Order Code RL32400
CRS Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
Patents and Drug Importation
May 25, 2004
John R. Thomas
Visiting Scholar
Resources, Science, and Industry Division
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

Patents and Drug Importation
Summary
Prescription drugs often cost far more in the United States than in other
countries. Some consumers have attempted to import medications from abroad in
order to realize cost savings. The practice of importing prescription drugs outside the
distribution channels established by the brand-name drug company is commonly
termed “parallel importation.” Parallel imports are authentic products that are
legitimately distributed abroad and then sold to consumers in the United States,
without the permission of the authorized U.S. dealer.
Parallel importation may raise significant intellectual property issues. Many
prescription drugs are subject to patent rights in the United States. In the Jazz Photo
decision, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit confirmed that the owner
of a U.S. patent may prevent imports of patented goods, even in circumstances where
the patent holder itself sold those goods outside the United States. The Jazz Photo
opinion squarely declined to extend the “exhaustion” doctrine — under which patent
rights in a product are spent upon the patent owner’s first sale of the patented product
— to sales that occurred in foreign countries. The court’s ruling will in some cases
allow brand-name pharmaceutical firms to block the unauthorized parallel
importation of prescription drugs through use of their patent rights.
Several state and local governments are either themselves importing, or
encouraging others to import, patented medications from foreign jurisdictions. The
Eleventh Amendment of the U.S. Constitution provides that a federal court may not
adjudicate a lawsuit by a private person against a state, except under certain limited
circumstances. The ability of a private party to obtain a remedy for patent
infringement against a state government is therefore uncertain. Eleventh Amendment
immunity may in some cases extend to political subdivisions of a state as well.
In addition to any patent rights they possess, brand-name drug companies may
place label licenses on their medications. It is possible to draft a label license
restricting use of a drug to the jurisdiction in which it was sold. As a result, in
addition to a charge of patent infringement, an unauthorized parallel importer may
potentially face liability for breach of contract.
Several bills have been introduced in the 108th Congress addressing the
importation of prescription drugs. One of them, S. 2328, the Pharmaceutical Market
Access and Drug Safety Act of 2004, would amend the Patent Act of 1952 to provide
that importation into the United States of a regulated pharmaceutical sold abroad by
a patent proprietor or its representative is not a patent infringement. Introduction of
an “international exhaustion” rule restricted to pharmaceuticals does not appear to
be restricted by the provisions of the so-called TRIPS Agreement, which is the
component of the World Trade Organization (WTO) agreements concerning
intellectual property. Another possible legislative response is the immunization of
specific individuals, such as pharmacies or importers, from patent infringement
liability. Alternatively, no legislative action need be taken if the current possibility
of an infringement action against unauthorized importers of patented pharmaceuticals
is deemed satisfactory.

Contents
Fundamentals of Pharmaceutical Patents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
Patent Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
U.S. Patent Acquisition and Enforcement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
The Exhaustion Doctrine . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
International Aspects . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
The Parallel Importation of Patented Pharmaceuticals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
State and Local Governments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
Label Licenses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
The TRIPS Agreement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
Legislative Issues and Alternatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

Patents and Drug Importation
The pricing of prescription drugs has become a significant concern for many
U.S. consumers.1 As spending on health care has risen in recent years,2 so too has
consumer interest in purchasing more affordable medications. Overseas markets
provide one possible source of less costly prescription drugs. Some comparative
studies of prescription drug prices in the United States and foreign nations have
concluded that prices for specific drugs may be significantly lower abroad.3 These
price disparities in some instances have encouraged individuals and firms, as well
as state and local governments, to attempt to import comparable medications from
abroad in order to realize cost savings.4
The practice of importing patented prescription drugs outside the distribution
channels established by the brand-name drug company is commonly termed “parallel
importation.”5 Parallel imports are authentic products that are legitimately
distributed abroad and then sold to consumers in the United States, without the
permission of the authorized U.S. dealer. These goods are legitimate in that they are
produced by the brand-name drug company or its authorized representative. In
particular, parallel imports are not generic versions of a brand-name drug distributed
by a different manufacturer, nor are they pirated copies that form part of the “black
market.” Because parallel imports disrupt the marketing arrangements established
by the brand-name drug company, however, they are sometimes called “grey market
goods.”6
Current debate surrounding the parallel importation of prescription
pharmaceuticals has largely addressed the safety and efficacy of the imported
1 See CRS Report RS20612, Medicare: Prescription Drug Expenditures, 1997, by Paulette
C. Morgan.
2 See CRS Report RL31094, Health Care Spending: Past Trends and Projections, by
Paulette C. Morgan.
3 See, e.g., Farin Khosravi, “Price Discrimination in the United States: Why Are
Pharmaceuticals Cheaper in Canada and Are Americans Seizing the Opportunities Across
the Border?,” 9 Law and Business Review of the Americas (2003), 427.
4 See, e.g., Shubha Ghosh, “Pills, Patents and Power: State Creation of Gray Markets as a
Limit on Patent Rights,” 14 Florida Journal of International Law 217 (2002).
5 See, e.g., Warwick A. Rothnie, Parallel Imports (Sweet & Maxwell 1993); Simon Horner,
Parallel Imports (Blackwell Science 1987).
6 See, e.g., Seth E. Lipner, The Legal and Economic Aspects of Gray Market Goods
(Quorum Books, Westport, Connecticut 1990).

