all 6 of the commercial radio stations
in Fargo, North Dakota because a long chain of rural stations with overlapping signal
contours were included in the geographic market definition.134 The FCC therefore
133 Ibid., at ¶ 300-301.
134 Jennifer Lee, “On Minot, N.D., Radio, a Single Corporate Voice,” New York Times,
March 29, 2003. To understand how this occurred, it may be simplest to think of a station’s
principal community contours as being, as an approximation, a circle around the station’s
transmitter. Radio stations’ transmitters and principal community contours, though
concentrated to some extent in urbanized areas, are geographically dispersed. A geographic
market defined by overlapping contours can result in a series of contours overlapping one
another to create a very extended market — sort of a daisy chain effect. Thus, the contours
of stations in Fargo overlapped with stations in several directions outside Fargo, all in an
extended chain, resulting in a such a large number of stations being included in the market
that a single entity was allowed to own 6 of them, all located in close proximity to one
another rather than being spread across the large geographic market created by the
overlapping contour methodology.

CRS-34
chose to replace the overlapping contour methodology with a methodology based on
market-driven factors identified by Arbitron.
Many aspects of the FCC’s 2003 Local Radio Multiple Ownership rule were
appealed, and most were upheld by the Third Circuit. In its Prometheus decision, the
Third Circuit:
! upheld the Commission’s use of market-based Arbitron Metro
markets instead of the contour-overlap methodology to define local
radio markets;135
! upheld the inclusion of noncommercial radio stations when
performing the station count in a market;136
! found the FCC’s transfer restriction is in the public interest;137
! affirmed the attribution of Joint Sales Agreements, counting stations
brokered under a JSA toward the brokering station’s permissible
ownership totals; 138 and
! found the FCC’s numerical limits approach rational and in the public
interest.139
But, the Third Circuit
! remanded the specific numerical limits in the rule to the
Commission for further justification;140 and
! found the Commission did not justify its decision to retain “sub-
caps” on the number of AM and number of FM stations an entity
could own in a local market .141
In particular, the Third Circuit found that the Commission failed to provide a
justification for basing its bright line numerical benchmark on the use of a Diversity
Index based on the assumption of five equal-sized competitors, rather than on actual
market shares.142
135 Prometheus, 373 F.3d at 423-426.
136 Ibid., at 426-427.
137 Ibid., at 427-428.
138 Ibid., at 429-430.
139 Ibid., at 431-432.
140 Ibid., at 432-435.
141 Id., at 434-435.
142 Id., at 432.

CRS-35
Since the Third Circuit had upheld the FCC’s findings as they applied to the
methodology underlying the revised local radio ownership rules, the FCC filed a
narrowly focused petition for panel rehearing, asking the Third Circuit to reconsider
its extension of the stay of the revised Local Radio Multiple Ownership rule, arguing
that the “stay prevents the Commission from implementing regulatory changes that
this Court has upheld as a reasonable exercise of the Commission’s public interest
authority.”143 The Third Circuit approved a partial lifting of the stay:
Inasmuch as we held in our Opinion and Judgment of June 24, 2004, that certain
changes to the local radio ownership rule proposed by the Federal
Communications Commission (the “Commission”) in its Report and Order and
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 18 F.C.C.R. 13,620 (2003) — specifically,
using Arbitron Metro markets to define local markets, including noncommercial
stations in determining the size of a market, attributing stations whose
advertising is brokered under a Joint Sales Agreement to a brokering station’s
permissible ownership totals, and imposing a transfer restriction (collectively, the
“Approved Changes”) — are constitutional and/or consistent with the
Administrative Procedure Act, 5 U.S.C. Section 706(2), and Section 202(h)
of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, the foregoing motion by the
Commission is granted to the extent that it requests a partial lifting of the
stay to allow the Approved Changes to go into effect. All other aspects of
the Commission’s motion, including matters pertaining to numerical limits
on local radio ownership and AM “subcap” are hereby denied.144
The Third Circuit was silent on the FCC’s elimination of its policy to “flag” and
conduct further competitive review to those radio station transactions that would
result in one entity controlling 50% or more of the radio advertising revenues in the
relevant Arbitron radio market or two entities controlling 70% or more of such
advertising revenues. The Commission no longer flags those transactions.
Cross-Media Limits: Newspaper-Broadcast and Television-
Radio

Current Status.
As a result of the Third Circuit’s Prometheus decision remanding and extending
its stay of the Cross-Media rule that the FCC adopted on June 2, 2003, the
Newspaper-Broadcast Cross Ownership rule and the Television-Radio Cross
Ownership rule that were in force on June 2, 2003 remain in place.
! Newspaper-Broadcast Cross Ownership: common ownership of
a full-service broadcast station and a daily newspaper is prohibited
when the broadcast station’s service contour encompasses the
newspaper’s city of publication. When it adopted the rule in 1975,
the Commission not only prohibited future newspaper-broadcast
143 Prometheus Radio Project v. Federal Communications Commission, Petition of the FCC
and the United States for Panel Rehearing, August 6, 2004.
144 USCA3 Docket Sheet for 03-3388, Prometheus Radio v. FCC, 9/3/04.

