Order Code RS21939
Updated February 24, 2005
CRS Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
The Magnitude of Changes That Would Be
Required to Balance the FY2006 Budget
Marc Labonte
Analyst in Macroeconomics
Government & Finance Division
Summary
A balanced federal budget is a bipartisan goal of many Members of Congress. In
addition, moving the budget closer to balance is a long-term necessity because the
national debt cannot grow as a percentage of GDP indefinitely, as it would under current
policy. The budget deficit in FY2006 is projected to be between $295 billion and $400
billion. Mathematically, the budget could be balanced by reducing total spending by
12%-16%, or mandatory spending by 20%-28%, or discretionary spending by 31%-38%,
or non-military discretionary spending by 59%-79%, or by raising income tax rates by
29%-40%, or some combination of these options. The budget is unlikely to return to
balance “on its own,” as some have suggested, since higher productivity rates are already
incorporated in the projections; research suggests that the revenue estimates of tax cuts
are unlikely to be significantly overstated; and the decline in the deficit found in the
CBO baseline or President’s budget rests on assumptions that differ substantially from
what is typically thought of as current policy. This report assumes a familiarity with
basic budgetary terms and concepts and will be updated as events warrant.
Many Members of Congress of both parties support the goal of a balanced budget.
In addition, moving the budget closer to balance is a long-term necessity because the
projected deficits would cause the national debt to grow indefinitely as a percentage of
GDP.1 If this occurred, it would eventually result in financial insolvency. This report lays
out generic scenarios for balancing the budget in the next fiscal year. Although these are
not policy options that are likely to be enacted, they are meant to offer simple examples
to gauge the scope of changes that would be required if policymakers eventually decide
to bring the budget back to balance. If changes are postponed or made over a longer time
period, they would need to be larger because of higher debt service. (CRS takes no
position on the appropriate time frame for balancing the budget.)
Under the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) baseline, the FY2006 budget deficit
is projected to be $295 billion. In the Administration’s budget proposal, the deficit would
be $390 billion. However, these estimates are unlikely to match actual outcomes for a
1 See Congressional Budget Office, Long Term Budget Outlook, Dec. 2003.
Congressional Research Service { The Library of Congress

CRS-2
number of reasons. CBO is required to assume that discretionary spending would grow
at the rate of inflation and all expiring tax provisions (including the recent tax cuts) would
not be renewed, and to exclude supplemental spending for military operations in Iraq.
The baseline is not meant to offer a “best guess” of future policy. The Administration’s
budget proposal depends on congressional enactment and Congress may have other
priorities. The Administration’s budget assumed a lower rate of spending growth than
CBO, allowed alternative minimum tax (AMT) relief to expire, and included little
supplemental military spending. Even congressional resolutions often turn out to be
different from actual results. For example, the actual budget deficit in FY2003 was $27
billion higher than called for in the conference budget resolution. Thus, it is useful to
project the budget deficit under alternative assumptions as well. In line with historical
experience, one reasonable alternative projection would be to keep discretionary spending
constant as a percentage of GDP, assume military operations continue, and renew expiring
tax provisions. This approach would increase the FY2006 deficit to $400 billion and is
referred to as the “alternative baseline” later in the report.2
The deficit can be eliminated through higher tax revenue, lower spending, or some
combination of the two. This report quantifies the scope of changes required to balance
the budget under the following options:
! reduce total spending
! reduce mandatory spending
! reduce discretionary spending
! reduce non-military discretionary spending
! raise individual income tax rates
! reduce tax expenditures
! raise individual income tax rates and reduce spending equally
Spending Reductions
Rather than single out any specific spending area to bear a disproportionate burden
of the reductions, one option would be to spread deficit reduction evenly across all policy
areas by $283 billion under the CBO baseline or $384 billion under the alternative
baseline.3 (All policy options are smaller than the deficit because of the resulting
reduction in debt service caused by the balanced budget.) Under this option, total non-
interest spending would decrease by 12% from the CBO baseline and 16% from the
alternative baseline.
