Order Code RL32076
CRS Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
The Bayh-Dole Act:
Selected Issues in Patent Policy
and the Commercialization of Technology
Updated June 10, 2005
Wendy H. Schacht
Specialist in Science and Technology
Resources, Science, and Industry Division
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

The Bayh-Dole Act: Selected Issues in Patent Policy
and the Commercialization of Technology
Summary
Congressional interest in facilitating U.S. technological innovation led to the
passage of P.L. 96-517, Amendments to the Patent and Trademark Act (commonly
referred to as the Bayh-Dole Act after its two main sponsors). The act grants patent
rights to inventions arising out of government- sponsored research and development
(R&D) to certain types of entities with the expressed purpose of encouraging the
commercialization of new technologies through cooperative ventures between and
among the research community, small business, and industry.
Patents provide an economic incentive for companies to pursue further
development and commercialization. Studies have shown that research funding
accounts for approximately one-quarter of the costs associated with bringing a new
product to market. Patent ownership is seen as a way to encourage the additional,
and often substantial investment necessary for generating new goods and services.
In an academic setting, the possession of title to inventions is expected to provide
motivation for the university to license the technology to the private sector for
commercialization in expectation of royalty payments.
The Bayh-Dole Act has been seen as particularly successful in meeting its
objectives. However, while the legislation provides a general framework to promote
expanded utilization of the results of federally funded research and development,
questions are being raised as to the adequacy of current arrangements. Most agree
that closer cooperation among industry, government, and academia can augment
funding sources (both in the private and public sectors), increase technology transfer,
stimulate more innovation (beyond invention), lead to new products and processes,
and expand markets. However, others point out that collaboration may provide an
increased opportunity for conflict of interest, redirection of research, less openness
in sharing of scientific discovery, and a greater emphasis on applied rather than basic
research. Additional concerns have been expressed, particularly in relation to the
pharmaceutical and biotechnology industries, that the government and the public are
not receiving benefits commensurate with the federal contribution to the initial
research and development.
Actual experience and cited studies point to the conclusion that companies
which do not control the results of their investments – either through ownership of
patent title, exclusive license, or pricing decisions – tend to be less likely to engage
in related R&D. The importance of control over intellectual property is reinforced
by the positive effect P.L. 96-517 has had on the emergence of new technologies and
techniques generated by U.S. companies.
This report will be updated as events warrant.


Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
An Historical Perspective . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
The Rationale . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
The Patent System: A Brief Overview . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
University-Industry Cooperation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
Small Business . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
Bayh-Dole and Related Law . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
Provisions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
Implementation and Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
Current Issues and Concerns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
Recoupment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
Government Rights: Royalty Free Licenses and Reporting
Requirements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
University Research . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
Biotechnology and Pharmaceuticals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
Concluding Observations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23

The Bayh-Dole Act: Selected Issues in
Patent Policy and the Commercialization of
Technology
Introduction
Congressional interest in facilitating U.S. technological innovation led to the
passage of P.L. 96-517, Amendments to the Patent and Trademark Act, commonly
referred to as the “Bayh-Dole Act” after its two main sponsors former Senators
Robert Dole and Birch Bayh. Under this 1980 law, as amened, title to inventions
made with government support is provided to the contractor if that contractor is a
small business, a university, or other non-profit institution. The legislation is
intended to use patent ownership as an incentive for private sector development and
commercialization of federally funded research and development (R&D). As a
response to congressional efforts to create a unified government patent policy
pertaining to inventions made with federal support, the Bayh-Dole Act promotes
cooperative activities among academia, small business, and industry leading to new
products and processes for the marketplace.
This paper discusses the rationale behind the passage of P.L. 96-517, its
provisions, and implementation of the law. Observers generally agree that the Bayh-
Dole Act has successfully met its objectives. However, some experts argue that the
issues associated with the law’s patent policies should be revisited given the current
R&D environment. Much of the renewed interest is a result of the legislation’s effect
on the biotechnology and pharmaceutical industries where critics assert that the
private sector is receiving benefits to the detriment of the public interest. Other
analysts, particularly in the defense arena, maintain that the existing rights
maintained by the government are too restrictive and prevent industry from meeting
national needs. Many of these issues and concerns are similar, if not identical to
those addressed during the 15 to 20 years of deliberation prior to enactment of the
law. These too will be explored to provide a context for current discussions.
An Historical Perspective
The Rationale
In the late 1970s, the United States Congress was involved in a series of
legislative debates over ways to promote private sector development and utilization
of federally funded research and development. This was soon followed by expanded
congressional interest in additional means to foster technological advancement and
commercialization in industry. During the 1980s and 1990s, various initiatives

CRS-2
resulted in laws designed to encourage increased innovation-related activities in the
business community and to remove barriers to technology development, thereby
permitting market forces to operate.1 Laws promoting cooperative R&D and/or joint
ventures involving the federal government, industry, and academia have been a
cornerstone of the majority of these efforts and include legislation that created a
system to transfer technology from federal laboratories to the private sector;
implemented tax incentives for collaborative work; instituted direct and indirect
government support for increased R&D; and changed government patent policy to
provide an economic inducement for commercialization of federally funded
technology, the subject of this report.
P.L. 96-517, the Bayh-Dole Act, was one of the first of these initiatives. Prior
to 1980, only 5% of government owned patents were ever used in the private sector
although a portion of the intellectual property portfolio had potential for further
development, application, and marketing. The Bayh-Dole Act was developed, in
part, to address the low utilization rate of these federal patents. The House report to
accompany H.R. 6933 (the House counterpart to the Senate bill that eventually
became the Bayh-Dole Act) noted that, at the time the bill was considered, 26
different agency policies existed regarding the use of the results of federally funded
R&D. Generally the government retained title to inventions made with government
support whether the research was performed in federal laboratories, in universities,
or by individual companies. Licenses to use the government patents were then
negotiated with firms either on a non-exclusive basis (meaning additional companies
could use the technology) or, more rarely, for the exclusive use by one manufacturer.
However, it was widely argued that without title (or at least an exclusive license) to
an invention and the protection it conveys, a company would not invest the
additional, and substantial time and money necessary to commercialize a product or
process for the marketplace.
In 1980, the federal expenditures for research and development totaled $62.6
billion ($52.7 billion in constant 1998 dollars).2 The money typically was used to
support research and development to meet the mission requirements of the federal
departments and agencies (e.g., defense, public health, environmental quality) or to
finance work in areas where there was an identified need for research, primarily basic
research, not being performed in the private sector. While the government’s
investment led to many new inventions that have profoundly influenced our society,
many in Congress were of the opinion that additional applications could be pursued
by the private sector if provided the proper incentives.
The intent of the new law was to replace this situation with a “single, uniform
national policy designed to cut down on bureaucracy and encourage private industry
to utilize government financed inventions through the commitment of the risk capital
1 For additional discussion see CRS Issue Brief IB91132, Industrial Competitiveness and
Technological Advancement: Debate Over Government Policy
, by Wendy H. Schacht.
2 National Science Foundation, Science and Engineering Indicators - - 2002, Washington,
2002, A4-9.

