Order Code RS20746
Updated April 4, 2005
CRS Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
Export Tax Benefits and the WTO:
The Extraterritorial Income Exclusion and
Foreign Sales Corporations
David L. Brumbaugh
Specialist in Public Finance
Government and Finance Division
Summary
The U.S. tax code’s Foreign Sales Corporation (FSC) provisions provided a tax
benefit for U.S. exporters. However, the European Union (EU) in 1997 charged that the
provision was an export subsidy and contravened the World Trade Organization (WTO)
agreements. A WTO ruling upheld the EU complaint, and to avoid retaliatory tariffs,
U.S. legislation in 2000 replaced FSC with a redesigned export benefit, the
“extraterritorial income” (ETI) provisions. The EU maintained that ETI was also not
compliant, and WTO decisions again supported the EU while approving the EU’s
request for tariffs. After a delay, the EU began to phase in tariffs on U.S. goods in
March 2004.
Congress considered ETI legislation throughout much of 2003 and 2004, and in
Spring 2004, both the House and Senate approved versions of legislation that proposed
to repeal ETI while implementing a mix of tax benefits for foreign and domestic
investment not explicitly related to exports. The House and Senate approved a
conference agreement on the legislation in October; the measure became P.L. 108-357.
(For a summary of the measure, see CRS Report RL32652, The 2004 Corporate Tax and
FSC/ETI Bill: The American Jobs Creation Act of 2004.
) However, the EU lodged a
complaint with the WTO, objecting to the repeal legislation’s transition effects. A WTO
panel has been established to assess the charge, but has not issued a ruling.
For its part, economic analysis suggests that FSC and ETI do little to increase
exports but likely trigger exchange rate adjustments that also result in an increase in U.S.
imports; the long-run impact on the trade balance is probably extremely small.
Economic theory also suggests that export benefits likely reduce U.S. economic welfare.
This report will be updated as events warrant.
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

CRS-2
History: DISC and the General Agreements on Tariffs and Trade
The FSC/ETI controversy has its roots in the legislative antecedent of both: the U.S.
tax code’s Domestic International Sales Corporation (DISC) provisions, enacted as part
of the Revenue Act of 1971 (P.L. 92-178). Like FSC and the ETI provisions, DISC
provided a tax incentive to export, although its design was different in certain respects.
It was thought that a tax incentive for exports was desirable in order to stimulate the U.S.
economy; to offset the tax code’s “deferral” benefit, which posed an incentive for U.S.
firms serving foreign markets to produce overseas rather than in the United States; and
to offset export benefits other countries were thought to give their firms.1
DISC soon encountered difficulties with the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(GATT), a trade agreement to which the United States and most of its trading partners
were signatories. Members of the European Community (EC) submitted a complaint to
the GATT Council arguing that DISC was an export subsidy and therefore contravened
GATT. The United States, however, filed a counter-claim, holding that the “territorial”
income tax systems of France, the Netherlands, and Belgium themselves conferred export
subsidies. Under a territorial tax system, a nation does not tax the income of its
corporations if that income is earned by a branch located abroad. A GATT panel issued
reports in 1976, finding that elements of both the territorial systems and DISC constituted
export subsidies prohibited under GATT.
In 1981, the GATT council adopted the panel’s findings, but with an understanding
aimed at settling the dispute: countries need not tax income from economic processes that
occur outside their borders. Territorial tax systems, in other words, do not by themselves
contravene GATT. The understanding also held, however, that arm’s length pricing2
must be used in applying the territorial system to exports. Nevertheless, the controversy
continued to simmer. The United States never conceded that DISC was a subsidy, but
was concerned that the issue threatened breakdown of the dispute resolution process. To
defuse the issue, the U.S. Treasury proposed the FSC provisions. FSC was designed to
conform to GATT by providing an export tax benefit incorporating elements of the
territorial tax system countenanced by the 1981 understanding. Although the United
States does not operate a territorial system (it taxes U.S.-chartered corporations on their
worldwide income), it taxes foreign corporations only on their U.S.-source income. Firms
availed themselves of the FSC benefit by selling their exports through FSCs that were
required to be chartered offshore.