CRS-2
medications.7 This practice may also raise significant intellectual property concerns,
however. Many prescription drugs are subject to patent rights in the United States.
Indeed, because patented drugs usually have no exact generic equivalent available in
the marketplace,8 economic incentives for parallel importation may be strongest for
patented medications. Among the rights granted by an issued patent is the ability to
exclude others from importing the patented product into the United States.9 As a
result, even if a foreign drug is judged safe and effective for domestic use, brand-
name firms may nonetheless be able to block the unauthorized importation of
prescription drugs through use of their patent rights.
In the 108th Congress, several bills have been introduced that concern the
importation of prescription drugs but most do not address intellectual property
issues.10 However, one of these bills, S. 2328, the Pharmaceutical Market Access and
Drug Safety Act of 2004, accounts for the patent implications of the parallel
importation of pharmaceuticals. In particular, section 4(f) of S. 2328 amends the
Patent Act of 1952 to provide that it is not an act of patent infringement to import
into the United States a drug that was first sold abroad by or under authority of the
owner or licensee of such patent. The effect of S. 2328 would be to introduce a
doctrine known as “international exhaustion” into the U.S. patent law.11
The parallel trade of patented pharmaceuticals involves a fundamental trade-off
within the intellectual property law: encouraging the labors that led to technological
innovation, on one hand, and promoting access to the fruits of those labors, on the
other. The patent system is built upon the premise that patents provide individuals
with an incentive to innovate by awarding inventors exclusive rights in their
inventions for a limited period of time.12 Some observers believe that a
diminishment of patent rights will decrease incentives to develop new
pharmaceuticals in the future.13 Yet there is growing concern that drug prices are too
high in the United States as compared to other nations. Some commentators believe
7 See CRS Report RL32271, Importation of Prescription Drugs Provisions in P.L. 108-173,
the Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act of 2003
, by Susan
Thaul & Donna U. Vogt.
8 See, e.g., Melissa K. Davis, “Monopolistic Tendencies of Brand-Name Drug Companies
in the Pharmaceutical Industry,” 15 Journal of Law and Commerce (1995), 357.
9 See 35 U.S.C. § 271(a) (2000) (providing patent proprietors with the right to exclude
others from importing patented inventions into the United States).
10 S. 2137; S. 1781; H.R. 2427 (each titled the “Pharmaceutical Market Access Act of
2003").
11 See Rebecca S. Eisenberg, “Patents, Product Exclusivity, and Information Dissemination:
How Law Directs Biopharmaceutical Research and Development,” 72 Fordham Law
Review
(2003), 477.
12 Bonito Boats, Inc. v. Thunder Craft Boats, Inc., 489 U.S. 141 (1989).
13 Claude E. Barfield & Mark A. Groombridge, “Parallel Trade in the Pharmaceutical
Industry: Implications for Innovation, Consumer Welfare, and Health Policy,” 10 Fordham
Intellectual Property, Media and Entertainment Law Journal
(1999), 185.

CRS-3
that the patent system should not be used to regulate the movement of legitimate,
lawfully purchased products through the global marketplace.14
This report explores the intellectual property laws and policies concerning the
parallel importation of patented pharmaceuticals into the United States.15 It begins
with a review of patent policy and procedures. The report then discusses the current
legal framework for analyzing the permissibility of the parallel importation of
patented pharmaceuticals, including both the domestic and international exhaustion
doctrines. Special consideration is given to state and local governments that have
either themselves imported, or have encouraged others to import, patented
medications from foreign jurisdictions; the potential use of label licenses on patented
drugs; and the implications of international trade rules established by World Trade
Organization. This report closes with a review of legislative issues and alternatives
as they relate to intellectual property issues and parallel importation.
Fundamentals of Pharmaceutical Patents
Patent Policy
The patent system is animated by a number of policy objectives designed to
promote the production and dissemination of technological information. Many
commentators have argued that the patent system is necessary to encourage
individuals to engage in inventive activity.16 Proponents of this view reason that,
absent a patent system, inventions could easily be duplicated by free riders, who
would have incurred no cost to develop and perfect the technology involved, and who
could thus undersell the original inventor. The resulting inability of inventors to
capitalize on their inventions would lead to an environment where too few inventions
are made. By providing individuals with exclusive rights in their inventions for a
limited time, the patent system allows inventors to realize the profits from their
inventions. Further, these rights are grounded in the U.S. Constitution, which
authorizes Congress to delineate them.17
The courts have also suggested that absent a patent law, individuals would favor
maintaining their inventions as trade secrets so that competitors could not exploit
them. Trade secrets do not enrich the collective knowledge of society, however, nor
14 William Davis, “The Medicine Equity and Drug Safety Act of 2000: Releasing Grey
Market Pharmaceuticals,” 9 Tulane Journal of International and Comparative Law (2001),
483.
15 This report does not address other mechanisms to lower the prices of pharmaceuticals.
For one view on whether allowing the parallel importation of pharmaceuticals would in fact
lower prices, see Congressional Budget Office, Economic and Budget Issue Brief, Would
Prescription Drug Importation Reduce U.S. Drug Spending?
, by Colin Baker (April 29,
2004).
16 E.g., Dan L. Burk & Mark A. Lemley, “Policy Levers in Patent Law,” 89 Virginia Law
Review
(2003), 1575.
17 U.S. Constitution, Article I, § 8, cl. 8.