CRS-36
combinations, but also required existing combinations in highly
concentrated markets to divest holdings to come into compliance
within five years. The Commission grandfathered combinations in
less concentrated markets, so long as the parties to the combination
remained the same. The Commission adopted a policy of waiving
the rule, for existing or future combinations, if (1) a combination
could not sell a station; (2) a combination could not sell a station
except at an artificially depressed price; (3) separate ownership and
operation of a newspaper and a station could not be supported in a
locality; or (4) for whatever reason, the purposes of the rule would
be disserved.145
! Television-Radio Cross Ownership: An entity may own up to 2
television stations (provided it is permitted under the Local
Television Multiple Ownership rule) and up to 6 radio stations
(provided it is permitted under the Local Radio Multiple Ownership
rule) in a market where at least 20 independently owned media
voices would remain post-merger. Where entities may own a
combination of 2 television stations and 6 radio stations, the rule
allows an entity alternatively to own 1 television station and 7 radio
stations. An entity may own up to 2 television stations (as permitted
under the Local Television Multiple Ownership rule) and up to 4
radio stations (as permitted under the Local Radio Multiple
Ownership rule) in markets where, post-merger, at least 10
independently owned media voices would remain. A combination
of 1 television station and 1 radio station is allowed regardless of the
number of voices remaining in the market.146
On November 13, 2007, FCC chairman Martin announced that he proposes to
modify the newspaper-broadcast cross-ownership rule,147 to make it presumptively
in the public interest, in the 20 largest local markets (DMAs), for a major daily
newspaper to own a single television or radio station, so long as the television station
is not among the four highest-rated stations in the market and after the transaction
there are at least eight independently owned and operating major media voices. In
all other situations, any newspaper-broadcast cross-ownership would be
presumptively not in the public interest.
145 Amendment of Sections 73.34, 73.240,and 73.636 of the Commission’s Rules Relating to
Multiple Ownership of Standard, FM, and Television Broadcast Stations
, Docket No.
18110, Second Report and Order, 50 FCC 2d at 1085.
146 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(c) as it existed prior to the FCC’s June 2, 2003 Order. For this rule,
media “voices” include independently owned and operating full-power broadcast
television stations, broadcast radio stations, English-language newspapers (published
at least four times a week), one cable system located in the market under scrutiny,
plus any independently owned out-of-market broadcast radio stations with a
minimum share as reported by Arbitron.
147 “Chairman Kevin J. Martin Proposes Revision to the Newspaper/Broadcast Cross-
Ownership Rule,” FCC News Release, November 13, 2007, available at [http://hraunfoss.
fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DOC-278113A1.pdf], viewed on November 19, 2007.

CRS-37
In any situation, the Commission would be required to make a public interest
finding and, in so doing, consider, among other factors: whether the cross-ownership
will increase the amount of local news disseminated through the affected media
outlets in the combination; whether each affected media outlet in the combination
will exercise its own independent news judgment; the level of concentration in the
DMA; and the financial condition of the newspaper, and if the newspaper is in
distress, the owner’s commitment to invest significantly in newsroom operations.
Thus, under the proposed rule, a newspaper-broadcast combination in a top 20
market could be rejected by the Commission and a newspaper-broadcast combination
in a smaller market could be approved. Commissioners Copps and Adelstein issued
a joint statement criticizing and opposing Chairman Martin’s proposal,148 claiming
that the “proposal could repeal the ban in every market in America, not just the top
twenty.”
In the interim, as explained in the Overview section above, the Commission
continues to consider waiver requests from media companies that wish to do
transactions that do not meet the rules currently in place149 and to make
determinations on requests for the extension of temporary waivers that have expired.
Recent History.
The newspaper-broadcast cross ownership ban has been in place since 1975.
In 1970, the Commission restricted the combined ownership of radio and television
stations in local markets.150 In 1989 the Commission adopted a liberalized waiver
policy for stations in the top 25 markets, and Section 202(d) of the 1996
Telecommunications Act instructed the Commission to extended its liberalized
waiver policy to the top 50 markets. In 1999, the Commission modified the
television-radio cross ownership rule to its current form.151
In its June 2, 2003 Order, the FCC replaced its rules prohibiting newspaper-
broadcast cross ownership and limiting television-radio cross ownership within a
market with a single rule on cross media limits:152
148 “Joint Statement by Commissioners Copps and Adelstein on Chairman Martin’s Cross-
Ownership Proposal,” FCC News Release, November 13, 2007, available at [http://hraun
foss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DOC-278142A1.pdf], viewed on November 19,
2007.
149 See, for example, Brigitte Greenberg and Tania Panczyk-Collins, “Ferree Sees Issues
That Could Interest the Supreme Court,” Communications Daily, July 1, 2004, at pp. 1-4.
150 Amendment of Section 73.35, 73.340, and 73.630 of the Commission’s Rule Relating to
Multiple Ownership of Standard, FM, and Television Broadcast Stations
, 22 F.C.C.2d at
306 ff.
151 Report and Order at ¶¶ 372-373.
152 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(c), replacing the old 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(c) and 47 C.F.R. 73.3555(d).

