Order Code RL33178
CRS Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
Japan’s Currency Intervention: Policy Issues
December 5, 2005
Dick K. Nanto
Specialist in Industry and Trade
Foreign Affairs, Defense, and Trade Division
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress
Japan’s Currency Intervention: Policy Issues
Summary
Japan’s intervention to slow the upward appreciation of the yen has raised
concerns in the United States and brought charges that Tokyo is manipulating its
exchange rate in order to gain unfair advantage in world trade. This coincides with
similar charges being made with respect to the currencies of the People’s Republic
of China and South Korea. In the 109th Congress, S. 377 (Fair Currency Enforcement
Act of 2005) would require negotiation and appropriate action with respect to certain
countries that engage in currency manipulation. H.R. 3283 (United States Trade
Rights Enforcement Act) would require the Secretary of the Treasury to provide to
Congress a periodic assessment of countries — including Japan — that intervene to
influence the value of their currency.
Japan intervened (bought dollars and sold yen) extensively to counter the yen’s
appreciation in 1976-1978, 1985-1988, 1992-1996, and 1998-2004. Since March
2004, the Japanese government has not intervened significantly, although some claim
that Tokyo continues to “talk down the value of the yen.” This heavy buying of
dollars has resulted in an accumulation of official foreign exchange reserves now
exceeding a record $800 billion by Japan. The intervention, however, seems to have
had little lasting effect. It may only have slowed the rise in value of the yen, since
the yen rose from 296 yen per dollar in 1976 to 103 yen per dollar at the end of 2004.
In late 2005, the exchange value of the yen had depreciated to about 115 yen per
dollar. Japan’s intervention, therefore, amounted to what is called “leaning against
the wind” or intervening to smooth strong short-term trends rather than to reverse the
direction of change. Estimates on the cumulative effect of the interventions range
from an undervaluation of the yen of about 3 or 4 yen to as much as 20 yen per
dollar.
In March and November 2005, the U.S. Secretary of the Treasury indicated that
it had not found currency manipulation by any country, including by Japan. An April
2005 report by the Government Accountability Office reported that Treasury had not
found currency manipulation because it viewed “Japan’s exchange rate interventions
as part of a macroeconomic policy aimed at combating deflation...” In its August
2005 report on consultations with Japan, the International Monetary Fund, likewise,
did not find currency manipulation by Japan. The criteria for finding currency
manipulation, however, allows for considerable leeway by Treasury and the IMF.
One problem with the focus on currency intervention to correct balance of trade
deficits is that only about half of the increase in the value of a foreign currency is
reflected in prices of imports into the United States. Periods of heaviest intervention
also coincided with slower (not faster) economic growth rates for Japan.
Major policy options for Congress include (1) let the market adjust (do nothing);
(2) clarify the definition of currency manipulation; (3) require negotiations and
reports; (4) require the President to certify which countries are manipulating their
currencies and take remedial action if the manipulation is not halted; and (5) take the
case to the World Trade Organization under the dispute settlement mechanism or
appeal to the IMF. This report will be updated as circumstances require.
Contents
The Interventions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
Economic Studies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
The Link Between Exchange Value and Trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
Intervention or Manipulation? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
Policy Issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
Let the Market Adjust (Do Nothing) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
Clarify the Definition of Currency Manipulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
Require Negotiations and Reports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Certify Currency Manipulation and Take Remedial Action . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
Appeal to the WTO or IMF . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
List of Figures
Figure 1. Japan’s Yen Exchange Rate, Foreign Exchange Reserves,
and Periods of Intervention into Currency Markets, 1972-2004 . . . . . . . . . . 4
Figure 2. Japan’s Currency Intervention, Rates of Growth in Real Gross
National Product, and Annual Changes in the Dollar/Yen Exchange
Rate and Japan’s Foreign Exchange Reserves, 1972-2004 . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
Figure 3. Indexes of the Value of the Japanese Yen and
German Mark per U.S. Dollar, 1972-2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
List of Tables
Table 1. Japan’s GDP Growth Rate, Yen/Dollar Exchange Rate, and
Foreign Exchange Reserves, 1970-2004 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
Japan’s Currency Intervention: Policy
Issues
Japan’s intervention to slow the upward revaluation of the yen has raised
concerns in the United States and brought charges that Tokyo is manipulating its
exchange rate in order to gain unfair advantage in world trade. This coincides with
similar charges being made with respect to the currencies of China and South Korea.
This report provides an overview and analysis of Japan’s official intervention into
currency markets, reviews various studies on the probable effect of that intervention,
examines the charge that Japan has manipulated its exchange rate as defined by the
International Monetary Fund (IMF), and reviews legislation and policy options.
Foreign governments intervene into currency markets by buying foreign
exchange — usually dollars, Euros, or British pounds — in order to increase demand
for dollars and support its value relative to the intervening government’s own
currency. Likewise, they can sell foreign exchange in order to decrease demand for
dollars and increase the value of the country’s own currency. In Japan’s case, it has
usually bought dollars from its domestic exporters in exchange for yen and used
those dollars to buy U.S. Treasury securities or other liquid dollar assets.
In the 109th Congress, the Fair Currency Enforcement Act of 2005 (S. 377,
Lieberman) would require negotiation and appropriate action with respect to certain
countries that engage in currency manipulation. H.R. 3283 (United States Trade
Rights Enforcement Act) would require the Secretary of the Treasury to provide to
Congress a periodic assessment of countries that intervene (including Japan) to
influence the value of their respective currency.
Concern over such intervention stems from the basic U.S. interest in American
national prosperity. Manipulation of exchange rates to undervalue foreign currencies
potentially can increase the U.S. trade deficit,1 increase U.S. dependency on foreign
investors to finance U.S. budget deficits, affect the level of U.S. interest rates, and
negatively affect U.S. businesses competing with imports or exporting.
In Japan’s case, the Bank of Japan (in consultation with the Ministry of Finance)
has bought U.S. Treasury securities and other liquid dollar assets at times when the
value of the dollar relative to the yen was declining. The intended result was to keep
the value of the yen from appreciating too quickly in order to keep the price of
Japanese exports from rising in markets such as the United States and to maintain the
profitability of those exports. Some experts argue that the yen is undervalued by
1 The overall size of a nation’s current account balance (trade in goods and services plus
unilateral transfers) is determined mainly by rates of savings and investment, interest rates,
and other factors, but the foreign exchange rate plays a key role in adjusting for imbalances.
CRS-2
10% to 20% or more. If so, this would give many Japanese manufacturers a 10% to
20% price advantage over U.S. competitors.
