Order Code IB97057
CRS Issue Brief for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
Global Climate Change:
Market-Based Strategies
to Reduce Greenhouse Gases
Updated August 1, 2003
Larry Parker
Resources, Science, and Industry Division
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

CONTENTS
SUMMARY
MOST RECENT DEVELOPMENTS
BACKGROUND AND ANALYSIS
Status of Global Climate Change Issue and Response
Estimating Cost Impacts of Controls
Market-Based Mechanisms for Reducing Greenhouse Gases
Tradeable Permits (Allowances)
Tradeable Permits (Credits)
Carbon/CO2 Emissions Tax
Joint Implementation
Issues
Cost-Effectiveness: Price versus Quantity
Comprehensiveness
Economic Impact
Equity
Legislation in the 108th Congress
Other Proposals
United States and International Activities
Administration Domestic Initiatives


IB97057
08-01-03
Global Climate Change:
Market-Based Strategies to Reduce Greenhouse Gases
SUMMARY
The possibility that human activities are
The specific effects of both a carbon tax
releasing gases, including carbon dioxide
and tradeable permit program would depend
(CO2), at rates that could affect global climate
on the specific levy (carbon tax) or allocation
has resulted in proposals for national pro-
scheme (tradeable permit) chosen, the scope
grams to curtail emissions. An international
of the program, the timing of the reductions,
framework for specific reductions in green-
and the recycling of any revenues.
house gases was negotiated at a meeting in
Kyoto in December 1997.
Concern about
In addition, many tradeable permit pro-
costs has encouraged consideration of CO2
posals include provisions allowing countries
reduction proposals that employ market-based
to accumulate permits by reducing emissions
mechanisms. The passage in 1990 of a trade-
in other countries. This scheme, called joint
able allowance system for sulfur dioxide
implementation, was approved in principle at
(SO2) control in the United States to reduce
the Kyoto conference in December 1997.
acid rain provides a precedent for such mecha-
nisms.
The climate change issue and CO2 con-
trol raise numerous equity issues.
In one
The two mechanisms receiving the most
sense, climate change is a concern about
attention are a tradeable permit program
intergenerational equity — i.e., the well-being
(similar to the acid rain program) and carbon
of the current generation versus generations to
taxes. Proposed CO2 reduction schemes
come. On a global level, the issue also in-
present large uncertainties in terms of the
volves the North-South debate. At the domes-
perceived reduction needs and the potential
tic level, equity questions include the regional
costs of achieving those reductions. Tradeable
distribution of costs under a tradeable permit
permit programs would reduce CO2 emissions
or carbon tax scheme. For example, an impor-
to a specific level with the control cost han-
tant impact of either a carbon tax based on the
dled efficiently, but not at a specific cost level.
carbon content of fossil fuels or a tradeable
Carbon taxes would effectively cap marginal
permit program would be the pressure for fuel
control costs at the specific tax level, but the
shifts away from coal and toward gas. Re-
precise level of CO2 reduction achieved
gions such as fast-growing areas in need of
would be less certain. Hence, a major policy
more energy and owners of “all electric”
question is whether one is more concerned
homes, among others, would likely be dispro-
about the possible cost of the program and
portionately hit by a CO2 control scheme. In
therefore willing to accept some uncertainty
addition, people may be affected differently
about emission reduction in order to have
according to income class.
These issues,
some limits on costs (i.e., carbon taxes) or
however, have not been sufficiently analyzed
whether one is more concerned about achiev-
at the current time to be sure of how various
ing a specific emission reduction level with
sectors would be affected.
costs handled efficiently, but not capped (i.e.,
tradeable permits).
Congressional Research Service
˜ The Library of Congress

IB97057
08-01-03
MOST RECENT DEVELOPMENTS
In July 2003, the Senate leadership announced that as part of an agreement to pass a
comprehensive energy bill that S. 139 would be brought before the Senate at a future date.
In the 108th Congress, four bills have been introduced to control CO2 emissions. S. 139,
introduced by Senators McCain and Lieberman, would reduce and cap emissions of carbon
dioxide from electricity generation, transportation, industrial, and commercial sectors. The
reductions would be implemented in two phases with an emissions cap in the year 2010
based on affected facilities’ 2000 emissions, and a further reduction cap imposed in the year
2016 based on affected facilities’ 1990 emissions. The program would be implemented
through an expansive allowance trading program that includes cross-sector trading and
limited acquisition of allowances from foreign sources. The second bill, S. 366, introduced
by Senator Jeffords, is a modified version of the multi-pollutant bill reported out by the
Senate Environment and Public Works Committee in the 107th Congress. It would reduce
and cap emissions of carbon dioxide from electricity generation at their 1990 levels by the
year 2009. Similar to S. 139, the program would be implemented through an allowance
trading program. The third bill, S. 843, introduced by Senator Carper, is a multi-pollutant
control bill that includes carbon dioxide reductions. S. 843 would cap carbon dioxide
emissions from powerplants at their 2006 levels by 2009 and further cap emissions at their
2001 levels by 2013. The fourth bill, H.R. 2042, introduced by Representative Waxman, is
also a multi-pollutant control bill and would cap carbon dioxide emissions from powerplants
at their 1990 levels by the year 2009.
In December 2002, the Slovak Republic and a Japanese firm become the first entities
to consummate an emissions trade under the Kyoto Protocol. No price was released on the
200,000 metric ton trade, but current global prices for greenhouse gas credits suggest a range
of $3-$5 a ton.
In February 2002, the Bush Administration initiated a new voluntary greenhouse gas
reduction program. Rather than attempting to meet a specific reduction target, the proposal
focuses on improving the carbon efficiency of the economy.
BACKGROUND AND ANALYSIS
Certain gases emitted as a result of human activities may be affecting global climate.
Most concern centers on the possibility that CO2, along with other gases, could increase
global temperatures, with subsequent effects on precipitation patterns and ocean levels that
could affect agriculture, energy use, and other human activities.
Status of Global Climate Change Issue and Response
The initial issue of whether the potential for global climate change poses a threat that
justifies prompt action to curtail CO2 and other so-called greenhouse gases remains actively
CRS-1

