Order Code RS21951
Updated April 22, 2005
CRS Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
Changing Causes of the U.S. Trade Deficit
Marc Labonte and Gail Makinen
Government and Finance Division
Summary
The nation’s trade deficit is equal to the imbalance between national investment
and national saving. National saving is the sum of household saving, business saving,
and public sector saving (a budget deficit equals public sector borrowing). In the 1990s,
this imbalance was largely due to a private investment boom and decline in private
saving. In the 2000s, private investment fell and private saving rose. All else equal, this
should have led to a smaller trade deficit. However, all else was not equal during this
period — the public sector budget moved from a surplus of 2.4% of GDP in 2000 to a
deficit of 3.1% in 2004. Thus, while the borrowing needs of the U.S. private sector
declined, the public sector borrowing needs increased, and a stable U.S. national saving-
investment gap continued to be filled by foreign lending as a result. The composition
of capital inflows has also changed from the 1990s. While capital inflows were from
mostly private sources through 2001, since then they have come increasingly from
official sources. This is largely the result of a few Asian countries purchasing U.S.
assets to moderate or prevent their currencies from appreciating against the dollar. If
official capital inflows declined sharply, the dollar and trade deficit would likely decline,
U.S. interest rates would rise, and U.S. spending on capital investment and consumer
durables would fall, all else equal. This report will be updated as events warrant.
By accounting identity, the current account balance (which primarily consists of the
trade balance) must equal the capital account balance, or net international capital flows.
That is because a country can borrow from abroad only if it imports more than it exports.1
Capital outflows are investments abroad by Americans while capital inflows are
investment in U.S. assets by foreigners. Capital flows can take the form of direct
investment or portfolio investment in financial securities. Also by identity, U.S.
investment spending must equal national saving plus net capital flows. National saving
consists of private saving (household and business saving) and public sector saving
(federal, state, and local government saving). When the public sector runs a budget
deficit, it has a negative saving rate and reduces national saving.
1 For more information, see CRS Report RL30534, America’s Growing Current Account
Deficit
, by Marc Labonte and Gail Makinen; and CRS Report RL31032, The Trade
Deficit: Causes, Consequences, and Cures
, by Craig Elwell.
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

CRS-2
These concepts are useful when attempting to provide a proximate explanation for
why the U.S. trade deficit has stayed at very high levels from the late 1990s, a period of
rapid economic expansion, through the recession of 2001, and to the present.
The 1990s Experience
In the late 1990s, the United States experienced an investment boom and a decline
in the private saving rate. As can be seen in Figure 1, there was a widening gap between
the private saving and investment rates as the decade progressed. The result was a
growing trade deficit to fill that gap — from 1.3% of GDP in 1997 to 4% of GDP in 2000.
Although the public sector budget balance improved as the decade progressed, moving
to surplus in 1998, this shift was not enough to offset the growing private saving-
investment imbalance, and the trade deficit continued to grow. So paradoxically for
some, the budget deficit and trade deficit did not move in the same direction, as had
occurred in the 1980s. The reason was that all else did not remain constant — investment
rose and private saving fell.
Figure 1: U.S. Saving, Investment, Budget Balance, and Trade Balance
25%
private
20%
saving
15%
domestic
P 10%
D
investment
5%
f G
government
0%
%o
saving
-5%
trade
-10%
balance
1991 1994 1997 2000 2003
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), U.S. Department of Commerce
Notes: Private saving equals household and business saving. (Net) government saving equals the
combined budget balance of the federal and state and local sector. Domestic investment includes
private and public investment. The trade deficit measure used in this chart is measured as the
current account deficit in the BEA saving and investment tables. BEA measures government
saving on a calendar year basis using a different definition than in budget documents.
Why did the 1990s investment boom lead to a growing trade deficit and an
appreciating dollar? The substantial acceleration in productivity growth that began in the
last half of the 1990s undoubtedly increased the real rate of return on U.S. capital. Since
this rise in productivity was a largely American phenomenon, real rates of return in the
U.S. rose relative to those abroad and this served to increase the attractiveness of U.S.
assets. The response of foreigners (and Americans) was to substitute American assets for