Most economic studies, however, indicate that currency intervention for large
countries with floating exchange rates (such as Japan and South Korea) merely slows
the rate of currency appreciation or depreciation over the short run (less than 30 days)
and has little effect over the long term. Whether Japan has manipulated its exchange
rate under criteria set by the IMF is open to debate. The IMF and the Secretary of the
Treasury have not found such manipulation in recent years, but others charge that
such manipulation has taken place. Japan claims that it has not intervened in foreign
exchange markets since March 2004, although some claim that Japan still “talks
down the value of the yen.”
The Interventions
In 1971, when the link between the U.S. dollar and gold was severed and the
dollar was allowed to float within certain bands, the yen began to appreciate in value.
The yen/dollar exchange rate, established during the U.S. occupation of Japan in
1949, had been held at 360 yen per dollar for 22 years. Since then, it appreciated to
around 105 yen per dollar in early 2005 but in late 2005 had depreciated to around
115 yen per dollar.
Japan’s government has intervened in currency markets to buy dollars or other
foreign exchange at times when the yen was appreciating at a pace considered to be
too rapid. Japan also has intervened by selling dollars at times when the yen was
depreciating too rapidly. The net result of this intervention is that Japan’s holdings
of foreign exchange reserves have risen to about $830 billion in late 2005.2
As can be seen in Figure 1, the most significant of Japan’s interventions to
counter the yen’s appreciation took place in 1976-78, 1985-88, 1992-96, and 1998-
2004. Since March 2004, the Japanese government has not intervened significantly
in currency markets to support the value of the dollar, although some claim that Japan
continues to “talk down” the value of the yen.3 Figure 1 also shows that despite
heavy buying (or selling) of dollars during certain periods of time, the intervention
seems to have had little lasting effect. It might have slowed the change in value of
the yen, but the appreciation (or depreciation) occurred anyway. This is called
“leaning against the wind” in economic parlance or intervening to oppose strong
short-term trends rather than to reverse the direction of change. In most cases,
Japan’s intervention resulted in the “smoothing” of fluctuations in exchange rates
2 Japan. Ministry of Finance at [http://www.mof.go.jp/english/e1c006.htm].
3 For data on intervention, see Japan. Ministry of Finance. International Reserves/Foreign
Currency Liquidity. Issued monthly. Also see Foreign Exchange Intervention Operations.
Issued periodically. [http://www.mof.go.jp/english/files.htm]
CRS-3
rather changing the direction of movement. As one author put it, Japan seems to
have won many daily battles with the foreign exchange market, yet it lost the war.4
Even though Japan has invested hundreds of billions of dollars in buying dollar
assets that are then held as foreign exchange reserves, many observers point out that
such transactions are small when compared with the average daily turnover of $1.9
trillion in traditional foreign exchange markets and $2.4 trillion in over-the-counter
currency and interest rate derivatives markets.5 Currency transactions in support of
imports and exports, investments, remittances, and other purposes dwarf
interventions by central banks. Still, it is the effect of central government
intervention on net — rather than gross — flows that make the difference (since
imports and exports tend to balance on a global basis). Government purchases and
sales constitute a net addition to or subtraction from global demand and supply. Also
government interventions can have a powerful signaling effect on market participants
who may prudently reduce their speculative buying should it be in a contrary
direction to what the government is doing. Central banks also often coordinate
intervention (intervening in the same direction the same day). This multiplies the
effect of the intervention.
4 Dominguez, Kathryn M. “Foreign Exchange Intervention: Did It Work in the 1990s?,”
In Dollar Overvaluation and the World Economy, ed. by Fred Bergsten and John
Williamson, Washington, Institute for International Economics, 2003. pp. 217-245.
5 Bank for International Settlements. Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange
and Derivatives Market Activity 2004 - Final Results. March 17, 2005. p. 1.
CRS-4
Figure 1. Japan’s Yen Exchange Rate, Foreign Exchange Reserves,
and Periods of Intervention into Currency Markets, 1972-2004
Foreign Exchange Reserves ($Billions)
Yen per Dollar Exchange Rate
1000
350
Weaker Yen
$834 billion)
Plaza
300
Accord
800
Stronger Yen
250
Inter-
Bubble Burst
Inter-
vention
600
Inter-
vention
vention
200
Inter-
vention
Yen/Dollar
150
400
Exchange Rate
(Right Axis)
100
Foreign Exchange
200
Reserves
(Left Axis)
Asian Financial
50
Crisis
0
0
1972 73 74 75 76 77 78 791980 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 891990 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 992000 1 2 3 4
Year
Source: Data from World Bank. World Development Indicators
Economic Studies
Academic studies of intervention generally conclude that interventions did
increase exchange rate volatility (moved the market), were a good indicator that the
magnitude of the change in exchange value on subsequent days would decrease, and
that much of it amounted to “leaning against the wind.”6 A recent study of the 1991-
2002 period of Japanese intervention concluded that “prior to June 1995, Japanese
interventions only had value as a forecast that the previous day’s yen appreciation or
depreciation would moderate during the current day. After June 1995, Japanese
purchases of dollars had value as a forecast that the yen would depreciate” in the very
short run. This analysis also confirmed that large, infrequent interventions, which
characterized the latter period, had a higher likelihood of success than small, frequent
interventions. For 2003 and 2004, despite the record size and frequency of the
intervention by Japan, the authors found it difficult to statistically distinguish the
pattern of exchange rate movements on intervention days from that of all the days in
6 Neely, Christopher J. An Analysis of Recent Studies of the Effect of Foreign Exchange
Intervention. The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper 205-030B, Revised
June 2005. p. 3, 8ff.
CRS-5
that particular subperiod. This showed little effectiveness in the interventions for that
subperiod and only modest effectiveness overall.7
Another study examining data from 1991 to 2000 found strong evidence that
“sterilized” intervention (buying of dollars offset by domestic selling of yen-
denominated bonds to keep Japan’s money supply unchanged) systemically affected
the exchange rate in the short-run (less than one month). Large-scale intervention
(amounts over $1 billion) — coordinated between the Bank of Japan and the U.S.