IB97057
08-01-03
debated—both domestically and internationally. (For a review of the technical dimensions
of this question, see CRS Issue Brief IB89005, Global Climate Change.) Some view the
risks as sufficiently grave and urgent to justify immediate action. Others are uncertain of the
risks but believe that selected policies to reduce emissions can be justified for other reasons
and would provide insurance if the risks were borne out; these other reasons include
improved energy efficiency, reduced reliance on imported oil, and increased revenues. Still
others caution that actions to reduce CO2 and other greenhouse gases could disrupt the
nation’s economy and should not be undertaken unless further scientific evidence of risks
becomes available.
Despite the uncertainties, however, scientists and policymakers have increasingly
adopted the view that human activities are releasing greenhouse gases at rates that could
affect global climate. As a result, initiatives are underway to address the issue, resulting in
proposals for national and international programs to curtail emissions.
An agreement on a United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
(UNFCCC) was on the agenda at the U.N. Conference on Economic Development in Rio de
Janeiro in June 1992. The United States was an early signatory to the agreement, which was
approved by the Senate October 7, 1992. In April 1993, President Clinton directed the
federal government to craft a plan that would stabilize U.S. greenhouse gas emissions at
1990 levels by the year 2000. However, in 2000, the United States did not meet its voluntary
commitment at Rio to stabilize greenhouse gas emissions at 1990 levels. Indeed, it is unclear
when U.S. carbon emissions may stabilize. The 2002 Climate Action Report by the current
Bush Administration estimates U.S. carbon emissions in the year 2010 will be 34% above
their 1990 levels. (For more on U.S. domestic climate change policy since Rio, see CRS
Report RL30024, Global Climate Change Policy: Cost, Competitiveness, and
Comprehensiveness
.)
Meanwhile, the United States and other signatories to the Climate Change Convention
met in December 1997 in Kyoto, Japan, to conclude negotiations on a binding protocol for
specific provisions to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by developed countries, including the
United States. The final protocol agreed to at Kyoto requires the United States to reduce
emissions of six greenhouse gases (CO2, methane, nitrous oxide, hydrofluorocarbons,
perfluorocarbons, sulfur hexafluoride) by 7% on average from 1990 levels over the period
2008-2012. In contrast, undeveloped countries are not required to make reduction under the
Protocol. In November 1998, the parties met in Buenos Aires to develop work plans for
specific elements of the Kyoto Protocol, including the trading of emission reductions and the
Clean Development Mechanism. The parties decided that these work plans should be
completed by the year 2000. The November 1999 meeting in Bonn postponed decisions
about emissions trading until the November 2000 meeting at the Hague. The meeting at The
Hague failed to arrive at agreement on emissions trading, and scheduled further negotiations
May 2001. However, in March 2001, the current Bush Administration announced that it was
formally abandoning the emission targets set under Kyoto. (For more on the U.S. reduction
requirement under Kyoto, see CRS Report 98-235 ENR, Global Climate Change: U.S.
Greenhouse Gas Emissions — Status, Trends, and Projections.
)
This decision by the Bush Administration has not deterred the international community.
In July 2001, the Sixth Conference of Parties to the Framework Convention on Climate
Change agreed to a draft decision on implementing the Kyoto Protocol. With respect to
CRS-2