CRS-4
do they discourage others from engaging in duplicative research. The patent system
attempts to avoid these inefficiencies by requiring inventors to consent to the
disclosure of their inventions in issued patent instruments.18
There are still other explanations for the patent laws. For instance, the Patent
Act of 195219 is thought by supporters to stimulate technological advancement by
inducing individuals to “invent around” patented technology. Issued patent
instruments may point the way for others to develop improvements, exploit new
markets or discover new applications for the patented technology.20 The patent
system may encourage patentees to exploit their proprietary technologies during the
term of the patent. Proponents believe the protection provided by a patent’s
proprietary rights increases the likelihood a firm will continue to refine, produce and
market the patented technology.21 Finally, the patent law has been identified as a
facilitator of markets. Absent patent rights, an inventor may have scant tangible
assets to sell or license, and even less ability to police the conduct of a contracting
party. By reducing a licensee’s opportunistic possibilities, the patent system lowers
transaction costs and makes technology-based transactions more feasible.22
The current patent system has a great number of critics. Some assert that the
patent system is unnecessary due to market forces that already suffice to create an
optimal level of invention. The desire to gain a lead time advantage over
competitors, as well as the recognition that technologically backward firms lose out
to their rivals, may well provide sufficient inducement to invent without the need for
further incentives.23 Some commentators observe that successful inventors are
sometimes transformed into complacent, established enterprises that use patents to
suppress the innovations of others.24 Others assert that the inventions that have
fueled some of our most dynamic industries, such as early biotechnologies and
computer software, arose at a time when patent rights were unavailable or uncertain.25
While these various justifications and criticisms have differing degrees of
intuitive appeal, none of them has been empirically validated. No conclusive study
18 See, e.g., Grant v. Raymond, 31 U.S. 218, 247 (1832).
19 Pub. L. No. 82-593, 66 Stat. 792 (codified at Title 35 United States Code).
20 R. Polk Wagner, “Information Wants to Be Free: Intellectual Property and the Mythology
of Control,” 103 Columbia Law Review (2003), 995.
21 F. Scott Kieff, “Property Rights and Property Rules for Commercializing Inventions,” 85
Minnesota Law Review (2000), 697.
22 See Robert P. Merges, “Intellectual Property and the Costs of Commercial Exchange: A
Review Essay,” 93 Michigan Law Review (1995), 1570.
23 See Frederic M. Scherer & David Ross, Industrial Market Structure and Economic
Performance
(Rand McNally & Co., 3d ed. 1990).
24 See Robert P. Merges and Richard R. Nelson, On the Complex Economics of Patent
Scope
, 90 Columbia Law Review (1990), 839.
25 See, e.g., Pamela Samuelson, Benson Revisited: The Case Against Patent Protection for
Algorithms and Other Computer Program — Related Inventions
, 39 Emory Law Journal
(1990), 1025.

CRS-5
broadly demonstrates that we get more useful inventive activity with patents than we
would without them. The justifications and criticisms of the patent system therefore
remain open to challenge by those who are unpersuaded by their internal logic.26
U.S. Patent Acquisition and Enforcement
As mandated by the Patent Act of 1952,27 U.S. patent rights do not arise
automatically. Inventors must prepare and submit applications to the U.S. Patent and
Trademark Office (“USPTO”) if they wish to obtain patent protection.28 USPTO
officials, known as examiners, then assess whether the application merits the award
of a patent.29 The patent acquisition process is commonly known as “prosecution.”30
In deciding whether to approve a patent application, an USPTO examiner will
consider whether the submitted application fully discloses and distinctly claims the
invention.31 In addition, the application must disclose the “best mode,” or preferred
way, that the applicant knows to practice the invention.32 The examiner will also
determine whether the invention itself fulfills certain substantive standards set by the
patent statute. To be patentable, an invention must be useful, novel and nonobvious.
The requirement of usefulness, or utility, is satisfied if the invention is operable and
provides a tangible benefit.33 To be judged novel, the invention must not be fully
anticipated by a prior patent, publication or other knowledge within the public
domain.34 A nonobvious invention must not have been readily within the ordinary
skills of a competent artisan at the time the invention was made.35
If the USPTO allows the patent to issue, the patent proprietor obtains the right
to exclude others from making, using, selling, offering to sell or importing into the
United States the patented invention.36 The term of the patent is ordinarily set at
twenty years from the date the patent application was filed.37 Patent title therefore
provides inventors with limited periods of exclusivity in which they may practice
their inventions, or license others to do so. The grant of a patent permits the inventor
26 See CRS Report RL31951, Innovation, Intellectual Property, and Industry Standards, by
John R. Thomas.
27 Pub. L. No. 82-593, 66 Stat. 792 (codified at Title 35 United States Code).
28 35 U.S.C. § 111 (2000).
29 35 U.S.C. § 131 (2000).
30 John R. Thomas, “On Preparatory Texts and Proprietary Technologies: The Place of
Prosecution Histories in Patent Claim Interpretation,” 47 UCLA Law Review (1999), 183.
31 35 U.S.C. § 112 (2000).
32 Ibid.
33 35 U.S.C. § 101 (2000).
34 35 U.S.C. § 102 (2000).
35 35 U.S.C. § 103 (2000).
36 35 U.S.C. § 271(a) (2000).
37 35 U.S.C. § 154(a)(2) (2000).

CRS-6
to receive a return on the expenditure of resources leading to the discovery, often by
charging a higher price than would prevail in a competitive market.
Patent rights are not self-enforcing. A patentee bears responsibility for
monitoring its competitors to determine whether they are using the patented invention
or not. Patent owners who wish to compel others to observe their intellectual
property rights must usually commence litigation in the federal district courts. The
U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit (“Federal Circuit”) possesses exclusive
national jurisdiction over all patent appeals from the district courts,38 while the U.S.
Supreme Court possesses discretionary authority to review cases decided by the
Federal Circuit.39
Pharmaceutical patents are subject to special provisions created by the Drug
Price Competition and Patent Restoration Act of 1984.40 This legislation, which was
subject to significant legislative revisions in 2003,41 is commonly known as the
Hatch-Waxman Act.42 This statute establishes special rules for enforcement of
certain patents on certain drugs and medical devices by brand-name firms against
generic competitors. The Hatch-Waxman Act includes provisions extending the term
of a patent to reflect regulatory delays encountered in obtaining marketing approval
by the Food and Drug Administration (FDA);43 exempting from patent infringement
certain activities associated with regulatory marketing approval;44 establishing
mechanisms to challenge the validity of a pharmaceutical patent;45 and creating a
reward for disputing the validity, enforceability, or infringement of a patented and
approved drug.46 The 1984 Act also provides the FDA with certain authorities to
offer periods of marketing exclusivity for a pharmaceutical independent of the rights
conferred by patents.47
38 28 U.S.C. § 1295(a)(1) (2000).
39 28 U.S.C. §1254(1) (2000).
40 Pub. L. No. 98-417, 98 Stat. 1585 (1984).
41 The Medicare Prescription Drug and Modernization Act of 2003, Pub. L. No. 108-173,
Title XI (Dec. 8, 2003). See CRS Report RL32377, The Hatch-Waxman Act: Legislative
Changes in the 108th Congress Affecting Pharmaceutical Patents
, by Wendy H. Schacht and
John R. Thomas.
42 See CRS Report RL30756, Patent Law and Its Application to the Pharmaceutical
Industry: An Examination of the Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act
of 1984 (“The Hatch-Waxman Act”)
, by Wendy H. Schacht and John R. Thomas.
43 35 U.S.C. § 156 (2000).
44 35 U.S.C. § 271(e)(1) (2000).
45 21 U.S.C. § 355(j) (2000).
46 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv) (2000).
47 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(4)(D) (2000).

