Order Code RS22232
August 29, 2005
CRS Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
The Government’s Long-Term Fiscal
Shortfall: How Much Is Attributable to
Social Security?
Marc Labonte
Specialist in Macroeconomics
Government and Finance Division
Summary
One reason that Social Security reform is on the congressional agenda is the large
projected long-term fiscal shortfall facing Social Security, estimated at an average of
0.9% of gross domestic product (GDP) between now and 2080. But relatively little
attention has been given to the potential long-term shortfall faced by the rest of the
government, which is estimated to be more than 6.5 times larger than Social Security’s
shortfall. The government’s overall fiscal gap under an extension of current policy,
estimated at an average of 7.2% of GDP between now and 2080, is the result of the large
projected increase in future spending that is not matched by any projected increase in tax
revenue. Most of the increase in spending occurs in Medicare and Medicaid; Social
Security is the third largest contributor to the fiscal gap. If viewed from the revenue
side, the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts increased the fiscal gap by an average of 2.2% of GDP
between now and 2080. The fiscal gap measure may be useful to policymakers because
it highlights the unsustainability of current policy in the long term and the potential cost
of inaction, and it provides a measure that can be used to estimate the implications of
current policy for the macroeconomy and generational equity. This report will be
updated when new data become available.
One rationale given for Social Security reform is the large long-term fiscal shortfall
that Social Security is projected to face. In particular, observers point to the 75-year
shortfall faced by the Social Security trust fund, which amounts to a present value
(defined below) of $4.3 trillion according to official estimates.
While this amount is unquestionably large, the government’s ability to close that
shortfall under current policy depends on the fiscal position of non-Social Security
spending and revenues. If the rest of the budget were in surplus, then revenues could be
transferred from the rest of the budget to finance promised Social Security benefits
without raising taxes or cutting spending on Social Security. However, if the rest of the
government were in deficit, then there would be no general revenues to transfer to Social
Security to finance the benefits promised to retirees, without policy changes that improved
the government’s overall fiscal position.
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress
CRS-2
Thus, to determine whether the government will have the means to compensate for
Social Security’s fiscal shortfall and honor promised benefits, one needs to look at the
government’s overall fiscal position. There is no official estimate of the government’s
overall fiscal shortfall, or “fiscal gap”; there have been two recent unofficial estimates,
however, that reached similar conclusions. According to the more detailed estimate, the
government’s overall fiscal gap to 2080 equals an annual average of 7.2% of GDP or a
sum of $36.3 trillion in present value terms, as seen in Figure 1, under an extension of
current policy.1 In this estimate, Social Security accounts for $4.7 trillion of the fiscal gap
to 2080, and the rest of the government accounts for $31.6 trillion of the gap. In other
words, the projected fiscal gap facing the rest of the government is more than 6.5 times
larger than the one facing Social Security.
Figure 1: Fiscal Gap by Source, 2004-2080
Rest of
6.3
31.6
Government
Social Security
0.9
4.7
% of GDP
trillions of $ (PV)
Source: Auerbach, Gale, and Orszag, 2004
Note: PV = present value, GDP = gross domestic product. See text for details
The fiscal gap measures in present discounted value terms the cumulative excess of
future spending over future revenues plus the current national debt. To keep the national
debt from rising as a share of GDP until 2080, taxes would need to be immediately raised
or spending immediately cut by 7.2% of GDP — far greater than the changes required to
1 Alan Auerbach, William Gale, and Peter Orszag, “Sources of the Long-Term Fiscal Gap,” Tax
Notes, May 24, 2004, p. 1049 unless otherwise noted. Similar results can be found in Jagdeesh
Gokhale and Kent Smetters, Fiscal and Generational Imbalances (Washington, DC: AEI Press,
2003). CBO presented Gokhale and Smetters’ results in Congressional Budget Office, Measures
of the U.S. Government’s Fiscal Position Under Current Law, Aug. 2004, but presented data only
over an infinite horizon.