CRS-38
! In markets with three or fewer television stations, no cross
ownership is permitted among television, radio, and newspapers.153
! In markets with between four and eight television stations,
combinations are limited to one of the following:
! One daily newspaper, one television station, and up to half of
the radio station limit under the local radio ownership rule for
that market (for example, if the radio limit in the market is six,
the company can only own three); OR
! One daily newspaper, and up to the radio station limit under
the Local Radio Multiple Ownership rule for that market, but
no television stations; OR
! Two television stations (if permissible under the Local
Television Multiple Ownership rule) and up to the radio
station limit under the Local Radio Multiple Ownership rule
for that market, but no daily newspapers.
! In markets with nine or more television stations, the FCC eliminated
the newspaper-broadcast cross ownership ban and the television-
radio cross ownership ban.
The Commission determined that neither the newspaper-broadcast prohibition
nor the television-radio cross ownership limitations could be justified for large
markets in light of the abundance of sources that citizens rely on for news.154 It also
found that the old rules did not promote competition because radio, television, and
newspapers generally compete in different economic markets.155 Moreover, the FCC
found that greater participation by newspaper publishers in the television and radio
business would improve the quality and quantity of news available to the public.156
The Commission therefore replaced the old rules with the new cross media
limits intended to protect viewpoint diversity by ensuring that no company, or group
of companies, can control an inordinate share of media outlets in a local market. The
Commission developed a Diversity Index to measure the availability of key media
outlets in markets of various sizes. It concluded that there were three tiers of markets
in terms of “viewpoint diversity” concentration, each warranting different regulatory
treatment:157
153 A company may obtain a waiver of this ban if it can show that the television station does
not serve the area served by the cross-owned property.
154 Report and Order at ¶ 365.
155 Ibid., at ¶ 332.
156 Ibid., at ¶ 342.
157 Ibid., at ¶ 443 ff.

CRS-39
! In the tier of smallest markets (three or fewer television stations), the
FCC found that key outlets were sufficiently limited that any cross
ownership among the three leading outlets for local news —
broadcast television, radio, and newspapers — would harm diversity
viewpoint.
! In the medium-sized tier (four to eight television stations), markets
were found to be less concentrated today than in the smallest
markets and thus certain media outlet combinations could safely
occur without harming viewpoint diversity. Certain other
combinations would threaten viewpoint diversity and are thus
prohibited.
! In the largest tier of markets (nine or more television stations), the
FCC concluded that the large number of media outlets, in
combination with ownership limits for local television and radio,
were more than sufficient to protect viewpoint diversity.
The arguments of proponents of retaining the old rules included
! any cross ownership reduces the number of independent voices in
the community, especially in small markets with only a small
number of voices;
! the merged entities, facing less competition for local news service
and in the name of cost savings, will reduce the total amount of
resources going to produce local news in the community;
! satellite and Internet voices are not local and therefore do not
contribute to local diversity;
! newspaper-broadcast or television-radio cross ownership will give
the merged company a competitive advantage in the advertising
market over its non-cross owned competitors.
Commissioner Adelstein stated that he could have supported modification of the
cross ownership rules if the new rule had employed a diversity index applied on a
case-by-case basis by measuring the actual diversity impact of individual media
voices in the market under scrutiny.158 But the Commission majority rejected such
case-by-case merger review because it would add uncertainty in the market and
would impose an administrative burden on the Commission.
These cross ownership rules represent a situation where economic and diversity
goals can be in strong conflict. On one hand, it is in small markets, where resources
are limited, that individual broadcasters are most likely to lack the wherewithal to
158 “Statement of Commissioner Jonathan S. Adelstein Dissenting,” FCC News Release,
June 2, 2003, available at [http://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DOC-
235047A8.pdf], viewed on November 20, 2007.