CRS-3
necessary to develop such inventions to the point of commercial application.”3
Expanded technology commercialization was to be accomplished by employing the
patent system to augment collaboration between universities (as well as other
nonprofit institutions) and the business community to ensure that inventions are
brought to market. The Bayh-Dole Act also provides for the increased participation
of small firms in the national R&D enterprise under the assumption that these
companies tend to be more innovative than larger companies.
The Patent System: A Brief Overview
The patent system was created to promote invention and innovation. Article I,
Section 8, Clause 8 of the U.S. Constitution states: “The Congress Shall Have Power
. . . To promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited
Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and
Discoveries . . .” Patents are widely believed to encourage innovation by
simultaneously protecting the inventor and fostering competition. They provide the
inventor with a right to exclude others, temporarily, from use of the invention
without compensation. Patents give the owner an exclusive right for 20 years (from
date of filing) to further develop the idea, commercialize a product or process, and
potentially realize a return on the initial investment. Concurrently, the process of
obtaining a patent places the concept in the public arena. As a disclosure system, the
patent can, and often does, stimulate other firms or individuals to invent “around”
existing patents to provide for parallel technical developments or meet similar market
needs.4
Not everyone agrees that the patent system facilitates innovation. Critics argue
that patents provide a monopoly which induces additional social costs and that cross
licensing between companies can result in exploitation of markets. Some analysts
claim that the patent system was designed to assist the individual inventor and the
shift toward more R&D being performed in large companies has diminished the
patent’s value to society since these firms can utilize other methods to protect their
investments including lead time and trade secrets.
The importance of patents varies among industrial sectors. Patents are
perceived as critical in the drug and chemical industries in part because of the ease
of replicating the finished product. While it is expensive, complicated, and time
consuming to duplicate an airplane, it is relatively simple to chemically analyze a pill
and reproduce it.5 The degree to which industry perceives patents as effective has
been characterized as “. . . positively correlated with the increase in duplication costs
3 House Committee on the Judiciary, Report to Accompany H.R. 6933, 96th Cong., 2d Sess.,
H.Rept. 96-1307, Part 1, 3.
4 For more information see CRS Report 97-599, Patents and Innovation: Issues in Patent
Reform
, by Wendy H. Schacht,
5 Federic M. Scherer, “The Economics of Human Gene Patents”, 77 Academic Medicine,
December 2002, 1350.

CRS-4
and time associated with patents.”6 In certain industries, patents significantly raise
the costs incurred by nonpatent holders wishing to use the idea or invent around the
patent — an estimated 40% in the pharmaceutical sector, 30% for major new
chemical products, and 25% for typical chemical goods — and are thus viewed as
significant. However, in other industries, patents have much smaller impact on the
costs associated with imitation (e.g. in the 7%-15% range for electronics), and may
be considered less successful in protecting resource investments.7
Patents provide an economic incentive for companies to pursue further
development and commercialization. Studies have shown that research funding
accounts for approximately one-quarter of the costs associated with bringing a new
product to market. According to The Economist, “A dollar’s worth of academic
invention or discover requires upwards of $10,000 of private capital to bring [it] to
market.”8 Patent ownership is seen as a way to encourage the additional, and often
substantial investment necessary for new goods and services, particularly in the case
of small business. In an academic setting, the possession of title to inventions is
expected to provide motivation for the university to license the technology to the
private sector for commercialization in anticipation of royalty payments.
University-Industry Cooperation
Changes to the patent laws embodied in the Bayh-Dole Act had as an objective
the facilitation of collaborative ventures between and among academia, industry, and
government. In 1980, universities performed 14% of the R&D undertaken in the
United States (similar to today); much of this fundamental research basic to
technological advance.9 The work is accomplished as part of the education process
and provides training for scientists, engineers, and managers subsequently employed
by the private sector.
Universities, however, generally do not have the means of production necessary
to take the results of research and generate marketable products. Such activities are
carried out by industry. Thus, the emphasis in the Bayh-Dole Act on the promotion
of cooperative efforts between academia and the business community. By providing
universities with intellectual property ownership with which to pursue and structure
collaborative ventures, the legislation encourages the two sectors to work together
to generate new goods, processes, and services for the marketplace. Such joint work
allows for shared costs, shared risks, shared facilities, and shared expertise.
6 Richard C. Levin, Alvin K. Klevorick, Richard R. Nelson, and Sidney G. Winter.
“Appropriating the Returns for Industrial Research and Development,” Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity
, 1987, in The Economics of Technical Change, eds. Edwin Mansfield
and Elizabeth Mansfield (Vermont, Edward Elgar Publishing Co., 1993), 269.
7 Edwin Mansfield, Mark Schwartz, and Samuel Wagner. “Imitation Costs and Patents: An
Empirical Study,” The Economic Journal, December 1981, in The Economics of Technical
Change
, 270.
8 “Innovation’s Golden Goose,” The Economist (US), Dec. 14, 2002.
9 Science and Engineering Indicators - - 2002, A4-9.

CRS-5
Prior to World War II, industry was the primary source of funding for basic
research in universities. This financial support helped shape priorities and build
relationships. However, after the war, the federal government supplanted the private
sector as the major financial contributor and became the principal determinant of the
type and direction of the research performed in academic institutions. This situation
oftentimes resulted in a disconnect between the university and industrial
communities. Because the private sector and not the government typically is
involved in commercialization, the difficulties in moving an idea from the research
stage to a marketable product or process appear to have been compounded. Thus,
efforts to encourage increased collaboration between and among the sectors through
the Bayh-Dole Act were expected to augment the contribution of both parties to
technological advancement.
Small Business
In P.L. 96-517, special consideration concerning patent title is given to small
businesses in part because of the role these companies were seen as playing in the
generation of new jobs and in technological advancement. Research supported by
several federal agencies concluded that small, high technology companies are the
source of significant innovation. An often cited 1982 study done for the Small
Business Administration determined that small firms were 2.4 times as innovative
per employees as large companies.10 Similar work performed at the time the
legislation was being considered found that firms of less than 1,000 employees were
responsible for more major innovations than large firms in the years 1953-1966 and
for an equal number from 1967-1973.11 A study of national and regional data by the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago concluded that “small firms - - those with 20 or
fewer employees - - create a larger proportion of new jobs than their share of
employment in the economy and continue to create jobs even during recession.”12
However, certain caveats need to be stated particularly within the context of
small business, innovation, and technology development. Over the years, experts
have argued that the contribution of small firms to the economy is overstated. Marc
Levinson, writing in Dun’s Business Month, maintained that small companies tended
to produce fewer goods than larger ones because they are less capital intensive and,
on the whole, add less to the gross national product because they offer lower salaries
and often do not provide health insurance or pension plans.13 Professors Zoltan Acs
(University of Baltimore) and David Audretsch (University of Indiana) argue that the
relationship between company size and innovation capacity varies by industry.14
10 National Science Board, Science and Engineering Indicators - - 1993, Washington, 185.
11 National Science Board, Science Indicators -- 1976, Washington, 116.
12 Eleanor H. Erdevig, “Small Business, Big Job Growth,” Chicago Economic Perspectives,
Nov.-Dec. 1986, 22.
13 Marc Levinson, “Small Business: Myth and Reality,” Dun’s Business Month, Sept. 1985,
32-33.
14 Zoltan J. Acs and David B. Audretsch, Innovation and Small Firms (Cambridge: The MIT
Press, 1990), 50-51.

CRS-6
Others maintain that there is no conclusive evidence that firm size affects the
“success” of R&D.15
An important factor affecting the ability of small companies to effect
technological advance is the relationship between these firms and large corporations,
a concept that is reflected in the provisions of the Bayh-Dole Act. It appears evident
that “. . .small high-tech companies play a critical and diverse role in creating new
products and services, in developing new industries, and in driving technological
change and growth in the U.S. economy,” as a National Academy of Engineering
study concluded.16 The reasons for this include the ability of these firms to rapidly
develop markets, generate new goods and services and offer product diversity. Small
businesses tend to be willing to take those technological risks that are not taken by
large firms and may be in a position to quickly exploit market opportunities.17 Yet,
while small businesses can serve as the source of new products and processes, they
often “. . .cannot take advantage of their initial technological lead to establish a
secure foothold in the key markets.”18
Bayh-Dole and Related Law
Provisions
In enacting P.L. 96-517, the Congress accepted the proposition that vesting title
to the contractor will encourage commercialization and that this should be used to
support innovation in certain identified sectors. The law states:
It is the policy and objective of the Congress to use the patent system to promote
the utilization of inventions arising from federally-supported research or
development; . . . to promote collaboration between commercial concerns and
nonprofit organizations, including universities; . . . to promote the
commercialization and public availability of inventions made in the United States
by United States industry and labor; [and] to ensure that the Government obtains
sufficient rights in federally-supported inventions to meet the needs of the
Government and protect the public against nonuse or unreasonable use of
inventions. . .19
15 Charles Brown, James Hamilton, and James Medoff, Employers Large and Small,
(Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1990), 10.
16 National Academy of Engineering, Risk & Innovation, The Role and Importance of Small
High-Tech Companies in the U.S. Economy
(Washington: National Academy Press, 1995),
37.
17 For more information see CRS Report RL30216, Small, High Tech Companies and Their
Role in the Economy: Issues in the Reauthorization of the Small Business Innovation
Research Program
, by Wendy H. Schacht.
18 Clyde V. Prestowitz, Jr., “Big Versus Little,” Business Month, April 1989, 60.
19 P.L. 96-517, sec. 200.