CRS-3
non-American assets in their portfolios.2 To buy American assets, foreigners had first to
buy dollars. This drove up the price of the dollar on the foreign exchange market (the
dollar appreciated) and, as explained above, this led to a growing trade deficit.
The 2000s Experience
In this decade, the investment boom came to an abrupt halt with the 2001 economic
recession. Domestic investment spending fell from 20% of GDP in 2000 to 18% of GDP
in 2002-2003. (In 2004, investment spending increased to 19% of GDP.) Over that
period, private saving increased from 14% of GDP in 2000 to 15% of GDP in 2002-2004.
Since the trade deficit reflects the imbalance of saving and investment, one would assume
that the change in saving and investment would result in a smaller trade deficit, all else
equal. However, other things were not equal during this period — the public sector went
from being a net contributor to national saving, running a budget surplus of 2.4% of GDP
in calendar year 2000, to a net borrower, running a budget deficit of 3.1% of GDP in
2004.3 The shift in the fiscal position meant that the nation’s overall shortfall of U.S.
saving in the 2000s was roughly the same as the 1990s even though the borrowing needs
of the private sector were much diminished. It also meant that long-term interest rates did
not fall as much as they otherwise would have.4
Investors choose where to invest based on the (risk-adjusted) rate of return. The
Federal Reserve had an important influence on interest rates from 2000 to 2003, lowering
short-term interest rates from 6.5% to 1%. It might be expected that the fall in interest
rates that accompanied the investment slowdown and the steep stock market decline of
mid-2000 to 2002 made the U.S. economy a less attractive investment destination. As can
be seen in Figure 2, this was, in fact, the case. Annual private capital inflows fell from
about $1 trillion in 2000 to $0.6 trillion in 2002-2003. However, at the same time that
the U.S. was experiencing an investment downturn, so was much of the rest of the world,
and private U.S. investment abroad also fell sharply, from $0.6 trillion in 2000 to $0.3
trillion in 2002. Thus, the fall in capital inflows was mostly offset by the fall in capital
outflows, and the decline in net private foreign investment — from $0.4 trillion a year in
2000-2002 to $0.3 trillion in 2003 — was much more modest. (In 2004, capital inflows
increased sharply to $1.1 trillion, but capital outflows grew even more rapidly to $0.8
trillion, so net flows declined to $0.26 trillion.)
Based on the decline in net private capital flows, one would have expected the trade
deficit to decline by about $150 billion from 2002 to 2004. This did not occur because
of an increase in official capital inflows — primarily, purchases of U.S. assets by foreign
central banks.

2 For more information on foreign lending to the United States, see CRS Report RL32462,
Foreign Investment in U.S. Securities, by James Jackson.
3 Most of the fiscal shift from 2000 to 2004 came at the federal level, since state and local
governments have balanced budget rules. The federal budget shifted from a surplus of 1.9% of
GDP in 2000 to a deficit of 3.2% of GDP in 2004.
4 This was the same logic behind the “twin deficits” argument made in the 1980s. See CRS
Report RS21409, The Budget Deficit and the Trade Deficit: What is the Connection?, by Marc
Labonte and Gail Makinen.

CRS-4
Figure 2: Composition of U.S. Private Capital Flows
1200
1000
private outflow
800
$ 600
private inflow
of 400
ns 200
net private
llio
0
inflow
bi -200
1995199619971998199920002001200220032004
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis
As seen in Figure 3, net private inflows tracked net total inflows very closely from
1997 to 2001. After that, net total inflows kept climbing while net private inflows first
stabilized in 2002 and then fell in 2003. The two diverged because of the sharp rise in net
official capital inflows from $0 in 2001 to $94 billion in 2002 to $249 billion in 2003 and
$353 billion in 2004. Five countries had very large official foreign exchange reserve
accumulations in recent years — China, India, Japan, Korea, and Taiwan. From 2002 to
2004, official foreign exchange reserves increased by $323 billion in China, $59 billion
in India, $78 billion in Korea, $373 billion in Japan, and $80 billion in Taiwan. (These
increases represent foreign reserve assets originating from all countries; data for assets
from only the U.S. are not available.)
Figure 3: U.S. Net Capital Inflows by Type
700
600
500
400
$
net official inflow
300
of 200
net private inflow
100
llions
0
bi -100
1995199619971998199920002001200220032004
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