CRS-7
The Exhaustion Doctrine
Patent rights are subject to a significant restriction that is termed the
“exhaustion” doctrine. Under the exhaustion doctrine, an authorized, unrestricted
sale of a patented product depletes the patent right with respect to that physical
object.48 As a result of this doctrine, the purchaser of a patented good ordinarily may
use, charge others to use, or resell the good without further regard to the patentee.
The courts have reasoned that when a patentee sells a product without restriction, it
impliedly promises its customer that it will not interfere with the full enjoyment of
that product.49 The result is that the lawful purchasers of patented goods may use or
resell these goods free of the patent.50 Because it is the first sale of a patented
product that extinguishes patent rights with respect to the item that is sold, some
authorities refer to the exhaustion doctrine as the “first sale rule.”51
For example, suppose that a consumer purchases an appliance at a hardware
store. The appliance is subject to a patent that is owned by the manufacturer. Later,
the consumer sells the appliance to a neighbor at a garage sale. Ordinarily, the patent
laws provide the manufacturer with the ability to prevent others from selling an
appliance that uses its patented design.52 In this case, however, the patent right in
that particular appliance was exhausted when the manufacturer made its first sale to
the consumer. That consumer, as well as any subsequent purchasers of that
individual appliance, may freely sell it without concern for the manufacturer’s
patent.53
International Aspects
U.S. patents provide their owners with rights only within the United States.54
The grant of a U.S. patent provides its owner with no legal rights in any foreign
nation. If inventors desire intellectual property protection in another country, they
must specifically procure a patent in that jurisdiction. Ordinarily the foreign patent
acquisition process begins with the submission of a patent application to a foreign
patent office.55
48 See Intel Corp. v. ULSI System Technology, 995 F.2d 1566, 1568 (Fed.Cir.1993).
49 See B. Braun Medical, Inc. v. Abbott Laboratories, 124 F.3d 1419, 1426, (Fed.Cir.1997).
50 See Intel Corp. v. ULSI System Technology, 995 F.2d 1566 (Fed.Cir.1993).
51 See, e.g., Alan O. Sykes, “TRIPS, Pharmaceuticals, Developing Countries, and the Doha
‘Solution’,” 3 Chicago Journal of International Law (2002), 47.
52 35 U.S.C. § 271(a) (2000).
53 See Roger E. Schechter & John R. Thomas, Intellectual Property: The Law of Copyrights,
Patents and Trademarks
§ 1.2.3 (2003).
54 Quality Tubing, Inc. v. Precision Tube Holdings Co., 75 F.Supp.2d 613, 619 (S.D. Tex.
1999).
55 See CRS Report RL31132, Multinational Patent Acquisition and Enforcement: Public
Policy Challenges and Opportunities for Innovative Firms
, by John R. Thomas.

CRS-8
As a practical matter, multinational corporations often obtain a set of
corresponding national patents for each of their significant inventions. Although
these patents concern the same invention — for example, the same chemical
compound that possesses pharmacological properties — they often do not have
precisely the same legal effect in each jurisdiction. Divergent wordings of the
patents’ claims, translations into various languages, and distinctions between national
patent laws and practice are among the factors that lead to these differences.56
Under an important international agreement concerning patents, the Convention
of Paris for the Protection of Industrial Property (“Paris Convention”),57 each issued
national patent is an independent legal instrument. One significant consequence of
the independence of national patents is that they must be enforced individually.58 For
example, suppose that an inventor owns patents directed towards the same invention
in both the United States and Canada. Following litigation in Canada, a court rules
that the Canadian patent is invalid. Even though the Canadian patent may be similar
or identical to the U.S. patent, the U.S. patent may still be freely enforced. Although
a U.S. court may find the reasoning of the Canadian court persuasive as it reaches its
own judgment regarding the validity of the U.S. patent, the Canadian court decision
has no direct effect upon the validity or enforceability of the U.S. patent.59
The Parallel Importation of Patented
Pharmaceuticals
In some circumstances, widely divergent drug prices between the United States
and other nations have encouraged parallel importation. Price disparities between the
United States and other nations create incentives for individuals to purchase
medications from abroad, and import them into the United States, in order to lower
health care costs or undercut the U.S. distributor.60 In this context, the term “parallel
imports” refers to patented products that are legitimately distributed abroad, and then
sold to consumers in the United States without the permission of the authorized U.S.
dealer. Although these “grey market goods” are authentic products that were sold
under the authorization of the brand-name drug company, they entered the U.S.
market outside the usual distribution channels for that drug.

The legal situation regarding the parallel importation of patented
pharmaceuticals remains somewhat clouded. In such circumstances, the U.S. patent
56 See Margaret A. Boulware et al., “An Overview of Intellectual Property Rights Abroad,”
16 Houston Journal of International Law (1994), 441.t
57 13 U.S.T. 25 (1962).
58 See John R. Thomas, “Litigation Beyond the Technological Frontier: Comparative
Approaches to Multinational Patent Enforcement,” 27 Law & Policy in International
Business
(1996), 277.
59 Ibid.
60 See, e.g., Shubha Ghosh, “Pills, Patents and Power: State Creation of Gray Markets as
a Limit on Patent Rights,” 14 Florida Journal of International Law 217 (2002).