CRS-7
Each nonprofit organization (including universities) or small business is
permitted to elect (within a reasonable time) to retain title to any “subject invention”
made under federally funded R&D; except under “exceptional circumstances when
it is determined by the agency that restriction or elimination of the right to retain title
to any subject invention will better promote the policy and objectives of this
chapter.”20 The institution must commit to commercialization within a
predetermined, agreed upon, time frame. As stated in the House report to accompany
the bill, “the legislation establishes a presumption [emphasis added] that ownership
of all patent rights in government funded research will vest in any contractor who is
a nonprofit research institution or a small business.”21
Certain rights are reserved for the government to protect the public’s interests.
The government retains “. . .a nonexclusive, nontransferable, irrevocable, paid-up
license to practice or have practiced for or on behalf of the United States any subject
invention throughout the world. . . .” The government also retains “march-in rights”
which enable the federal agency to require the contractor (whether he owns the title
or has an exclusive license) to “. . .grant a nonexclusive, partially exclusive, or
exclusive license in any field of use to a responsible applicant or applicants. . .” (with
due compensation) or to grant a license itself under certain circumstances. The
special situation necessary to trigger march-in rights involves a determination that the
contractor has not made efforts to commercialize within an agreed upon time frame
or that the “action is necessary to alleviate health or safety needs which are not
reasonably satisfied by the contractor. . . .”22
The government is “authorized” to withhold public disclosure of information
for a “reasonable time” until a patent application can be made. Licensing by any
contractor retaining title under this act is restricted to companies which will
manufacture substantially within the United States. Initially, universities were
limited in the time they could grant exclusive licenses for patents derived from
government sponsored R&D to large companies (5 of the then 17 years of the patent).
This restriction, however, was voided by P.L. 98-620, the Trademark Clarification
Act of 1984. According to Senate Report 98-662, extending the time frame for
licensing to large firms “. . .is particularly important with technologies such as
pharmaceuticals, where long development times and major investments are usually
required prior to commercialization.”23
Most experts continue to argue that patent exclusivity is important for both large
and small firms. In a February 1983 memorandum concerning the vesting of title to
inventions made under federal funding, then President Ronald Reagan ordered all
agencies to treat, as allowable by law, all contractors regardless of size the same as
prescribed in P.L. 96-517. This, however, does not have a legislative basis. P.L. 98-
620, noted above, further amended Bayh-Dole by loosening the time limitations for
20 Ibid.
21 Report to Accompany H.R. 6933, 5.
22 P.L. 96-517, sec. 203.
23 Senate Committee on the Judiciary, Report to Accompany S. 2171, 98th Cong., 2d Sess.
S.Rept. 98-662, 1984, 3.

CRS-8
both disclosure of an invention to the government agency and for the amount of time
provided within which to elect to take title. Nonprofit institutions were subsequently
permitted to assign title rights to another organization (e.g., one which markets
technology) and government-owned, contractor-operated laboratories (primarily
those of the Department of Energy) run by nonprofits were permitted to retain title
to inventions made in the facility with the exception of those dedicated to naval
nuclear propulsion or weapons development. In addition, the Federal Technology
Transfer Act (P.L. 99-502) allows firms regardless of size to be awarded patents
generated under a cooperative research and development agreement (CRADA) with
a federal laboratory.24
Implementation and Results
The Bayh-Dole Act appears to have met its expressed goals of using “. . .the
patent system to promote the utilization of inventions arising from federally-
supported research or development;. . .and to promote collaboration between
commercial concerns and nonprofit organizations, including universities. . .”25 In one
of the earliest studies of the legislation, the General Accounting Office (GAO) found
agreement among university administrators and small business representatives that
P.L. 96-517 had “. . .a significant impact on their research and innovation efforts.”26
While noting it was not correct to generalize about academia from the 25 universities
studied, GAO did find that by 1987 all university administrators questioned
indicated that the Bayh-Dole Act had “. . .been significant in stimulating business
sponsorship of university research, which has grown 74 percent . . .” from FY1980
to FY1985.27 This trend continues. According to the National Science Foundation,
industry support for academic research has grown faster than any other funding
source. Industry financing expanded from 3.9% of university R&D in 1980 to 7.2%
in 2000, although by FY2003 industry support had dropped to 5.2% of academic
R&D due to market conditions. In 1980, federal financing comprised 67.5% of the
total academic undertaking; by 2000 federal support declined to 58.2% of university
funding, yet increasing to 60.8% in FY2003.28 It should be noted, however, that the
federal government still remains the major source of academic research funding.
The majority of the university personnel involved in the GAO study indicated
that the increase in industry support for research at universities was “directly”
attributed to the patent changes in P.L. 96-517 and P.L. 98-620. Academic faculty
24 For additional discussion see Industrial Competitiveness and Technological Advancement:
Debate Over Government Policy
.
25 P.L. 96-517, sec. 200.
26 U.S. General Accounting Office, Patent Policy: Recent Changes in Federal Law
Considered Beneficial
, RCED-87-44, Apr. 1987, 3.
27 Ibid., 3.
28 National Science Foundation, “Changes in Federal and Non-Federal Support for
Academic R&D Over the Past Three Decades,” InfoBrief, June 2002 available at
[http://www.nsf.gov] and National Science Foundation, “National Patterns of R&D
R e s o u r c e s : 2 0 0 3 , S p e c i a l R e p o r t , ” a v a i l a b l e a t
[http://www.nsf.gov/statistics/nsf05308/pdfstart.htm].

CRS-9
interviews conducted by GAO found that “. . .since businesses knew that universities
could take title to federally funded inventions, they no longer were concerned that
their research efforts could be ‘contaminated’ by federal funding with the possibility
that a federal agency could assert title rights to resulting inventions.”29 All
respondents agreed that the removal of licensing restrictions on nonprofit institutions
(including universities) by P.L. 98-620 was of vital importance in promoting
industry-university interaction.30 This was reinforced by the finding that 9 out of 10
business executives questioned identified the Bayh-Dole Act as an “important factor”
in their decisions to fund R&D in academia.31
Another GAO study published in May of 1998 reported that agency and
university representatives believed the Bayh-Dole Act was meeting its goals as
articulated by the Congress and the law had a positive impact on all involved.
Academia was “. . .receiving greater benefits from their inventions and were
transferring technology better than the government did when it retained title to
inventions.”32 In addition, the report states that the increased commercialization of
federally funded research that resulted from the implementation of the act, positively
affected both the federal government and the American people.33
Other experts agree. Yale President Richard Levin argues that the purpose of
the Bayh-Dole Act is to transition the results of government funded research “. . .into
practice for the benefit of humanity. . .” and that results indicate a “ . . .pretty
emphatic positive answer that the Bayh-Dole Act has created public benefits” with
minimal costs.34 As stated in a recent article in The Economist, the Bayh-Dole Act
is “[p]robably the most inspired piece of legislation to be enacted in America over
the past half-century. . . .”35
One of the major factors in the reported success of the Bayh-Dole Act is the
certainty it conveys concerning ownership of intellectual property. The Director of
Stanford University’s Office of Technology Licensing, Katherine Ku, notes that
exclusivity is what motivates firms to invest financial and human resources in
technology development.36 It provides an incentive for universities to take the time
and effort to pursue a patent and to license those patents in its portfolio. This has led
29 Patent Policy: Recent Changes in Federal Law Considered Beneficial, 20-21.
30 Ibid., 16.
31 Ibid., 23.
32 U.S. General Accounting Office, Technology Transfer: Administration of the Bayh-Dole
Act by Research Universities
, RCED-98-126, May 1998, 2.
33 Ibid., 15.
34 National Academy of Sciences, Board on Science, Technology, and Economic Policy,
Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on
Commercialization and Research
, April 17, 2001 [transcript], 261-262 available at
[http://www.nas.edu]
35 Innovation’s Golden Goose
36 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on
Commercialization and Research
, 9.