Federal Reserve — gave the highest success rates. Of the 12 “large scale
coordinated” interventions studied, 11 achieved the desired effect: they moved the
yen either up or down in accordance with the policy goal of the moment, although the
effects were short-lived.8
The estimate that the yen is 10% to 20% undervalued comes mainly from U.S.
automaker interests. In 2003, General Motors claimed that the yen should be trading
at about 100, rather than at 110 yen per dollar.9 In late 2005, as the dollar
strengthened, General Motors claimed that the relatively weak yen (111 per dollar at
the time) was providing a significant cost advantage (about $3,000 per vehicle) to
Japanese automakers. GM also raised the issue of “jawboning” and verbal currency
intervention (talking the yen down) by high-ranking Japanese officials.10
A leading proponent of the position that Japan has manipulated its exchange rate
is Ernest Preeg.11 In one study, he concluded that Japan had manipulated its
exchange rate and that the yen in 2002 was about 20% undervalued and should have
been around 100 yen per dollar.12 His analysis is based on the observation that
Japan’s intervention has been large, protracted, and one-sided, but the 20% figure is
a rough estimate based primarily on the extent of the intervention, not on a rigorous
economic model.
A new approach to exchange rate valuation is based on a modeling structure that
estimates equilibrium exchange rates taking into account relative productivity
7 Chaboud, Alain P. and Owen F. Humpage. “An Assessment of the Impact of Japanese
Foreign Exchange Intervention: 1991-2004.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 824, January 2005. p. 1-5.
8 Faum, Rasmus and Michael M. Hutchinson. “Effectiveness of Official Daily Foreign
Exchange Market Intervention Operations in Japan.” National Bureau of Economic
Research Working Paper 9648, April 2003. p. 1-5.
9 Meredith, Robyn. GM: Weak Yen Hurts U.S. Automakers. Forbes, October 21, 2003.
Online version at [http://www.forbes.com/2003/10/21/cz_rm+1021gm.html].
10 Mohatarem, Mustafa. Statement before the House Committee on Ways and Means,
Hearing on United States-Japan Economic and Trade Relations, September 28, 2005.
11 Ernest H. Preeg is a Senior Fellow in Trade and Productivity at the Manufacturers
Alliance/MAPI.
12 Preeg, Ernest H. “Exchange Rate Manipulation to Gain an Unfair Competitive
Advantage: The Case Against Japan and China,” in C. Fred Bergsten and John Williamson,
Dollar Overvaluation and the World Economy, Washington, Institute for International
Economics, 2003. p. 273.
CRS-6
advances as well as internal (savings and investment) and external (trade and capital
flow) balances.13 One such study by Goldman Sachs in 2003 estimated that the dollar
was 10% overvalued but that the yen was “actually close to equilibrium against the
dollar with a specific point estimate suggesting a fair value of around 119 yen per
dollar.”14
The International Monetary Fund also conducts surveillance over the exchange
rates of its member countries. In the IMF’s August 2005 report on consultations with
Japan, the Fund noted that compared to the United States and the Euro Area, Japan
stands out for its active use of foreign exchange market intervention as a policy
instrument. The IMF reported that since 1991, the Bank of Japan had intervened on
340 days, the European Central Bank on four days (since its inception in 1998), and
the U.S. Federal Reserve on 22 days. The IMF further stated that “there is some
evidence that intervention has had some impact on yen movements.” It then quoted
Takatoshi Ito, a Japanese economist, who found that intervention of about ¥2.5
trillion (about $250 billion) on average moved the exchange rate by ¥1 per dollar or
about 1%.15
A fundamental problem with exchange rates is that no commonly accepted
method exists to estimate the effectiveness of official intervention into foreign
exchange markets. Many interrelated factors affect the exchange rate at any given
time, and no model exists that is able to provide a definitive causal relationship
between intervention and an exchange rate when so many interdependent variables
are acting simultaneously.16
Setting aside the problems with statistical estimates, what can be said is that the
Japanese economy has generated a surplus in its trade accounts for much of recent
history. Without an offsetting deficit in its capital account, market forces would have
forced an appreciation of the yen that would have worked to eliminate the trade
surplus. From 1977 to 2004, Japan’s cumulative surplus on current account (net
trade in goods and services plus remittances) totaled $2,077 billion. Offsetting
Japan’s surplus on current account was its net capital outflow and net official
purchases of foreign exchange reserves (intervention). From 1977 to 2004, Japan
recorded a deficit in its capital flows (investments in foreign securities, buying
foreign companies, deposits in foreign bank accounts, etc.) of $1,314 billion. In
13 See Williamson, John ed. Estimating Equilibrium Exchange Rates. Washington, Institute
for International Economics, 1994.
14 O’Neill, Jim. “Features of a Dollar Decline,” in C. Fred Bergsten and John Williamson,
Dollar Overvaluation and the World Economy, Washington, Institute for International
Economics, 2003. pp. 17-21.
15 International Monetary Fund. IMF Country Report No. 05/273, Japan: 2005 Article IV
Consultation — Staff Report; Staff Supplement; and Public Information Notice on the
Executive Board Discussion. August 2005. Ito, Takatoshi. Interventions and the Japanese
Economic Recovery, paper presented at the University of Michigan Conference on Policy
Options for Japan and the United States. October 2004.
16 See, for example, International Monetary Fund. IMF Country Report No. 05/273, Japan:
2005 Article IV Consultation — Staff Report; Staff Supplement; and Public Information
Notice on the Executive Board Discussion. August 2005. p. 7.
CRS-7
other words, Japan’s private investors sent $1,314 billion more abroad than
foreigners invested in Japan. The remaining $763 billion outflow ($2,077 billion
minus $1,314 billion) of dollars was primarily from official currency intervention
that added to Japan’s foreign exchange reserves. This net buying of $763 billion17
in dollars — over the 1977-2004 period provided more than a third (37%) of the total
capital outflow from Japan to offset the country’s surplus in trade. If Japan had not
intervened to this extent, the yen likely would have appreciated more than it did.
Taking the estimate by Takatoshi Ito that $250 billion in intervention moved the
exchange rate by about 1% or ¥1, the net effect of the intervention would have been
around ¥3 or ¥4 per dollar. Taking the estimates by Preeg and General Motors, the
upper bound on the effect of the intervention would be around 20% or about ¥20 per
dollar. The range, therefore, for the effect of exchange rate undervaluation because
of Japanese intervention would be from ¥3 to ¥20 yen per dollar with the statistical
likelihood more toward the lower end of the range.
In terms of current policy, Japan claims that it has not intervened in exchange
markets since March 2004.
