

Order Code RL33578
Energy Tax Policy:
History and Current Issues
Updated August 7, 2007
Salvatore Lazzari
Specialist in Public Finance
Resources, Science, and Industry Division
Energy Tax Policy: History and Current Issues
Summary
Historically, U.S. federal energy tax policy promoted the supply of oil and gas.
However, the 1970s witnessed (1) a significant cutback in the oil and gas industry’s
tax preferences, (2) the imposition of new excise taxes on oil, and (3) the
introduction of numerous tax preferences for energy conservation, the development
of alternative fuels, and the commercialization of the technologies for producing
these fuels (renewables such as solar, wind, and biomass, and nonconventional fossil
fuels such as shale oil and coalbed methane).
The Reagan Administration, using a free-market approach, advocated repeal of
the windfall profit tax on oil and the repeal or phase-out of most energy tax
preferences — for oil and gas, as well as alternative fuels. Due to the combined
effects of the Economic Recovery Tax Act and the energy tax subsidies that had not
been repealed, which together created negative effective tax rates in some cases, the
actual energy tax policy differed from the stated policy. The George H. W. Bush and
Bill Clinton years witnessed a return to a much more activist energy tax policy, with
an emphasis on energy conservation and alternative fuels. While the original aim
was to reduce demand for imported oil, energy tax policy was also increasingly
viewed as a tool for achieving environmental and fiscal objectives. The Clinton
Administration’s energy tax policy emphasized the environmental benefits of
reducing greenhouse gases and global climate change, but it will also be remembered
for its failed proposal to enact a broadly based energy tax on Btus (British thermal
units) and its 1993 across-the-board increase in motor fuels taxes of 4.3¢/gallon.
The Working Families Tax Relief Act of 2004 (P.L. 108-311) and the American
Jobs Creation Act of 2004 (P.L. 108-357) each contained several energy-related tax
breaks. The George W. Bush Administration has proposed a limited number of
energy tax measures, but the 109th Congress enacted the Energy Policy Act of 2005
(P.L. 109-58) — comprehensive energy legislation that included numerous energy
tax incentives to increase the supply of, and reduce the demand for, fossil fuels and
electricity. Signed by President Bush on August 8, 2005, it provided a net energy tax
cut of $11.5 billion ($14.5 billion gross energy tax cuts, less $3 billion of energy tax
increases). The act included tax incentives for energy efficiency in residential and
commercial buildings and for more energy efficient vehicles, and tax incentives for
several types of alternative and renewable resources, such as solar and geothermal.
The Tax Relief and Health Care Act of 2006 (P.L. 109-432), enacted in December
2006, provided for one-year extensions of these provisions.
The current energy tax structure is dominated by tax incentives for alternative
and renewable fuels supply relative to energy from conventional fossil fuels, and this
posture was accentuated by the tax incentives for renewables under the Energy Policy
Act of 2005. The 110th Congress is debating comprehensive energy policy legislation
(H.R. 6) that will likely include energy tax provisions; energy tax bills have been
reported by both the House Ways and Means Committee (H.R. 2776, which was
approved by the House on August 4, 2007) and Senate Finance Committee, which
was not approved by the Senate — the Senate defeated a procedural motion that
would have invoked cloture on the Finance Committee’s $32 billion tax title.
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
Background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
Energy Tax Policy from 1918 to 1970: Promoting Oil and Gas . . . . . . . . . . 2
Energy Tax Policy During the 1970s: Conservation and Alternative Fuels . 3
Energy Tax Policy in the 1980s: The “Free-Market Approach” . . . . . . . . . . 6
Energy Tax Policy After 1988 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
Energy Tax Incentives in Comprehensive Energy Legislation Since 1998 . . . . . . 8
Brief History of Comprehensive Energy Policy Proposals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
Energy Tax Action in the 107th Congress . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
Energy Tax Action in the 108th Congress . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
Energy Action in the 109th Congress . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
The Energy Policy Act of 2005 (P.L. 109-58) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
The Tax Relief and Health Care Act of 2006 (P.L. 109-432) . . . . . . . . . . . 13
Current Posture of Energy Tax Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
Energy Tax Policy Outlook . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
110th Congress . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
The Ways and Means Committee Energy Tax Bill (H.R. 2776) . . . . . . . . . 15
Renewable Production Incentives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
Conservation Incentives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
Tax Increases on the Oil and Gas Industry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
The Senate Finance Committee Energy Tax Bill . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
Likely Effects on Oil and Gas Prices and Oil Import Dependence . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Neutrality of the Corporate Income Tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Proposed Increases in Excise Taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
The Oil Spill Tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
Gasoline Tax Collection Point . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
Proposed New 13% Severance Tax on OCS Oil and Gas . . . . . . . . . . 21
For Additional Reading . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
List of Tables
Table 1. Comparison of Energy Tax Provisions the House, Senate, and
Enacted Versions of H.R. 6 (P.L.109-58): 11-Year Estimated Revenue
Loss by Type of Incentive . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
Table 2. Current Energy Tax Incentives and Taxes: Estimated Revenue
Effects FY2006 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
Energy Tax Policy: History and
Current Issues
Introduction
Energy tax policy involves the use of the government’s main fiscal instruments
— taxes (financial disincentives) and tax subsidies (or incentives) — to alter the
allocation or configuration of energy resources. In theory, energy taxes and subsidies,
like tax policy instruments in general, are intended either to correct a problem or
distortion in the energy markets or to achieve some social, economic (efficiency,
equity, or even macroeconomic), environmental, or fiscal objective. In practice,
however, energy tax policy in the United States is made in a political setting, being
determined by the views and interests of the key players in this setting: politicians,
special interest groups, bureaucrats, and academic scholars. This implies that the
policy does not generally, if ever, adhere to the principles of economic or public
finance theory alone; that more often than not, energy tax policy may compound
existing distortions, rather than correct them.1
The idea of applying tax policy instruments to the energy markets is not new,
but until the 1970s, energy tax policy had been little used, except for the oil and gas
industry. Recurrent energy-related problems since the 1970s — oil embargoes, oil
price and supply shocks, wide petroleum price variations and price spikes, large
geographical price disparities, tight energy supplies, and rising oil import
dependence, as well as increased concern for the environment — have caused
policymakers to look toward energy taxes and subsidies with greater frequency.
Comprehensive energy policy legislation containing numerous tax incentives,
and some tax increases on the oil industry, was signed on August 8, 2005 (P.L. 109-
58). The law, the Energy Policy Act of 2005, contained about $15 billion in energy
tax incentives over 11 years, including numerous tax incentives for the supply of
conventional fuels. However, record oil industry profits, due primarily to high crude
oil and refined oil product prices, and the 2006 mid-term elections, which gave the
control of the Congress to the Democratic Party, has changed the mood of
policymakers. Instead of stimulating the traditional fuels industry — oil, gas, and
electricity from coal — in addition to incentivizing alternative fuels and energy
conservation, the mood now is to take away, or rescind, the 2005 tax incentives and
use the money to further stimulate alternative fuels and energy conservation. A minor
step in this direction was made, on May 17, 2006, when President Bush signed a $70
billion tax reconciliation bill (P.L. 109-222). This bill included a provision that
1 The theory underlying these distortions, and the nature of the distortions, is discussed in
detail in a companion report: CRS Report RL30406, Energy Tax Policy: An Economic
Analysis, by Salvatore Lazzari.
CRS-2
further increased taxes on major integrated oil companies by extending the
depreciation recovery period for geological and geophysical costs from two to five
years (thus taking back some of the benefits enacted under the 2005 law). And
currently, the major tax writing committees in both Houses are considering further,
but more significant, tax increases on the oil and gas industry to fund additional tax
cuts for the alternative fuels and energy conservation industries. These bills are being
considered as part of the debate over new versions of comprehensive energy policy
legislation in the 110th Congress (H.R. 6).
This report discusses the history, current posture, and outlook for federal energy
tax policy. It also discusses current energy tax proposals and major energy tax
provisions enacted in the 109th Congress. (For a general economic analysis of energy
tax policy, see CRS Report RL30406, Energy Tax Policy: An Economic Analysis, by
Salvatore Lazzari.)
Background
The history of federal energy tax policy can be divided into four eras: the oil
and gas period from 1916 to 1970, the energy crisis period of the 1970s, the free-
market era of the Reagan Administration, and the post-Reagan era — including the
period since 1998, which has witnessed a plethora of energy tax proposals to address
recurring energy market problems.
Energy Tax Policy from 1918 to 1970: Promoting Oil and Gas
Historically, federal energy tax policy was focused on increasing domestic oil
and gas reserves and production; there were no tax incentives for energy conservation
or for alternative fuels. Two oil/gas tax code preferences embodied this policy: (1)
expensing of intangible drilling costs (IDCs) and dry hole costs, which was
introduced in 1916, and (2) the percentage depletion allowance, first enacted in 1926
(coal was added in 1932).2
Expensing of IDCs (such as labor costs, material costs, supplies, and repairs
associated with drilling a well) gave oil and gas producers the benefit of fully
deducting from the first year’s income (“writing off”) a significant portion of the
total costs of bringing a well into production, costs that would otherwise (i.e., in
theory and under standard, accepted tax accounting methods) be capitalized (i.e.,
written off during the life of the well as income is earned). For dry holes, which
comprised on average about 80% of all the wells drilled, the costs were also allowed
to be deducted in the year drilled (expensed) and deducted against other types of
income, which led to many tax shelters that benefitted primarily high-income
2 Tax preferences are special tax provisions — such as tax credits, exemptions, exclusions,
deductions, deferrals, or favorable tax rates — that reduce tax rates for the preferred
economic activity and favored taxpayers. Such preferences, also known as tax expenditures
or tax subsidies, generally deviate from a neutral tax system and from generally accepted
economic and accounting principles unless they are targeted to the correction of preexisting
market distortions.