CRS-9
proprietor may be able to use its patent rights to block the importation of grey market
pharmaceuticals. Because this scenario involves the distribution of a patented
product that initially sold under the authorization of the patent proprietor, it raises
issues concerning the exhaustion doctrine.61
One position, favorable to the patent proprietor, is that the U.S. patent is fully
enforceable against imports despite the exhaustion doctrine. Under this line of
reasoning, the fact that the sale by the patent proprietor or its representative took
place outside the United States is significant. This line of reasoning relies on the fact
that U.S. patents exist independently of foreign patents,62 and that U.S. patents are
effective only within the United States.63 As a result, this reasoning continues, a
foreign sale cannot result in exhaustion of a U.S. patent. This legal doctrine —
which restricts the exhaustion doctrine to domestic sales only — allows the U.S.
patent to be used to block unauthorized imports of a patented pharmaceutical.64
A competing view is that the exhaustion doctrine is not limited to domestic sales
by the patentee or its representative, but to all sales regardless of their location. This
position is commonly referred to as “international exhaustion.”65 Under this view,
because the importer lawfully purchased authentic goods from the patent holder or
its representative, the U.S. patent right is subject to “international exhaustion” due
to the sale, despite the fact that the sale technically took place under a foreign
patent.66
In its 2001 decision in Jazz Photo Corp. v. United States International Trade
Commission,67 the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit (“Federal Circuit”)
rejected the “international exhaustion” position and instead limited the exhaustion
doctrine to sales that occur within the United States. There the Federal Circuit issued
a succinct statement explaining:
United States patent rights are not exhausted by patent rights of foreign
provenance. To invoke the protection of the first sale doctrine, the authorized
first sale must have occurred under the United States patent. See Boesch v.
Graff
, 133 U.S. 697, 10 S.Ct. 378, 33 L.Ed. 787 (1890).68
61 Nanao Naoko et al., “Decisions on Parallel Imports of Patented Goods,” 36 IDEA: The
Journal of Law and Technology
(1996), 567.
62 See supra notes 57-59 and accompanying text.
63 See supra note 54 and accompanying text.
64 35 U.S.C. § 271(a) (2000).
65 See Bruce A. Lehman, “Intellectual Property Rights as a Trade, Health, and Economic
Development Issue,” 17 St. John’s Journal of Legal Commentary (Spring 2003), 417.
66 See Jamie S. Gorelick & Rory K. Little, “The Case for Parallel Importation,” 11 North
Carolina Journal of International Law and Commercial Regulation
(1986), 205.
67 264 F.3d 1094 (Fed. Cir. 2001).
68 264 F.3d at 1105.

CRS-10
Some commentators have criticized the Federal Circuit’s reasoning in the Jazz
Photo case, and in particular the court’s reliance on the Boesch v. Graff decision.69
In Boesch v. Graff, the plaintiff owned a U.S. patent for a lamp burner. An
individual named Hecht, who was not a party to the litigation, enjoyed a “prior user
right” pertaining to the lamp burners under German law. The German patent statute
allowed individuals who had used an invention prior to the date of another’s patent
application the privilege of continuing to exploit the invention commercially, without
regard to the patent. Hecht had met the conditions for this prior user right to apply,
and as a result could sell the burners in Germany. Hecht eventually sold some
burners to the defendants, who in turn imported them into the United States and
commenced sales. The plaintiff brought suit to enjoin the sale of the imported
burners in the United States. In opposing the injunction, the defendants argued that
they had lawfully purchased the burners and that the U.S. patent should be subject to
the exhaustion doctrine. The Supreme Court rejected the defendant’s arguments,
holding:
The right which Hecht had to make and sell the burners in Germany was allowed
him under the laws of that country, and purchasers from him could not be thereby
authorized to sell the articles in the United States in defiance of rights of
patentees under a United States patent. . . . The sale of articles in the United
States under a United States patent cannot be controlled by foreign laws.70
The facts and holding of Boesch have suggested to some commentators that its
precedential reach is quite limited. In Boesch, it was a prior user, rather than the
patentee or its licensee, which made the foreign sale. The patentee neither consented
to the sale of the invention nor received compensation for that sale. According to
some observers, this is a much different state of affairs than the typical parallel
importation case, where either the patentee or an authorized overseas distributor
makes a sale as part of an arm’s-length commercial transaction.71
Given this precedential foundation, as well as the limited consideration of the
issue in Jazz Photo, some legal commentators have questioned whether this apparent
absolute ban on parallel importation will survive further judicial scrutiny.72 At the
moment, however, the Federal Circuit’s statement in the Jazz Photo case remains the
controlling patent law precedent. In particular, the federal district courts are bound
by the Jazz Photo decision unless the Federal Circuit or Supreme Court alters the
rule.73
69 Daniel Erlikhman, “Jazz Photo and the Doctrine of Patent Exhaustion: Implications to
TRIPS and the International Harmonization of Patent Protection,” 25 Hastings
Communications and Entertainment Law Journal
(2003), 307.
70 133 U.S. at 703.
71 Erlikhman, supra note 69.
72 Ibid.
73 See Matthew F. Weil & William C. Rooklidge, “State Un-Decisis: The Sometimes Rough
Treatment of Precedent in Federal Circuit Decision-Making,” 80 Journal of the Patent and
Trademark Office Society
(1998), 791.