CRS-40
produce local news programming on their own, so that cross ownership might allow
for a broadcast news voice that would not otherwise exist. On the other hand, it is
exactly in these small markets that there are very few voices to begin with, so that
cross ownership might reduce what little diversity already exists.
Many aspects of the FCC’s 2003 Cross Media Ownership rule were appealed,
and while the Third Circuit upheld the conceptual basis for the rule, it remanded and
extended the stay of the rule because of it found the Commission did not provide
reasoned analysis to support the specific cross media limits that it chose.
Specifically, in its Prometheus decision, the Third Circuit found that:
! the Commission’s decision not to retain a ban on newspaper/
broadcast cross ownership is justified;159 and
! the Commission’s decision to retain some limits on common
ownership of different-type media outlets was constitutional and in
the public interest;160 but
! the Commission did not provide reasoned analysis to support the
specific cross media limit it chose.161
As explained earlier, the Third Circuit identified three problems with the
methodology underlying the Commission’s bright line rules: (1) the inconsistent
treatment of cable television and the Internet; (2) the assignment of equal weight to
all media outlets within a media category rather than actual market shares; and (3)
allowing some combinations where the increases in Diversity Index scores were
generally higher than for other combinations that were not allowed.
Transferability of Ownership
If the stay is lifted and the FCC’s new radio ownership rules are implemented,
it may result in a number of situations where current ownership arrangements exceed
ownership limits. The FCC grandfathered owners of those clusters, but generally
prohibited the sale of such above-cap clusters. The FCC made a limited exception
to permit sales of grandfathered combinations to small businesses as defined in the
Report and Order. In taking this action, the FCC sought to respect the reasonable
expectations of parties that lawfully purchased groups of local radio stations that
today, through redefined markets, now exceed the applicable caps. The FCC also
attempted to promote competition by permitting station owners to retain any above-
cap local radio stations but not transfer them intact unless there is a compelling
public policy justification to do so. The FCC found two such justifications: (1)
avoiding undue hardships to cluster owners that are small businesses; and (2)
promoting the entry into the broadcasting business by small businesses, many of
which are minority- or female-owned.
159 Prometheus, 373 F.3d at 398-400.
160 Ibid., at 400-402.
161 Ibid., at 402-405.

CRS-41
These transfer restrictions were appealed both by parties that claimed the
transfer restrictions were an unconstitutional holding and by parties that claimed the
transfers should have been restricted to socially and economically disadvantaged
businesses rather than to small businesses. The National Association of Black
Owned Broadcasters and other critics of this Commission rule complained that the
rule will not foster minority or female ownership because (1) the large radio groups
are unlikely to sell their clusters as long as they receive grandfathered rights, and (2)
even if these clusters were placed on sale, they are likely to command such a high
price that minority- or female-owned small businesses are unlikely to be able to
obtain the financing needed to make the acquisitions.
The Third Circuit upheld the transfer restriction set by the FCC as “in the public
interest,”162 and in rehearing explicitly allowed the FCC to implement the transfer
restriction.163
Legislative Policy Issues
To date, S. 2332 is the only bill directly addressing the FCC’s media ownership
rules that has been introduced in the 110th Congress. It would modify Section 202
of the 1996 Telecommunications Act by adding three provisions that would (1)
require the FCC to publish in the Federal Register any proposal to modify, revise, or
amend any of its regulations related to broadcast ownership at least 90 days before
voting to add the proposal, providing at least 60 days for public comment and 30 days
for reply comments; (2) require the FCC to initiate, conduct, and complete a separate
rulemaking proceeding to promote the broadcast of local programming and content
by broadcasters, including radio and television broadcast stations, and newspapers,
before voting on any change in the broadcast and newspaper ownership rules, and
require the FCC to conduct a study to determine the overall impact of television
station duopolies and newspaper-broadcast cross-ownership on the quantity and
quality of local news, public affairs, local news media jobs, and local cultural
programming at the market level; and (3) establish an independent Panel on Women
and Minority Ownership of Broadcast Media to make recommendations to the FCC
for specific Commission rules to increase the representation of women and minorities
in the ownership of broadcast media, and require the FCC to conduct a full and
accurate census of the race and gender of individuals holding a controlling interest
in broadcast station licenses, provide the results of the census to the Panel, study the
impact of media market concentration on the representation of women and minorities
in the ownership of broadcast media, and act on the Panel’s recommendations before
voting on any changes in its broadcast and newspaper ownership rules.
The FCC’s media ownership rules are intended to foster the three major policy
goals of competition, diversity, and localism. Since there are other public policies
also intended to foster competition, diversity, and localism — for example, utilizing
the spectrum more efficiently to create additional voices, fostering the development
162 Ibid., at 426-428.
163 USCA3 Docket Sheet for 03-3388, Prometheus Radio v. FCC, September 3, 2004.