CRS-3
taxpayers. Expensing accelerates tax deductions, defers tax liability, and encourages
oil and gas prospecting, drilling, and the development of reserves.
The oil and gas percentage depletion allowance permitted oil and gas producers
to claim 27.5% of revenue as a deduction for the cost of exhaustion or depletion of
the deposit, allowing deductions in excess of capital investment (i.e, in excess of
adjusted cost depletion) — the economically neutral method of capital recovery for
the extractive industries. Percentage depletion encourages faster mineral
development than cost depletion (the equivalent of depreciation of plants and
equipment).
These and other tax subsidies discussed later (e.g., capital gains treatment of the
sale of successful properties, the special exemption from the passive loss limitation
rules, and special tax credits) reduced marginal effective tax rates in the oil and gas
industries, reduced production costs, and increased investments in locating reserves
(increased exploration). They also led to more profitable production and some
acceleration of oil and gas production (increased rate of extraction), and more rapid
depletion of energy resources than would otherwise occur. Such subsidies tend to
channel resources into these activities that otherwise would be used for oil and gas
activities abroad or for other economic activities in the United States. Relatively low
oil prices encouraged petroleum consumption (as opposed to conservation) and
inhibited the development of alternatives to fossil fuels, such as unconventional fuels
and renewable forms of energy. Oil and gas production increased from 16% of total
U.S. energy production in 1920 to 71.1% of total energy production in 1970 (the peak
year).
Energy Tax Policy During the 1970s: Conservation and
Alternative Fuels
Three developments during the 1970s caused a dramatic shift in the focus of
federal energy tax policy. First, the large revenue losses associated with the oil and
gas tax preferences became increasingly hard to justify in the face of increasing
federal budget deficits — and in view of the longstanding economic arguments
against the special tax treatment for oil and gas, as noted in the above paragraph.
Second, heightened awareness of environmental pollution and concern for
environmental degradation, and the increased importance of distributional issues in
policy formulation (i.e., equity and fairness), lost the domestic oil and gas industry
much political support. Thus, it became more difficult to justify percentage depletion
and other subsidies, largely claimed by wealthy individuals and big vertically
integrated oil companies. More importantly, during the 1970s there were two energy
crises: the oil embargo of 1973 — also known as the first oil shock — and the Iranian
Revolution in 1978-1979, which focused policymakers’ attention on the problems
(alleged “failures”) in the energy markets and how these problems reverberated
throughout the economy, causing stagflation, shortages, productivity problems, rising
import dependence, and other economic and social problems.
These developments caused federal energy tax policy to shift from oil and gas
supply toward energy conservation (reduced energy demand) and alternative energy
sources.
CRS-4
Three broad actions were taken through the tax code to implement the new
energy tax policy during the 1970s. First, the oil industry’s two major tax
preferences — expensing of IDCs and percentage depletion — were significantly
reduced, particularly the percentage depletion allowance, which was eliminated for
the major integrated oil companies and reduced for the remaining producers. Other
oil and gas tax benefits were also cut back during this period. For example, oil- and
gas-fired boilers used in steam generation (e.g., to generate electricity) could no
longer qualify for accelerated depreciation as a result of the Energy Tax Act of 1978
(as discussed below).
The second broad policy action was the imposition of several new excise taxes
penalizing the use of conventional fossil fuels, particularly oil and gas (and later
coal). The Energy Tax Act of 1978 (ETA, P.L. 95-618) created a federal “gas
guzzler” excise tax on the sale of automobiles with relatively low fuel economy
ratings. This tax, which is still in effect, currently ranges from $1,000 for an
automobile rated between 21.5 and 22.5 miles per gallon (mpg) to $7,700 for an
automobile rated at less than 12.5 mpg. Chief among the taxes on oil was the
windfall profit tax (WPT) enacted in 1980 (P.L. 96-223). The WPT imposed an
excise tax of 15% to 70% on the difference between the market price of oil and a
predetermined (adjusted) base price. This tax, which was repealed in 1988, was part
of a political compromise that decontrolled oil prices. (Between 1971 and 1980, oil
prices were controlled under President Nixon’s Economic Stabilization Act of 1970
— the so-called “wage-price freeze.”) (For more detail on the windfall profit tax on
crude oil that was imposed from 1980 until its repeal in 1988, see CRS Report
RL33305, The Windfall Profit Tax on Crude Oil: Implications for Current Energy
Policy, by Salvatore Lazzari.)
Another, but relatively small, excise tax on petroleum was instituted in 1980:
the environmental excise tax on crude oil received at a U.S. refinery. This tax, part
of the Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation, and Liability Act of
1980 (P.L. 96-510), otherwise known as the “Superfund” program, was designed to
charge oil refineries for the cost of releasing any hazardous materials that resulted
from the refining of crude oil. The tax rate was set initially at 0.79¢ ($0.0079) per
barrel and was subsequently raised to 9.70¢ per barrel. This tax expired at the end
of 1995, but legislation has been proposed since then to reinstate it as part of
Superfund reauthorization.
The third broad action taken during the 1970s to implement the new and
refocused energy tax policy was the introduction of numerous tax incentives or
subsidies (e.g., special tax credits, deductions, exclusions) for energy conservation,
the development of alternative fuels (renewable and nonconventional fuels), and the
commercialization of energy efficiency and alternative fuels technologies. Most of
these new tax subsidies were introduced as part of the Energy Tax Act of 1978 and
expanded under the WPT, which also introduced additional new energy tax subsidies.
The following list describes these:
! Residential and Business Energy Tax Credits. The ETA provided
income tax credits for homeowners and businesses that invested in
a variety of energy conservation products (e.g., insulation and other
energy-conserving components) and for solar and wind energy
CRS-5
equipment installed in a principal home or a business. The business
energy tax credits were 10% to 15% of the investment in
conservation or alternative fuels technologies, such as synthetic
fuels, solar, wind, geothermal, and biomass. These tax credits were
also expanded as part of the WPT, but they generally expired (except
for business use of solar and geothermal technologies) as scheduled
either in 1982 or 1985. A 15% investment tax credit for business
use of solar and geothermal energy, which was made permanent, is
all that remains of these tax credits.
! Tax Subsidies for Alcohol Fuels. The ETA also introduced the excise
tax exemption for gasohol, recently at 5.2¢ per gallon out of a
gasoline tax of 18.4¢/gal. Subsequent legislation extended the
exemption and converted it into an immediate tax credit (currently
at 51¢/gallon of ethanol).
! Percentage Depletion for Geothermal. The ETA made geothermal
deposits eligible for the percentage depletion allowance, at the rate
of 22%. Currently the rate is 15%.
! §29 Tax Credit for Unconventional Fuels. The 1980 WPT included
a $3.00 (in 1979 dollars) production tax credit to stimulate the
supply of selected unconventional fuels: oil from shale or tar sands,
gas produced from geo-pressurized brine, Devonian shale, tight
formations, or coalbed methane, gas from biomass, and synthetic
fuels from coal. In current dollars this credit, which is still in effect
for certain types of fuels, was $6.56 per barrel of liquid fuels and
about $1.16 per thousand cubic feet (mcf) of gas in 2004.
! Tax-Exempt Interest on Industrial Development Bonds. The WPT
made facilities for producing fuels from solid waste exempt from
federal taxation of interest on industrial development bonds (IDBs).
This exemption was for the benefit of the development of alcohol
fuels produced from biomass, for solid-waste-to-energy facilities, for
hydroelectric facilities, and for facilities for producing renewable
energy. IDBs, which provide significant benefits to state and local
electric utilities (public power), had become a popular source of
financing for renewable energy projects.
Some of these incentives — for example, the residential energy tax credits —
have since expired, but others remain and still new ones have been introduced, such
as the §45 renewable electricity tax credit, which was introduced in 1992 and
expanded under the American Jobs Creation Act of 2004 (P.L. 108-357). This
approach toward energy tax policy — subsidizing a plethora of different forms of
energy (both conventional and renewable) and providing incentives for diverse
energy conservation (efficiency) technologies in as many sectors as possible — has
been the paradigm followed by policymakers since the 1970s. A significant increase
in nontax interventions in the energy markets — laws and regulations, such as the
Corporate Average Fuel Economy (CAFÉ) standards to reduce transportation fuel
use, and other interventions through the budget and the credit markets — has also
CRS-6
been a significant feature of energy policy since the 1970s. This included some of
the most extensive energy legislation ever enacted.