CRS-10
to a significant increase in academic patenting. In 1980, 390 patents were awarded
to universities;37 by 2001, this number increased to 3,203.38
Academia has become a major source of innovation for local and regional
economic development. In the latest published survey (FY2003) performed by the
Association of University Technology Managers (AUTM), universities identified 472
new products that were marketed based on academic R&D. In addition, the survey
indicated that during FY2003 more than 374 new companies had been created to
commercialize university research, small businesses are primarily responsible for the
commercialization, and 78.9% of the new firms were located in the same state as the
university. Since 1980, more than 4,000 new companies have been created to develop
and market academic R&D. Of these, 2,279 were still in operation by the close of
FY2003.39
The number of start-up companies created during FY2003 was 6.7% less than
the 401 created in FY2002, reflecting difficult market conditions for new firms.
However, this number of new companies was significantly more than the 275
reported in 1999.40 Many of the start-up businesses were associated with just seven
schools including the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT), the University
of California, California Tech, the University of Minnesota, the Johns Hopkins
University, the University of Utah, and the University of Virginia.41 Studies of
technology transfer activities at MIT and the University of Pennsylvania indicate that
each active exclusive license generates $1 million of additional R&D investment
each year.42 The Association of University Technology Managers also found that $1
billion in royalties were generated in FY2000 from 3,606 licenses, an increase of
almost 9% over the previous year.
However, several analysts argue that “. . .Bayh-Dole was only one of a number
of important factors behind the rise of university patenting and licensing activity.”43
In a study of the technology transfer and patenting activities of the University of
California, Stanford University, and Columbia University, Professor David Mowery
(University of California, Berkeley) and his colleagues concluded that increased
37 Science and Engineering Indicators - - 1993, 430.
38 National Science Board, Science and Engineering Indicators - - 2004, Washington, A5-
105.
39 Association of University Technology Managers, AUTM Licensing Survey: FY2003, 4
and 5, available at [http://www.autm.net/events/FILE/Surveys/03_Abridged_Survey.pdf].
40 Ibid., 4.
41 Goldie Blumenstyk, “Income From University Licenses on Patents Exceeded $1-
Billion,” The Chronicle of Higher Education, March 22, 2002.
42 Peter B. Kramer, Sandy L. Scheibe, Donyale Y. Reavis, and Louis P. Berneman, Induced
Investments and Jobs Produced by Exclusive Patent Licenses - a Confirmatory Study
, 1997
available at [http://www.autm.net]
43 David C. Mowery, Richard R. Nelson, Bhaven N. Sampat, and Arvids A. Ziedonis, “The
Growth of Patenting and Licensing by U.S. Universities: An Assessment of the Effects of
the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980,” Research Policy 30, 2001, 99.

CRS-11
federal funding for basic biomedical research, expanded research in biotechnology,
specific court rulings, and government policies augmenting what can be patented all
contributed to the rise in academic intellectual property activities. According to their
assessment, the Bayh-Dole Act had “. . .little impact on the content of academic
research.” The pursuit of patenting and licensing at universities has expanded
because of changes in biomedical and biotechnology R&D, not because of the act.44
Yet, others criticize this assessment and point out that the act had the most
significant impact on universities that were not actively engaged in patenting prior
to its passage.45 As a result of the Bayh-Dole Act, in part, “university patenting
increased particularly rapidly during the second half of the 1980s and early 1990s.”46
This growth in patenting has been concentrated in “middle-tier” schools, not just the
top research universities.47 The Mowery et.al. study focused solely on universities
that were previously involved in patenting and licensing and may not have fully
considered patent problems that existed before the legislation was implemented.
According to critics of the study, the analysts also failed to take into account changes
in the venture capital industry that promoted the development of start-up companies
to commercialize the results of university R&D.48
While the effects on the small business sector have not been as extensively
studied, the results appear similar. All eight small business owners interviewed by
the General Accounting Office for its 1987 study indicated that the patent changes
had a significant beneficial effect on research, development, and innovation in their
firms.49 Perhaps most illustrative of the influence of the Bayh-Dole Act on small
business is the biotechnology industry. According to Dr. Bernadine Healy, the
former Director of the National Institutes of Health, P.L. 96-517 is responsible for
the development and growth of the biotechnology sector.50 The biotechnology
industry primarily is composed of small firms that are developing technologies and
techniques derived from R&D funded by the National Institutes of Health (NIH).
Many of these companies are established by NIH alumni or university professors
previously supported by NIH grants. In Senate testimony delivered on August 1,
2001, Dr. Marie Freire, then Director of the Office of Technology Transfer at NIH,
stated that “[i]t is widely recognized that the Bayh-Dole Act and the Federal
Technology Transfer Act continue to contribute to the global leadership of the U.S.
biomedical enterprise. . . .” An industry that was in its infancy when the Bayh-Dole
44 Ibid., 100.
45 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on
Commercialization and Research
, 17.
46 Science and Engineering Indicators - - 1993, 152.
47 Ibid., 152 and Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing
on Commercialization and Research
, 57-58.
48 Ashley J. Stevens, “Is Bayh-Dole Under Siege Again?” Technology Access Report, July
2001.
49 Patent Policy: Recent Changes in Federal Law Considered Beneficial, 4.
50 House Committee on the Judiciary, Biotechnology Development and Patent Law, 102d
Cong., 1st Sess., Nov. 20, 1991, 48.

CRS-12
Act was passed, biotechnology firms now generate annual sales of $28.4 billion
(2003), and employ 198,300 people.51
The value of the Bayh-Dole Act might be reflected in state efforts to promote
industry-university cooperation based on the contributions of these activities to local
economic growth. As Mark Myers, retired Senior Vice-President of Xerox, told a
meeting of the National Academy of Sciences (NAS), “[t]he role of the research
university is growing ever important as an economic force in our economy. . . .”52
By 2000, the National Governors Association reports 13 states had created programs
to fund university-industry partnerships.53 In a report for the Biotechnology Industry
Organization (BIO), analysts found that there are biotechnology related initiatives in
40 states, including many that involve cooperative efforts between academia and the
private sector. Between 2000 and 2004, 19 states have developed specific bioscience
strategic plans. Twenty-six states have at least one seed or venture capital program
to invest in small firms undertaking work in bioscience. State laws also have been
changed to allow universities to become equity partners in start up firms designed to
commercialize academic R&D.54
Current Issues and Concerns
While the Bayh-Dole Act provides a general framework to promote expanded
utilization of the results of federally funded research and development, questions
have been raised as to the adequacy of current arrangements. Most experts agree that
closer cooperation among government, industry, and academia can augment funding
sources (both in the private and public sectors), increase technology transfer,
stimulate more innovation (beyond invention), lead to new products and processes,
and expand markets. However, others point out that cooperation may provide an
increased opportunity for conflict of interest, redirection of research, less openness
in sharing of scientific discovery, and a greater emphasis on applied rather than basic
research.
The successes of the Bayh-Dole Act and the visibility of the results of its
implementation have generated certain concerns, many of which are associated with
the role of the university in research, as well as biomedical and biotechnology R&D,
particularly as related to the availability and cost of pharmaceuticals. Several of
these issues are discussed below. However, it is important to place the Bayh-Dole
Act in context. The law is one significant factor in expanded industry, university,
51 Biotechnology Industry Organization, Biotechnology Industry Facts, available at
[http://www.bio.org/speeches/pubs/er/statistics.asp]
52 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on
Commercialization and Research
, 255.
53 Peter Schmidt, “States Push Public Universities to Commercialize Research,” Chronicle
of Higher Education
, March 29,2002.
54 Battelle Technology Partnership Practice and SSTI, Laboratories of Innovation: State
B i o s c i e n c e I n i t i a t i v e s 2 0 0 4
, J u n e 2 0 0 4 , 2 7 - 2 9 , a v a i l a b l e a t
[http://www.bio.org/local.battelle2003/battelle.2004.pdf].