CRS-5
The decline in net private capital flows placed downward pressure on the U.S. dollar
since foreigners needed to buy fewer dollars to buy U.S. assets. But the rise in net official
capital inflows tempered that decline, and the dollar has fallen 14% in real terms since its
peak in February 2002. When one examines the depreciation of the dollar since then, it
is due mainly to a decline against the euro (48%), the Canadian dollar (23%), and the
British pound (33%). In all three areas, short-term interest rates remained higher than in
the United States.5 The dollar declined by 17% in nominal terms against the Japanese yen
and stayed constant with the Chinese yuan. Japan is linked to the United States with a
flexible exchange rate while China maintains a fixed exchange rate.
Although Japan allows its currency to float, it would appear that the government is
committed to a policy of moderating the yen’s appreciation relative to the dollar so as not
to nip Japan’s revival of economic growth in the bud and add deflationary pressures to the
Japanese price level.6 This means that as relative private demand for U.S. goods or assets
in Japan declined, the Bank of Japan entered the foreign exchange market and bought
dollars (and with them dollar-denominated assets) to moderate the yen’s appreciation.
Thus, the bilateral trade deficit between the United States and Japan did not decline as
much as it would have if the Bank of Japan had not entered the exchange market to
support the dollar. A similar story can be told about Taiwan, Korea, and India.
The Chinese role in this situation is more complicated since its government does not
allow the free flow of capital out of China. Thus, lower U.S. interest rates are unlikely
to have had much of an effect on the bilateral flow of capital from China to the U.S.
Instead, the U.S.-China aspect is more directly centered on trade. Many argue that the
exchange value of the Chinese yuan is too low relative to the U.S. dollar and that this
undervaluation is growing. Why this is so is often left unspecified. It could be due to a
variety of factors: inflation is lower in China than in the United States, productivity is
growing more rapidly, a growing number of foreign export-oriented firms are
concentrating production in China, and so on. Regardless, what this means is that, over
time, China has become an increasingly attractive place from which to buy. The result
is a growing trade deficit. This deficit is only possible if the Bank of China buys the
surplus dollars represented by the trade deficit at the fixed exchange rate. And this it has
done: the foreign exchange reserves of the Bank of China have shown a large increase
5 Interestingly, although short-term rates were lower in the United States than in these other
countries, long-term rates were mostly higher. This may be a sign that budget deficits and the
low private saving rate have indeed pushed up long-term interest rates as economists have
predicted. See CRS Report RL31775, Do Budget Deficits Push Up Interest Rates and Is This the
Relevant Question?
, by Marc Labonte.
6 There is a large literature that questions whether official foreign exchange intervention is
effective if it is not accompanied by a change in monetary policy (referred to as “sterilized
intervention”). The reason being, without a change in interest rates, private investors have an
incentive to offset official capital flows with private capital flows, thereby pushing the exchange
rate back to its original level. In the Japanese case, it is difficult to tell if the intervention is
sterilized because short-term interest rates were already very close to zero and could not easily
be lowered further. Indeed, Japan may have been motivated to undertake foreign exchange
intervention as a means to expand monetary policy in the presence of near-zero interest rates.
In any case, the fact that the yen — rather than depreciating — appreciated by 17% after the large
increase in official foreign reserves is prima facie evidence in favor of the proposition that
foreign exchange intervention is not always effective.

CRS-6
since 2000. It should be noted that this is in its essence a capital movement from China
to the United States — an official capital movement set in motion by the Bank of China
as opposed to a private capital movement by Chinese citizens.7
What Do These Trends Mean for the U.S. Economy?
Since a large portion of the net capital inflow to the United States has changed from
private to official sources over the past few years, does the effect on the U.S. economy
change? After all, capital inflows are now based less on private investors’ seeking
profitable investments in the United States, and based more on efforts by foreign central
banks to keep their currency from appreciating against the dollar.
Although the motive for the trade deficit has partially changed since the 1990s, its
effect on the U.S. economy remains the same. When private foreigners decide to invest
in U.S. assets, they must first obtain dollars, and this pushes up the value of the dollar.
This makes U.S. exports and import-competing goods less desirable, reducing production
and employment in those industries. On the other hand, the capital inflow increases the
supply of saving available to U.S. borrowers, thereby pushing down domestic interest
rates. This has an offsetting positive effect on the U.S. economy because it increases
interest-sensitive spending on capital investment, residential investment, and consumer
durables (such as automobiles and appliances), thereby boosting employment in those
industries. In the medium term, the trade deficit has no net effect on U.S. aggregate
spending or employment, although there may be transitional effects. It does change the
composition of spending and employment, however, away from the trade sector and
toward the capital and durable good sectors.
When the trade deficit is instead the result of official capital flows, the outcome is
very much the same. When a country reduces its relative demand for U.S. goods and
services, U.S. exports (and employment within export industries) fall. With a floating
exchange rate, the dollar would depreciate. But if the foreign country has fixed its
exchange rate to the dollar, its central bank must instead purchase dollars (and U.S.
assets) to prevent the dollar from depreciating. This pushes down U.S. interest rates and
stimulates interest-sensitive U.S. spending just the same as if a private capital inflow
motivated by relative rates of return had occurred. While this may not be the most
efficient use of the nation’s (and world’s) resources, it should not lead to any
underutilization of those resources in the medium term.
Thus, if the purchase of U.S. assets by foreign central banks (official capital inflows
to the United States) ceased, the composition of output would change. All else equal, the
U.S. dollar would depreciate, increasing the output of U.S. exports and import-competing
industries. But at the same time, less capital would be available for U.S. firms to finance
their investment spending and for the U.S. government to finance its budget deficit. As
a result, interest rates would rise, all else equal.
7 Interestingly, it is noted in the financial press that China is now one of the leading recipients of
foreign direct investment (FDI) from around the world. The evidence in this paper suggests that
the Bank of China is recycling some of this capital to the United States by offsetting FDI inflows
with portfolio outflows.