Energy Tax Policy in the 1980s: The “Free-Market Approach”
The Reagan Administration opposed using the tax law to promote oil and gas
development, energy conservation, or the supply of alternative fuels. The idea was
to have a more neutral and less distortionary energy tax policy, which economic
theory predicts would make energy markets work more efficiently and generate
benefits to the general economy. The Reagan Administration believed that the
responsibility for commercializing conservation and alternative energy technologies
rested with the private sector and that high oil prices — real oil prices (corrected for
inflation) were at historically high levels in 1981 and 1982 — would be ample
encouragement for the development of alternative energy resources. High oil prices
in themselves create conservation incentives and stimulate oil and gas production.
President Reagan’s free-market views were well known prior to his election.
During the 1980 presidential campaign, he proposed repealing the WPT, deregulating
oil and natural gas prices, and minimizing government intervention in the energy
markets. The Reagan Administration’s energy tax policy was professed more
formally in several energy and tax policy studies, including its 1981 National Energy
Policy Plan and the 1983 update to this plan; it culminated in a 1984 Treasury study
on general tax reform, which also proposed fundamental reforms of federal energy
tax policy. In terms of actual legislation, many of the Reagan Administration’s
objectives were realized, although as discussed below there were unintended effects.
In 1982, the business energy tax credits on most types of nonrenewable
technologies — those enacted under the ETA of 1978 — were allowed to expire as
scheduled; other business credits and the residential energy tax credits were allowed
to expire at the end of 1985, also as scheduled. Only the tax credits for business
solar, geothermal, ocean thermal, and biomass technologies were extended. As
mentioned above, today the tax credit for business investment in solar and
geothermal technologies, which has since been reduced to 10%, is all that remains
of these tax credits. A final accomplishment was the repeal of the WPT, but not until
1988, the end of Reagan’s second term. The Reagan Administration’s other energy
tax policy proposals, however, were not adopted. The tax incentives for oil and gas
were not eliminated, although they were pared back as part of the Tax Reform Act
(TRA) of 1986.
Although the Reagan Administration’s objective was to create a free-market
energy policy, significant liberalization of the depreciation system and reduction in
marginal tax rates — both the result of the Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981
(ERTA, P.L. 97-34) — combined with the regular investment tax credit and the
business energy investment tax credits, resulted in negative effective tax rates for
many investments, including alternative energy investments, such as solar and
synthetic fuels. Also, the retention of percentage depletion and expensing of IDCs
(even at the reduced rates) rendered oil and gas investments still favored relative to
investments in general.
CRS-7
Energy Tax Policy After 1988
After the Reagan Administration, several major energy and non-energy laws
were enacted that amended the energy tax laws in several ways, some major:
! Revenue Provisions of the Omnibus Reconciliation Act of 1990.
President George H.W. Bush’s first major tax law included
numerous energy tax incentives: (1) for conservation (and deficit
reduction), the law increased the gasoline tax by 5¢/gallon and
doubled the gas-guzzler tax; (2) for oil and gas, the law introduced
a 10% tax credit for enhanced oil recovery expenditures, liberalized
some of the restrictions on the percentage depletion allowance, and
reduced the impact of the alternative minimum tax on oil and gas
investments; and (3) for alternative fuels, the law expanded the §29
tax credit for unconventional fuels and introduced the tax credit for
small producers of ethanol used as a motor fuel.
! Energy Policy Act of 1992 (P.L. 102-486). This broad energy
measure introduced the §45 tax credit, at 1.5¢ per kilowatt hour, for
electricity generated from wind and “closed-loop” biomass systems.
(Poultry litter was added later.) For new facilities, this tax credit
expired at the end of 2001 and again in 2003 but has been
retroactively extended by recent tax legislation (as discussed below).
In addition, the 1992 law (1) added an income tax deduction for the
costs, up to $2,000, of clean-fuel powered vehicles; (2) liberalized
the alcohol fuels tax exemption; (3) expanded the §29 production tax
credit for nonconventional energy resources; and (4) liberalized the
tax breaks for oil and gas.
! Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1993 (P.L. 103-66).
President Clinton proposed a differential Btu tax on fossil fuels (a
broadly based general tax primarily on oil, gas, and coal based on the
British thermal units of heat output), which was dropped in favor of
a broadly applied 4.3¢/gallon increase in the excise taxes on motor
fuels, with revenues allocated for deficit reduction rather than the
various trust funds.
! Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 (P.L. 105-34). This law included a
variety of excise tax provisions for motor fuels, of which some
involved tax reductions on alternative transportation fuels, and some
involved increases, such as on kerosene, which on balance further
tilted energy tax policy toward alternative fuels.
! Tax Relief and Extension Act. Enacted as Title V of the Ticket to
Work and Work Incentives Improvement Act of 1999 (P.L. 106-
170), it extended and liberalized the 1.5¢/kWh renewable electricity
production tax credit, and renewed the suspension of the net income
limit on the percentage depletion allowance for marginal oil and gas
wells.
CRS-8
As this list suggests, the post-Reagan energy tax policy returned more to the
interventionist course established during the 1970s and primarily was directed at
energy conservation and alternative fuels, mostly for the purpose of reducing oil
import dependence and enhancing energy security. However, there is an
environmental twist to energy tax policy during this period, particularly in the
Clinton years. Fiscal concerns, which for most of that period created a perennial
search for more revenues to reduce budget deficits, have also driven energy tax policy
proposals during the post-Reagan era. This is underscored by proposals, which have
not been enacted, to impose broad-based energy taxes such as the Btu tax or the
carbon tax to mitigate greenhouse gas emissions.
Another interesting feature of the post-Reagan energy tax policy is that while
the primary focus continues to be energy conservation and alternative fuels, no
energy tax legislation has been enacted during this period that does not also include
some, relatively minor, tax relief for the oil and gas industry, either in the form of
new tax incentives or liberalization of existing tax breaks (or both).
Energy Tax Incentives in Comprehensive Energy
Legislation Since 1998
Several negative energy market developments since about 1998, characterized
by some as an “energy crisis,” have led to congressional action on comprehensive
energy proposals, which included numerous energy tax incentives.
Brief History of Comprehensive Energy Policy Proposals
Although the primary rationale for comprehensive energy legislation has
historically been spiking petroleum prices, and to a lesser extent spiking natural gas
and electricity prices, the origin of bills introduced in the late 1990s was the very low
crude oil prices of that period. Domestic crude oil prices reached a low of just over
$10 per barrel in the winter of 1998-1999, among the lowest crude oil prices in
history after correcting for inflation. From 1986 to 1999, oil prices averaged about
$17 per barrel, fluctuating between $12 and $20 per barrel. These low oil prices hurt
oil producers, benefitted oil refiners, and encouraged consumption. They also served
as a disincentive to conservation and investment in energy efficiency technologies
and discouraged production of alternative fuels and renewable technologies. To
address the low oil prices, there were many tax bills in the first session of the 106th
Congress (1999) focused on production tax credits for marginal or stripper wells, but
they also included carryback provisions for net operating losses, and other fossil fuels
supply provisions.
By summer 1999, crude oil prices rose to about $20 per barrel, and peaked at
more than $30 per barrel by summer 2000, causing higher gasoline, diesel, and
heating oil prices. To address the effects of rising crude oil prices, legislative
proposals again focused on production tax credits and other supply incentives. The
rationale was not tax relief for a depressed industry but tax incentives to increase
output, reduce prices, and provide price relief to consumers.
CRS-9
In addition to higher petroleum prices there were forces — some of which were
understood (factors such as environmental regulations and pipeline breaks) and
others that are still are not so clearly understood — that caused the prices of refined
petroleum products to spike. In response, there were proposals in 2000 to either
temporarily reduce or eliminate the federal excise tax on gasoline, diesel, and other
special motor fuels. The proposals aimed to help consumers (including truckers)
cushion the financial effect of the price spikes. The Midwest gasoline price spike in
summer 2000 kept interest in these excise tax moratoria alive and generated interest
in proposals for a windfall profit tax on oil companies, which, by then, were earning
substantial profits from high prices.
Despite numerous bills to address these issues, no major energy tax bill was
enacted in the 106th Congress. However, some minor amendments to energy tax
provisions were enacted as part of nonenergy tax bills. This includes Title V of the
Ticket to Work and Work Incentives Improvement Act of 1999 (P.L. 106-170).
Also, the 106th Congress did enact a package of $500 million in loan guarantees for
small independent oil and gas producers (P.L. 106-51).
Energy Tax Action in the 107th Congress
In early 2001, the 107th Congress faced a combination of fluctuating oil prices,
an electricity crisis in California, and spiking natural gas prices. The gas prices had
increased steadily in 2000 and reached $9 per thousand cubic feet (mcf) at the outset
of the 107th Congress. At one point, spot market prices reached about $30 per mcf,
the energy equivalent of $175 per barrel of oil. The combination of energy problems
had developed into an “energy crisis,” which prompted congressional action on a
comprehensive energy policy bill — the first since 1992 — that included a significant
expansion of energy tax incentives and subsidies and other energy policy measures.