CRS-11
To summarize current law, the Federal Circuit has taken the position that patent
exhaustion applies only to sales that occurred in the United States. This rule squarely
rejects the principle of “international exhaustion.” As a result, brand-name drug
companies may potentially block imports of patented medications into the United
States even if the imported good is the patent owner’s own product, legitimately sold
to a customer in a foreign jurisdiction.74
Related Issues
In addition to the issue of patent infringement, the parallel importation of
patented pharmaceuticals potentially raises a number of other complex issues. This
report next considers three of these issues: the status of state and local governments
that have either themselves imported, or have encouraged others to import, patented
medications from foreign jurisdictions; the potential use of label licenses on patented
drugs; and the implications of international trade rules established by World Trade
Organization (WTO).
State and Local Governments
Several state governments are currently considering plans to import or facilitate
the importation of prescription drugs. California, Illinois, Iowa, Minnesota, New
Hampshire, North Dakota, Vermont and Wisconsin are among those that have
considered importation programs.75 If a state government or agency of a state
encourages the importation of a patented medication in a manner that would infringe
a patent, then the patentee’s ability to obtain relief is at present time uncertain.
Observers have questioned whether the states should be subject to the patent
rights of private parties.76 The U.S. Constitution places a significant jurisdictional
hurdle before a patentee seeking to vindicate its rights against a state. The Eleventh
Amendment provides that a federal court is without power to entertain a suit by a
private person against a state, except under certain limited circumstances.77 Because
74 See Catalin Cosovanu, “Piracy, Price Discrimination, and Development: The Software
Sector in Eastern Europe and Other Emerging Markets,” 31 American Intellectual Property
Law Association Quarterly Journal
(2003), 165.
75 See CRS Report RL32191, Prescription Drug Importation and Internet Sales: A Legal
Overview
, by Jody Feder.
76 See, e.g., Jennifer Polse, “Holding the Sovereign’s Universities Accountable for Patent
Infringement After Florida Prepaid and College Savings Bank,” 89 California Law
Review
(2001), 507; Kenneth S. Weitzman, “Copyright and Patent Clause of the
Constitution: Does Congress Have the Authority to Abrogate State Eleventh Amendment
Sovereign Immunity After Pennsylvania v. Union Gas Co.?,” 2 Seton Hall Constitutional
Law Journal
(1991), 297.
77 The Eleventh Amendment to the U.S Constitution stipulates: “The judicial power of the
United States shall not be construed to extend to any suit in law or equity, commenced or
prosecuted against one of the United States by citizens of another state, or by citizens or
(continued...)

CRS-12
the federal courts possess exclusive jurisdiction over patent infringement litigation,78
this situation creates a dilemma for patentees — the only statutorily authorized forum
is constitutionally unavailable, and the only constitutional forum is statutorily
unavailable, at least for the assertion of a conventional patent infringement claim.
This means that a patentee’s only option would be a state court suit charging the state
government with a taking, or asserting general unfair competition principles, in order
to vindicate its patent rights.79
The Supreme Court established one notable exception to the Eleventh
Amendment prohibition against federal court litigation against a state. In Ex parte
Young
,80 the Court allowed private citizens to petition a federal court to enjoin state
officials acting in their official capacity from engaging in future conduct that would
violate the Constitution or a federal statute. The doctrine is based on a premise that
state officers who violate federal law in the course of discharging the duties of their
positions are acting outside the authority of their office, and therefore do not qualify
as the state or its agent for Eleventh Amendment purposes.81 The only remedy
available under the Ex parte Young ruling is prospective injunctive relief, however,
rather than a monetary judgment that would compensate for past harms.82 Further,
some uncertainty exists over the application of the Young exception to patents.
Although the federal patent statute establishes the conditions under which inventors
may obtain patents, an individual patent is effectively the grant of a private right, not
a federal law.
Congress attempted to abrogate the Eleventh Amendment immunity of states to
patent infringement suits in 1992. The Patent and Plant Variety Protection Remedy
Clarification Act introduced section 271(h) into the Patent Act of 1952.83 That
provision specified not only that the states were subject to patent infringement suits
in the federal courts, but that they were liable for any remedies that could be had
against a private party.84 However, the 1999 opinion of the Supreme Court in
Florida Prepaid Postsecondary Education Expense Board v. College Savings Bank
found that Congress had not properly abrogated state immunity to patent
77 (...continued)
subjects of any foreign state.”
78 28 U.S.C.A. § 1338(a) (2000) (“The district courts shall have original jurisdiction of any
civil action arising under any Act of Congress relating to patents . . . . Such jurisdiction
shall be exclusive of the courts of the states in patent . . . cases.”)
79 See, e.g., Jacobs Wind Electric Co. v. Florida Dep’t of Transportation, 919 F.2d 726 (Fed.
Cir. 1990).
80 209 U.S. 123 (1908).
81 Cardenas v. Anzai, 311 F.2d 929, 935 (9th Cir. 2002).
82 See Edelman v. Jordan, 415 U.S. 651, 667-69 (1974).
83 Pub. L. No. 102 — 560, 106 Stat. 4230 (Oct. 28, 1992).
84 35 U.S.C.A. § 271(h) (2000).