CRS-42
and deployment of new technologies that may provide additional voices, maintaining
public interest obligations on existing broadcast licensees to foster localism and
diversity of voices, tax deferrals and credits to encourage diversified ownership —
one part of the debate has been how the ownership rules and these other policies can
work to reinforce, supplement, or substitute for one another.
Two bills introduced in the 110th Congress would amend the Internal Revenue
Code of 1986 with the intention of fostering diversity of voices by promoting the
diversity of ownership of telecommunications businesses. H.R. 600, introduced by
Representative Rush, would, subject to specific limitations, defer or exclude from
capital gains taxation certain sales of telecommunications businesses to economically
and socially disadvantaged businesses and would create a tax credit for certain
telecommunications businesses that locate in designated empowerment zones. H.R.
3003, introduced by Representative Rangel, would defer from capital gains taxation
certain sales of broadcast stations to a person with a qualified interest in 10 or fewer
broadcast stations and would create a loan guarantee program for qualified businesses
to encourage diversity of ownership of telecommunications businesses.
Policies aiming to utilize the spectrum more efficiently in order to create
additional voices also can foster the policy goals of diversity, localism, and
competition, and perhaps reduce the need for ownership limits. For example, in
January 2000, the FCC, recognizing that there was broadcast spectrum going unused
that could provide locally-oriented programming, created a new low power FM radio
service, limited to noncommercial operations and to maximum radiated power of 100
watts.164 In response to complaints from existing broadcasters that the new low
power FM stations might create harmful radio interference to the reception of
existing FM stations, in December 2000 Congress enacted Section 632 of the
FY2001 District of Columbia Appropriations Act,165 which required the FCC to
impose third-adjacent channel minimum distance separation requirements on low
power FM stations,166 and also to conduct independent field tests and an experimental
program to determine whether the elimination of these third-adjacent channel
protection requirements would result in low power FM stations causing harmful
interference to existing FM stations operating on third-adjacent channels.167 The
FCC hired the Mitre Corporation to perform the study. Mitre delivered its final
report to the FCC on June 2, 2003, with the finding that third adjacent locations
without distance separation requirements would not create harmful interference. The
FCC sought comment on the Mitre report. The National Association of Broadcasters
(NAB) filed comments critical of the report and its findings. Based on the Mitre
study and all the comments filed in the proceeding, the FCC reported back to
164 Rules were adopted on January 20, 2000 and appeared in the Federal Register on
February 15, 2000.
165 P.L. 106-55, § 632, 114 Stat. 2762, 2762A-111 (2000).
166 If an existing radio station is at 97.1 on the dial, then the first adjacent stations are at
96.9 and 97.3, the second adjacent stations are at 96.7 and 97.5, and the third adjacent
stations are at 96.5 and 97.7.
167 All radio station signals create some level of interference, but in most situations that
interference is so limited that it does not affect reception.