In 2002, the House and Senate approved two distinct versions of an omnibus
energy bill, H.R. 4. While there were substantial differences in the nontax provisions
of the bill, the energy tax measures also differed significantly. The House bill
proposed larger energy tax cuts, with some energy tax increases. It would have
reduced energy taxes by about $36.5 billion over 10 years, in contrast to the Senate
bill, which cut about $18.3 billion over 10 years, including about $5.1 billion in tax
credits over 10 years for two mandates: a renewable energy portfolio standard ($0.3
billion) and a renewable fuel standard ($4.8 billion). The House version emphasized
conventional fuels supply, including capital investment incentives to stimulate
production and distribution of oil, natural gas, and electricity. This focus assumed
that recent energy problems were due mainly to supply and capacity shortages driven
by economic growth and low energy prices. In comparison, the Senate bill would
have provided a much smaller amount of tax incentives for fossil fuels and nuclear
power and somewhat fewer incentives for energy efficiency, but provided more
incentives for alternative and renewable fuels. The conference committee on H.R.
4 could not resolve differences, so the bills were dropped on November 13, 2002.
CRS-10
Energy Tax Action in the 108th Congress
On the House side, on April 3, 2003, the Ways and Means Committee (WMC)
voted 24-12 for an energy tax incentives bill (H.R. 1531) that was incorporated into
H.R. 6 and approved by the House on April 11, 2003, by a vote of 247-175. The
House version of H.R. 6 provided about $17.1 billion of energy tax incentives and
included $83 million of non-energy tax increases, or offsets. This bill was a
substantially scaled-down version of the House energy tax bill, H.R. 2511 (107th
Congress), which was incorporated into H.R. 4, the House energy bill of the 107th
Congress that never became law. After returning from the August 2003 recess, a
House and Senate conference committee negotiated differences among provisions in
three energy policy bills: the House and Senate versions of H.R. 6, and a substitute
to the Senate Finance Committee (SFC) bill — a modified (or amended) version of
S. 1149 substituted for Senate H.R. 6 in conference as S.Amdt. 1424 and S.Amdt.
1431.
On November 14, 2003, House and Senate conferees reconciled the few
remaining differences over the two conference versions of H.R. 6, which primarily
centered on several energy tax issues — ethanol tax subsidies, the §29
unconventional fuels tax credit, tax incentives for nuclear power, and clean coal. On
November 18, 2003, the House approved, by a fairly wide margin (246-180), the
conference report containing about $23.5 billion of energy tax incentives. However,
the proposed ethanol mandate would further reduce energy tax receipts — the 10-
year revenue loss was projected to be around $26 billion. On November 24, Senate
Republicans put aside attempts to enact H.R. 6. A number of uneasy alliances pieced
together to bridge contentious divides over regional issues as varied as electricity,
fuel additives (MTBE), and natural gas subsidies, failed to secure the necessary 60
votes to overcome a Democratic filibuster before Congress’s adjournment for the
holiday season. This represented the third attempt to pass comprehensive energy
legislation, a top priority for many Republicans in Congress and for President Bush.
Senator Domenici introduced a smaller energy bill as S. 2095 on February 12,
2004. S. 2095 included a slightly modified version of the amended energy tax bill
S. 1149; the tax provisions of S. 2095 were added to the export tax repeal bill S.
1637, on April 5, 2004. The Senate approved S. 1637, with the energy tax measures,
on May 11. H.R. 4520, the House version of the export tax repeal legislation, did not
contain energy tax measures; they were incorporated into H.R. 6.
Some energy tax incentives were enacted on October 4, 2004, as part of the
Working Families Tax Relief Act of 2004 (P.L. 108-311), a $146 billion package of
middle class and business tax breaks. This legislation, which was signed into law on
October 4, 2004, retroactively extended four energy tax subsidies: the §45 renewable
tax credit, suspension of the 100% net income limitation for the oil and gas
percentage depletion allowance, the $4,000 tax credit for electric vehicles, and the
deduction for clean fuel vehicles (which ranges from $2,000 to $50,000). The §45
tax credit and the suspension of the 100% net income limitation had each expired on
January 1, 2004; they were retroactively extended through December 31, 2005. The
electric vehicle credit and the clean-vehicle income tax deduction were being phased
out gradually beginning on January 1, 2004. P.L. 108-311 arrested the phase-down
— providing 100% of the tax breaks — through 2005, but resumed it beginning on
CRS-11
January 1, 2006, when only 25% of the tax break was available. (For more
information, see CRS Report RL32265, Expired and Expiring Energy Tax Incentives,
by Salvatore Lazzari.)
The American Jobs Creation Act of 2004 (P.L. 108-357), enacted on October
22, 2004, included about $5 billion in energy tax incentives. This bill, commonly
referred to as the “FSC-ETI” or “jobs” bill, contained several energy-related tax
breaks:
! Expansion of the renewable electricity credit to open-loop biomass,
geothermal, solar, small irrigation power, and municipal solid waste
facilities, and introduction of a $4.375/ton production tax credit for
refined coal — not for the electricity produced from the coal. (The
refined coal tax credit was originally part of proposed expansion of
the §29 tax credit in the 2003 and 2004 proposed comprehensive
energy policy bills, which already benefitted “synfuels” from coal.
When comprehensive energy policy legislation failed, the refined
coal credit was added to the “jobs” bill, which inserted the provision
into the renewable electricity section of the tax code).
! Creation of a new tax credit for oil and gas from marginal (small)
wells, triggered when oil prices are below $18/barrel ($2/mcf for
natural gas).
! Liberalization of the tax treatment of electric cooperatives under a
restructured electricity market.
! Reduction of the depreciation recovery period for certain Alaska
pipelines to 7 years (15 years under prior law).
! Extension of the 15% enhanced oil recovery credit to Alaska gas
processing facilities.
! Reform of the tax subsidies for fuel ethanol — basically replacing
the excise tax exemption with an equivalent immediate tax credit —
and expansion of the credit to include biodiesel (at a higher rate for
biodiesel made from virgin oils).
! Repeal of the general fund component (4.3¢/gal.) excise tax on
diesel fuel used in trains and barges.
! A new $2.10/barrel tax credit for production of low-sulfur diesel fuel
and “expensing” of (basically, faster depreciation deductions for) the
capital costs to produce such fuels.
Energy Action in the 109th Congress
The 109th Congress enacted the Energy Policy Act of 2005 (P.L. 109-58), which
included the most extensive amendments to U.S. energy tax laws since 1992, and the
CRS-12
Tax Relief and Health Care Act of 2006, which extended the energy tax subsidies
enacted under the 2005 Energy Policy Act.
The Energy Policy Act of 2005 (P.L. 109-58)
On June 28, 2005, the Senate approved by an 85-12 vote a broadly based energy
bill (H.R. 6) with an 11-year, $18.6 billion package of energy tax breaks tilted toward
renewable energy resources and conservation. Joint Committee on Taxation figures
released on June 28 show that the bill included about $0.2 billion in non-energy tax
cuts and more than $4.7 billion in revenue offsets, meaning the bill had a total tax cut
of $18.8 billion over 11 years, offset by the $4.7 billion in tax increases. The House
energy bill, which included energy tax incentives totaling about $8.1 billion over 11
years, and no tax increases, was approved in April. This bill was weighted almost
entirely toward fossil fuels and electricity supply. On July 27, 2005, the conference
committee on H.R. 6 reached agreement on $11.1 billion of energy tax incentives,
including $3 billion in tax increases (both energy and non-energy). The distribution
of the cuts by type of fuel for each of the three versions of H.R. 6 is shown in Table
1.
One way to briefly compare the two measures is to compare revenue losses from
the energy tax incentives alone and the percentage distribution by type of incentive
as a percent of the net energy tax cuts (i.e., the columns marked “%” divided by the
dollar figures in row 11). The net revenue losses over an 11-year time frame from
FY2005 to FY2015 were estimated by the Joint Committee on Taxation. The total
revenue losses are reported in two ways. The absolute dollar value of tax cuts over
11 years and the percentage distribution of total revenue losses by type of incentive
for each measure.
Table 1 shows that the conference report provided about $1.3 billion for energy
efficiency and conservation, including a deduction for energy-efficient commercial
property, fuel cells, and micro-turbines, and $4.5 billion in renewables incentives,
including a two-year extension of the tax code §45 credit, renewable energy bonds,
and business credits for solar. A $2.6 billion package of oil and gas incentives
included seven-year depreciation for natural gas gathering lines, a refinery expensing
provision, and a small refiner definition for refiner depletion. A nearly $3 billion
coal package provided for an 84-month amortization for pollution control facilities
and treatment of §29 as a general business credit. More than $3 billion in electricity
incentives leaned more toward the House version, including provisions providing
15-year depreciation for transmission property, nuclear decommissioning provisions,
and a nuclear electricity production tax credit. It also provided for the five-year
carryback of net operating losses of certain electric utility companies. A
Senate-passed tax credit to encourage the recycling of a variety of items, including
paper, glass, plastics, and electronic products, was dropped from the final version of
the energy bill (H.R. 6). Instead, conferees included a provision requiring the
Treasury and Energy departments to conduct a study on recycling. The House
approved the conference report on July 28, 2005; the Senate on June 28, 2005, one
month later on July 28, 2005, clearing it for the President’s signature on August 8
(P.L. 109-58).