FSC, ETI, and the World Trade Organization
The European countries were not fully satisfied of FSC’s GATT-legality. Still, the
controversy remained below the surface until November 1997, when the EU requested
consultations with the United States over FSC, thereby taking the prescribed first step in
1 U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, General Explanation of the Revenue Act of 1971,
(Washington: GPO, 1972), p. 86.
2 Arm’s length pricing is a method of allocating income between different parts of the same firm
that is based on the prices the different parts would charge each other if they were unrelated.

CRS-3
the dispute settlement process established under the new WTO.3 The United States and
the EU held consultations without reaching a solution, and in July, 1998, the EU took the
next step in the WTO-prescribed dispute-resolution process by requesting a panel to
examine the issue. The panel made its findings public on October 8, 1999.
The panel generally supported the EU, holding that FSC was indeed a prohibited
export subsidy, and that FSC violated subsidy obligations under the WTO Agreement on
Subsidies and Countervailing Measures. In particular, Articles 3.1 and 1.1 of the
Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (SCM) Agreement prohibit subsidies “contingent
on export performance” and provide that a subsidy exists if “government revenue that is
otherwise due is forgone or not collected ... and a benefit is thereby conferred.” The panel
found that the FSC provisions carved out particular exceptions to various parts of U.S. tax
law that would otherwise have generally resulted in taxation of the FSC export income.4
The WTO’s Appellate Body essentially upheld the initial finding on appeal by the United
States. In the United States, replacement legislation was developed to head off retaliatory
measures; its basic provisions received bipartisan support in Congress and were supported
by the Administration. The final version of legislation revamping the tax benefit was
passed by Congress in November 2000 as H.R. 4986, the FSC Repeal and Extraterritorial
Income Exclusion Act. The President signed the bill, and it became P.L. 106-519.
Even before the ETI provisions were passed, the EU made known that it was
skeptical of their WTO-compatibility and maintained that, like FSC, they provide a tax
subsidy that is contingent on exporting.5 The EU asked the WTO to authorize imposition
of $4 billion in tariffs on U.S. products, and asked the WTO to rule on whether the ETI
provisions are WTO-compliant. On August 20, 2001, a WTO panel issued a report
concluding that the ETI provisions contravene the WTO agreements; the WTO Appellate
Body denied a U.S. appeal. On August 30, a WTO arbitration panel authorized the EU
to impose up to $4 billion of tariffs on U.S. imports.
In the 107th Congress, Chairman Thomas of the House Ways and Means Committee
introduced H.R. 5095, which proposed both repeal of ETI and a range of tax reductions
for the overseas business operations of U.S. firms, but the bill was not taken up by the full
House. In the 108th Congress, Representatives Crane and Rangel and Senator Hollings
introduced a bill (H.R. 1769/S. 970) that would have replaced ETI with a tax benefit
linked to domestic U.S. production income rather than to foreign investment. Chairman
Thomas introduced H.R. 2896, which contained provisions similar to H.R. 5095 in the
107th Congress, but with the addition of several tax benefits for domestic investment along
with the bill’s benefits for foreign investment. In October 2003, the Senate Finance
Committee approved S. 1637, containing its own mix of benefits, and the House Ways
and Means Committee approved H.R. 2896.6 Congress did not act on the bills in 2003,
but in May 2004, the Senate approved an amended version of S. 1637. In the House,
3 For information on the WTO’s dispute settlement process, see CRS Report RS20088, Dispute
Settlement in the World Trade Organization: An Overview,
by Jeanne J. Grimmett.
4 World Trade Organization, United States — Tax Treatment for “Foreign Sales Corporations”:
Report of the Panel,
WT/DS108/R (n.p., October 8, 1999), p. 275.
5 BNA Daily Tax Report, November 24, 2000, p. G-1.
6 For a description and analysis of the bills, see CRS Report RL32066, Taxes, Exports, and
International Investment: Proposals in the 108th Congress,
by David L. Brumbaugh.