About three-sevenths of total spending (excluding net interest) is discretionary
spending (i.e., spending specifically appropriated by Congress) and four-sevenths is
mandatory spending. Medicare, Social Security, and other retirement programs account
2 The alternative baseline is described and calculated in CRS Report RS22045, Baseline Budget
Projections Under Alternative Assumptions
, by Gregg Esenwein and Marc Labonte.
3 Researchers have singled out specific policy options for reducing the deficit that they think
would be desirable. See, for example, Chris Edwards, “Downsizing the Federal Government,”
Cato Institute Policy Analysis No. 515, June 2004 and Alice Rivlin and Isabel Sawhill, eds.,
Restoring Fiscal Sanity: How to Balance the Budget (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution
Press, 2004); Congressional Budget Office, Budget Options, March 2003.

CRS-3
for about two-thirds of mandatory spending, and income support programs account for
another one-sixth. To balance the budget solely through reductions in mandatory
spending, it would need to be reduced by 20% from the CBO baseline and 28% from the
alternative baseline. If the deficit were eliminated solely through reductions in
discretionary spending, it would need to be reduced by 31% from the CBO baseline and
38% from the alternative baseline.
Discretionary spending is split about evenly between military and non-military
spending. Given current military operations abroad and political support for military
spending, some policymakers would prefer to limit spending reductions to non-military
discretionary spending. Non-military discretionary spending is spread across many policy
areas; education and transportation are the largest. If the deficit were eliminated solely
through reductions in non-military discretionary spending, it would need to be reduced
by 59% from the CBO baseline and 79% from the alternative baseline.
Tax Increases
Tax increases could take many different forms and be pursued through many
different parts of the tax system. One approach might be an across-the-board increase in
marginal individual income tax rates. To balance the budget, average effective individual
income tax rates would need to be increased by 29% (i.e., from 10.2% to 13.2%) under
the CBO baseline or 39% under the alternative baseline. An approximately equivalent
increase in all marginal income tax rates would be needed to raise average tax rates to that
extent, assuming no behavioral responses. Because of interactions with the alternative
minimum tax, non-refundable tax credits, and so on, marginal tax rates would probably
need to be raised by a greater extent to actually achieve a 29%-39% increase in average
effective tax rates.4
To raise revenue, economists often favor reforms that broaden the tax base rather
than raise marginal tax rates.5 Under a theoretically “ideal” income tax system, the tax
treatment of all net income would be the same, regardless of how it is earned or spent.
In our current tax structure, tax expenditures (deductions, exemptions, and credits) give
special preferences to certain types of economic behavior. While it is beyond the scope
of this report to evaluate the effect on efficiency of any particular tax expenditure, it is
useful to consider how much revenue could be generated by broadening the base as an
alternative to raising marginal tax rates. Eliminating only the 7 largest tax expenditures,
which include exclusions for pension contributions and health insurance premiums, and
deductions for home mortgage interest and state and local taxes, would raise more than
enough revenue to balance the budget without any change in marginal rates.6
4 Some policymakers have argued that the fiscal position should be improved by repealing the tax
cuts of 2001, 2003, and 2004. According to revenue estimates by the Joint Tax Committee, this
policy would reduce the alternative baseline budget deficit by 53% in 2006.
5 The Tax Reform Act of 1986 (P.L.99-514) is a prominent example of an act that broadened the
tax base and increased tax revenues (at least initially) — despite reducing marginal tax rates.
6 Based on OMB estimates of the revenue lost to tax expenditures in 2006 relative to an ideal tax
system. This can be considered only a rough estimate because if different tax expenditures were
simultaneously reduced, there would be interactions between them that could be higher or lower
(continued...)

CRS-4
The large sums involved in the previous examples suggest that some might find it
desirable to balance the budget through a combination of tax increases and spending cuts.
One option would be to split the revenue difference evenly between overall spending cuts
and individual income tax increases. This solution would require a 6% decrease in total
spending and a 14% increase in average effective tax rates under the CBO baseline and
an 8% decrease in total spending and a 20% increase in average effective tax rates under
the alternative baseline.