CRS-13
Four revenue offsets were retained in the conference report: reinstatement of the
Oil Spill Liability Trust Fund; extension of the Leaking Underground Storage Tank
(LUST) trust fund rate, which would be expanded to all fuels; modification of the
§197 amortization, and a small increase in the excise taxes on tires. The offsets total
roughly $3 billion compared with nearly $5 billion in the Senate-approved H.R. 6.
Because the oil spill liability tax and the Leaking Underground Storage Tank
financing taxes are imposed on oil refineries, the oil and gas refinery and distribution
sector (row 2 of Table 1) received a net tax increase of $1,769 ($2,857-$1,088).
The Tax Relief and Health Care Act of 2006 (P.L. 109-432)
At the end of 2006, the 109th Congress enacted a tax extenders package that
included extension of numerous renewable energy and excise tax provisions. Many
of the renewable energy provision in this bill had already been extended under the
Energy Policy Act of 2005 and were not set to expire until the end of 2007 or later.
The Tax Relief and Health Care Act of 2006 provided for one-year extensions of
these provisions.
Current Posture of Energy Tax Policy
The above background discussion of energy tax policy may be conveniently
summarized in Table 2, which shows current energy tax provisions — both special
(or targeted) energy tax subsidies and targeted energy taxes — and related revenue
effects. A minus sign (“-“) indicates revenue losses, which means that the provision
is a tax subsidy or incentive, intended to increase the subsidized activity (energy
conservation measures or the supply of some alternative and renewable fuel or
technology); no minus sign means that the provision is a tax, which means that it
should reduce supply of, or demand for, the taxed activity (either conventional fuel
supply, energy demand, or the demand for energy-using technologies, such as cars).
Note that the table defines those special or targeted tax subsidies or incentives
as those that are due to provisions in the tax law that apply only to that particular
industry and not to others. Thus, for example, in the case of the oil and gas industry,
the table excludes tax subsidies and incentives of current law that may apply
generally to all businesses but that may also confer tax benefits to it. There are
numerous such provisions in the tax code; a complete listing of them is beyond the
scope of this report. However, the following example illustrates the point: The
current system of depreciation allows the writeoff of equipment and structures
somewhat faster than would be the case under both general accounting principles and
economic theory; the Joint Committee on Taxation treats the excess of depreciation
deductions over the alternative depreciation system as a tax subsidy (or “tax
expenditure”). In FY2006, the JCT estimates that the aggregate revenue loss from
this accelerated depreciation deduction (including the expensing under IRC §179) is
$6.7 billion. A certain, but unknown, fraction of this revenue loss or tax benefits
accrues to the domestic oil and gas industry, but separate estimates are unavailable.
This point applies to all the industries reflected in Table 2.
CRS-14
Energy Tax Policy Outlook
After expanding energy tax incentives in the Energy Policy Act of 2005, the
109th Congress moved to rescind oil and gas incentives, and even to raise energy
taxes on oil and gas, in response to the high energy prices and resulting record oil and
gas industry profits. Many bills were introduced in the 109th Congress to pare back
or repeal the oil and gas industry tax subsidies and other loopholes. Many of the bills
focused on the oil and gas exploration and development (E&D) subsidy — expensing
of intangible drilling costs (IDCs). This subsidy, which has been in existence since
the early days of the income tax, is available to integrated and independent oil and
gas companies, both large and small alike.3 It is an exploration and development
incentive, which allows the immediate tax write-off of what economically are capital
costs, that is, the costs of creating a capital asset (the oil and gas well). On September
18, 2006, Senators Wyden and Bennett introduced a bill (S. 3908) to give consumers
a discount on the purchase of more fuel-efficient vehicles that would have been paid
for by reducing the IDCs deduction for major integrated oil companies.
Comprehensive energy legislation (S. 2829) unveiled by Senate Democrats on May
17, 2006, would not only have eliminated expensing of IDCs but also would have
reduced several other tax benefits (or loopholes) to the oil and gas industry (such the
foreign tax credits). The latter are not subsidies (or tax expenditures) in the strict
sense of special tax measures unavailable generally, but as discussed below, some
consider these unnecessary tax benefits nonetheless.4 H.R. 5234 focused on repealing
three of the seven fossil fuel tax provisions in the 2005 act: temporary expensing of
equipment costs for crude oil refining, the small refiner exception to percentage
depletion, and the amortization of geological and geophysical (G&G) costs. H.R.
5218 would have denied oil and gas companies the new domestic manufacturing
deduction under IRC§199.
Ultimately, only a negligible tax increase on major integrated oil companies was
enacted when, on May 17, 2006, the President signed a $70 billion tax reconciliation
bill (P.L. 109-222). Under that bill, geological and geophysical (G&G) costs
undertaken in exploring for oil and gas by major integrated oil companies are
amortized over five years rather than two years. The two-year period was enacted
under the Energy Policy Act of 2005. Prior to that, G&G costs were capitalized,
which is consistent with economic and accounting theory. The 2006 change increases
taxes on major integrated oil companies by an estimated $189 million over 10 years,
effectively rescinding about 20% of the nearly $1 billion 11-year tax cut under the
Energy Policy Act of 2005.
3 As is discussed later in the report, many of the other remaining tax subsidies are only
available to independent oil and gas producers, which, however, may be very large.
4 There is an important economic distinction between a subsidy and a tax benefit. As is
discussed elsewhere in this report, firms receive a variety of tax benefits that are not
necessarily targeted subsidies (or tax expenditures) because they are available generally.
CRS-15
110th Congress
Efforts to reduce oil and gas production incentives or subsidies have continued
in the 110th Congress, and are now part of comprehensive energy policy legislation.
In the House, most action has focused on the Speaker’s announced “Energy
Independence Day” initiative (H.R. 3221), which combines bills approved by several
House committees. This bill began with the CLEAN Energy Act of 2007 (H.R. 6),
which was introduced by the House Democratic leadership to revise certain tax and
royalty policies for oil and natural gas and to use the resulting revenue to support a
reserve for energy efficiency and renewable energy. The bill was part of the House
Democrats’ “100 hours” package of legislative initiatives. This bill passed the House
on January 18 by a vote of 264-123. In the Senate, H.R. 6 was derived mainly from
S. 1419, which was itself an amalgamation of four separate energy bills. It was
approved by the Senate on June 21, 2007.
In the debate over these two comprehensive energy bills, raising taxes on the oil
and gas industry, by either repealing tax incentives enacted under EPACT05, by
introducing new taxes on the industry, or by other means was a key objective,
motivated by the feeling that additional tax incentives were unnecessary — record
crude oil and gasoline prices and industry profits provides sufficient (if not
excessive) incentives. On June 19, House Ways and Means Committee (W&MC)
Chairman Charles Rangel introduced a $15.2 billion package of tax credits and
extensions (H.R. 2776, the Renewable Energy and Energy Conservation Tax Act of
2007) over 12 years to encourage more use of clean energy, at the expense of oil and
gas producers. The committee approved the bill on June 20, 2007. The tax cuts for
alternative fuels and energy conservation would be financed largely by rescinding the
IRC §199 manufacturing tax deduction for oil and gas producers, which is expected
to generate about $11.4 billion in revenue.5 This bill was approved by the House on
August 4, 2007, by a vote of 221-189.
The Ways and Means Committee Energy Tax Bill (H.R. 2776)
H.R. 2776 would essentially finance the expansion of tax subsidies for
alternative (including renewable) fuels and energy conservation by raising taxes on
the oil and gas industry. The major highlights of the bill are as follows.
Renewable Production Incentives.
! The bill expands the §45 tax credits for electricity produced from
renewable energy such as wind turbines, solar, biomass, geothermal,
river currents, ocean tides, landfill gas, and trash combustion
resources. It also extends the placed in service date by four years.
! It liberalizes the 30% investment tax credit for business solar and
fuel cells, and extends the credit by eight years.
5 This tax incentive, which is not technically a tax expenditure or subsidy because it is
available to all domestic manufacturing firms, was enacted under the American Jobs
Creation Act of 2004 (P.L. 108-357), signed on October 22, 2004.
CRS-16
! It provides additional authority to raise the limits on a category of
“Clean Renewable Energy Bonds” eligible as tax-exempt bond
financing. The bill encourages the deployment of renewable energy
by providing electric cooperatives and public power providers with
new clean renewable energy bonds that will allow these entities to
install facilities that generate electricity from renewable resources.
! It extends the biodiesel tax credits by two years and restricts the tax
credits for renewable diesel. It creates a new tax credit for cellulosic
ethanol and increases the number of E-85 pumps for consumers with
flex-fuel vehicles.
Conservation Incentives.
! The bill adds employer-funded bicycle purchase and repair costs
toward commuting expenses to the list of tax-exempt transportation
fringe benefits, which are exempt from gross income.
! It creates a new tax credit for plug-in hybrids to complement the
existing hybrid vehicle tax credits.
! The bill provides incentives for manufacturers to build appliances
that meet or exceed Energy Star efficiency standards, and helps
businesses create energy-efficient workplaces.
! It also help States leverage tax credit bonds to implement
low-interest loan programs and grant programs to help working
families purchase energy-efficient appliances, make energy-efficient
home improvements, or install solar panels, small wind turbines, and
geothermal heat pumps.