The Link Between Exchange Value and Trade
Setting aside the question of the efficacy of Japan’s intervention into exchange
markets and to weaken the yen, a second question is whether changes in the yen-
dollar exchange rate actually affect imports and exports. In theory, Japan’s
intervention by buying dollars and selling yen induces a cheaper yen which then
assists Japan’s exporters by allowing them either to lower their export price or to
maintain their export price while increasing profits. It also makes imports relatively
more expensive in Japan. Lowered export prices and higher import prices will tend
to increase Japan’s trade surplus which then contributes to a higher growth rate. The
Bank of Japan may or may not sterilize the currency operation by selling Japanese
bonds locally to keep the domestic money supply constant. In an economic sense,
if the intervention is not sterilized, buying dollars is equivalent to increasing the
Japanese money supply, since the Finance Ministry purchases the dollars from
Japanese exporters with yen which then enters the Japanese money supply.
In actual practice, the operation of currency markets often deviates from that
represented in economic theory and in models. In particular, the long-term link
between intervention and the foreign exchange rate is difficult to show empirically.
While the intervention has short-term effects, the long-term effects on exchange rates
and trade flows are much less apparent — especially considering that most of the
time, the intervention leans against the wind rather than reversing the direction of
change.
A second problem is that, in practice, Japan’s automakers and other exporters
to U.S. markets usually do not make short-run adjustments to prices in response to
17 Japan’s holdings of foreign exchange reserves actually rose by $811 billion over this
period. Some of this may have been interest earned on its holdings.
CRS-8
exchange rate fluctuations. Unlike generic commodities (such as crude oil or wheat
that have standardized commodity markets), Japan’s exports tend to be brand-named
products for which the sellers have some control over prices. When selling in the
United States, dealers and retailers of products from Japan tend to “price to market”
or set prices according market conditions.18
For instance, between January 5, 1994, and April 19, 1995, the Japanese yen
appreciated by 34% against the dollar (it rose from 113 to 80 yen per dollar). Prices
for exported products from Japan to the United States should have risen significantly,
but, for example, the U.S. sticker price of a Toyota Celica ST Coup rose by only 2%
(it went from $16,968 to $17,285), while the suggested retail price of a large-screen
Sony Trinitron television receiver actually fell by 15%. Japanese exporters simply
absorbed exchange rate changes into their costs. They tended to gain or lose profits
— rather than market share — because of exchange rate changes. In the case of
Toyota Motors, it is estimated that the company’s profit increases by ¥25 billion
($227 million) a year for every ¥1 the currency depreciates against the dollar.19 For
shipments to the United States, economic studies have found that, on average, an
exchange rate change induces a price response equal to one-half the amount, although
it varies by industry.20 An implication of this lack of a complete response of
domestic prices to exchange rate changes is that a currency depreciation will not
necessarily eliminate — or even reduce significantly — a nation’s trade deficit.
Empirical studies indicate, however, that for most countries over the long run,
a real depreciation (adjusting for domestic inflation) is likely to improve a nation’s
current account balance while a real appreciation is likely to worsen it. In the
short-run, however, the opposite is likely to occur. This is called the J-curve effect.
As the value of the yen rises, for example, some Japanese exporters do increase their
prices, and U.S. importers end up paying more for the quantity of goods they need.
This worsens the balance of trade before U.S. importers can switch to other
suppliers.21
Still, Japan’s balance of trade does respond somewhat in the long run to a large
appreciation of the yen. Japanese exporters ultimately have to either raise prices or
decrease costs of production, and importers of commodities in Japan face lower
international prices. This works to reduce Japan’s surplus in trade (exports fall while
imports rise).
18 Goldberg, Pinelopi Koujianou and Michael M. Knetter. Goods Prices and Exchange
Rates: What Have We Learned? Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 35, September 1997.
pp. 1244, 1270.
19 “Toyota Hits Year’s High on Robust Car Sales, Weak Yen.” Nikkei Weekly, August 22,
2005. p. 27.
20 Goldberg, Pinelopi Koujianou and Michael M. Knetter. “Goods Prices and Exchange
Rates: What Have We Learned?” Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 35, September 1997.
pp. 1244, 1270.
21 In order for a real depreciation to improve the current account, exports and imports must
be sufficiently elastic respect to the real exchange rate. This condition holds for most
industrialized countries for trade in manufactured goods in the long run but not in the short
run. Krugman and Obstfeld, International Economics, pp. 450, 468.
CRS-9
One economic study indicated that, in 2002, a 1% appreciation of the yen
induced a 2.2% decrease in Japan’s current account surplus (balance of trade with the
world in goods and services plus unilateral transfers).22 At that time, Japan’s current
account surplus was about $110 billion. Therefore, a 1% yen appreciation was
estimated to decrease Japan’s current account balance by about $2.4 billion. Another
study for 1985-1991 found that a 10% sustained appreciation of the yen would reduce
Japan’s trade surplus by 0.7% of gross national product (GNP).23 At that time,
Japan’s GNP was around $3,000 billion. A 1% appreciation of the yen, therefore,
would have reduced Japan’s trade surplus by about $2.1 billion.
In actuality, from 2002 to 2004, the yen appreciated from ¥120 to ¥104 per
dollar (up by 13%), but Japan’s current account surplus rose (not fell) from $113
billion to $172 billion (up by 52%).24 Part of this rise in Japan’s current account
surplus may have been the J-curve effect, but in this case the yen appreciation was
overshadowed by other variables. Yen appreciation may have slowed the rise in
Japan’s current account surplus, but it did not stop it. Other factors also came into
play. These included growth in the American and other major markets, relative
savings and inflation rates, the level of interest rates in various markets, earnings
from investments, the competitiveness of Japanese products, the price of petroleum,
competition from China, and intra-firm trade between home suppliers and overseas
manufacturing subsidiaries.
Another question is whether Japan’s intervention into foreign exchange markets
raised its rate of growth. Figure 2 shows Japan’s currency intervention in terms of
annual rates of change in its foreign exchange reserves and the yen/dollar exchange
rate. It also shows Japan’s economic growth rate (in real gross domestic product).
The chart indicates that many of the periods of yen appreciation and intervention into
foreign exchange markets to buy dollars also were periods of relatively slower — not
faster — economic growth rates. Except in the late 1970s, Japan’s growth
performance during periods of intervention was rather lackluster. Growth tended to
be higher during periods without intervention, although it can be argued that the
intervention may have helped to keep economic conditions from becoming worse
than they actually were.
22 Cline, William R. The Impact of US External Adjustment on Japan. In Dollar
Overvaluation and the World Economy, ed. by C. Fred Bergsten and John Williamson.
Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC, 2003. Pp. 190-91.
23 Yoshitomi, Masaru. Surprises and Lessons from Japanese External Adjustment in 1985-
91. In International Adjustment and Financing: The Lessons of 1985-1991, ed. by C. Fred
Bergsten, Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC, 1991. Pp. 128-29.