CRS-13
infringement litigation in the federal courts in keeping with the requirements of the
Eleventh Amendment.85
In Florida Prepaid and other opinions, the Supreme Court did leave open the
possibility that a state could waive its Eleventh Amendment immunity by submitting
to federal jurisdiction.86 In addition, Congress may in some cases overcome state
Eleventh Amendment immunity through legislation pursuant to another constitutional
authority, such as the Fourteenth Amendment.87 Several bills have been introduced
before Congress since the Supreme Court issued the Florida Prepaid decision that
would take this approach, but none has been enacted.88
The immunity to federal suit provided by the Eleventh Amendment is restricted
to state governments, and does not ordinarily apply to local governments.89 As a
result, a city or county government is generally not entitled to claim Eleventh
Amendment immunity and avoid a suit for patent infringement in a federal court.
However, some judicial opinions have reasoned that a political subdivision of a state
can qualify for Eleventh Amendment immunity where the locality is only nominally
the actor, and the state itself is the real party in interest in the litigation.90 This
determination depends on the precise relationship between the state and its political
subdivision under the circumstances of a particular case.91
Label Licenses
As noted previously, the theory behind the exhaustion doctrine is that when a
patent proprietor makes an unrestricted sale of a product to a consumer, the
proprietor impliedly promises its customer that it will not use its patent rights to
interfere with the full enjoyment of that product.92 As a result, lawful purchasers of
patented goods should be able to use or resell these goods free of the patent.93
85 527 U.S. 627, 119 S.Ct. 2199, 144 L.Ed.2d 575 (1999).
86 Atascadero State Hospital v. Scanlon, 473 U.S. 234, 238 (1985).
87 Welch v. Department of Highways and Public Transportation, 483 U.S. 468, 477 (1987).
88 Jeffrey W. Childers, “State Sovereign Immunity and the Protection of Intellectual
Property: Do Recent Congressional Attempts to ‘Level the Playing Field’ Run Afoul of
Current Eleventh Amendment Jurisprudence and Other Constitutional Doctrines?,” 82 North
Carolina Law Review
(2004), 1067.
89 See, e.g. Mount Healthy School District v. Doyle, 429 U.S. 274 (1977). See also Melvyn
R. Durschlag, “Should Political Subdivisions Be Accorded Eleventh Amendment
Immunity?,” 43 DePaul Law Review (1994), 577; Anthony J. Harwood, “A Narrow
Eleventh Amendment Immunity for Political Subdivisions: Reconciling the Arm of State
Doctrine with Federalism Principles,” 55 Fordham Law Review (1986), 101.
90 See, e.g., Belanger v. Madera Unified School District, 963 F.2d 248, 254 (9th Cir. 1992).
91 Donald L. Boren, “Congressional Power to Grant Federal Courts Jurisdiction Over States:
The Impact of Pennsylvania v. Union Gas,” 24 Akron Law Review (1990), 13.
92 See B. Braun Medical, Inc. v. Abbott Laboratories, 124 F.3d 1419, 1426 (Fed.Cir.1997).
93 See Intel Corp. v. ULSI System Technology, 995 F.2d 1566 (Fed.Cir.1993).

CRS-14
In some circumstances, however, the patent owner may attempt to restrict a
customer’s use of a good. Sales contracts are the typical mechanism for imposing
such limitations. Contractual provisions that are placed on the product or its
packaging are sometimes termed “label licenses” or “bag tags.”94 A commonly
observed label license is “Single Use Only,” as applied to printer cartridges or other
goods that the manufacturer does not intend for consumers to reuse.95 Other patent
proprietors have attempted to impose geographical limitations upon the use of their
products. A label stating “For Use in Canada Only” is representative of such a
restriction.
Whether such label licenses are enforceable, or are instead nullified by the
exhaustion principle, is a complex legal issue. However, the prevailing view of the
Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit is that absent exceptional circumstances —
such as an antitrust violation or misuse of the patent by its proprietor — these
restrictions will be upheld.96 The legal theory is that the patent right gives proprietors
the ability to exclude others from using the patented product, they may also impose
lesser restrictions when they choose to sell the patented product.97 In addition,
customers are presumed to have entered into binding sales contracts that are
presumptively valid.98 As the law currently stands, then, a customer who violates a
label license could be liable both for breach of contract and for patent infringement.99
The TRIPS Agreement
As a member of the World Trade Organization (WTO), the United States is a
signatory to the so-called TRIPS Agreement, or Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects
of Intellectual Property Rights.100 Under Part III of the TRIPS Agreement, all
member countries agreed to enact patent statutes that include certain substantive
provisions. In particular, Article 27 stipulates that “patents shall be available and
patent rights enjoyable without discrimination as to the place of invention, the field
94 See, e.g., Daniel R. Cahoy, “Oasis or Mirage? Efficient Breach as a Relief to the Burden
of Contractual Recapture of Patent and Copyright Limitations,” 17 Harvard Journal of Law
and Technology
(2003), 135; Michael J. Madison, “Reconstructing the Software License,”
35 Loyola University of Chicago Law Journal (2003), 275.
95 See Mallinckrodt, Inc. v. Medipart, Inc., 976 F.2d 700 (Fed. Cir. 1992).
96 See Monsanto Co. v. McFarling, 363 F.3d 1336 (Fed. Cir. 2004); Bowers v. Baystate
Technologies, Inc.
, 320 F.3d 1317 (Fed. Cir. 2003).
97 See Richard Stern, “Post-Sale Restrictions After Mallinckrodt — An Idea in Search of
a Definition,” 5 Albany Law Journal of Science and Technology (1994), 1.
98 See Merritt A. Gardiner, “Bowers v. Baystate Technologies: Using the Shrinkwrap
License to Circumvent the Copyright Act and Escape Federal Preemption,” 11 University
of Miami Business Law Review
(Winter/Spring 2003), 105.
99 See Raymond Nimmer, “Issues in Software Licensing,” 576 Practising Law Institute/Pat.
(1999), 399.
100 See Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, Apr. 15, 1994,
Annex 1C, 33 I.L.M. 1197 (1994) [hereinafter “TRIPS Agreement”].