Tax Increases on the Oil and Gas Industry. To pay for these renewable
energy and conservation incentives, the bill repeals approximately $16 billion in tax
breaks for oil and gas companies. More specifically, H.R. 2776:
! denies the Internal Revenue Code (IRC) §199 manufacturing
deduction to major oil and gas producers. It was originally estimated
to raise $6.5 billion over 10 years but was revised in June by the
Joint Committee on Taxation to $11.4 billion over ten years. First
enacted in 2004, this provision in IRC §199 allows a deduction, as
a business expense, for a specified percentage of the qualified
production activity’s income subject to a limit of 50% of the wages
paid that are allocable to the domestic production during the taxable
year. The deduction was 3% of income for 2006, is currently 6%,
and is scheduled to increase to 9% when fully phased in by 2010.
For the domestic oil and gas industry, the deduction applies to oil
and gas or any primary product thereof, provided that such product
was “manufactured, produced, or extracted in whole or in significant
part in the United States.” Note that extraction is considered to be
CRS-17
manufacturing for purposes of this deduction, which means that
domestic firms in the business of extracting oil and gas from
underground reservoirs or deposits qualify for the deduction. This
deduction was enacted under the American Jobs Creation Act of
2004 (P.L. 108-357, also known as the “JOBS” bill). It was
originally a substitute for repeal of the export tax benefits under the
extra-territorial income tax exclusion, which was ruled to be in
violation of trade laws;6
! restricts the ability of major oil and gas companies to claim tax
credits for taxes and other payments to foreign governments against
the U.S. tax on foreign source income;
! amortizes geological and geophysical costs over 7 years instead of
the current 5 years for the major integrated oil companies; and
! closes the “Hummer” Tax Loophole, that provides an extra
depreciation tax incentive for businesses buying luxury SUVs, while
exempting vehicles that are used for legitimate business purposes.
The Senate Finance Committee Energy Tax Bill
On the Senate side, the Senate Finance Committee’s (SFC) energy tax bill (the
Energy Advancement and Investment Act) proposes a $32 billion tax cut for
alternative fuels and energy conservation, more than double the size of the W/M bill,
to be offset by $32.2 billion of tax increases primarily on the domestic oil and gas
industry, including $4 billion of taxes from disallowing losses on abusive SILO (sale-
in, lease out) transactions, and by several other relatively minor tax increases. The
proposed tax increases on the domestic oil and gas industry total nearly $27 billion
over ten years and account for about 83% of the tax increases. Like the W/M bill, the
SFC bill would rescind the IRC §199 manufacturing tax deduction for oil and gas
producers, although the Senate bill applies only to the major integrated producers
while in the House bill it applies to all oil and gas producers. The SFC bill also funds
the additional tax cuts for alternative fuels and energy conservation by a doubling of
the oil spill liability excise tax (from 5¢/ barrel to 10¢/barrel) and by imposition of
a new excise tax — at 13% of the price — on oil and gas produced from federal lands
in the Gulf of Mexico. This severance tax provision is not in H.R. 2776, but a similar
tax increase was added to the farm bill (H.R. 2419) approved by the House on July
26. This tax increase, which is called a “conservation of resources fee” in the bill but
is no different from a tax, is a unit tax of $9/barrel of oil and $1.25/million Btus of
gas applicable to all oil and gas produced pursuant to federal leases in the Gulf of
Mexico.
There are many other differences between the two bills. At half the size of the
$32 billion SFC bill, the W/M bill forgoes some of the tax incentives for the
production of energy from wind, hydroelectric power, biomass, or clean coal
6 CRS Report RL32652, The 2004 Corporate Tax and FSC/ETI Bill: The American Jobs
Creation Act of 2004, by David L. Brumbaugh. January 26. 2006.
CRS-18
technologies that are in the SFC bill. The SFC bill was the energy tax title to the
Senate’s version of comprehensive energy legislation (H.R. 6) and was reported by
the Committee on June 19, 2007, but failed a procedural vote to limit debate (cloture)
when it was on the Senate floor. The SFC reported bill was not numbered, but was
Senate Amendment 1704 to Senator Reid’s Substitute Amendment 1502 to H.R. 6,
which was approved by the House on January 18, 2007, and by the Senate on June
21, 2007.
Likely Effects on Oil and Gas Prices and Oil Import
Dependence
In general, for reasons explained more fully below, none of the oil and gas tax
provisions listed above are expected to have significant price effects, either on crude
oil or natural gas prices, or refined petroleum product prices, such as pump prices.
The market price of crude oil and natural gas, or even of refined petroleum products,
such as gasoline, would not be expected to increase very much, if at all. In general,
also, the income tax increases are not expected to have real output effects in the short
run, although they will cause resources to flow to other industries in the long run as
long as these other industries are allowed the manufacturing deduction, which is
equivalent to a lower marginal tax rate.
With regards to the excise tax increases and gasoline tax reforms in the SFC bill,
economic theory suggests that the oil spill tax will have price effects, but, based on
the relative magnitude of the proposed increase, which is quite small, these are
projected to be negligible. Neither the gasoline tax proposal nor the proposed 13%
severance tax are expected to have price effects, the former because it is a change in
the gasoline tax collection point rather than a tax increase, and the latter because
crude oil prices are determined in the world oil market rather than in the United
States. However, as is discussed more fully below, the proposed 13% severance tax
in the SFC bill (or the farm bill version of this tax, the so-called “conservation of
resources fee”) will likely reduce output of domestic oil and increase dependence on
imports.
Neutrality of the Corporate Income Tax
Two of the provisions in both the W&MC and SFC energy tax bills constitute
increases in the corporate income tax and would raise a substantial fraction of the
revenues from increased taxation of the oil and gas industry. The larger of the two
would rescind an income tax cut enacted nearly three years ago; the second would
raise U.S. tax on foreign-source oil and gas income by limiting the foreign tax credit.
One of the biggest revenue raisers in both bills is the provision denying the §199
manufacturing deduction to major oil producers. First enacted in 2004, this provision
in IRC §199 allows a deduction, as a business expense, for a specified percentage of
the qualified production activity’s income subject to a limit of 50% of the wages paid
that are allocable to the domestic production during the taxable year. The deduction
was 3% of income for 2006, is currently 6%, and is scheduled to increase to 9%
when fully phased in by 2010. For the domestic oil and gas industry, the deduction
CRS-19
applies to oil and gas or any primary product thereof, provided that such product was
“manufactured, produced, or extracted in whole or in significant part in the United
States.” Note that extraction is considered to be manufacturing for purposes of this
deduction, which means that domestic firms in the business of extracting oil and gas
from underground reservoirs or deposits qualify for the deduction. This deduction
was enacted under the American Jobs Creation Act of 2004 (P.L. 108-357, also
known as the “JOBS” bill). It was originally a substitute for repeal of the export tax
benefits under the extra-territorial income tax exclusion, which was ruled to be in
violation of trade laws.7
To understand why repealing this deduction, whether for oil and gas or any other
industry, would not likely have price effects, note that the deduction is effectively
equivalent to a reduction in the marginal income tax rate. For example, at the
marginal corporate tax rate of 35%, which typically applies to large corporations such
as oil and gas producers and refiners, the current deduction of 6% is equivalent to a
marginal corporate income tax rate of 32.9% (35% x 0.94) rather than 35%.8 The
proposed elimination of this deduction is, thus, equivalent to an increase in the
marginal tax rate from 32.9% to 35% for those major oil companies to which this
would apply. All other large corporations would continue to face a top marginal tax
rate of 32.9%, with the exception of non-manufacturing enterprises (services, for
example), which do not qualify for the §199 deduction.
From an economic perspective, that is to say, in theory, increasing marginal tax
rates on corporate income would be relatively neutral in the short run — it would
have no (or few) price effects and other economic effects. The reason for this is that
a firm maximizes profit at the point at which market prices are equal to marginal
production costs, and neither are affected by an increase in marginal tax rates — the
profit maximizing level of output and price are unaffected by the tax. Thus, while
eliminating the deduction — that is to say, raising the corporate tax rate — would
increase total (or average) business costs and therefore reduce profitability among the
major oil and gas producers, as long as marginal production costs are unaffected,
there would be no price effects in the short run. Note also that while the current
corporate income tax is not a pure corporate profits (or cash-flow) tax, a surtax for
oil companies would arguably be an administratively simple and economically
effective way to capture any oil windfalls in the short run.
In the long run, however, all taxes distort resource allocation, and even a
corporate profit tax (either of the pure type or the surtax on the existing rates) would
reduce the rate of return and reduce the flow of capital into the industry. In the long
run, eliminating the deduction for the domestic oil and gas industry will raise average
production costs, adversely affecting the economics of domestic oil and gas projects
as compared to domestic non-oil and gas projects. Generally, rates of return to
investments in oil and gas would decline, causing a decline in capital flows to this
7 CRS Report RL32652, The 2004 Corporate Tax and FSC/ETI Bill: The American Jobs
Creation Act of 2004, by David L. Brumbaugh.
8 Corporations are currently taxed at 15% of the first $50,000 of taxable income, 25% of the
taxable income from $50,001 to $75,000, 34% of the taxable income from $75,001 to $10
million, and 35% of taxable income above $10 million.