CRS-4
Representative Thomas introduced a modified ETI bill as H.R. 4520, and the full House
approved the measure on June 17. In July, the Senate prepared the legislation for
conference by approving its own version of H.R. 4520, amended to include the tax
language of S. 1637 along with tobacco buy-out provisions. (The House bill also
contained buy-out provisions.) A conference committee approved a version of the bill on
October 6. For its part, the EU indicated it would not apply tariffs as long as the United
States made progress towards WTO-compliance. However, in November 2003, it set a
deadline of March 2004 and on March 1 began a phased-in application of tariffs on U.S.
products. The tariffs began at an initial rate of 5% but were scheduled to increase by 1%
each month for a year, reaching a ceiling of 17% in March 2005.7
Upon U.S. enactment of legislation phasing out ETI in October 2004, EU officials
announced their intent to suspend tariffs in January 2005. They also indicated, however,
their intention of lodging a complaint with the WTO regarding the legislation’s transition
rules providing for a two-year phaseout rather than immediate repeal of ETI and
provisions allowing ETI to apply to exports made under existing contracts. On February
17, 2005, a WTO panel was formed, but it has yet to rule on the matter.
How FSC Worked
In general, the United States taxes corporations chartered in the United States on
their worldwide income, and ordinarily a U.S. corporation could expect to be taxed on
its export income, regardless of whether the income were adjudged to have a foreign or
domestic source. In contrast, the United States taxes corporations chartered abroad only
on income from the conduct of a U.S. business. U.S. firms used the FSC benefit by
selling their exports through specially qualified subsidiary corporations (FSCs) organized
abroad. As foreign corporations, FSCs would ordinarily be subject to U.S. tax on the part
of their export income determined to be from U.S. sources. However, the FSC rules deem
a specified portion of FSC income not to be from the active conduct of a U.S. business,
and thus to be exempt from U.S. tax. The size of the FSC benefit resulted from rules
governing how much of the FSC’s income was tax exempt, and on the rules governing
how the combined parent-and-FSC export income was allocated between the two. As a
result of these rules, a firm could exempt 15-30% of export income from taxes.
The FSC provisions and its successor are only one of two alternative tax benefits for
exporting in the U.S. tax code. The second benefit, known variously as the “sales source
rule,” the “inventory source rule,” or the “export source rule,” permits export firms in
some cases to exempt 50% of their export income from U.S. tax, but its use is dependent
on an exporter possessing a surfeit of foreign tax credits generated by foreign taxes on
non-export income. Thus, the sales source rule can be used only by firms that have
foreign operations and income that have borne foreign taxes.
7 For further information on the application of tariffs, see CRS Report RS21742, European Trade
Retaliation: The FSC-ETI Case
, by Raymond J. Ahearn.

CRS-5
The Extraterritorial Income (ETI) Exclusion
The ETI provisions provide a tax benefit of the same basic magnitude as FSC: firms
can exempt between 15% and 30% of export income from tax using the ETI provisions.
The ETI provisions, however, go beyond FSC and also provide their 15-30% tax
exemption to a limited amount of income from foreign operations. It is the extension of
the exemption to foreign-source income that is apparently designed to incorporate
elements of territorial systems and on which the U.S. officials based their belief in the
provisions’ WTO-compatibility. The mechanics of ETI provisions also differ from FSC.
No longer must an exporter sell through a subsidiary to obtain a tax benefit. The ETI
benefit results from two rules: one specifies the type of income to which its tax exemption
applies; the second dictates the size of the applied tax exemption. The provisions set the
scope of tax-favored income by first stating that “extraterritorial income” is exempt from
U.S. tax, and go on to define extraterritorial income as income from the sale of property
that is sold for use outside the United States. The provisions also stipulate that not more
than 50% of the value of qualifying property can be attributable to articles produced
abroad and foreign labor costs. Thus, the amount of foreign-source income that qualifies
as “extraterritorial” cannot exceed the amount of export income that qualifies. Or, viewed
another way, the ETI benefit applies to a firm’s exports and a matching amount of its
foreign-produced goods. The provisions set the size of the tax exemption by specifying
that only part of “extraterritorial income” is tax-exempt. The provisions set forth several
percentages and rules that have the effect of limiting the exemption to between 15% and
30% of qualified income, depending on the circumstances of the exporter.
The Economics of FSC and the ETI Provisions
Both FSC and the ETI provisions increase the after-tax return of investment in the
export sector and thus attract investment to exporting. As a consequence, U.S. exports
are probably higher than they would be without the provisions. How much higher
depends on the extent to which export supply increases in response to the tax benefit (that
is, how much of the tax benefit U.S. suppliers pass on to foreign consumers as lower
prices) and on how responsive foreign consumers are to the reduced prices.