CRS-15
of technology and whether products are imported or locally prevented.”101 Article 27
ordinarily requires that all classes of invention receive the same treatment under the
patent laws, subject to certain minor exceptions. It would generally be impermissible
under Article 27, for example, for a country to accord patents on pharmaceuticals a
lesser set of proprietary rights than is available for patents on automobile engines,
computers, or other kinds of inventions.102
The TRIPS Agreement places lesser obligations upon signatory states with
regard to the exhaustion doctrine, however.103 Article 6 of the TRIPS Agreement
states:
For the purposes of dispute settlement under this Agreement, subject to the
provisions of Articles 3 and 4 above nothing in this Agreement shall be used to
address the issue of the exhaustion of intellectual property rights.104
The referenced Articles 3 and 4 of the TRIPS Agreement impose obligations of
national treatment and most-favored-nation status respectively. As a result, a TRIPS
Agreement signatory may not permissibly establish more favorable exhaustion rules
for its own citizens than for citizens of other WTO countries.105 In addition, if a
TRIPS Agreement signatory provides for favorable treatment with respect to the
exhaustion doctrine to one WTO member state, then the same treatment must be
extended to all WTO member states.106 Other than these basic national treatment and
most-favored-nation obligations, the TRIPS Agreement does not impose other
restrictions regarding the exhaustion doctrine. In particular, the TRIPS Agreement
does not appear to require that all types of inventions be treated equally with regard
to the exhaustion doctrine.
Legislative Issues and Alternatives
Should congressional interest continue in this area, a variety of options are
available. If the possibility of an infringement action against unauthorized importers
of patented pharmaceuticals is deemed sound, then no action need be taken.
Alternatively, Congress could confirm the Federal Circuit’s decision in Jazz Photo,
101 TRIPS Agreement, Article 27(1).
102 See J.H. Reichman, “Universal Minimum Standards of Protection Under the TRIPS
Component of the WTO Agreement,” 29 International Lawyer (1995), 345.
103 See Lana Kraus, “Medication Misadventures: The Interaction of International Reference
Pricing and Parallel Trade in the Pharmaceutical Industry,” 37 Vanderbilt Journal of
Transnational Law
(2004), 527.
104 TRIPS Agreement, Article 6.
105 See, e.g., Shubha Ghosh, “Pills, Patents and Power: State Creation of Gray Markets as
a Limit on Patent Rights,” 14 Florida Journal of International Law 217 (2002).
106 Ibid.

CRS-16
which rejects the doctrine of international exhaustion and confines the exhaustion
principle to sales that occurred within the United States.107
If legislative activity is deemed appropriate, however, another possibility is the
introduction of some form of international exhaustion doctrine into U.S. patent law.
The TRIPS Agreement does not seem to require that a country adopt the international
exhaustion doctrine as an all-or-nothing proposition, applying either to all patented
products or to none.108 As a result, if Congress chose to limit application of the
international exhaustion doctrine to patented pharmaceuticals, or some other specific
type of invention, then no ramifications appear to arise with respect to the TRIPS
Agreement obligations of the United States. It should be noted, however, that there
appears to be no precedent, either domestically or abroad, for establishing an
international exhaustion doctrine that is specific to pharmaceuticals.
At least two statutory mechanisms exist for implementing the international
exhaustion doctrine into U.S. patent law. One possible approach would be to declare
that importation into the United States of goods sold abroad by a patent proprietor or
its representative is not a patent infringement. S. 2328, the Pharmaceutical Market
Access and Drug Safety Act of 2004, takes this approach with respect to patented
pharmaceuticals, specifying that:
It shall not be an act of infringement to use, offer to sell, or sell within the United
States or to import into the United States any patented invention under section
804 of the Federal Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act that was first sold abroad by
or under authority of the owner or licensee of such patent.109
S. 2328 further stipulates that this amendment shall not be construed “to affect the
ability of a patent owner or licensee to enforce their patent, subject to such
amendment.”110 This language suggests a congressional intention to leave intact
other rights established by the Patent Act of 1952.
In addition to codifying the international exhaustion doctrine with respect to
pharmaceuticals, the amendment proposed in S. 2328 may conversely lead to the
implication that the international exhaustion doctrine does not apply to patented
inventions other than pharmaceuticals. This provision could potentially fortify the
ruling in the Jazz Photo case for inventions outside of the pharmaceutical field.
Another statutory mechanism for promoting the importation of patented drugs
is to immunize specific individuals from infringement liability. The Patent Act takes
this approach in the area of patented medical methods, exempting licensed medical
practitioners and certain health care entities from patent infringement in certain
107 See supra notes 67-74 and accompanying text.
108 See supra notes 100-06 and accompanying text.
109 S. 2328, § 4(f)(1)(B).
110 S. 2328, § 4(f)(2).

CRS-17
circumstances.111 In the case of drug importation, potential patent infringers include
importers, distributors, wholesalers, pharmacies, and individual consumers. Should
Congress wish to promote parallel trade in patented pharmaceuticals, an explicit
statutory infringement exemption could encourage individuals to engage in drug
importation.
In considering these or other legal changes to the patent laws, the possibility of
label licenses should be kept in mind. Even if Congress exempted drug importation
practices or practitioners from patent infringement liability, firms may still be able
to stipulate through the contract law that a drug sold in a foreign jurisdiction is for
use exclusively within that jurisdiction.112 If a purchaser instead imported that
medication into the United States, then the seller may have a cause of action for
breach of contract. As a result, any legal changes may need to account for the ability
of firms to use contractual provisions as something of a substitute for patent
protection in the area of prescription drug importation.
In addition, the issue of drug importation may provide an impetus for
clarification of the patent infringement liability of state governments.113 Some states,
as well as political subdivisions of the states, have either seriously considered or
commenced the practice of drug importation. To the extent that these authorities
continue this trend, their potential Eleventh Amendment immunity to a patent
infringement case in federal court may present another significant issue concerning
patents and drug importation.
Controlling the costs of prescription drug spending, on one hand, and
encouraging the development of new drugs, on the other, are both significant goals.
These aspirations may potentially conflict, however. Although introducing
international exhaustion into U.S. patent law may initially lower the price of patented
drugs, it might also decrease the incentive of firms to engage in the research and
development of new pharmaceuticals, as well as to shepherd new drugs through time-
consuming and costly marketing approval procedures. Consideration of patent law
reforms would likely be put into the larger context of drug costs, which may be
influenced by the pricing policies of foreign nations, profits earned by wholesalers
and other intermediaries, the physical costs of shipment into the United States, and
other diverse factors.114 Striking a balance between increasing access to medications
and ensuring the continued development of new drugs by our nation’s pharmaceutical
firms is a central concern of the current drug importation debate
111 35 U.S.C. § 287(c) (2000).
112 See supra notes 92-99 and accompanying text.
113 See supra notes 75-91 and accompanying text.
114 See Congressional Budget Office, Economic and Budget Issue Brief, Would Prescription
Drug Importation Reduce U.S. Drug Spending?
, by Colin Baker (April 29, 2004).