CRS-43
Congress on February 19, 2004, with the recommendation that Congress eliminate
the existing third-adjacent minimum distance separation requirements between low
power FM and existing full-service FM stations and FM translators and boosters.
This would allow many additional low power FM stations to be constructed.
Senators Cantwell and McCain have introduced S. 1675, and Representatives Doyle
and Terry have introduced H.R. 2802, which would implement the recommendations
of the FCC report by repealing Sec. 632 of the FY2001 District of Columbia
Appropriations Act, instructing the FCC to modify its rules to eliminate the third-
adjacent minimum distance separation requirements between low power FM stations
and full-service FM stations, clarifying that the FCC should retain its rules that
provide third-adjacent channel protection for full-power non-commercial FM stations
that broadcast radio reading services via a subcarrier frequency from a potential low-
power FM station, and requiring the FCC, when licensing FM translator stations, to
guarantee that licenses are available to both FM translator stations and low power FM
stations and that such decisions are made based on the needs of the local community.
The NAB claims that satellite radio service (formally called digital audio radio
service or DARS), although created by the FCC to provide national radio
programming, threatens the provision of local programming on traditional broadcast
radio stations because the national licensees have begun to offer local weather reports
and other informational programming that compete head-on with the programming
of local radio broadcasters. The two satellite radio providers (XM and Sirius) claim
their local programming is limited in scope and meets the needs of mobile listeners
who seek weather reports and other information as they travel from one location to
another. Representative Gene Green has introduced H.R. 983, which instructs the
FCC to revise its regulations to prohibit satellite radio providers from providing
services that are locally differentiated or that result in programming being delivered
to consumers in one geographic market that is different from the programming that
is delivered to consumers in any other geographic market and to restrict satellite radio
repeaters to simultaneously retransmitting the programming transmitted by satellite
directly to satellite radio subscribers’ receivers, prohibiting the use of those repeaters
to distribute any information not also transmitted to all subscribers’ receivers. The
bill also instructs the FCC to complete a rulemaking proceeding within 270 days to
determine whether satellite radio licensees should be permitted to provide locally
oriented services on nationally distributed channels, taking into account (1) the
impact of locally oriented satellite radio services on the viability of local radio
broadcast stations and their ability to provide news and other services to the public;
(2) the ability of satellite radio licensees to afford listeners the same emergency and
other information as is afforded listeners of other local broadcast radio stations; (3)
whether satellite radio licensees committed to providing only national services in
order to obtain authorization for their services; and (4) whether the same level and
quality of emergency communications services could be provided to consumers by
satellite radio licensees as by local broadcast radio stations.
On February 19, 2007, XM and Sirius announced their plan to merge.
Subsequently, both the House Judiciary Committee antitrust task force and the
telecommunications Subcommittee of the House Energy and Commerce Committee
held hearings to address the radio market in the United States, with a focus on the
potential impact of an XM-Sirius merger. In these hearings, representatives of the
NAB testified that traditional local broadcast radio is not a sufficiently close

CRS-44
substitute to satellite radio to be able to constrain prices for satellite radio and
therefore should not be considered to be in the same market.168 They therefore
opposed the merger as anticompetitive. In contrast, in its various filings in the FCC’s
media ownership rules, the NAB has argued that the ownership restrictions should
be eased or eliminated because of widespread intermodal competition for broadcast
radio.
The transition to digital television will allow for more efficient utilization of the
spectrum, providing additional spectrum for public safety and wireless broadband
and also allowing broadcasters to use digital technology to offer more programming
than they can using analog technology. As valuable as the UHF band is for public
safety and wireless purposes, it is inferior to the VHF band for the analog
transmission of broadcast signals. After the digital transition, the current
technological inferiority of UHF to VHF will no longer be an issue. Ownership of a
UHF station will not bring with it more limited audience reach. The rationale for
treating UHF stations differently from VHF stations will disappear. In its June 2,
2004 Order, the FCC adopted a rule to end the UHF discount for stations owned by
the four major television networks — but not for other stations — when the transition
to digital television has been completed. When that transition is completed (and
likely long before its completion), the current UHF and VHF licensees will have the
ability to multicast as many as six channels of programming over their licensed
spectrum. This will increase the amount and perhaps diversity of programming
available, though it may not result in an increase in the diversity of voices or
localism. Congress may want to review the UHF discount — and its impact on the
goals of competition, diversity, and localism — in light of the digital transition and
in light of some of the policies it develops for that transition. For example, Congress
might be concerned that a network comprised entirely of UHF stations offering five
channels of broadcast programming could reach 78% of all U.S. television
households.
Under sections 614(b)(3)(A) and 615(g)(1) of the Communications Act,169 cable
operators are required to carry the primary signals of qualified local commercial and
noncommercial television stations. The FCC has ruled that when a broadcaster
transmits multiple video streams, cable systems are required to carry only the
broadcaster’s primary signal, not all the signals.170 Broadcasters claim that this ruling
will undermine their ability to use multicasting to offer additional local news and
weather programming — citing, in particular, the potentially negative impact on a
project by ABC affiliates to use a secondary signal to offer ABC News Now, a mix
of international, national, and local news, and on NBC Weather Plus, NBC-
168 Testimony of David Rehr, president of the National Association of Broadcasters, before
the Antitrust Task Force of the House Judiciary Committee, February 28, 2007, and
Testimony of Peter Smythe, president and CEO of Greater Media Inc., on behalf of Greater
Media and the National Association of Broadcasters, before the Telecommunications
Subcommittee of the House Energy and Commerce Committee, March 7, 2007.
169 47 U.S.C. 534, 535.
170 In the Matter of Carriage of Digital Television Broadcast Signals: Amendments to Part
76 of the Commission’s Rules
, CS Docket No. 98-120, Second Report and Order and First
Order on Reconsideration, adopted February 10, 2005 and released February 23, 2005, at
¶ 3.