24 Over the 2002-2004 period, differences in rates of inflation would have changed the real
exchange rate and real current account balance somewhat.
CRS-10
Figure 2. Japan’s Currency Intervention, Rates of Growth in Real
Gross National Product, and Annual Changes in the Dollar/Yen
Exchange Rate and Japan’s Foreign Exchange Reserves, 1972-2004
Annual Percent Change
100
100
Inter-
Stronger Yen
vention
80
80
60
60
Inter-
Inter-
GDP Growth Rate
Inter-
vention
vention
vention
40
40
20
20
0
0
-20
-20
Change in Dollars/Yen
-40
-40
Change in Foreign Exchange Reserves
-60
-60
72 73 74 75 76 77 78 791980 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 891990 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 992000 1 2 3 4
Year
Source: Data from World Bank. World Development Indicators
Intervention or Manipulation?
A question for U.S. policy is whether Japan’s intervention into currency markets
constituted manipulation of its exchange rate. Under U.S. law, 25 the Secretary of the
Treasury is required to analyze the exchange rate policies of foreign countries
annually (in consultation with the International Monetary Fund) and consider whether
countries manipulate their exchange rate for purposes of preventing effective balance
of payments adjustment or gaining unfair competitive advantage in international
trade. If the Secretary considers that such manipulation is occurring with respect to
countries that (1) have material global current account surpluses; and (2) have
significant bilateral trade surpluses with the United States, the Secretary of the
Treasury shall take action to initiate negotiations with such foreign countries on an
expedited basis, in the International Monetary Fund or bilaterally, for the purpose of
ensuring that such countries regularly and promptly adjust the rate of exchange
between their currencies and the United States dollar to permit effective balance of
payment adjustments and to eliminate the unfair advantage. The Secretary of the
Treasury also is to provide reports on exchange rate policy that contain the results of
exchange rate negotiations conducted pursuant to this law.
25 22 U.S.C. §5304-5305.
CRS-11
At various periods from 1988 through 1994, Treasury found that China, Taiwan,
and South Korea were each considered to have manipulated their currencies.26 In the
March and November 2005 reports to Congress as required by the Omnibus Trade
and Competitiveness Act of 1988, Treasury indicated that it had reviewed the
exchange rates, external balances, foreign exchange reserve accumulation,
macroeconomic trends, monetary and financial developments, state of institutional
development, and financial and exchange restrictions for U.S. trading partners. In
both reports, Treasury did not find currency manipulation by any country, including
by Japan.27
In April 2005, the Government Accountability Office examined Treasury’s
assessments of whether countries were manipulating their currencies and concluded
that “although China and Japan have engaged in economic activities that have led to
concerns about currency manipulation,” Treasury “did not find that Japan met the
Trade Act’s definition for currency manipulation in 2003 and 2004.” GAO reported
that Treasury viewed “Japan’s exchange rate interventions as part of a
macroeconomic policy aimed at combating deflation....”28
In testimony before the House Ways and Means Committee, Deputy Assistant
Secretary of the Treasury David Loevinge stated that Treasury has discussed foreign
exchange market issues with Japanese officials. Japan has not intervened in the
foreign exchange market since March 2004, and the country has also supported the
G-7 position on exchange rates, expressed in a series of G-7 Communiqués, calling
for greater exchange rate flexibility. Japan also has worked with the United States
to bring about greater exchange rate flexibility in China and in other large economies
in East Asia.29
The International Monetary Fund also conducts surveillance over the exchange
rates of its member countries. A 1977 decision by the Fund (as amended), a principle
for guidance of member’s exchange rate policies states, “A member shall avoid
manipulating exchange rates or the international monetary system in order to prevent
effective balance of payments adjustment or to gain unfair competitive advantage
over other members.” The decision, does allow, however, for governments to
26 Treasury considered the following countries to be manipulating their exchange rates under
22 U.S.C. 5304: Oct 1988 Report — Korea and Taiwan; April 1989 Report — Korea and
Taiwan; October 1989 Report — Korea, May 1992 Report — China and Taiwan; December
1992 Report — China and Taiwan; May 1993 Report — China; November 1993 Report —
China; July 1994 Report — China.
27 U.S. Department of the Treasury. Report to the Committees on Appropriations on
Clarification of Statutory Provisions Addressing Currency Manipulation. Press Release
js2308, May 25, 2005. P. 4. Report to Congress on International Economic and Exchange
Rate Policies, November 2005.
28 United States Government Accountability Office. Treasury Assessments Have Not Found
Currency Manipulation, but Concerns about Exchange Rates Continue. GAO Report GAO-
05-351, April 2005. P. 4.
29 U.S. Department of the Treasury. Testimony of Deputy Assistant Secretary of the
Treasury David Loevinger before the House Ways and Means Committee, JS-2954,
September 28, 2005.
CRS-12
intervene in the exchange market if necessary to counter disorderly conditions
(disruptive short-term movements in the exchange value of its currency).30 In the
IMF’s August 2005 report on consultations with Japan, the Fund did not find
currency manipulation, but noted that compared to the United States and the Euro
Area, Japan stands out for its active use of foreign exchange market intervention as
a policy instrument.31
As a comparison, one can compare the movement of the exchange rate between
the German mark and the dollar with that for the yen and the dollar. Figure 3 shows
the movement of indexes (1972 = 100) for the value of the two exchange rates. From
1972 to 2005, the yen has appreciated more than the mark, and they generally have
moved together. The correlation coefficient between the two indexes is 0.82 (they
move together 82% of the time). This indicates that most of the time both currencies
are responding to the same outside influences.
Figure 3. Indexes of the Value of the Japanese Yen and
German Mark per U.S. Dollar, 1972-2005
Index of Currency Value in $
120
+
100
Stronger Dollar &
Weaker Yen or Mark
80
60
40
Weaker Dollar &
Stronger Yen or Mark
20
Yen
Mark
0
1972 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 2000 2
4 Nov
2005
Year
Note: 1972 = 100. Underlying exchange rates from PACIFIC Exchange Rate Service.
30 International Monetary Fund. Surveillance Over Exchange Rate Policies, Decision No.
5392-(77/63), April 29, 1977 as amended.
31 International Monetary Fund. IMF Country Report No. 05/273, Japan: 2005 Article IV
Consultation — Staff Report; Staff Supplement; and Public Information Notice on the
Executive Board Discussion. August 2005.