IB97057
08-01-03
flexible implementation mechanisms, the Parties agreed to exclude nuclear power as a
possible non-carbon alternative under the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) and joint
implementation program. The Parties also reiterated that use of flexible mechanisms shall
be supplemental to domestic efforts.
The United States did not participate in these
deliberations. In November 2001, the Seventh Conference of Parties to the Framework
Convention on Climate Change concluded negotiations on implementation of the Kyoto
Protocol. With respect to flexible implementation mechanisms, the Parties outlined the
institutions that would oversee the flexible implementation mechanisms contained in the
Protocol. However, the Conference put off deciding on the consequences of non-compliance
until a later date. The United States was a non-participant to most of what took place at this
conference.
In October 2002, the Eighth Conference of Parties to the Framework Convention on
Climate Change met in New Delhi (October 23 - November 1). The conference produced
agreement on the procedures governing the Clean Development Mechanism.
In December 2002, the Slovak Republic and a Japanese firm become the first entities
to consummate an emissions trade under the Kyoto Protocol. No price was released on the
200,000 metric ton trade, but current global prices for greenhouse gas credits suggest a range
of $3-$5 a ton. Thus, despite continuing uncertainties about the risks of global climate
change, proposals for addressing it are going forward, and it is the content of those proposals
rather than the issue of whether the problem is exigent that is the focus of this brief.
Estimating Cost Impacts of Controls
Estimates of costs to reduce CO2 emissions vary greatly and focus attention on an
estimator’s basic beliefs about the problem and the future, rather than on simple, technical
differences in economic assumptions. (See CRS Report 98-738, Global Climate Change:
Three Policy Perspectives
. It identifies three “lenses” through which people can view the
global climate change issues, and their influence on cost analysis.) These are summarized in
Table 1. None of these perspectives is inherently more “right” or “correct” than another;
rather, they overlap and to varying degrees complement and conflict with each other. People
hold to each of the lenses to some degree.
However, the differing perspectives lead to very different cost estimates. Figure 1 below
shows a scatter-plot by World Resources Institute (WRI) of the predicted impacts from 162
estimates from 16 different economic models on the U.S. economy from a CO2 abatement
program. Although the size of the proposed CO2 reduction and the time allowed to achieve
it (not explicitly modeled in the WRI report) are critical factors in determining the costs and
benefits of any reduction program, WRI found that underlying modeling assumptions not
related to policy decisions explained a significant amount of the difference in the estimates.
Consistent with a “technological” view of the problem, models that assumed technological
development of non-carbon substitutes for current fossil fuel use, along with increased
energy and product substitutions, had significantly less cost than models that assumed such
advancements would not occur in a timely fashion. For example, a recent study by the
American Council for an Energy-efficient Economy (ACEEE) argues that carbon emissions
could fall 10% below 1990 levels by 2010 with a net economic savings of $58 billion along
with 800,000 new jobs. Such savings are assumed to come from new technology and market
CRS-3


IB97057
08-01-03
mechanisms to encourage cost-effective implementation strategies.
Such a position
presumes that technologies are available now, or will be very shortly, that can achieve these
reductions cost-effectively.
Likewise, consistent with an “ecological” perspective, models that included the benefits
of air pollution damages and climate change damages averted by the CO2 reduction
estimated considerably less costs to the economy than models that did not include such
benefits. The WRI report suggests that the cost profile of a CO2 reduction program changes
substantially if one includes the benefits of air pollution and climate change effect averted
by controlling CO2. The Clinton Administration’s 1998 analysis of costs to comply with
Kyoto estimates benefits from controlling ancillary pollutants (SO2, NOx, and fine
particulates) at between $1.8 and $10.6 billion annually.
Consistent with an “economic” perspective, models that included policy approaches that
encouraged efficient economic responses to CO2 reductions, included joint implementation
schemes, and involved efficient recycling of any revenues from control strategies
significantly reduced costs over models runs that did not include such policy options. Like
the technology perspective, economically efficient solutions assume that the program is
CRS-4

IB97057
08-01-03
implemented in such a way to permit the economy sufficient time to absorb the new price
signals with minimal short-term constraints.
The uncertainty about the risk of climate change and the critical impact of assumptions
about the nature of the problem effectively preclude predictions of the ultimate costs of
reducing greenhouse gases. As a result, attention has focused on how to minimize costs by
selecting the most economically efficient strategies to reduce CO2 emissions. Traditionally,
air pollution control programs have relied on various “command and control” regulatory
approaches, including ambient quality and technology-based standards. But increasingly,
economic efficiency concerns have been directed toward supplementing regulatory control
with market-based mechanisms, including pollution taxes and tradeable permits.
The tradeable allowance system for SO2 control in the acid rain program enacted in
1990 represents a significant step in this evolution of economic mechanisms. Acceptance
of this system has led to calls for use of a similar system with other pollutants, including
CO2. Three bills proposing a tradeable permit-type system to begin controlling CO2
emissions have been introduced in the 107th Congress, which are discussed in a later section.
Table 1: Influence of Climate Change Perspectives on Policy
Parameters
Seriousness of
Risk in developing
Approach
problem
mitigation program
Costs
Technology
Is agnostic on the merits
Believes any reduction
Viewed from the bottom-
of the problem. The
program should be
up. Tends to see
focus is on developing
designed to maximize
significant energy
new technology that can
opportunities for new
inefficiencies in the
be justified from
technology. Risk lies in
current economic system
multiple criteria,
not developing technology
that currently (or
including economic,
by the appropriate time.
projected) available
environmental and
Focus on research,
technologies can
social perspectives.
development, and
eliminate at little or no
demonstration; and on
overall cost to the
removing barriers to
economy.
commercialization of new
technology.
Economic
Understands issue in
Believes that economic
Viewed from the top-
terms of quantifiable
costs should be examined
down. Tends to see a
cost-benefit analysis.
against economic benefits
gradual improvement in
Generally assumes the
in determining any specific
energy efficiency in the
status quo is the
reduction program. Risk
economy, but significant
baseline from which
lies in imposing costs in
costs (quantified in terms
costs and benefits are
excess of benefits. Any
of GDP loss) resulting
measured.
chosen reduction goal
from global climate
Unquantifiable
should be implemented
change control programs.
uncertainty tends to be
through economic
Typical loss estimates
ignored.
measures such as tradeable
range from 1-2% of
permits or emission taxes.
GDP.
CRS-5