CRS-20
industry, and an increase in capital flowing to other industries, including foreign
industries. This would tend to adversely affect domestic production and increase
imports: Domestic oil and gas output would be lower, and imports would be higher
than they otherwise would be without the tax increase. However, because of the
structure of the world oil market, market oil prices are exogenous to U.S. producers
(and gas prices tend to follow market oil prices), even these longer term effects are
not likely to affect oil and gas prices. Also, the retail price of refined petroleum
products, such as gasoline, to consumers is determined by a complex interplay of
world supply and demand market variables rather than a domestic corporate tax
increase.
As to the restrictions to the foreign tax credits, this proposal would also be
effectively an increase in the corporate income tax on domestic oil and gas producers
operating abroad. Again, owing to the structure of the world oil market and how
crude prices are determined in this market, there are likely to be few price effects
either in the short or long run. However, raising domestic income taxes by restricting
the industry’s ability to claim credits against the income taxes imposed by foreign
countries might negatively affect the competitiveness of the domestic U.S. oil
producers operating abroad and competing with foreign firms that would not have
such restrictions.
Proposed Increases in Excise Taxes
Unlike corporate income taxes, excise taxes, such as crude oil taxes imposed on
all crude oil purchases or gasoline taxes, would raise marginal production costs, and
thus would generally tend to raise prices, reduce output, or both. Of the three
proposed excise tax provisions in the SFC bill, however, there is a distinction
between the effects of oil spill and gasoline tax proposals, and the effects of the
severance tax proposal.
The Oil Spill Tax. The oil spill liability trust fund tax is an excise tax on
crude oil purchased or used by a refinery as well on petroleum product imports. This
tax, which is currently 5¢ per barrel, was reinstated by the Energy Policy Act of 2005
(P.L. 109-58) after a ten-year lapse. The SFC proposal would be a simple doubling
in the per barrel tax from 5¢ to 10¢. Whether the oil is produced domestically or
imported, all such crude oil purchased by refineries would be taxed at twice the rate,
thereby increasing the marginal production costs — the costs of refining petroleum
products — and raising the price of all petroleum products. However, the proposed
tax increase of 5¢/barrel of crude oil is such a small increase — amounting to just
over 1/10 of 1¢ per gallon of refined products — that it would be difficult to detect
and measure in a petroleum products market as large as that in the United States.
Gasoline Tax Collection Point. Likewise, increases in taxes on gasoline
and other motor fuels would, depending on the amount of the tax increase, and the
market response to that increase (e.g., the price elasticities of the supply and demand
for gasoline), tend to raise the price of the taxed fuel and reduce consumption and
output of the taxed fuel. However, the SFC proposal is to eliminate or repeal the
current bulk transfer exception to the gasoline tax collection system, a feature that
essentially allows finished gasoline to move by pipeline or barge from the refiner or
importer tax-free until it gets to the terminal operator. Currently, refiners are
CRS-21
generally permitted to ship gasoline by pipeline or barge to terminals for ultimate
distribution to wholesalers or retailers tax-free. Essentially this means that the
gasoline tax is imposed at the terminal when the product breaks bulk. Under the
proposed change, the 18.4¢ tax on finished gasoline would be imposed at the refinery
gate (for domestically refined product) or on its entry into the United States, and thus
is fundamentally a change in the gasoline tax collection point, rather than an increase
in the gasoline tax per se. Repealing the bulk transfer exception to the gasoline tax
means essentially that refiners and importers would not be able to ship finished motor
gasoline in bulk to terminals or other points of distribution without tax. This would
accelerate the payment of the existing 18.4¢/gallon tax on finished motor gasoline,
and might be an administrative burden on refiners, as well. It might also reduce tax
evasion, which is perhaps the source of the estimated $824 million in additional
revenues over 10 years. However, since it is not an increase in the gasoline tax, which
would remain at 18.4¢/gallon, it should not lead to an increase in gasoline prices.
Proposed New 13% Severance Tax on OCS Oil and Gas. The SFC
energy tax bill also includes a proposed 13% new excise tax on the price of all oil
and gas produced from the federal outer continental shelf in the Gulf of Mexico
(GOM). Any royalties paid on such oil and gas would be fully creditable against this
new tax, up to 13%. Thus, an operator paying a 1/6th royalty (16b%) would be
assessed a 13% excise tax but 13 percentage points of the royalty would be creditable
against the tax, and the net excise tax would be zero. An operator paying a 1/8th
royalty (12.5%) would be assessed a 13% tax and 12.5% would be creditable against
it, for a net tax increase of 0.5%. However, because both the royalty and the excise
tax would be deductible against income taxes, the net tax increase would be 0.335%
(0.5 x 0.671).9 An operator that would otherwise pay no royalty because the leases
were so drawn up and agreed to would be assessed a 13% excise tax and receive no
credit. Royalty free oil production from the GOM is a small fraction of the total
GOM oil production, but royalty free gas production is estimated at nearly 1/3 of total
GOM production.10 And given the recent high market prices of oil and natural gas,
the foregone royalty revenues have been quite large, estimated at about $1 billion so
far. The 13% excise tax would also be deductible against the income tax, so that the
after-tax liability would be currently 8.723% (or 8.45% with the repeal of the
manufacturing deduction).
Regardless of how operators respond to such a proposed tax — that is, whether
non-royalty payers would elect to renegotiate their leases and agree to pay a royalty
— the tax itself cannot be shifted because it is imposed only on domestic output, and
not imported oil, the marginal source of oil for the United States. As long as a
significant fraction of the available oil and gas is not subject to tax, the world market
price of oil and gas cannot increase. However, as before, the tax eventually would
9 That is, the net tax increase, after income taxes, would be (1-t)x0.5, where t is the marginal
statutory tax rate, currently 32.9% because of the 6% manufacturing deduction. If the
manufacturing deduction is repealed, then the net tax increase on production from the leases
that are currently not paying a royalty rate would actually be less: 0.325% (0.5x0.65) instead
of 0.335%.
10 Executive Office of the President. 2007 President’s Budget Federal OCS Production and
Royalty Revenue Projections. November 22, 2005.
CRS-22
tend to reduce output of oil and gas from the OCS, which would tend to increase
imports unless aggregate demand for oil and gas in the United States could be
curtailed. This would tend to make the U.S. more dependent on imports.11
For Additional Reading
U.S. Congress, Senate Budget Committee, Tax Expenditures: Compendium of
Background Material on Individual Provision, Committee Print, December
2006, 109th Cong., 2nd sess.
U.S. Congress, Joint Tax Committee, “Description of the Tax Provisions in H.R.
2776, The Renewable Energy and Energy Conservation Tax Act of 2007,” June
19, 2007 (JCX-35-07).
U.S. Congress, Joint Tax Committee, “Description of the Chairman’s Modification
to the Provisions of the Energy Advancement and Investment Act of 2007,”
June 19, 2007 (JCX-33-07).
U.S. Congress, Joint Tax Committee, Description And Technical Explanation of the
Conference Agreement of H.R. 6, Title XIII, “Energy Tax Policy Tax Incentives
Act of 2005,” July 27, 2005.
CRS Report RS21935, The Black Lung Excise Tax on Coal, by Salvatore Lazzari.
CRS Report RL33302, Energy Policy Act of 2005: Summary and Analysis of Enacted
Provisions, by Mark Holt and Carol Glover.
CRS Report RL30406, Energy Tax Policy: An Economic Analysis, by Salvatore
Lazzari.
CRS Report RS22344, The Gulf Opportunity Zone Act of 2005, by Erika Lunder.
CRS Report RL33763, Oil and Gas Tax Subsidies: Current Status and Analysis, by
Salvatore Lazzari.
CRS Report RS22558, Tax Credits for Hybrid Vehicles, by Salvatore Lazzari.
CRS Report RS22322, Taxes and Fiscal Year 2006 Reconciliation: A Brief
Summary, by David L. Brumbaugh.
11 The economic effects of the proposed severance tax would, in its effects on prices and
imports, be quite similar to the effects of the crude oil windfall profits tax that was in effect
in the United States from 1980 to 1988. See CRS Report RL33305,The Crude Oil Windfall
Profits Tax of the 1980s: Implications for Current Energy Policy, by Salvatore Lazzari.