CRS-13
Policy Issues
Even though Japan claims that it has not intervened into currency markets since
March 2004, this issue still is a U.S. policy concern because of Tokyo’s past
intervention and the possibility that it could resume intervening should the yen
strengthen too rapidly or excessively against the dollar. Japan also could be caught
up in the concern over China’s currency policy. Policies aimed at China also could
affect Japan. Currently, Tokyo seems content to abstain from active intervention into
international currency markets. At some point, however, Japan may want to decrease
its $830 billion in foreign exchange holdings. It would likely do this by selling
dollar-denominated assets, an action that would weaken the dollar and strengthen the
yen. Depending on how this potential divestiture is conducted, it could be viewed
as intervention into foreign exchange markets.
A question remains, however, of whether the United States should take
measures to compensate for past intervention by Japan. Setting aside the issue of
how much past intervention actually moved the exchange rate and whether any
exchange rate change affected actual market transactions, if U.S. industries were
significantly impacted negatively, should remedial action be taken now? If, for
example, the U.S. automobile industry lost market share because of past Japanese
government attempts to reduce the value of the yen, is there action that should be
taken now to remedy the lost market share?
The major policy options for Congress32 include the following:
! let the market adjust (do nothing);
! clarify the definition of currency manipulation;
! require reports and negotiations;
! require the President to certify which countries are manipulating
their currencies and take remedial action if the manipulation is not
halted; and
! take the case to the World Trade Organization under the dispute
settlement mechanism or appeal to the International Monetary Fund.
Let the Market Adjust (Do Nothing)
Most economists argue that currency markets are so large that only extensive
and coordinated intervention has any lasting effects. Countries that do intervene
often find themselves “leaning against the wind” and not materially altering either the
direction of or the extent of change. Also, intervention is expensive. It is not clear
that Japan could afford to invest another $800 billion in U.S. Treasury securities.
Allowing market forces to determine exchange rates while permitting central banks
32 For analysis of policy with respect to China’s exchange rate, see CRS Issue Brief
IB91121, China-U.S. Trade Issues, by Wayne M. Morrison; CRS Report RL33018, China’s
Currency: U.S. Options, by Jonathan E. Sanford; and CRS Report RS21625, China’s
Currency Peg: A Summary of the Economic Issues, by Wayne M. Morrison and Marc
Labonte.
CRS-14
to intervene only to counter abnormal market shifts is the policy pursued for most
major currencies of the world.
In terms of foreign exchange intervention, Japan differs from China in two
important respects. First, Japan does not peg its exchange rate. It generally
intervenes to slow down rates of change not to maintain a certain exchange rate. It
also does not require citizens to sell foreign exchange to the central bank at an
official rate of exchange. Second, Japan allows for free flows of capital into and out
of the country. This makes currency manipulation much more difficult in Japan,
since speculators and investors can offset official buying and selling of foreign
financial assets.
A currency peg without capital controls is expensive and difficult to maintain
during a financial crisis. During the 1997-1998 Asian financial crisis, for example,
Hong Kong maintained its pegged exchange rate partly by raising domestic interest
rates to attract foreign capital and to retard capital flight by local investors (to reduce
the incentive to convert Hong Kong dollars to U.S. dollars in anticipation of a drop
in the value of the Hong Kong dollar). On October 23, 1997, the overnight rate of
interest in Hong Kong jumped from 6.25% to 100.0% as the monetary authorities
tried to stem the capital outflow. Even though Hong Kong was able to maintain its
exchange rate peg, the high interest rates caused a near collapse of real estate markets
there. This is one reason China still maintains some capital controls.33 Since the
Asian financial crisis, Japan and other Asian nations have negotiated currency swap
agreements to provide short-term sources of foreign exchange in times of crisis.34
This obviates, somewhat, the need to rely on interest rates to attract foreign capital.
Under a policy of allowing market forces to determine exchange rates, some
intervention still may be necessary to calm excessive volatility in markets or to
counter trends that overshoot because of herd mentality and other effects. In the past,
the more successful of such interventions were coordinated among the large,
industrialized nations.
33 For financial data, see Global Financial Data at [http://www.globalfinancialdata.com].
34 This is called the Chiang Mai Initiative. See Seok-Dong Wang and Lene Andersen.
“Regional Financial Cooperation in East Asia: the Chiang Mai Initiative and Beyond,”
UNESCAP Bulletin on Asia-Pacific Perspectives 2002/03, Chapter 8.
CRS-15
Clarify the Definition of Currency Manipulation
A major provision of the various currency bills in the 109th Congress is to clarify
the definition of currency manipulation. While the legislation is aimed primarily at
China’s currency policy, in cases, it also cites Japan (and South Korea) in the
findings. S. 377 (Lieberman), for example, states that “experts estimate that the yen
is undervalued by approximately 20 percent or more, giving Japanese manufacturers
a significant price advantage over United States competitors.”
Selected Legislation in the 109th Congress
H.R. 1498 (Tim Ryan) Chinese Currency Act of 2005.
H.R. 2414 (Mike Rogers) Currency Rate Adjustment and Trade Enforcement
Act.
H.R. 3283 (English) U.S. Trade Rights Enforcement Act. Passed/agreed to in
House: 255 - 168 (July 27,2005).
S. 377 (Lieberman) Fair Currency Enforcement Act of 2005.
S. 295, S.Amdt.309 (Schumer) To authorize appropriate action if negotiations
regarding China’s undervalued currency are not successful. Motion to table
amendment SA 309 rejected in Senate by Yea-Nay Vote. 33-67 (April 6,
2005).
S. 14 (Stabenow) Fair Wage, Competition, and Investment Act of 2005.
S. 1421 (Collins) United States Trade Rights Enforcement Act.
Currently, the Department of the Treasury, in consultation with the International
Monetary Fund, determines each year whether countries are manipulating their
exchange rate for purposes of gaining an unfair trade advantage or preventing
effective balance of payments adjustments and also have a material global current
account surplus and a significant bilateral trade surplus with the United States.35
In the 109th Congress, H.R. 1498 defines exchange-rate manipulation as
“protracted large-scale intervention by an authority to undervalue its currency in the
exchange market that prevents effective balance-of-payments adjustment or that
gains an unfair competitive advantage over any other country.” In determining
whether exchange-rate manipulation is occurring, the administering authority is to
consider the exporting country’s:
! bilateral balance of trade surplus or deficit with the United States,
! balance of trade surplus or deficit with other trading partners,
! foreign direct investment in its territory,
35 Omnibus Trade and Competitiveness Act of 1988, 22 U.S.C. § 5304(b), § 3004(b) . The
global current account surplus is the current account surplus of merchandise, services, and
transfers with all other countries, while the bilateral trade surplus is the surplus in goods and
services trade with one trading partner country only.