IB97057
08-01-03
Seriousness of
Risk in developing
Approach
problem
mitigation program
Costs
Technology
Is agnostic on the merits
Believes any reduction
Viewed from the bottom-
of the problem. The
program should be
up. Tends to see
focus is on developing
designed to maximize
significant energy
new technology that can
opportunities for new
inefficiencies in the
be justified from
technology. Risk lies in
current economic system
multiple criteria,
not developing technology
that currently (or
including economic,
by the appropriate time.
projected) available
environmental and
Focus on research,
technologies can
social perspectives.
development, and
eliminate at little or no
demonstration; and on
overall cost to the
removing barriers to
economy.
commercialization of new
technology.
Ecological
Understands issues in
Rather than economic
Views costs from an
terms of their potential
costs and benefits or
ethical perspective in
threat to basic values,
technological opportunity,
terms of the ecological
including ecological
effective protection of the
values that global climate
viability and the well-
planet’s ecosystems should
change threatens.
being of future
be the primary criterion in
Believes that values such
generations. Such
determining the specifics
as intergenerational
values reflect ecological
of any reduction program.
equity should not be
and ethical
Focus of program should
considered commodities
considerations;
be on altering values and
to be bought and sold.
adherents see attempts
broadening consumer
Costs are defined broadly
to convert them into
choices.
to include aesthetic and
commodities to be
environmental values that
bought and sold as
economic analysis cannot
trivializing the issue.
readily quantify and
monetize.
Market-Based Mechanisms for Reducing Greenhouse
Gases
Proposals to use market mechanisms to implement greenhouse gas emission reductions
have revolved around three approaches: tradeable permits (as “allowances” and as “credits”),
carbon taxes, and joint implementation. The protocol negotiated at Kyoto contains articles
on emissions trading and joint implementation. These provisions were strongly supported
by the Clinton Administration. In addition, some European countries have implemented or
are considering carbon taxes to bring about greenhouse gas reductions in their countries.
Tradeable Permits (Allowances)
A model for a tradeable permit approach is the SO2 allowance program to reduce acid
rain contained in Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments. The Title IV program is
based on two premises. First, a set amount of SO2 emitted by human activities can be
assimilated by the ecological system without undue harm. Thus the goal of the program is
to put a ceiling, or cap, on the total emissions of SO2 rather than limit ambient
concentrations.
Second, a market in pollution rights between polluters is the most
cost-effective means of achieving a given reduction. This market in pollution rights (or
CRS-6

IB97057
08-01-03
allowances, each of which is equal to one ton of SO2) is designed so that owners of
allowances can trade those allowances with other emitters who need them or retain (bank)
them for future use or sale. Initially, most allowances were allocated by the federal
government to utilities according to statutory formulas related to a given facility’s historic
fuel use and emissions; other allowances have been reserved by the government for periodic
auctions to ensure the liquidity of the market.
Conceptually, a CO2 tradeable permit program could work similarly. Some number of
CO2 allowances could be allocated, and a market in the allowances would permit emitters
to use, sell, buy, or bank them. However, significant differences exist between acid rain and
possible global warming that may affect the appropriateness of a Title IV-type response to
CO2 control. For example, the acid rain program involves up to 3,000 new and existing
electric generating facilities that contribute two-thirds of the country’s SO2 and one-third of
its nitrogen oxide (NOx) emissions (the two primary precursors of acid rain).
This
concentration of sources makes the logistics of allowance trading administratively
manageable and enforceable. However, CO2 emissions are not so concentrated. Although
over 95% of the CO2 generated comes from fossil fuel combustion, only about 33% comes
from electricity generation. Transportation accounts for about 33%, direct residential and
commercial use about 12%, and direct industrial use about 20%. Thus, small dispersed
sources in transportation, residential/commercial, and the industrial sectors are far more
important in controlling CO2 emissions than they are in controlling SO2 emissions. This
creates significant administrative and enforcement problems for a tradeable permit program
if it attempts to be comprehensive.
These concerns multiply as the global nature of the climate change issue is considered,
along with other potential greenhouse gases. Article 3 of the protocol negotiated at Kyoto
emphasizes that any international emissions trading should be supplemental to a country’s
domestic efforts, not a substitute for them.
Current SO2 allowance trading plans between individual utilities do not shed much light
on how well the existing allowance market will work over the long-term. Some individual
trades between utilities and EPA-sponsored auctions have been conducted, but the current
level of trading activity has not established the long-term viability of the marketplace. For
a market to thrive, transactions must become sufficiently commonplace for an open, public
market price to be established with limited bilateral negotiation. Based on the results of the
EPA auctions conducted by the Chicago Board of Trade, allowance prices are considerably
below that anticipated when the legislation was enacted. However, the six-year experience
of the SO2-allowance market may be insufficient to give much guidance on how well a
CO2-allowance market might work.
Tradeable Permits (Credits)
As noted above, a tradeable allowance involves future emissions. An allowance is a
limited authorization to emit a ton of pollutant; allowances are allocated to an emitting
facility under an applicable emission limitation at the beginning of a year. The facility
decides whether to use, trade, or bank those allowances, depending on its emissions strategy.
Then, at the end of the year, the agency compares an emitting facility’s actual emissions with
its available allowances to determine compliance.
CRS-7