CRS-23
Table 1. Comparison of Energy Tax Provisions the House,
Senate, and Enacted Versions of H.R. 6 (P.L.109-58):
11-Year Estimated Revenue Loss by Type of Incentive
(in millions of dollars; percentage of total revenue losses)
House H.R. 6
Senate H.R. 6
P.L. 109-58
$
%
$
%
$
%
INCENTIVES FOR FOSSIL FUELS SUPPLY
(1) Oil & Gas Production
-1,525
18.9%
-1,416
7.6%
-1,132
7.8%
(2) Oil & Gas Refining
-1,663
20.6%
-1,399
7.5%
-1,501
10.4%
and Distribution
(3) Coal
-1,490
18.4%
-3,003
16.2%
-2,948
20.3%
(4) Subtotal
-4,678
57.8%
-5,818
31.3%
-5,581
38.6%
ELECTRICITY RESTRUCTURING PROVISIONS
(5) Nuclear
-1,313
16.2%
-278
1.5%
-1,571
10.9%
(6) Other
-1,529
18.9%
-475
2.6%
-1,549
10.7%
(7) Subtotal
-2,842
35.1%
-753
4.1%
-3,120
21.6%
INCENTIVES FOR EFFICIENCY, RENEWABLES, AND ALTERNATIVE FUELS
(8) Energy Efficiency
-570
7.0%
-3,987
21.4%
-1,260
8.7%
(9) Renewable Energy &
0
0%
-8,031
43.2%
-4,500
31.1%
Alternative Fuels
(10) Subtotal
-570
7.0%
-12,018
64.6%
-5,760
39.8%
(11) Net Energy Tax Cuts
-8,010
100%
-18,589
100%
-14,461
100.0%
(12) Non Energy Tax
0
-213
-92
Cutsa
(13) Total Energy and
0
-18,802
-14,553
Non-Energy Tax Cuts
(14) Energy Tax
0
0
+2,857
Increasesb
(15) Other Tax Increases
+ 4,705
171
(16) NET TAX CUTS
-8,010
-14,055
-11,525
Source: CRS estimates based on Joint Tax Committee reports.
a. The conference report includes a provision to expand R&D for all energy activities. This provision
is listed as a nonenergy tax cut to simplify the table.
b. Energy tax increases comprise the oil spill liability tax and the Leaking Underground Storage Tank
financing rate, both of which are imposed on oil refineries. If these taxes are subtracted from
the tax subsidies (row 2), the oil and gas refinery and distribution sector suffered a net tax
increase of $1,356 ($2,857-$1501); if the taxes are subtracted from all of the industry’s tax
subsidies (rows 1 and 2), the industry experienced a net tax increase of $224 million ($2,857-
$2,633). Also, the Tax Increase Prevention and Reconciliation Bill of 2006 (P.L. 109-222),
enacted on May 17, 2006, increased taxes on the oil industry by about $189 million.
CRS-24
Table 2. Current Energy Tax Incentives and Taxes:
Estimated Revenue Effects FY2006
(in millions of dollars)
Revenue
Category
Provision
Major Limitations
Effects
FY2006
CONVENTIONAL FOSSIL FUELS SUPPLY
(bpd = barrels per day; < indicates less than)
Targeted Tax Subsidies
disposition of
capital gain
proceeds must be
- 600
electricity
recognized evenly
reinvested in other
transmission
over 8 years
electricity generating
property to
assets
implement FERC
policy
% depletion — oil,
15% of sales (higher
only for independents,
- 1,100
gas, and coal
for marginal wells);
up to 1,000 or equiv.
10% for coal
bpd
expensing of
100% deductible IDCs
corporations expense
- 1,100a
intangible drilling
in first year/ 2 year
only 70% of IDCs
costs (IDCs) and
amortization of
amortization of
geological and
exploration and
geophysical costs
development costs
— oil/gas and other
fuels
expensing of
deduction of 50% of
must increase the
- 26
refinery investments
the cost of qualified
capacity of an existing
refinery property, in
refinery by 5%;
the taxable year in
remaining 50% is
which the refinery is
depreciated; must be
placed in service
placed in service before
January 1, 2012
CRS-25
Revenue
Category
Provision
Major Limitations
Effects
FY2006
Tax Credits for
IRC §43 provides for a
The EOR credit is non
0
Enhanced Oil
15% income tax credit
refundable, and is
Recovery Costs
for the costs of
allowable provided that
(EOR)
recovering domestic
the average wellhead
oil by qualified
price of crude oil
“enhanced-oil-
(using West Texas
recovery” (EOR)
Intermediate as the
methods, to extract oil
reference), in the year
that is too viscous to
before credit is
be extracted by
claimed, is below the
conventional primary
statutorily established
and secondary water-
threshold price of $28
flooding techniques.
(as adjusted for
inflation since 1990),
in the year the credit is
claimed. With average
wellhead oil prices for
2005 (about $65) well
above the reference
price (about $38) the
EOR credit was not
available.
Marginal
A $3 tax credit is
The credit phases out
0
Production Tax
provided per barrel of
as oil prices rise from
Credit
oil ($0.50 per
$15 to $18 per barrel
thousand cubic feet
(and as gas prices rise
(mcf)) of gas from
from $1.67 to
marginal wells, and
$2.00/thousand cubic
for heavy oil.
feet), adjusted for
inflation. The credit is
limited to 25 bpd or
equivalent amount of
gas and to 1,095 barrels
per year or equivalent.
Credit may be carried
back up to 5 years. At
2005 oil and gas prices,
the marginal
production tax credit
was not available.
nuclear
liberalizes tax
in general, the IRS sets
- 120
decommissioning
deductible
limits on the annual
contributions to a fund
amounts made to a
in advance of actual
nuclear
decommissioning
decommissioning fund
CRS-26
Revenue
Category
Provision
Major Limitations
Effects
FY2006
electric utilities
allows net-operating
only 20% of the NOLs
-72
losses (NOLs) to be
in
carried back 5 years,
2003-2005 qualify
as compared with 2
years for all other
industries
incentives for small
$2.10 credit per barrel
credit limited to 25%
- < 50
refiners to comply
of low-sulfur diesel,
of capital costs;
with EPA sulfur
plus expensing of 75%
expensing phases out
regulations
of capital costs
for refining capacity of
155,000-205,000
barrels per day.
credit for clean-coal
20% for integrated
each system has
- 26
technologies
gasification combined
maximum aggregate
cycle (IGCC) systems;
dollar limits
15% for other
advanced coal
technologies
Targeted Taxes
black-lung coal
$1.25/ton for
coal tax not to exceed
789
excise taxes and
underground coal
4.4% of sales price
abandoned
($0.90 for surface
(2.2% for the AML
mineland
coal)
fee)
reclamation (AML)
fees
oil spill liability
$0.05/barrel tax on
moneys are allocated
150
trust fund excise tax
every barrel of crude
into a fund for cleaning
oil refined
up oil spills
ALTERNATIVE, UNCONVENTIONAL, AND RENEWABLE FUELS
Targeted Tax Subsidies
§29, production tax
$6.40/bar. of oil or
biogas, coal synfuels,
- 2,700
credit
($1.13/mcf of gas)
coalbed methane, etc.
credits for fuel
$0.51 blender’s credit,
for biomass ethanol
- 1,890
ethanol
plus $0.10/gal small
only (e.g., from corn)
producer credit
tax credit for clean-
$30,000 tax credit for
per location, per
- < 50
fuel refueling
alternative fuel
taxpayer (replaces a
property
equipment
deduction)
§45 credit for
1.8¢/kWh. (0.9¢ in
wind, closed-loop
- 900
renewable
some cases;
biomass, poultry
electricity
$4.375/ton of refined
waste, solar,
coal
geothermal, etc.
CRS-27
Revenue
Category
Provision
Major Limitations
Effects
FY2006
alternative fuel
$400-$40,000 credit
tax credit is function of
- 283
motor vehicle
for each fuel cell,
vehicle weight, fuel
(AFV) tax credits
hybrid, lean burn and
economy, and lifetime
other AFVs
fuel savings
exclusion of interest
interest income
for hydroelectric or
- 100
on State & Local
exempt from tax
biomass facilities used
bonds
to produce electricity
credits for biodiesel
$0.50/gal. of recycled
sold at retail or used in
- 122
biodiesel; $1.00/gal.
a trade or business;
for virgin biodiesel
applies to oils from
vegetables or animal
fats
credit for solar &
10% investment tax
utilities excluded
- < 50
geothermal tech.
credit for businesses
ENERGY CONSERVATION
Targeted Subsidies
mass transit
exclusion of
- 192
subsidies
$105/month
manufacturer’s
max credit is $50 for
amount of credit
- 117
credit for energy
dishwashers, $175 for
depends on energy
efficient appliances
refrigerators, and $200
efficiency, energy
for clothes washers
savings, and varies by
year; total annual credit
is also limited
deduction for the
tax deduction of cost
total deductions cannot
- 81
cost of energy
of envelope
exceed $1.80/sq.ft.
efficient property in
components, heating
commercial
cooling systems, and
buildings
lighting
credit for energy
10% tax credit
max credit on windows
- 55
efficiency
($500/home) on up to
is $200
improvements to
$5,000 of costs; $50-
existing homes
$300 credit for other
items
Targeted Taxes
fuels taxes
18.4¢/gal. on gasoline
4.4¢-24.4¢ for other
34,870
(FY2005)
fuels
gas-guzzler tax
$1,000-$7,700/
trucks and SUVs are
160
(FY2005)
vehicle weighing
exempt
6,000 lbs. or less
CRS-28
Revenue
Category
Provision
Major Limitations
Effects
FY2006
exclusion for utility
subsidies not taxable
any energy
< - 50
conservation
as income
conservation measure
subsidies
Source: Joint Tax Committee estimates and Internal Revenue Service data.
Notes: A negative sign indicates a tax subsidy or incentive; no negative sign indicates an energy tax.
NA denotes not available.
a. The revenue loss estimate excludes the benefit of expensing costs of dry tracts and dry holes, which
includes expensing some things that would otherwise be capitalized. This is a normal feature
of the tax code but confers special benefits on an industry where the cost of finding producing
wells includes spending money on a lot that turn out dry. This is probably more important than
IDCs or percentage depletion.