Please note that Auerbach et al. $4.7 trillion projection of Social Security’s 75-year shortfall is
similar to, but slightly larger than, the Social Security Trustees’ official projection ($4.3 trillion).
The sources of the difference include Auerbach using a longer time period (2004-2080 vs. 2005-
2079), different forecasting assumptions, and older data. Since the official estimate is based on
different assumptions, however, it cannot be compared to Auerbach et al. estimate of the overall
fiscal gap.
CRS-3
balance the FY2006 budget because the budget deficit is forecast to grow significantly
from present levels under an extension of current policy.2
The fiscal gap, like budget deficits in general, can be eliminated only through higher
taxes or lower spending. There is no objective way to assign the source of the fiscal gap
to excessive spending or inadequate taxation. By definition, the fiscal gap is caused by
spending exceeding taxation. Whether this means that spending should be lower or taxes
higher is a value judgment. But, in the discussion below, the reader should keep in mind
that future deficits are not growing because spending rises under current policy. Rather,
future deficits grow because revenues are not projected to rise along with spending.
Fiscal gap calculations are made in present value terms because a $1 deficit today
cannot be meaningfully compared to a $1 deficit in 50 years. Present discounted value
calculations adjust for the fact that a dollar borrowed today would grow because of
compound interest. If a dollar were borrowed today at, say, a 3% real rate of interest, it
would grow to $4.38 in 50 years. In this example, the fiscal gap could be reduced by $1
by instituting a one-time tax increase or spending cut equal to $1 today or by instituting
a one-time tax or spending cut equal to $4.38 (in real terms) 50 years from now. Thus,
the tax increases or benefit cuts needed to eliminate the fiscal gap are smaller if taken now
rather than in the future. A failure to adjust future sums into present value terms
overstates the contributions of future financial flows relative to present flows. (If future
deficits were not discounted, as 5-year and 10-year budget totals are usually presented,
then the fiscal gap would be much larger than $36.3 trillion.)3
For example, Social Security’s annual deficits in 75 years are large, equal to about
2% of GDP. But Social Security is currently in surplus, and will remain so until 2018.
Therefore, Social Security reduces the fiscal gap in the short run, and its overall
contribution to the fiscal gap is relatively small (0.9% of GDP) once its distant deficits
are discounted to the present. By contrast, budget deficits today outside of Social Security
will compound under current policy and become very large in the distant future. The
budget deficit outside of Social Security in 2004 was 4.9% of GDP, more than twice as
large as Social Security’s deficit at its 75-year peak. The policy changes that moved the
2 Auerbach et al. use an adjusted version of CBO’s baseline as the basis of their projection. It
differs from CBO over the first 10 years of the projection by assuming that the 2001 and 2003
tax cuts will be extended, tax extenders that are routinely renewed will not expire, alternative
minimum tax (AMT) reform will not be allowed to expire, and discretionary spending will keep
pace with population growth. After the first 10 years, they use the trustees’ projections for
Medicare and Social Security, and CBO’s projections for Medicaid. They assume that
discretionary spending, other entitlement spending, and income tax revenue will stay constant as
a percentage of GDP. For more information on the CBO baseline, see CRS Report RL31414,
Baseline Budget Projections: A Discussion of Issues, by Marc Labonte.
3 Some economists argue that the fiscal gap should be measured over an infinite horizon rather
than 75 years. The main drawback to the 75-year period is that even if the fiscal gap were
eliminated, it would reappear in the 76th year. The main drawback to using an infinite horizon
is that the longer the projection window, the larger the uncertainty and errors in the projection
will be. If an infinite horizon is used, the fiscal gap increases to 10.5% of GDP or $85.5 trillion
in present value terms. In any case, the results are qualitatively similar under either time horizon:
the bulk of the gap is due to increases in spending on Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid.
CRS-4
budget from surplus to deficit in the past four years have increased the fiscal gap by more
than Social Security’s total contribution to the fiscal gap.