IB97057
08-01-03
A different approach to creating a tradeable permit program is to use credits instead of
allowances. A credit is created when a facility actually emits a pollutant at less than its
allowable limit as defined in by the program. An example of this type of program is EPA’s
“Emission Reduction Credit program” (ERC) under the Clean Air Act. Under the ERC
program, EPA requires that any credit created under a state program implementing emissions
trading be “surplus, enforceable (by the state), permanent, and quantifiable.” Thus, a state
must certify the creation of the credit, unlike an allowance program, where allocation is
dictated by a statutory or regulatory formula. Any CO2 reduction credit program could build
on EPA’s and states’ experience with the current emission reduction credit program.
The primary advantage of a credit program over an allowance program is that it does
not discriminate against new sources. Allowance programs tend to allocate their allowances
based on some historic baseline year. Those sources included in the baseline get their
allowances free. Those future sources not included in the baseline have to pay either the
older, existing sources to obtain allowances or to buy allowances at auction. With a credit
program, sulfur credits can be created by any source, as the baseline is dictated by the
emissions cap and yearly production, not a historical year. The disadvantage of such a
system is that facility planning is very difficult as operators do not know precisely what their
permissible limit will be from year to year.
Carbon/CO2 Emissions Tax
An alternative market-based mechanism to the tradeable permit system is carbon taxes
— generally conceived as a levy on natural gas, petroleum, and coal according to their carbon
content, in the approximate ratio of 0.6 to 0.8 to 1, respectively. In the view of most
economists, the most efficient approach to controlling CO2 emissions would be a carbon tax.
With the complexity of multiple pollutants and millions of emitters involved in controlling
CO2, the advantages of a tax are self-evident. Imposed on an input basis, administrative
burdens such as stack monitoring to determine compliance would be reduced. Also, a carbon
tax would have the broad effect across the economy that some feel is necessary to achieve
long-term reductions in emissions.
However, in other ways, a tax system merely changes the forum rather than the
substance of the policy debate. Because paying an emissions tax becomes an alternative to
controlling emissions, the debate over the amount of reductions necessarily becomes a debate
over the tax level imposed. Those wanting large reductions quickly would want a high tax
imposed over a short period of time. Those more concerned with the potential economic
burden of a carbon tax would want a low tax imposed at a later time with possible exceptions
for various events. Emissions taxes would remain basically an implementation strategy;
policy determinations such as tax levels would require political/regulatory decisions. In
addition, a tax system would raise revenues. Indeed, one argument for—or against—such
a system would be that it is a tax that would raise revenues. The disposition of these
revenues would significantly affect the economic and distributional impacts of the tax.
Other tax schemes to address global climate change are also possible. For example, the
European Community (EC) has discussed periodically a hybrid carbon tax/energy tax to
begin addressing CO2 emissions. Fifty percent of the tax would be imposed on energy
production (including nuclear power) except renewables; 50% of the tax would be based on
CRS-8