CRS-13
small business collaboration, but not the only one. Therefore, it may be difficult to
assess what concerns are the direct result of the Bayh-Dole Act and which arise from
the overall research environment. The rising costs associated with the performance
of research and development, the availability of venture capital, increased R&D
outsourcing by large firms, and expanded federal funding for biomedical research all
contribute to increased interaction among the parties. Additional legislative
initiatives including the research and experimentation tax credit, the National
Cooperative Research Act, the small business technology transfer program, the
advanced technology program, and cooperative R&D agreements established by the
Stevenson-Wydler Technology Innovation Act all facilitate joint R&D activities
leading to the commercialization of new technologies for the marketplace.55
Recoupment
Over the years, several legislators have suggested that the government “recoup”
its investments from firms using federally supported research and development after
profits are generated. This is particularly true in the area of pharmaceuticals. Such
arguments are similar to those that were identified and considered as part of the
original legislative debate over patent policy and cooperative R&D. Congress, over
20 or more years, weighed these issues and decided that, in the case of patent and
technology policies, the benefits to the Nation brought about by increased innovation
were paramount. The passage of the Bayh-Dole Act represented a determination that,
with respect to certain types of organizations, the economic incentive to realize a
return on investment provided by a patent is necessary to stimulate companies to
provide the often substantial financial commitment to turn federally-funded R&D
into marketable technologies and techniques. This decision was based on several
determinations deriving from the rationale for federal support of basic research, the
importance of technological progress to the Nation, and the critical role of private
sector commercialization in technological advancement.
Federal support for basic research is founded, in large part, on the understanding
that the rate of return to society as a whole generated by investments in research is
significantly larger than the benefits that can be captured by any one firm performing
it.56 It has been estimated that the returns to society generated by investments in
basic research are approximately twice those to the company performing the work.
Government support reflects a consensus that basic research is the foundation for
many innovations, but that incentives for private sector financial commitments are
dampened by the fact that spending for R&D runs a high risk of failure. Even results
of fruitful R&D often are exploited by other domestic and foreign companies, thus
resulting in underinvestment in research by the private sector. The returns from basic
research are generally long term, sometimes not marketable, and not always evident.
55 For additional information see CRS Issue Brief IB89056, Cooperative R&D: Federal
Efforts to Promote Industrial Competitiveness
, by Wendy H. Schacht, and CRS Report 95-
50, The Federal Role in Technology Development, by Wendy H. Schacht.
56 Edwin Mansfield, “Social Returns From R&D: Findings, Methods, and Limitations,”
Research/Technology Management, Nov.-Dec. 1991, 24.

CRS-14
It is now widely accepted that “. . . from one-third to one-half of all [U.S.]
growth has come from technical progress, and that it is the principal driving force for
long-term economic growth and the increased standards of living of modern
industrial societies.”57 Technological advancement can clearly contribute to the
resolution of those national problems which are amenable to technological solutions.
Such progress is achieved through innovation, the process by which industry provides
new and improved products, processes, and services. An invention becomes an
innovation when it has been integrated into the economy such that the knowledge
created results in a new or improved good or service that can be sold in the
marketplace or is applied to production to increase productivity and quality. It is only
through commercialization, a function of the business sector, that a significant
stimulus to economic growth occurs. Thus, there is congressional interest in
accelerating development and commercialization activities in the private sector
through the Bayh-Dole Act as well as other legislation.
Actual experience and cited studies point to the conclusion that companies
which do not control the results of their investments - - either through ownership of
patent title, exclusive license, or pricing decisions - - tend to be less likely to engage
in related R&D. This fact is reflected in the provisions of the Bayh-Dole Act (as well
as other laws). Providing universities, nonprofit institutions, and small businesses
with title to patents arising from federally-funded R&D offers an incentive for
cooperative work and commercial application. Royalties derived from intellectual
property rights provide the academic community an alternative way to support further
research and the business sector a means to obtain a return on their financial
contribution to the endeavor. While the idea of recoupment was considered by the
Congress in hearings on the legislation, it was rejected as an unnecessary obstacle,
one which would be perceived as an additional burden to working with the
government. It was thought to be particularly difficult to administer. Instead,
Congress accepted as satisfactory the anticipated payback to the country through
increased revenues from taxes on profits, new jobs created, improved productivity,
and economic growth. For example, according to the MIT Technology Licensing
Office, 15% of the sales of licensed products derived from federally funded
university research is returned to the government in the form of income taxes, payroll
taxes, capital gains taxes, and corporate income taxes. This is estimated to be 6 times
the royalties paid by companies to the universities.58 The emergence of the
biotechnology industry and the development of new therapeutics to improve health
care are other prominent indications of such benefits. These benefits have been
considered more important than the initial cost of the technology to the government
or any potential unfair advantage.
57 Gregory Tassey, The Economics of R&D Policy (Connecticut: Quorum Books, 1997), 54.
See also: Edwin Mansfield, “Intellectual Property Rights, Technological Change, and
Economic Growth,” in: Intellectual Property Rights and Capital Formation in the Next
Decade
, eds. Charls E. Walker and Mark A. Bloomfield (New York: University Press of
America, 1988), 5.
58 Kenneth D. Campbell, “TLO Says Government Research Pays Off Through $3 billion in
Taxes, MIT Tech Talk, April 15, 1998 available at [http://web.mit.edu].

CRS-15
Government Rights: Royalty Free Licenses and Reporting
Requirements

As discussed above, the government retains certain rights under the Bayh-Dole
Act to protect the public interest. The act states that the government is provided a “.
. .nonexclusive, nontransferable, irrevocable, paid-up license to practice or have
practiced for or on behalf of the United States any subject invention throughout the
world. . . .” This license, commonly known as a “royalty free license,” has been the
subject of some discussion including whether or not this permits government
purchasers to obtain discounts on products developed from federally funded R&D,
particularly pharmaceuticals. A July 2003 GAO report addressed this issue and
concluded that the license entitles the government to practice or have practiced the
invention on the government’s behalf, but “. . .does not give the federal government
the far broader right to purchase, ‘off the shelf’ and royalty free (i.e. at a discounted
price), products that happen to incorporate a federally funded invention when they
are not produced under the government’s license.”59 The study goes on to say that
rights in one patent do not “automatically” permit rights in subsequent, related
patents.60 Because the government apparently holds few licenses on the biomedical
products it purchases (generally through the Veteran’s Administration and the
Department of Defense),61 federal officials indicated that procurement costs were best
reduced by use of the Federal Supply Schedule and national contracts.62 Government
licenses are used primarily in the performance of research in the biomedical area.63
A related issue is that of tracking the government’s interest in patents resulting
from federally funded research and development. In an August 1999 study, GAO
noted that federal contractors and grantees were not meeting the reporting
requirements associated with the Bayh-Dole Act, making it difficult to identify and
assess what licenses the government retained, among other things.64 Two years later,
in a follow-up report, GAO stated that four of the five agencies had taken steps to
insure improved compliance with the law including several new monitoring systems,
although more needed to be done.65 Of particular interest is iEdison, created by the
National Institutes of Health, which electronically tracks federal inventions and is
used by other agencies in addition to NIH.66
59 General Accounting Office, Technology Transfer: Agencies’ Rights to Federally
Sponsored Biomedical Inventions
, GAO-03-536, July 2003, 7.
60 Ibid., 8.
61 Ibid., 8.
62 Ibid., 12.
63 Ibid., 10.
64 General Accounting Office, Technology Transfer: Reporting Requirements for Federally
Sponsored Inventions Need Revision
, August 1999, GAO/RCED-99-242, 2.
65 General Accounting Office, Intellectual Property: Federal Agency Efforts in Transferring
and Reporting New Technology
, October 2002, GAO-03-47, 29.
66 Ibid., 33.