CRS-16
! currency specific and aggregate amounts of foreign currency
reserves, and
! mechanisms employed to maintain its currency at a fixed exchange
rate and the nature, duration, and monetary expenditures of those
mechanisms.
The bill also specifies that trade data are to be those of the United States and other
trading partners of the exporting country, unless such trade data are not available or
are demonstrably inaccurate, in which case the exporting country’s trade data may
be relied upon if shown to be sufficiently accurate and trustworthy.
S. 377 defines currency manipulation in three parts to mean:
! large-scale manipulation of exchange rates by a nation in order to
gain an unfair competitive advantage as stated in Article IV of the
Articles of Agreement of the International Monetary Fund and
related surveillance provisions,
! sustained, large-scale currency intervention in one direction, through
mandatory foreign exchange sales at a nation’s central bank at a
fixed exchange rate, or
! other mechanisms used to maintain a currency at a fixed exchange
rate relative to another currency.
These bills would provide further specificity to the definition of currency
manipulation. The criteria identified are those that usually are examined when
Treasury and the IMF determine whether or not a country is manipulating its
exchange rate, but the bills focus the criteria on intervention, the type of foreign
exchange regime (fixed rate), and the source of data.
Bills (such as S.Amdt.309 to S. 600) would focus the criteria for determining
currency manipulation on the existence of large-scale intervention for the purpose of
gaining an unfair advantage in international trade. Under IMF surveillance
guidelines, such intervention is not necessarily considered to be manipulation, but it
may trigger discussions between the IMF and the member country involved.
The bills also would define intervention in terms of government purchases of
foreign exchange in order to support certain types of foreign exchange regimes,
particularly fixed or pegged rates of exchange. Under IMF rules, a country is
permitted to maintain a fixed (or pegged) exchange rate.36 Economies, such as Hong
Kong and Malaysia, also peg their exchange rates. For the IMF, the currency regime,
per se, is not the issue. The issue, however, is whether the pegged rate does not
reflect market conditions and whether large-scale intervention is required to maintain
it. In Japan’s case, it has intervened massively even though its exchange rate is
floating.
36 International Monetary Fund. Articles of Agreement, Article IV — Obligations
Regarding Exchange Arrangements.
CRS-17
As for the source of data when considering a country’s trade balance, S. 377
requires U.S. data to be used to determine the exporting country’s bilateral balance
of trade with the United States. For the exporting country’s global current account
deficit or surplus, however, the bill would rely on U.S. and other partner country data
first and the exporting country’s own data second.
The issue of which data to use applies primarily to China, mainly because of
imports and exports that flow through, but do not originate in, Hong Kong and the
general lack of confidence in China’s system for compiling statistics and reporting
them. The data problem, however, also arises with Japan. In 2004 for Japan,
Japanese data (as accessed through the IMF or Global Trade Atlas37) reported a
merchandise trade surplus of $110 billion (2.4% of GDP), but a compilation of
partner country data (statistics from countries that export to and import from Japan)
showed a surplus for that year of $208 billion (4.5% of GDP).38
Each bill places more emphasis on large-scale intervention by a country into
currency markets — particularly when evidenced by large accumulations of foreign
exchange. Such accumulations of dollars, do not constitute prima facie evidence of
currency manipulation, but they would be used along with other criteria to determine
whether a country has been engaged in it.
The bills do not address the issue of sterilization in currency intervention.39 In
2003 and 2004, Treasury found that Japan did not meet the criteria for currency
manipulation in part because its exchange rate interventions were considered to be
part of a macroeconomic policy to combat deflation.40 (It was considered to be
unsterilized intervention to increase the money supply.) A policy question is whether
large-scale interventions are justified when part of macroeconomic policy even
though they may have adverse affects on exchange markets.
37 The Japanese government reports trade data in yen values. They convert those data into
dollars when reporting them to the IMF. Global Trade Atlas is a propriety database of trade
statistics.
38 Data from International Monetary Fund. Direction of Trade Statistics. September 2005.
For 2004, China reported a merchandise trade surplus of $32 billion, but the exports and
imports of trading partners implied a trade surplus of $314 billion. The IMF notes that data
reported by exporting and importing countries can be inconsistent because of differences in
country of origin or destination classification concepts, lack of destination detail, time of
recording, valuation, coverage, and processing errors.
39 Sterilized intervention refers, in the government of Japan’s case, to the buying of dollars
(or other foreign exchange) from Japanese holders and using those dollars to buy dollar-
denominated securities in the United States while simultaneously selling yen-denominated
securities in Japan to keep the domestic money supply unchanged.
40 United States Government Accountability Office. Treasury Assessments Have Not Found
Currency Manipulation, but Concerns about Exchange Rates Continue. GAO Report
GAO-05-351, April 2005. p. 4.
CRS-18
Require Negotiations and Reports
Current trade law requires the President to seek to confer and negotiate with
other countries to achieve:
! more appropriate and sustainable levels of trade and current account
balances and exchange rates of the dollar and other currencies
consistent with such balances; and
! improvement in the functioning of the exchange rate system to
provide for long-term exchange rate stability consistent with more
appropriate and sustainable current account balances.41
The United States and Japan also conduct regular cabinet and sub-cabinet
meetings that provide a venue to discuss exchange rates. In addition, the two
countries meet in G-7 summits and at the APEC (Asia Pacific economic cooperation)
meetings where currency and exchange rate policy is discussed.42 In a 2000 G-7
meeting, for example, the communique stated that the group had discussed
developments in exchange and financial markets and said that they welcomed the
reaffirmation by the Japanese monetary authorities that exchange rate policies would
be conducted appropriately in view of their potential impact and that they would
continue to monitor developments in exchange markets and cooperate as
appropriate.43
Some bills call for the Treasury Secretary to seek to convene a multilateral
summit with G-7 nations, Asian governments, and other interested parties to discuss
exchange rates (S.Amdt. 309 to S. 600, S. 14, S. 295).
The bills also include various reporting requirements by either the Secretary of
the Treasury, International Trade Commission, or Secretary of Defense. Treasury
would provide annual reports that define currency manipulation; describe actions of
foreign countries considered to be currency manipulation; and describe how to clarify
statutory provisions addressing currency manipulation by trading partners and
relevant U.S. law (H.R. 3283, S. 1421). The International Trade Commission would
report on how currency manipulation affects U.S. manufacturers, trade levels, interest
rates, and public debt financing, and determine all available mechanisms for redress
under U.S. trade laws and international trade treaties and agreements (S. 377). The
Secretary of Defense would provide a detailed report to Congress evaluating the
effects on U.S. national security of countries engaging in significant currency
manipulation and the effect of such manipulation on critical manufacturing sectors
(S. 377).