IB97057
08-01-03
carbon emissions. Some European countries have modified their energy taxation to fit the
model discussed by the EC.
Currently, five European countries have carbon-based taxes. Finland imposed the first
CO2 tax in 1990 and modified it in 1994. The Finnish tax has two components: (1) a basic
tax component to meet fiscal needs and (2) a combined energy/CO2 tax component. For
coal, peat, and natural gas, there is no fiscal component. The Netherlands also introduced
a CO2 tax in 1990, modified in 1992 to fit the EC model; however, the tax does not vary
according to fuel type and energy use. . It does include tax relief from the energy component
of the tax for energy-intensive industries. Sweden introduced a CO2 tax in 1991 on all fossil
fuels, unless they are used in electricity production. In 1993, the tax scheme was modified
to reduce its burden on industry. Denmark introduced a CO2 tax in 1992 that covers fuel oil,
gas, coal, and electricity (gasoline is taxed separately).
Taxes paid by industry are
completely reimbursed to the sector. Norway introduced a CO2 tax in 1991 on oil and
natural gas and extended it to some coal and coke use in 1992. However, there are many
exemptions and the tax rate is not differentiated according to the carbon content of the fuels.
Joint Implementation
Joint Implementation (JI) is an attempt to expand the availability of cost-effective CO2
reductions into the international sphere through a variety of different activities. Basically,
a developed country (where opportunities for reducing emissions are expensive) needing
CO2 reductions to meet its obligations under any international treaty could obtain reduction
credits by financing emission reductions in another country, usually a developing country
(where more cost-effective reductions are available). As generally conceived, the developed
country financing the reductions and the developing country hosting the reduction project
would split the achieved reductions between them in some previously agreed-upon manner.
Joint Implementation is a keystone of U.S. climate change policy; it was subject to
considerable debate at the Conference of Parties (COP) meetings in Berlin. These discussions
resulted in agreement to implement JI in a pilot phase. Projects must be compatible with and
supportive of national environmental and development priorities; accepted, approved, or
endorsed beforehand by the Parties’ governments; and have anticipated environmental
benefits and projected financing fully articulated beforehand. Credits generated cannot be
used to meet the Rio Treaty year 2000 target; credit for post-2000 targets was left to the
meeting in Kyoto, which included JI as one of its flexible implementation mechanisms.
The focus of the U.S. JI effort is the U.S. Initiative on Joint Implementation (USIJI).
Managed by a Secretariat cooperatively staffed by 8 federal agencies, the USIJI is a pilot JI
program initiated by the Clinton Administration as part of its “Climate Change Action Plan”
in 1993.
Currently, there are about 26 projects in 11 countries that have received USIJI
approval. The USIJI encourages U.S. industry to use its resources and technology to reduce
greenhouse gas emissions and promote sustainable development.
(Its web site is
[http://www.ji.org].)
The advantage of JI for developed countries is that it widens the options available to
obtain necessary credits under any reduction program. This translates into lower costs to
those countries, compared with their own domestic reduction activities. For the developed
country, particularly where it does not have the resources to control emissions or protect
CRS-9

IB97057
08-01-03
sequestration areas, reductions or protection would occur more quickly than would otherwise
be possible.
However, the disadvantages are also significant. A developed country may have to rely
on another sovereign government to ensure compliance with part of its international
commitment. Governments change, and policies change. If a new government chose to
remove or shut down a pollution control device, the developed country might have little
recourse but to look elsewhere for its necessary reduction. Particularly with sequestration
projects that involve marketable commodities, such as trees, enforcement could be quite
difficult. A tree’s value as cooking or heating firewood for natives could easily exceed its
value as a carbon sequester. In the long-run, the enthusiasm with which a developing country
may enforce agreements with respect to JI projects is unclear.
Indeed, developing countries could have significant economic incentives to abrogate JI
projects, particularly if they are viewed as constraining necessary development, or locking
up a natural resource that the country would like to exploit. This incentive is further
encouraged if the JI project is perceived as a developed country’s project. The term
“economic imperialism” has already been applied to JI projects by some opponents.
After much negotiation, the protocol agreed to at Kyoto contains provisions on joint
implementation that generally follow the guidelines set up at Berlin. Because developing
countries have no emission requirements to meet (unlike developed countries), the protocol
sets up a Clean Development Mechanism to promote sustainable development in them while
providing emission reduction opportunities for developed countries. Participation is
voluntary; benefits must be real, measurable, and long-term; reductions must be in addition
to any normal activity. Operated under supervision of the COP, reductions achieved between
2000 and 2008 may be used to offset commitments in the 2008-2012 time period. In the July
2001 COP-6 meeting, it was agreed that nuclear power was not an acceptable option under
the CDM.
Issues
Cost-Effectiveness: Price versus Quantity
Proposed CO2 reduction schemes present large uncertainties in terms of the perceived
reduction needs and the potential costs of achieving those reductions. In one sense,
preference for a carbon tax or tradeable permit system depends on how one views the
uncertainty of costs involved and benefits to be received. For those confident that achieving
a specific level of CO2 reduction will yield very significant benefits—enough so that even
the potentially very high end of the marginal cost curve does not bother them — then a
tradeable permit program may be most appropriate. CO2 emissions would be reduced to a
specific level, and in the case of a tradeable permit program, the cost involved would be
handled efficiently, but not controlled at a specific cost level. This efficiency occurs because
control efforts are concentrated at the lowest-cost emission sources through the trading of
permits.
CRS-10