CRS-16
University Research
A question often posed is whether or not patent ownership rights provided by
P.L. 96-517 have interfered with the traditional operating procedures of academia.
A fear is that private sector funding of university R&D has led to conflicts of interest
by scientists performing the research, particularly when academics have equity
positions in the relevant companies. There are concerns that industry agendas will
distort or supplant the basic research and educational responsibilities of academia.
Complaints have also been expressed that the free exchange of ideas and scientific
discovery are constrained as a result of both the university and the business
community’s interest in protecting their competitive positions.
The issue of conflict of interest is a complex one particularly when trying to
determine what direct role the Bayh-Dole Act has in generating such concerns and
what are the results of other factors that have lead to increased industrial funding of
university research. As noted above, laws that provide tax incentives for private
sector financing of university basic research and facilitate technology transfer and
cooperative R&D among government, industry, and academia, as well as changes in
the way companies obtain the basic research necessary for product development
shape the environment within which academic research is pursued. Thus, as argued
by Stanford University’s Katherine Ku, it is necessary to evaluate criticisms of the
Bayh-Dole Act and to understand that the success of the law has made many in
government uncomfortable despite the clear guidelines for technology transfer it
established.67
Senior Research Scholar Mildred Cho (Stanford University Center for
Biomedical Ethics) and her coauthors assert that the Bayh-Dole Act:
. . .has created opportunities for conflict of interest for university faculty
members because academic-industry partnerships can offer direct financial
rewards to individual faculty members in the form of consulting fees, royalties,
and equity in companies while simultaneously funding these faculty members’
research.68
This, it is argued, has resulted in situations where the researcher’s ties to private
sector interests may not be evident and may adversely affect “. . .the quality,
outcome, and dissemination of research.”69 Other studies indicate that obligations
to industry “. . .pose a threat to scientific integrity.”70 Private sector funded research
tends to generate conclusions favorable to industry; however, the factor that is
67 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on
Commercialization and Research
, 98, 100-101.
68 Mildred K. Cho, Ryo Shohara, Anna Schissel, and Drummond Rennie, “Policies on
Faculty Conflicts of Interest at U.S. Universities,” Journal of the American Medical
Association
, Nov. 1, 2000.
69 Ibid.
70 Justin E. Bekelman, Yan Li, and Cary P. Gross, “Scope and Impact of Financial Conflicts
of Interest in Biomedical Research: A Systematic Review,” Journal of the American
Medical Association
, Jan.22/Jan.29, 2003.

CRS-17
primarily associated with the withholding or delay of information is the involvement
of the scientist in bringing his research to market in a product, not the industrial
financing itself.71
Data collected by Harvard Medical School Professor David Blumenthal and his
colleagues also support the assessment that involvement in commercialization
activities is related to delays in publication.72 This study indicated that approximately
20% of life science researchers delayed publication of their studies more than six
months at least once for reasons associated with patents and commercialization
considerations. Almost 9% of faculty refused to share research or materials with
other university scientists in the past three years. However, the authors conclude that
“withholding of research results is not a widespread phenomenon among life-science
researchers.”73 A survey of industry-university research centers by Wesley Cohen
(now at Duke University), et. al. found that over half of the centers permitted firms
to request publication delays and 35% of the institutions allowed researchers to delete
information prior to publication. At those centers with a mission to improve
industrial products and processes, 63% allowed publication delays and 54%
permitted the deletion of information.74
Delays in publication and the free flow of information from academia, according
to Carnegie Mellon University Professor Richard Florida, “. . .may well discourage
or even impede the advancement of knowledge, which retards the efficient pursuit
of scientific progress, in turn slowing innovation in industry.”75 Professor Florida
also points to concerns over the increasing number of academic institutions taking
equity positions in and/or incubating spin-off companies. These actions “. . .simply
tend to distract the university from its core missions of conducting research and
generating talent.” Professor Florida concludes that publication delays and greater
secrecy in the research process resulting from implementation of the Bayh-Dole Act
have shifted the university away from the pursuit of its traditional goals.
Other experts, including Robert Barchi, Provost of the University of
Pennsylvania, maintain that the Bayh-Dole Act has not generated a significant set of
issues concerning conflicts of interest and publication delays primarily because of the
importance of academic freedom to the faculty.76 Publications are the basis for
71 Ibid.
72 David Blumenthal, Eric G. Campbell, Melissa S. Anderson, Nancyanne Causino, and
Karen Seashore Louis, “Withholding Research Results in Academic Life,” Journal of the
American Medical Association
, April 16, 1997, 1224.
73 Ibid., 1224
74 Wesley M. Cohen, Richard Florida, Lucien Randazzese, and John Walsh, “Industry and
the Academy: Uneasy Partners in the Cause of Technological Advance,” in: Challenges to
Research Universities, eds. Linda R. Cohen, Wesley Cohen, Roger Noll, William Rogerson,
and Albert Teich (Washington: The Brookings Press, 1998), 188-189.
75 Richard Florida, “The Role of the University: Leveraging Talent, Not Technology,” Issues
in Science and Technology
, Summer 1999.
76 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on
(continued...)

CRS-18
promotion and tenure and methods to respect reasonable intellectual property
protection have been established. Similarly, as noted by Professor Pam Samuelson
(University of California, Berkeley), conflicts of interest would jeopardize tenure
thus regulations are in place to instruct faculty what is required of them.77
In response to these issues, many universities have hired professional technology
managers to work with faculty and to address patents. Universities with extensive
research capabilities and resources were the first to create offices of technology
transfer; after passage of the Bayh-Dole Act these offices were established with much
greater frequency.78 These university technology transfer offices have established
guidelines to cover industry-university relationships, with education and publication
remaining academic priorities.79 The financial rewards derived from patenting are
only a small portion of the total amount of R&D funding for academic institutions
(3% in FY2000)80 and what substantial money does flow into individual institutions
tends to be the result of one “blockbuster” patent. University technology managers
report that the major reason for patent licensing is commercialization, not profit,
particularly since the cost of a patent, which can run approximately $10,000, is so
high.81 While the Bayh-Dole Act focused universities on “. . .commercially relevant
technologies and closer ties between research and technological development,”82 the
costs of patenting are such that “. . .most university licensing offices barely break
even.”83
University limitations on outside research, expeditious publication obligations
mandated for certain federally-funded R&D, and conflict of interest provisions also
help to preserve a balance between federal policies like the Bayh-Dole Act that
promote industry-university cooperation and concerns over excessive control of the
research environment by the business community. For example, the National
Institutes of Health requires grant recipients to publish the results of their government
funded R&D. This is augmented by tax code regulations necessitating prompt
76 (...continued)
Commercialization and Research,19-20.
77 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on
Commercialization and Research
,193.
78 Rogers, Everett, Jing Yin, and Joern Hoffmann, “Assessing the Effectiveness of
Technology Transfer Offices at U.S. Research Universities,” Journal of the
Association of University Technology Managers
, v. XII, 2000, available at
[http://www.autm.net]
79 Technology Transfer: Administration of the Bayh-Dole Act by Research Universities.
80 National Science Foundation, Academic Research and Development Expenditures: Fiscal
Year 2001
, 44 available at [http://www.nsf.gov/sbe/srs].
81 Ann M. Thayer, “University Technology Moves to Market via Patenting, Licensing,:
Chemical and Engineering News, Aug. 24, 1992, 17-18.
82 National Science Board, Science and Engineering Indicators - - 2002, Washington, 5-54.
83 Lita Nelson, “Increase of Intellectual Property Licensing at Universities Stems from
Changes in Funding and Legislation,” MIT Tech Talk, Aug. 26, 1998 available at
[http://web.mit.edu].