Measuring the Fiscal Gap on the Spending Side. Because Social Security
is intended to be entirely self-financed, it is the only program that can be assigned a
portion of the government’s fiscal gap in a straightforward manner. Although the same
sort of straightforward comparison of spending and revenue could be made for Medicare
Part A, it could not be made for Medicare Parts B, C, or D since they were designed to
rely heavily on general revenues. Most other spending programs receive general revenue.
Since most other programs do not receive specific revenue streams, there is no way to
compare projections of any other program’s spending to its revenue.
Therefore, if one is interested in breaking the sources of the fiscal gap down by
spending programs, one must make a somewhat arbitrary assumption about how much
general revenue to dedicate to each program. In one scenario, Auerbach et al. assume that
each program continues to receive its current fraction of general revenue for the next 75
years. In other words, they assume that each program’s share of the revenue “pie” in the
future is determined by its share of the pie today. This assumption means that spending
programs that grow relative to other programs in the future, such as Medicare and
Medicaid, will be assigned higher portions of the fiscal gap than if some other assumption
were made. (Estimates of the fiscal gap under other assumptions can be found in their
article.) Medicare and Medicaid spending are projected to increase from 3.8% of GDP
in 2004 to 16.7% of GDP in 2080. This increase is driven by the aging of the population
and the assumption that health care spending will continue to grow as a share of GDP.
Table 1 shows that the rapid projected growth in future Medicare and Medicaid spending
— which are not matched by any corresponding increase in revenues under current policy
— are responsible for most of the fiscal gap by this measure. Similar results were found
in another recent estimate of the fiscal gap published by AEI Press.4
Table 1. Fiscal Gap by Spending Program, 2004-2080
Present Value
% of GDP
(trillions of $)
Social Security
0.9%
$4.7
Medicare
4.1
20.5
Medicaid
1.7
8.4
Other Entitlement Spending
-0.1
-0.6
Defense and Homeland Security Discretionary Spending
0.3
1.7
Non-Defense, Non-Homeland Security Discretionary
0.3
1.5
Spending
Total
7.2%
$36.3
Source: Auerbach, Gale, and Orszag, 2004
Note: See the text for a discussion of how the estimates were calculated.
4 Jagdeesh Gokhale and Kent Smetters, Fiscal and Generational Imbalances (Washington, DC:
AEI Press, 2003).
CRS-5
Discretionary spending makes a small contribution to the fiscal gap, about two-thirds
as much as Social Security’s contribution. However, discretionary spending is assumed
to fall to relatively low levels by historical standards in this projection. If, instead, it
remained at its current share of GDP, both the fiscal gap and discretionary spending’s
contribution to the fiscal gap would be greater. Other entitlement spending (e.g.,
unemployment insurance) reduces the gap because it is projected to be lower than its
current share of revenue in the future.
Measuring the Fiscal Gap on the Revenue Side. As discussed above, the
fiscal gap is not the result of spending or revenue policy decisions in isolation, but rather
represents the shortfall under current policy of past and projected future revenue relative
to past and projected future spending. Table 1 illustrates the contribution of various
spending programs to the fiscal gap given current revenue policy. One would also like
to be able to see the opposite: the contribution of different revenue decisions given current
spending policy.
The major policy change affecting revenue in the past few years has been the 2001
tax cuts (P.L.107-16), which were expanded and accelerated in 2003 (P.L.108-27).
Assuming that the tax cuts are not allowed to sunset, Auerbach et al. have estimated that
the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts have increased the 75-year fiscal gap by an average of 2.2%
of GDP or a total of $10.9 trillion in present value terms.5 This equals nearly one-third
of the total fiscal gap, and is larger than the contribution of any single spending category
except Medicare to the fiscal gap. The authors estimate that total spending would need
to be immediately reduced by 9% to cancel out the effects of the tax cuts on the fiscal gap.
Why Is the Fiscal Gap Important?
Thus far, this report has presented data on the size of the fiscal gap and its causes.