Table: Summary of Selected Policy Options to Balance the Budget
Policy Option
Percent decrease in spending/increase in
taxes from:
CBO Baseline
Alternative
Baseline
Reduce total spending
12%
16%
Reduce mandatory spending
20%
28%
Reduce discretionary spending
31%
38%
Reduce non-military discretionary spending
59%
79%
Raise individual income taxes
29%
40%
Raise individual income taxes and reduce
spending: 6%
spending: 8%
spending equally
taxes: 14%
taxes: 20%
Source: CRS calculations based on CBO projections.
Notes: Alternative baseline assumes that discretionary spending stays constant as a percentage of GDP,
expiring tax provisions are renewed, and military operations abroad continue at current levels. See CRS
Report RS22045 for more information. All options are smaller than the deficit because of the resulting debt
service savings caused by the balanced budget. Calculations assume that the deficit would have been
financed at a composite interest rate of 4.3%, as assumed by CBO in the Budget and Economic Outlook.
Will the Budget Deficit Go Away on Its Own?
Some commentators have argued that the drastic policy changes illustrated above
will not be necessary because the budget deficit will shrink on its own. They make a
number of arguments to support this claim.
First, they point to the improvement in the deficit that occurs over time in the CBO
baseline and the President’s budget proposal. In the CBO baseline, the deficit falls from
$368 billion in 2005 to a surplus of $141 billion in 2015. In the President’s budget
proposal, which covers only five years, the deficit falls to $207 billion in 2010. It is
accurate to characterize these projections as requiring significant changes from what is
typically considered current policy, however. The CBO baseline assumes discretionary
6 (...continued)
than the cost of reducing them separately. For examples, see Leonard Berman, “Is the Tax
Expenditure Concept Still Relevant?” National Tax Journal, Sept. 2003, p. 615.

CRS-5
spending will decline 2 percentage points to 5.6% of GDP in 2014; discretionary spending
has never been this low since World War II. The CBO baseline also assumes that there
will be no spending on military operations in Iraq after 2005 and all expiring tax
provisions will not be renewed, including the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts. The President’s
FY2006 budget proposal assumes that there will be little spending on operations in Iraq
after 2005, AMT relief will be allowed to expire, and discretionary spending will fall to
its lowest post-World War II level by 2009. Under the alternative baseline, the deficit
increases over the next 10 years.
Second, it is argued that faster economic growth will lead to higher revenues than
predicted, similar to the experience of the late 1990s. It is true that actual growth was
higher than projected in the late 1990s, and this, in turn, caused revenues to be higher than
projected. But at this point, much of the then-unexpected increase in economic growth
has been built into CBO’s projections. For example, CBO estimates that potential labor
productivity grew by an average of 2.5% from 1996 to 2004 compared to 1.5% from 1974
to 1995. In the baseline, it assumes that potential labor productivity will grow by an
average of 2.4%. In other words, most of the acceleration of productivity growth from
1996 to 2004 is already incorporated in CBO’s projection of the next 10 years.
The unexpectedly rapid increase in revenue from capital gains realizations was
another important element of the “revenue surprise” of the late 1990s. Capital gains
revenues rose from $54 billion in 1996 to $119 billion in 2000, but then fell, following
the stock market crash, to a estimated $45 billion in 2003. Since the high realizations of
the late 1990s were caused by the extremely rapid increase in equity prices, this source
of the revenue surprise may also be unlikely to be repeated in the future. Adjusted for
inflation, CBO does not project capital gains revenues to reach its previous peak at any
point in the 10-year forecast.
It should also be noted that the improvement in the budget balance in the 1990s was
not just good fortune, but also the result of underlying budgetary decisions. To achieve
budget balance, taxes were raised in 1990 (P.L.101-508) and 1993 (P.L.103-66) and
spending was reduced from 22.3% of GDP in 1991 to 18.4% of GDP in 2000. The largest
reduction in spending was defense spending in response to the end of the Cold War.