CRS-45
Universal’s new digital 24-hour national and local weather network if cable systems
are not required to carry those signals.171 But in its September 8, 2005 Report to
Congress on Retransmission Consent and Exclusivity Rules, the FCC found that
“since the Commission’s decision to deny broadcasters the ability to assert dual and
multicast must-carry, broadcasters have begun using their retransmission consent
negotiations to negotiate carriage of their digital signals.”172
Some observers have suggested that a more nuanced rule on multicast must
carry could help to serve the goals of diversity and localism, and reduce the need for
strict ownership limits. For example, policy makers might want to consider the pros
and cons of granting multiple must carry rights to those broadcasters whose coverage
area overlaps multiple states (a very frequent occurrence since state lines often follow
rivers that have large population centers on either side of the river) for each of the
multicast channels that provides state-jurisdiction-specific local coverage. That is,
an argument in favor of multicast must carry might be that, with associated local
programming requirements, it could foster localism.173 On the other hand, if a local
programming requirement is imposed on broadcasters that choose to use digital
technology to multicast, this might artificially incent broadcasters to choose to use
their spectrum for HDTV or other purposes, rather than multicasting, just to avoid
the burden of providing additional local programming.
More broadly, the FCC in 2004 adopted a Notice of Inquiry on broadcast
localism,174 seeking information on broadcasters’ responsibilities with respect to
communication with their local communities, the nature and amount of community-
responsive programming, political programming, underserved audiences, disaster
warnings, network-affiliation rules, payola and sponsorship identification, voice-
tracking, national playlists, and license renewals. S. 2332 instructs the FCC to
initiate and complete a proceeding to foster localism before adopting new media
ownership rules. It is possible that more stringent or more well-defined localism
requirements on all broadcasters might reduce concerns about the impact of media
ownership consolidation on local programming.
Some observers have been concerned with the impact of media ownership
consolidation on control of programming — and hence on the diversity of voices.
When television was dominated by three networks, the FCC had financial
syndication and network program ownership rules that restricted the ownership stake
that networks could have in the programming they carried. These rules were
eliminated in the 1990s, after which the networks integrated backward into program
171 See Communications Daily, February 4, 2005, at p. 4.
172 “Retransmission Consent and Exclusivity Rules: Report to Congress Pursuant to Section
208 of the Satellite Home Viewer Extension and Reauthorization Act of 2004,” Federal
Communications Commission, September 8, 2005, at p. 25, para. 45.
173 But Supreme Court rulings relating to First Amendment constraints on government
regulation of broadcast stations have set heightened scrutiny when the speech to be
regulated is content-based rather than content-neutral (Turner Broadcasting Sys. v. F.C.C.,
512 U.S. 622 (1994) at 642-3).
174 In the Matter of Broadcast Localism, Notice of Inquiry, MB. Docket No. 04-233, adopted
on June 7, 2004, released on July 1, 2004.

CRS-46
production. Some independent program producers allege that, as a result of that
vertical integration, they are not able to control the programming they produce, with
the consequence that creative programming has been discouraged. For example, they
claim if they produce a program for a network and then the network decides not to
air the programming, the independent producer is not allowed to try to sell that
programming to another network. The large media conglomerates deny that their
vertical reach has any harmful effect on consumers or competition.