Beyond this effect, however, traditional economic theory indicates that the export
benefits produce effects that are perhaps surprising to non-economists. First, because of
exchange rate adjustments, the FSC/ETI-induced increase in exports is diminished, and
U.S. imports also are increased; sales of U.S. import-competing industries thus fall.
Economic theory indicates that while the provisions increase the overall level of U.S.
trade, they do not change the balance of trade or reduce the U.S. trade deficit. The
adjustments work as follows: the tax benefits increase foreign purchases of U.S. exports,
but to buy the U.S. products, foreigners require more dollars. The increased demand for
U.S. dollars drives up the price of the dollar in foreign exchange markets, making U.S.
exports more expensive. This partly offsets the effect FSC and ETI have in increasing
U.S. exports, but it also makes imports to the United States cheaper, which causes U.S.
imports to increase. The result is a higher level of both imports and exports, but no change
in the balance of trade. This result is better seen by stepping back from the exchange rate
mechanisms and recognizing that when a country runs a trade deficit, it is using more
goods and services than it produces. To do so, it must necessarily borrow from abroad
by importing more foreign investment than it exports. A country’s trade deficit, in other

CRS-6
words, is mirrored by a deficit on capital account. And a country’s trade balance changes
only if the balance on capital account changes. Thus, if we assume that the export benefits
do not change the balance on capital account, they cannot change the trade balance.
The export benefits also affect U.S. economic welfare. Traditional economic
analysis indicates that they reduce overall U.S. economic welfare because at least part of
the tax benefit is passed on to foreign consumers in the form of lower prices. This price
reduction can be viewed as a transfer of economic welfare from U.S. taxpayers in general
to foreign consumers. These effects, however, are probably not large. According to CRS
estimates based on 1996 data, FSC increased the quantity of U.S. exports by a range of
two-tenths of 1% to four-tenths of 1% and increased the quantity of imports by a range
of two-tenths of 1% to three-tenths of 1%. The shift of economic welfare to foreign
consumers is equal to an estimated one-tenth of 1% of exports.8 The impact on the trade
balance was probably negligible. The Joint Committee on Taxation has estimated ETI’s
cost in forgone tax revenue at $4.8 billion for FY2003.
The ETI provisions introduce a new wrinkle to this economic analysis, but probably
not a large one: their extension to a limited amount of foreign-source income likely
provides a tax incentive for some exporters to increase their overseas investment. The
size of this new incentive, however, is probably not large, because of several factors.
First, the amount of foreign-source income that receives the benefit is limited by a firm’s
exports. Second, existing U.S. tax law provides an alternative tax benefit for investing
abroad in the form of an indefinite deferral of U.S. tax on income reinvested abroad by
foreign subsidiaries of U.S. companies. For some exporters, this deferral benefit is
probably larger than that available under the ETI provisions. If economic analysts are
generally critical of tax benefits like FSC and ETI, support for them can be found in the
business community. A reason for the divergence in views may be perspectives:
economic analysis looks at the benefits’ impact from the perspective of the economy as
a whole, attempting to account for its full range of effects and adjustments in all markets.
Supporters of the provision, however, are frequently businessmen whose exporting firms
would likely face declining sales, profits, and employment if provisions were to be
eliminated. For economists, there is no denying that FSC and ETI boost employment and
increase incomes in certain sectors of the economy. But it also results in contraction of
other parts (for example, firms that compete with imports) and transfers economic welfare
to foreign consumers.
FSC and the ETI provisions have also been defended on the grounds that they
counter subsidies provided to foreign producers by their own governments. A purported
subsidy that is sometimes cited is the practice among European (and other) countries of
rebating the value-added taxes (VATs) that would otherwise apply to export sales.
However, from an economic perspective such “border adjustments” do not distort trade
and are in fact necessary if exported goods are to be part of the same relative price
structure as other goods in the importing country. In addition, U.S. sales and excise taxes
do not apply to exports, while European countries do not have a formal system for
forgiving corporate income tax on exports. (However, under territorial tax systems, lax
administration of transfer pricing rules may result in export subsidies.)
8 CRS Report RL30684, The Foreign Sales Corporation (FSC) Tax Benefit for Exporting: WTO
Issues and an Economic Analysis,
by David L. Brumbaugh.