Defense spending fell from 6.2% of GDP in 1986 to 4.6% of GDP in 1991 to 3.0% of
GDP in 2000. Spending on non-defense discretionary, Social Security, and interest
payments on the debt (because the debt was declining) also fell as a percentage of GDP
between 1991 and 2000. Since 2000, spending has risen as a percentage of GDP to an
estimated 20.6% in 2005; higher military spending accounted for about half of the rise.
Third, it is argued that the deficit projections are based on faulty assumptions that
overestimate the cost of tax cuts because they do not include “feedback effects.” It is
claimed that, in reality, the tax cuts will cost much less than originally projected because
tax cuts spur higher growth, thereby “paying for themselves,” at least in part. (The
revenue-raising options laid out in this report also assume there will be no feedback
effects.) Based on existing theory and empirical evidence, CBO and the Joint Committee
on Taxation (JCT) have provided alternative estimates of how much the 2003 tax cuts will
cost after allowing for feedback effects on GDP. Assuming that the Federal Reserve does
not let inflation rise, JCT found that the tax cuts could cost 5.8%-16.1% less in the first
five years, and 2.6%-11.8% less in the next five years. CBO found that the cost of the
President’s 2004 budget proposals could be between 29% lower and 10% higher over the

CRS-6
first five years, and between 17% lower and 15% higher over the next five years.7 This
indicates that, under the best case scenario, the feedback effects of the tax cuts would not
generate enough revenues to move the budget significantly closer to balance and, under
the worst case scenario, could increase the budget deficit more than under “static” revenue
estimates. It should also be noted that, to date, there is no evidence that the tax cuts have
resulted in less revenue loss than originally projected. After adjusting for economic
conditions and temporary factors, revenues have fallen by more than the original “budget
scores” for the tax cuts had indicated.8
Fourth, it is argued that budget projections are highly uncertain, and may prove to
be too pessimistic. This is true: the degree of uncertainty surrounding budget projections
dwarfs the projected deficits in the out years of the projections. For example, CBO
estimates there is a 50% chance that the deficit will be at least $316 billion higher or
lower than projected in 2010.9 This means that the permanency of the deficits now
projected is far from being a “sure thing.” But while the projections may prove to be too
pessimistic, it is equally likely that the projections are too optimistic. While projections
made today will certainly prove to be incorrect, the probability that the budget deficit will
turn out to be higher than predicted is equal to the probability that it will turn out to be
lower than predicted.
The Burden of the Status Quo
Many would consider the policy options laid out in this report to be too burdensome
to be feasible. But in mainstream economics, a budget deficit imposes a burden that is
just as real as higher taxes or spending cuts. Deficits can be financed only by borrowing
real resources. When these resources are borrowed out of American saving, the budget
deficit pushes up interest rates and “crowds out” private investment spending that is
necessary to increase future standards of living. In effect, this outcome shifts the burden
of the deficit to future generations by causing future living standards to be lower than they
otherwise would be. When the resources are borrowed from foreigners, the trade deficit
widens and foreigners, rather than Americans, enjoy the returns from that borrowing.
Balancing the budget shifts a burden, but it does not create one.10
7 Congressional Budget Office, An Analysis of the President’s Budgetary Proposals for FY2004,
March 2004; Congressional Budget Office, How CBO Analyzed the Macroeconomic Effects of
the President’s Budget
, July 2003; Joint Committee on Taxation, “Macroeconomic Analysis of
H.R.2,” Congressional Record, Doc 2003-11771, May 8, 2003. For a discussion, see CRS Report
RL31949, Issues in Dynamic Revenue Estimating, by Jane Gravelle.
8 See CRS Report RS21786, The Federal Budget Deficit: A Discussion of Recent Trends, by
Gregg Esenwein, Marc Labonte, and Philip Winters.
9 See Congressional Budget Office, The Uncertainty of Budget Projections, April 2004, p. 17.
10 See CRS Report RL30520, The National Debt: Who Bears Its Burden? by Marc Labonte and
Gail Makinen. A trade deficit is the necessary result of borrowing abroad because borrowing can
only occur if Americans spend more abroad than foreigners spend on American goods.