Even if the FCC were to meet the requirements of the Third Circuit by
constructing broadcast media ownership limits based on the local market shares of
the broadcasters and other media outlets, there might be concern that the simple
market shares do not reflect actual economic market power or diversity market
power. For example, if a locally-owned stand-alone television station has the same
ratings in a local market as another local station that is owned and operated by a
media giant that also owns multiple cable networks that are shown on the cable and
satellite systems serving that local market, some observers would argue that the two
local stations should not be accorded the same diversity market share. This
highlights the conflict between those who argue for case-by-case analysis of all
proposed media ownership transactions in order to have an in-depth picture of the
impact on the specific market affected and those who argue that as soon as one gets
away from bright line tests and into case-by-case analysis, regulatory uncertainty
becomes so great that all merger activity — including mergers that are clearly
beneficial to consumers — may be discouraged.
More broadly, this raises the issue of whether and how Congress might craft
legislation focused on media market structure beyond the basically horizontal media
ownership rules now in effect.
In congressional hearings, a number of policies besides ownership limits have
been identified that affect the goals of media competition, diversity, and localism.175
The discussions in those hearings suggested that the ownership rules represented just
a subset of those existing policies that were implemented before the widespread
occurrence of media consolidation and vertical integration and might merit review.
For example, small cable companies and consumer groups claimed that the media
conglomerates that own both broadcast television stations and multiple cable
networks have taken advantage of their retransmission consent rights to require cable
companies to carry their full suite of cable networks in order to have access to their
broadcast signals.176 This may restrict diversity of voices. The small cable operators
175 See, for example, prepared testimony and transcripts from the Telecommunications and
the Internet Subcommittee of the House Energy and Commerce Committee hearing on
Competition and Consumer Choice in the MVPD Marketplace — Including an Examination
of Proposals to Expand Consumer Choice, such as a la Carte and Theme-Tiered Offerings,
July 14, 2004.
176 See the testimony of Bennett Hooks, chief executive officer, Buford Media Group,
before the Telecommunications and the Internet Subcommittee of the House energy and
Commerce Committee hearing on Competition and Consumer Choice in the MVPD
Marketplace — Including Examination of Proposals to Expand Consumer Choice, such as
a la Carte and Theme-Tiered Offerings, July 14, 2004. See, also, American Cable
(continued...)

CRS-47
called on Congress to revise the retransmission consent requirement to prohibit large
integrated broadcasters from imposing such tying arrangements.177 The media giants
responded that they do make their broadcast signals available for rebroadcast
transmission at a stand-alone price and, moreover, it was the cable companies that
originally preferred to offer cable carriage of the conglomerates’ cable networks
rather than cash to obtain retransmission consent.178 In the Satellite Home Viewer
Extension and Reauthorization Act, Congress instructed the FCC to complete an
inquiry and report to Congress by September 8, 2005 regarding the impact of the
current retransmission consent rules (and also the current network non-duplication,
syndicated exclusivity, and sports blackout rules) on competition in the multi-channel
television market, including the ability of rural cable operators to compete with
satellite television providers in the provision of digital television signals to
consumers.179 The FCC submitted a report that did “not recommend any changes at
this time to the statutory provisions relating to Commission rules under consideration
in this Report.”180
This legislative policy discussion has at least implicitly assumed that the
underlying Supreme Court rationale for government regulation of broadcasting —
spectrum scarcity — will remain. As indicated earlier, several broadcasting
companies, in seeking to appeal the Prometheus decision at the Supreme Court,
challenge that rationale. They claim that, even if spectrum is scarce, such scarcity
does not restrict the diversity of voices available or the ability of non-licensees to
present their views on an alternative medium. On June 13, 2005, the Supreme Court
declined to consider the appeal. It is possible that broadcasters or other parties
currently subject to broadcast regulation will use that same argument when
challenging other rules. If their argument were to prevail, Congress might have to
reconsider the legal basis for many of its statutory policies and rules, including those
related to media ownership.
crsphpgw
176 (...continued)
Association Petition for Inquiry into Retransmission Consent Practices, filed with Federal
Communications Commission on October 1, 2002 (ACA Petition).
177 See testimony of James M. Gleason, chairman of the American Cable Association and
president and chief operating officer of CableDirect, before the Senate Commerce, Science,
and Transportation Committee hearing on Media Ownership and Transportation, May 6,
2003.
178 See, for example, the testimony of Ben Pyne, executive vice president of Disney and
ESPN Affiliate Sales and Marketing, before the Subcommittee on Telecommunications and
the Internet of the House Energy and Commerce Committee hearing on Competition and
Consumer Choice in the MVPD Marketplace — Including an Examination of Proposals to
Expand Consumer Choice, such as a la Carte and Theme-Tiered Offerings, July 14, 2004.
179 Satellite Home Viewer Extension and Reauthorization Act, passed as Title IX of the
FY2005 Consolidated Appropriations Act (H.R. 4818, P.L. 108-447), § 208.
180 “Retransmission Consent and Exclusivity Rules: Report to Congress Pursuant to Section
208 of the Satellite Home Viewer Extension and Reauthorization Act of 2004,” Federal
Communications Commission, September 8, 2005, at p. 41, para. 86. For more detailed
discussions of the issues surrounding retransmission consent, see CRS Report RL34028,
Retransmission Consent and Other Federal Rules Affecting Programmer-Distributor
Negotiations: Issues for Congress
, by Charles B. Goldfarb.