41 22 U.S.C. § 5304
42 See, for example: U.S. Department of the Treasury. Statement of G-7 Finance Ministers
and Central Bank Governors. September 25, 1999. Washington, DC.
43 Statement of G-7 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors. January 22, 2000.
Tokyo, Japan.
CRS-19
Certify Currency Manipulation and Take Remedial Action
Several of the currency bills in the 109th Congress would require the President
to certify which countries are engaging in currency manipulation (defined in S. 295
to be “acquiring foreign exchange reserves to prevent the appreciation of the rate of
exchange between its currency and the U.S. dollar”) for purposes of gaining an unfair
competitive advantage in international trade.44 This certification would then trigger
certain remedial actions under U.S. trade law.
Under current law, the Secretary of the Treasury (and International Monetary
Fund) determines whether a country is manipulating its exchange rate. A presidential
certification arguably raises the profile of the process and could require more detailed
procedures on how the certification is made.
S. 295 (Schumer) and S.Amdt. 309 (Schumer) to S. 600, would impose a 27.5%
tariff on Chinese goods if the President could not certify that it is not manipulating
its currency to gain an unfair trade advantage and if China failed to appreciate its
currency to market levels. S. 377 would require the President to begin negotiations
for a 90-day period after enactment with nations engaged in currency manipulation.
Meanwhile, in S. 377 the International Trade Commission would ascertain and
quantify the results of that manipulation on U.S. manufacturers and trade levels. If
agreements are not reached, the President would institute proceedings under U.S. and
international trade laws — including sections 301 (unfair trade practices) and 40645
(trade with communist countries) of the Trade Act of 1974 — with respect to those
countries that based on the ITC findings, continue to engage in the most egregious
currency manipulation.
One currency bill aimed at China (H.R. 2414) would require that the Secretary
of the Treasury determine the percentage rate of undervaluation of the Chinese
currency and that the President seek to impose tariffs to offset the subsidy inherent
in the undervalued currency through the dispute settlement mechanism of the World
Trade Organization.46 Under H.R. 2414, the President also would take measures to
offset the disadvantage resulting from such undervaluation to exports of U.S. goods
and services to the PRC. Whether such measures would include an export subsidy
is not specified in the bill.
Under current law, the Secretary of the Treasury (and International Monetary
Fund) determines whether a country is manipulating its exchange rate. A presidential
44 The certification also can be that a country is not engaged in currency manipulation.
45 Under section 406 of the Trade Act of 1974, the Commission determines whether imports
from a Communist country are causing market disruption in the United States. Section 406
investigations are similar procedurally to Commission investigations under section 201 of
the Trade Act of 1974. If the Commission finds market disruption, it then makes a remedy
recommendation to the President. The President makes the final decision with respect to
remedy. (19 U.S.C. §2436)
46 International Monetary Fund. Guidelines/Framework for Fund Staff Collaboration with
the World Trade Organization, April 21, 1995. Selected Decisions and Selected Documents
of the International Monetary Fund, 24th Issue, June 30, 1999. pp. 552-559.
CRS-20
certification arguably raises the profile of the process and could require more detailed
procedures on how the certification is made.
Appeal to the WTO or IMF
Some of the currency bills in the 109th Congress call for taking the currency
manipulation case to the World Trade Organization through its dispute settlement
mechanism or to the International Monetary Fund.
Currently, an agreement between the IMF and WTO requires the WTO to refer
exchange rate disputes to the IMF and accept the IMF’s findings as conclusive. If the
IMF finds currency manipulation, it is not clear how a WTO dispute settlement panel
would rule. There is no precedent for a case in which currency manipulation is
considered to have the effect of an export subsidy and allows for direct retaliation
against the exports of the offending country.
Even though the IMF did not find that Japan was manipulating its currency
during its 2005 Article IV consultations, the United States could inform the IMF that
it believes Japan is not complying with the requirements of Article IV. This would
trigger consultations with Tokyo and a report by the Managing Director to the IMF’s
executive board.47 While the IMF still might not find Japan guilty of currency
manipulation, it would put pressure on the Bank of Japan not to intervene in currency
markets in the future.
47 For detail, see CRS Report RL33018, China’s Currency: U.S. Options, by Jonathan E.
Sanford.
CRS-21
Appendix
Table 1. Japan’s GDP Growth Rate, Yen/Dollar Exchange Rate,
and Foreign Exchange Reserves, 1970-2004
GDP
Foreign Exchange
Year
Growth Rate (%)
Exchange Rate
Reserves (US$)
1970
10.7
360.0
4,307,530,000
1971
4.7
350.7
14,621,900,000
1972
8.4
303.2
17,563,610,000
1973
8.0
271.7
11,354,560,000
1974
-1.2
292.1
12,614,290,000
1975
3.1
296.8
11,950,210,000
1976
4.0
296.6
15,746,250,000
1977
4.4
268.5
22,340,960,000
1978
5.3
210.4
32,407,240,000
1979
5.5
219.1
19,521,520,000
1980
2.8
226.7
24,636,450,000
1981
2.9
220.5
28,208,420,000
1982
2.8
249.1
23,333,970,000
1983
1.6
237.5
24,601,580,000
1984
3.1
237.5
26,429,150,000
1985
5.1
238.5
26,718,650,000
1986
3.0
168.5
42,256,600,000
1987
3.8
144.6
80,972,870,000
1988
6.8
128.2
96,728,190,000
1989
5.3
138.0
83,957,350,000
1990
5.2
144.8
78,500,590,000
1991
3.4
134.7
72,058,840,000
1992
1.0
126.7
71,622,670,000
1993
0.2
111.2
98,524,340,000
1994
1.1
102.2
125,860,200,000
1995
1.9
94.1
183,249,800,000
1996
3.4
108.8
216,648,000,000
1997
1.9
121.0
219,648,300,000
1998
-1.1
130.9
215,470,700,000
1999
0.1
113.9
286,916,100,000
2000
2.8
107.8
354,902,100,000
2001
0.4
121.5
395,155,000,000
2002
-0.4
125.4
461,185,600,000
2003
1.4
115.9
663,289,100,000
2004
2.7
103.8
833,891,000,000
Oct. 2005
2.4
114.9
830,211,000,000
Source: International Monetary Fund.
Note: The growth rate is the annual change in real gross domestic product. The exchange rate is yen
per U.S. dollar, period average. Foreign exchange Reserves are official reserves excluding gold