IB97057
08-01-03
However, if one is more uncertain about the benefits of a specific level of reduction —
particularly with the potential downside risk of substantial control cost to the economy —
then a carbon tax may be most appropriate. In this approach, the level of the tax effectively
caps the marginal control costs that affected activities would have to pay under the reduction
scheme, but the precise level of CO2 achieved is less certain. Emitters of CO2 would spend
money controlling CO2 emissions up to the level of the tax. However, since the marginal
cost of control among millions of emitters is not well known, the overall effect of a given tax
level on CO2 emission cannot be accurately forecasted. Hence, a major policy question is
whether one is more concerned about the possible economic cost of the program and
therefore willing to accept some uncertainty about the amount of reduction received (i.e.,
carbon taxes) or whether one is more concerned about achieving a specific emission
reduction level with costs handled efficiently, but not capped (i.e., tradeable permits).
A proposal was floated by the Clinton Administration for a tradeable permit program
with a ceiling on the price of permits. If permit prices rose above a certain price, the
government would have intervened to control costs by selling more permits at a specific
price. In essence, this would have given the permit program the character of a carbon tax by
controlling costs through a price “safety valve,” while allowing quantity to increase to any
level necessary to prevent price increases. Not surprisingly, environmental groups interested
in protecting the emission limitations of any global climate change program attacked the idea
as a “target-busting escape clause.” Industry groups suggested that such a tradeable permit
program amounts to a tax. For a discussion of other “safety valve” proposals, see CRS
Report RS21067, Global Climate Change: Controlling CO2 Emissions – Cost-limiting
Safety Valves
.
Comprehensiveness
As suggested earlier, carbon emissions are ubiquitous. Much of the emissions come
from the direct combustion of fossil fuels from small, dispersed sources such as automobiles,
homes, and commercial establishments. For example, the 12% of emissions from the
residential/commercial sector come from such things as space heating/cooling (9.3%, oil and
natural gas), water heating (1.5%, mostly natural gas), and appliances (1.2%, mostly natural
gas). If one adds to these dispersed sources the 33% of emissions that come from direct
combustion from automobiles (13.9%), trucks (11.2%), airplanes (4.5%), ships (1.8%),
pipelines (0.6%), and railroads (0.8%), the number of individual sources runs into the
millions; very small sources contribute almost half the emissions.
Assuming a carbon tax is assessed on an input basis (i.e., on the carbon content of the
fuel), then the number of sources is largely irrelevant — the sources would get the correct
price signal from the increased cost of their fuel. This is one of the primary strengths of the
carbon tax scheme—it can be very comprehensive and potentially induce the necessary
changes in individual as well as corporate behavior that could substantially reduce
dependence on carbon emitting energy sources. In this sense, a carbon tax is not just a
band-aid to reduce CO2 emissions, but a program to reduce carbon intensiveness in the
economy and in individual lifestyles.
For a tradeable permit program, the numbers of sources can represent a substantial
administrative and enforcement problem. One approach to making the situation more
manageable would be to limit the scope of the trading system to domestic implementation
CRS-11

IB97057
08-01-03
strategies. As noted above, international emission trading is termed “supplemental” under
the consolidated negotiating text. Likewise, the scope could be limited further by focusing
the trading program on the electric utility sector. Another approach could be to limit the size
of the source included in the trading program. Others could “opt-in,” but their participation
would be voluntary. Thus, direct combustion of fossil fuels in the residential, commercial,
and industrial sectors (e.g., natural gas, home heating oil) would be indirectly encouraged by
the program and use of CO2 emitting electricity (particularly coal-fired electricity)
discouraged. The transportation sector would be little affected (unless it chose to be).
Economic Impact
Obviously, the economic impact of either a tradeable permit program or a carbon tax
depends on the level of reductions desired and the timing of those reductions. Most of the
studies on the economic impact of CO2 control programs have focused primarily on carbon
taxes. This is not surprising as carbon taxes are easier to model than a tradeable permit
program. However, the uncertainty involved in these analyses is quite large; further work
is necessary to reduce the current range of estimates
For example, estimates of the carbon tax necessary to stabilize U.S. CO2 emissions at
their 1990 level by the year 2000 ranged from under $30 a ton to over $100 a ton. Economic
assumptions that result in this range of estimates include: (1) carbon emissions growth
assumptions in the absence of legislation, (2) responsiveness of the economy to the carbon
tax in terms of increased energy efficiency, and (3) type of model employed.
This
uncertainty is compounded when attempts are made to estimate GNP effects of carbon taxes.
Very small differences in GNP estimation techniques can result in large differences in
projected impacts (particularly over the long term). Preliminary evidence indicates that the
adverse effects of a carbon tax can be reduced if the proceeds from that tax are “recycled”
either to offset certain existing taxes or fund investment incentives to encourage economic
growth (particularly through greater capital formation). Thus, the impact of a carbon tax on
the economy would depend to some degree on how the government disposed of generated
revenues. However, considerably more work is needed to define the economic consequences
of a specific proposal to recycle revenues before much confidence can be put into the results.
Of course, if one has a technological or ecological orientation, the assumptions resulting
from those orientations can outweigh the economic assumptions discussed here.
The extent that economic analysis of carbon tax programs provides insight for a
tradeable permit program depends partially on the scope of the program, the options
included, and the monitoring and transaction costs. If the government chose to sell its
allowances at auction, rather than giving them away (as is typical), the government would
have revenue like a carbon tax to recycle or readdress perceived distortions in the current tax
code. In June 2000, the Congressional Budget Office released a study on the distributional
effects of carbon trading programs. It concludes that if the government gave away carbon
allowances to U.S. firms (as is typical for trading programs), the effects would be regressive
on households. If the allowances were sold at auction, the distributional effects would
depend on the ultimate disposition of the revenue received from the sale. However, the
carbon tax analysis does suggest that the price of a permit (and any revenues from the sale
thereof) would be difficult to estimate with any precision at the current time.
CRS-12