CRS-19
dissemination of actual research results in order for a university or research
institution to retain its tax exempt status. NIH also has policies and guidelines
promoting the availability of patents arising from federal funding for use by other
scientists for research purposes without acquisition of a license.84
Critics argue that the Bayh-Dole Act is distorting the traditional role of the
university to the detriment of future technological development. Professor Florida
maintains that because universities are seen as “engines” of growth, they focus on
applied rather than fundamental research. This has lead to unrealistic national and
local policies and practices that encourage the commercialization of academic
research while ignoring the real value of universities as the “. . .nation’s primary
source of knowledge creation and talent.”85 Mildred Cho also asserts that university
research is “skewed” toward marketable products and not basic research.86 Studies
by Washington University researchers Dianne Rahm and Robert P. Morgan et. al.
indicate the greater the faculty interaction with industry the more the applied
research.87
Other experts disagree. A study of 3,400 faculty at six major research
institutions by Professors Jerry Thursby (Emory University) and Marie Thursby
(Georgia Institute of Technology) found that “. . .the basic/applied split in research
did not change over the period 1983-1999 even though licensing had increased by a
factor greater than 10.”88 Data collected by the National Science Foundation appear
to support this assessment. According to NSF, in 1980, basic research comprised
66.6% of academic R&D endeavors while applied research and development were
33.4% of the total. In 2001, the percent of academic R&D expenditures devoted to
basic research increased to 74.1% while applied research and development declined
to 25.9% of the total.89
Commentators claim that the Bayh-Dole Act encourages the type of research
that is attractive to faculty. James Severson, President of the Cornell Research
Foundation, testified before the House Committee on the Judiciary that
Today, the protection and commercialization of academic research is one way for
universities to attract, retain, and reward talented faculty who wish to see the
results of their research programs benefit society. A commitment to the
84 Available at [http://www.nih.gov].
85 The Role of the University: Leveraging Talent, Not Technology.
86 Eric Niller, “Biotech & Health: Report Fails to Address the Downside of Academic-
Industry Collaborations,” Wall Street Journal (Europe), Aug. 6, 2001, 17.
87 Industry and the Academy: Uneasy Partners in the Cause of Technological Advance, 186.
88 Jerry G. Thursby and Marie C. Thursby, University Licensing Under Bayh-Dole: What
are the Issues and Evidence?,
May 2003.
89 Academic Research and Development Expenditures: Fiscal Year 2001, 42.

CRS-20
protection of research results is important for universities to develop closer ties
to companies, and to attract additional funds to support research programs.90
As noted by Terry Young, Assistant Vice Chancellor for Technology Transfer
atTexas A&M University, the act requires funds generated by licensing to be used for
future education and research necessary to “. . .deliver ‘real world’ products to the
public.”91 Assessing the legislation, the Biotechnology Industries Association,
contends that “[w]ithout the Bayh-Dole Act, few licensing agreements would be
executed between private companies and federally supported research institutions,
and the enormous investment our government makes in medical research would be
wasted.”92
Biotechnology and Pharmaceuticals
Many of the current concerns about the Bayh-Dole Act primarily arise out of its
application to the biotechnology and pharmaceutical industries. Congressional
interest in providing lower cost drugs, particularly to seniors, has focused attention
on the role the act has had on the development of new pharmaceuticals for the
marketplace. Certain critics maintain that the price of many therapeutics derived
from federally funded R&D are excessive considering the government’s financial
contribution.93 Others argue that the Bayh-Dole Act does not significantly affect
pharmaceutical prices and point to a July 2001 study by the National Institutes of
Health that found only four of the 47 FDA approved drugs generating $500 million
a year were developed in part with NIH funded technologies.94 Although the
government generally does not directly support pharmaceutical research aimed at
product development,95 legislative attempts have been made to require cost controls
or recoupment on drugs generated, in part, with federal funds. This is in sharp
contrast to congressional and executive branch efforts, particularly in the defense
arena, to make it easier for firms to acquire and utilize intellectual property
associated with federally financed R&D.96
90 House Committee on the Judiciary, Subcommittee on Courts and Intellectual Property,
Hearings on Gene Patents and Other Genomic Inventions, July 13, 2000, available at
[http://www.house.gov/judiciary/seve0713.htm].
91 U.S. Department of Commerce, Technology Administration, Innovation in America:
University R&D
, June 11, 2002, available at [http://www.ta.doc.gov/reports].
92 Biotechnology Industry Organization, Testimony on Bayh-Dole and Technology Transfer
Before the President’s Council on Science and Technology, Office of Science and
Technology Policy
, April 11, 2002, available at [http://www.bio.org].
93 See CRS Report RL32324, Federal R&D, Drug Discovery, and Pricing: Insights from the
NIH-University-Industry Relationship
, by Wendy H. Schacht,.
94 Department of Health and Human Services, National Institutes of Health , NIH Response
to the Conference Report Request for a Plan to Ensure Taxpayers’ Interests are Protected
,
July 2001, available on the web at [http://www.nih.gov/news/070101wyden.htm]
95 See CRS Report RL30913, Pharmaceutical Research and Development: A Description
and Analysis of the Process
, by Richard E. Rowberg,
96 See House Committee on Government Reform, Subcommittee on Technology and
(continued...)

CRS-21
Funding for university R&D in the life sciences, particularly medical and
biological sciences, comprises by far the largest portion of academic research
support. In 2001, 58% of total R&D expenditures at academic institutions went to
finance the medical and biological sciences.97 When the Bayh-Dole Act was passed
in 1980, 40% of the research spending at universities was in these areas.98 Industry’s
share of biomedical R&D grew from approximately 32% in 1980 to 62% in 2000
while at the same time, the federal share declined.99 According to the National
Science Foundation, the federal portion of academic research funding in biological
sciences declined from approximately 74% in 1980 to 65% in 2000 as government
support for medical research decreased from approximately 64% to 60% during the
same time period.100 However, the federal government continues to be the primary
source of funding for university R&D in these areas.
Overall support for biological and medical sciences has grown significantly
since the passage of the Bayh-Dole Act. As measured in constant 1996 dollars, total
(federal and non-federal) spending for academic R&D in these areas has increased
from $4,296 million in 1980 to $13,651 million in 2000.101 This expanded support
is important in light of findings by the late University of Pennsylvania Wharton
School of Business Professor Edwin Mansfield showing that academic research was
particularly significant in the development of new products and processes in the
pharmaceutical and medical device industries.102 His research indicated that between
1986 and 1994, 31% of new innovations would not have been developed without
substantial delay in the “absence of academic research.”
Interest and activity in the biomedical and biotechnology sectors has sparked
some concern over the effects of the Bayh-Dole Act on research in these areas.
According to information provided by the Boston Consulting Group, in the years
between 1990 and 1999, new gene patents granted increased from about 400 to 2,800
while the number granted to universities expanded from 55% to 73% during that time
96 (...continued)
Procurement Policy, Toward Greater Public-Private Collaboration in Research and
Development: How the Treatment of Intellectual Property Rights is Minimizing Innovation
in the Federal Government
, hearings, July 17, 2001, available at
[http://www.house.gov/reform].
97 Academic Research and Development Expenditures: Fiscal Year 2001, 44.
98 Changes in Federal and Non-Federal Support for Academic R&D Over the Past Three
Decades.