But why is it important to Congress? This section discusses four reasons.6
The Sustainability of Current Policy. Estimates of the fiscal gap suggest that
budget deficits would need to be reduced by 7.2% of GDP annually between now and
2080 to keep the national debt stable as a share of GDP. Deficits at the end of the
projection will be even larger than the 75-year average. Financing deficits this large on
an ongoing basis would be unprecedented and lead to a continually rising national debt.
If current policy were not altered, at some point, creditors would likely conclude that they
could not reasonably expect the government to honor its debt and refuse to continue
financing the deficit. This would disrupt government operations, and lead to serious
economic and financial disruptions. The fiscal gap highlights this danger, while current
year deficits, or even 10-year deficit projections, do not.
Macroeconomic Effects. Even if long-term budget deficits prove to be smaller
than expected because of projection errors or policy changes, large budget deficits would
5 This estimate assumes that the AMT has been reformed, but does not assign the cost of AMT
reform to the tax cuts, even though interaction between the AMT and the tax cuts raise the cost
of AMT reform.
6 These issues are analyzed in greater depth in CRS Report RL32747, Social Security and
Medicare: The Economic Implications of Current Policy, by Marc Labonte.
CRS-6
still have a negative effect on economic growth. Private capital investment spending must
be financed out of national saving or foreign borrowing. National saving consists of
household saving, business saving, and government saving; when the government runs
a budget deficit, it has a negative saving rate. In the case of no foreign borrowing, the
budget deficit is said to “crowd out” private investment because it is financed out of
private saving that is diverted from financing private investment. Since interest rates are
determined by the supply of national saving and investment demand, budget deficits raise
interest rates, all else equal. Private investment is a source of economic growth; if budget
deficits crowd out private investment, then the future size of the economy will be smaller
and future living standards will be lower than they otherwise would have been.7
To the extent that shortfalls in national saving can be financed through foreign
borrowing, interest rates will not rise and private investment will not be crowded out. But
foreign borrowing comes to the United States in the form of a trade deficit: Americans
can borrow abroad only if they import more than they export. While foreign borrowing
is one factor that appears to have prevented the budget deficit from pushing up interest
rates at present, it is highly unlikely that the United States could borrow enough abroad
to prevent long-term crowding out of private investment under current policy.
Reforming Now vs. Later. The fiscal gap highlights the advantage of reforming
current policy now, rather than waiting until budget deficits become unsustainably large.
Because of the power of compound interest, spending cuts or tax increases that reduce the
budget deficit today would reduce the fiscal gap more than if the same spending cuts or
tax increases were implemented in the future. That is because reductions in the budget
deficit would reduce interest payments on the national debt, which compound to further
reduce future deficits from what they otherwise would be. By contrast, if no action is
taken, the current trajectory of deficits will lead to a larger national debt, and higher
interest payments which will compound to increase future deficits further. For example,
Auerbach et al. estimate that if no action is taken between now and 2014, the fiscal gap
will increase by another 1.1 percentage points of GDP.
Generational Equity. The fiscal gap measure also highlights the generational
equity issues inherent in current policy. While an unsustainably large fiscal gap may have
little effect on economic outcomes today, it portends significant reductions in economic
output in the long-term future. Budget deficits allow current generations to consume
more than they otherwise would by borrowing against national saving to finance
spending. This implies that consumption is in effect being transferred from future
generations (since they will consume out of a smaller economy) to current generations
under current policy. To compound the generational transfer, the “pay-as-you-go” nature
of elderly entitlement spending means that if entitlement spending as a share of GDP
increases as current policy dictates, it would be financed through higher taxes on future
workers. As a result of these two factors, current policy makes current generations better
off and future generations worse off than if there were no fiscal gap.
Equity questions can be identified but not resolved by economic analysis — only the
political process can determine whether it is “fair” to transfer consumption from future
generations to current generations.
7 See CRS Report RL31325, The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit, by Brian Cashell.