99 Scope and Impact of Financial Conflicts of Interest in Biomedical Research: A
Systematic Review
.
100 Changes in Federal and Non-Federal Support for Academic R&D Over the Past Three
Decades.

101 Ibid.
102 Edwin Mansfield, “Academic Research and Industrial Innovation: An Update of
Empirical Findings,” Research Policy, 1998, 773-776.

CRS-22
period.103 Similarly, the number of U.S. biotechnology patents granted grew from
1,765 in 1990 to 7,763 in 2002.104 The focus on intellectual property has led critics
to charge that the Bayh-Dole Act encourages the patenting of fundamental research
which, in turn, prevents further biomedical innovation. Law professors Rebecca
Eisenberg (University of Michigan) and Arti Rai (University of Pennsylvania) argue
that due to the legislation, “[p]roprietary claims have increasingly moved upstream
from the end products themselves to the ground-breaking discoveries that made them
possible in the first place.”105 While patents are designed to spur innovation, Rai and
Eisenberg maintain that certain patents hinder the process. From their perspective,
by permitting universities to patent discoveries made under federal funding, the
Bayh-Dole Act “. . .draws no distinction between inventions that lead directly to
commercial products and fundamental advances that enable further scientific
studies.”106 These basic innovations are generally known as “research tools.”
Eisenberg and Richard Nelson of Columbia University argue that ownership of
research tools may “. . .impose significant transaction costs” that result in delayed
innovation and possible future litigation.107 It also can stand in the way of research
by others:
Broad claims on early discoveries that are fundamental to emerging fields of
knowledge are particularly worrisome in light of the great value, demonstrated
time and again in history of science and technology, of having many independent
minds at work trying to advance a field. Public science has flourished by
permitting scientists to challenge and build upon the work of rivals.108
Similar concerns were expressed by Harold Varmus, President of Memorial Sloan-
Kettering and former Director of the National Institutes of Health. In July 2000
prepared testimony, he spoke to being “. . .troubled by widespread tendencies to seek
protection of intellectual property increasingly early in the process that ultimately
leads to products of obvious commercial value, because such practices can have
detrimental effects on science and its delivery of health benefits.”109 While the Bayh-
Dole Act and scientific advances have helped generate a dynamic biotechnology
industry, there have been changes that “. . .are not always consistent with the best
interests of science.”110
103 Hamilton Moses, III and Joseph B. Martin, “Academic Relationships with Industry,”
Journal of the American Medical Association, Feb. 21, 2001, 933.
104 Biotechnology Industry Facts.
105 Arti K. Rai and Rebecca S. Eisenberg, “Bayh-Dole Reform and the Progress of
Biomedicine,” American Scientist, Jan.- Feb. 2003, 52.
106 Ibid.
107 Rebecca S. Eisenberg and Richard R. Nelson, “Public vs. Proprietary Science: A Fruitful
Tension?,” Daedalus, Spring 2002.
108 Ibid.
109 Hearings on Gene Patents and Other Genomic Inventions.
110 Ibid.

CRS-23
However, as Varmus and others acknowledge, the remedies to this situation are
not necessarily associated with the Bayh-Dole Act. Yale President Richard Levin
notes that while some research should be kept in the public domain, including
research tools, the fact that it is privatized is not the result of the Bayh-Dole Act, but
rather the result of patent law made by the courts and the Congress. Therefore, he
believes that changes to the act are not the appropriate means to address the issues.111
Current law, as reaffirmed by court decisions, permits the patenting of research
tools. However, there have been efforts to encourage the widespread availability of
these tools. Marie Freire testified that the value to society is greatest if the research
tools are easily available for use in research. She asserted that there is a need to
balance commercial interests with public interests.112 To achieve this balance, the
National Institutes of Health has developed guidelines for universities and companies
receiving federal funding that make clear research tools are to be made available to
other scientists under reasonable terms.113 In addition, the U.S. Patent and Trademark
Office recently made changes in the guidelines used to determine the patentability of
biotechnology discoveries.
A study by Professors John Walsh (University of Illinois, Chicago), Ashish
Arora (Carnegie Mellon University), and Wesley Cohen (Duke University) found that
although there are now more patents associated with biomedical research, and on
more fundamental work, there is little evidence that work has been curtailed due to
intellectual property issues associated with research tools.114 Scientists are able to
continue their research by “. . .licensing, inventing around patents, going offshore,
the development and use of public databases and research tools, court challenges, and
simply using the technology without a license (i.e., infringement).” According to the
authors of the report, private sector owners of patents permitted such infringement
in academia (with the exception of those associated with diagnostic tests in clinical
trials) “. . .partly because it can increase the value of the patented technology.”
Concluding Observations
The discussion surrounding changes to the patent laws in 1980 and 1986, and
the debate over technology transfer since the late 1970s, acknowledged many of the
issues currently being explored. As a result of expressed concerns, certain safeguards
were built into the activities authorized by the Bayh-Dole Act. As discussed
previously, march-in rights, the government’s retention of an irrevocable license to
patents generated under federally funded R&D, publication requirements, and
commercialization schedules, among other things, all are incorporated into the
111 Workshop on Academic IP: Effects of University Patenting and Licensing on
Commercialization and Research
, 262.
112 Senate Committee on Appropriations, Subcommittee on Labor, Health and Human
Services, Education and Related Agencies, Hearings, Aug. 1, 2001.
113 Available on the NIH website at [http://www.nih.gov].
114 John P. Walsh, Ashish Arora, Wesley M. Cohen, “Working Through the Patent
Problem,” Science, Feb. 14, 2003, 1021.

CRS-24
process to protect the public interest. While there is a potential for creating an
“unfair” advantage for one company over another, this is balanced against the need
for new technologies and techniques and their contribution to the well-being of the
Nation.
Despite arguments that title should remain in the public sector where it is
accessible to all interested parties, the earlier lack of exclusivity interfered with the
further development and commercialization of federally funded R&D. During the
1980s, Congress determined that the dispensation of patent rights to universities,
small businesses, and nonprofit institutions and cooperative efforts took precedence,
projecting the greater good generated by new products and processes that improve
the country’s health and welfare. Lawmakers anticipated the economic benefits
through increased revenues from profits, wages, and salaries. The government
receives a significant payback through taxes on profits and society benefits from new
jobs created and expanded productivity. The importance of patent ownership has
been reinforced by the positive effects studies have demonstrated P.L. 96-517 is
reported to have had on the emergence of new technologies and new techniques
generated by American companies.
There remain areas of concern, as discussed above, that Congress may decide
to pursue. Some argue, particularly with respect to pharmaceuticals and
biotechnology, that under the Bayh-Dole Act companies are receiving too many
benefits at the expense of the public. Others, particularly in the defense arena, assert
that the existing rights retained by the government under the act are too restrictive
and are an impediment to meeting federal needs. But the impact of the legislation is
still seen as significant. As summed up by Howard Bremer, who was patent counsel
to the Wisconsin Alumni Research Foundation from 1960 through 1988:
One important factor, which is often overlooked, is that the success was achieved
without cost to the taxpayer. In other words, no separate appropriation of
government funds was needed to establish or manage the effort. In fact, it has
been estimated that the economic benefits flowing from the universities’
licensing activities adds about $41 billion to the United States economy.
Significant as that dollar amount is, it should not be overlooked that university
inventions, arising, as most of them do, from basic research, have led to many
products which have or exhibit the capability of saving lives or of improving the
lives, safety and health of the citizens of the United States and around the world.
In that context their contribution to society is immeasurable.115
115 Howard Bremer, “The First Two Decades of the Bayh-Dole Act as Public Policy,”
National Association of State Universities and Land-Grant Colleges, November 11, 2001,
available at [http://www.nasulgc.org].