IB97057
08-01-03
The specific effects of both a carbon tax and tradeable permit program would depend
on the specific levy (carbon tax) or allocation scheme (tradeable permit) chosen. Experience
with both tax code revisions and the allocation scheme under the acid rain title suggests that
regional, state, and sector-specific concerns could receive special treatment in these
decisions. In addition, for a carbon tax, the allocation of revenue received could also be
influenced by such concerns.
Equity
The climate change issue and CO2 control raise numerous equity issues. In one sense,
the concern about climate change is a concern about intergenerational equity—i.e., the
well-being of the current generation versus generations to come. On a global level, the issue
also involves the North-South debate. Some industrialized Northern countries suggest that
the lesser-developed Southern countries refrain from certain activities (such as clearing rain
forests) that Southern countries feel are important for their economic growth. Southern
countries often suggest that the Northern countries change their current “unsustainable”
growth practices and assist the South in sustainable development. Some supporters of
tradeable permits have suggested that internationalization of the permit program could allow
the wealthy countries to fund CO2-reducing activities (preserving forests, improving
efficiency, etc.) as a means of achieving cost-effective reductions and assisting developing
countries (i.e., joint implementation). However, as noted above, monitoring the long-term
efficacy of JI projects raises administrative issues. Some carbon tax proponents have
suggested that a portion of collected revenue could be set aside for assisting developing
countries. Percentages to be set aside and more generally the political acceptability of such
a proposal are unclear.
Other equity questions include the regional distribution of costs under a tradeable
permit or carbon tax scheme. For example, an important impact of either a carbon tax based
on the carbon content of fossil fuels or a tradeable permit program would be the pressure for
fuel shifts away from coal and toward gas. Other regions, such as fast growing areas in need
of more energy and owners of “all electric” homes, among others, would likely be
disproportionately hit by a CO2 control scheme. In addition, people may be affected
differently according to income class. These issues have not been sufficiently analyzed at
the current time to draw firm conclusions.
Legislation in the 108th Congress
In the 108th Congress, four bills has been introduced to control CO2 emissions. S. 139,
introduced by Senators McCain and Lieberman, would reduce and cap emissions of carbon
dioxide from electricity generation, transportation, industrial, and commercial sectors –
sectors that account for about 85% of U.S. greenhouse gas emissions. The reductions would
be implemented in two phases with an emissions cap in the year 2010 based on affected
facilities’ 2000 emissions, and a further reduction cap imposed in the year 2016 based on
affected facilities’ 1990 emissions.
The program would be implemented through an
expansive allowance trading program that includes cross-sector trading and limited
acquisition of allowances from foreign sources. For a comparison of S. 139 with other
CRS-13

IB97057
08-01-03
Senate bills to reduce greenhouse gases, see CRS Report RS21581: Climate Change: Senate
Proposals to Reduce Greenhouse Gas Emissions
.
The second bill, S. 366, introduced by Senator Jeffords, is a modified version of the
multi-pollutant bill (S. 556) reported out by the Senate Environment and Public Works
Committee in the 107th Congress. Placing emission caps on nitrogen oxides, sulfur dioxide,
and carbon dioxide, S. 366 would reduce and cap emissions of carbon dioxide from
electricity generation at their 1990 levels by the year 2009. Similar to S. 139, the program
would be implemented through an allowance trading program. In addition to these emission
caps, S. 366 would place facility-specific emission limitations on mercury.
The third bill, S. 843, introduced by Senator Carper, is a multi-pollutant control bill
similar to S. 3135 introduced in the 107th Congress. Placing emission caps on nitrogen
oxides, sulfur dioxide, mercury, and carbon dioxide, S. 843 would cap carbon dioxide
emissions from powerplants at their 2006 levels by 2009 and further cap emissions at their
2001 levels by 2013. Similar to the other two control bills, S. 843 would be implemented
through an allowance trading program.
The fourth bill, H.R. 2042, introduced by Representative Waxman, is a multi-pollutant
control bill similar to H.R. 1256 introduced in the 107th Congress. Placing emission caps on
nitrogen oxides, sulfur dioxide, mercury, and carbon dioxide, H.R. 2042 would cap carbon
dioxide emissions from powerplants at their 1990 levels by the year 2009. Implementation
strategies are to be determined by EPA with market mechanisms explicitly permitted (except
for mercury). For a further discussion of multi-pollutant legislation introduced in the 108th
Congress, see CRS Report RL31779: Air Quality: Multi-Pollutant Legislation in the 108th
Congress.

In July 2003, the Senate leadership announced that as part of an agreement to pass a
comprehensive energy bill that S. 139 would be brought before the Senate at a future date.
Other Proposals
United States and International Activities
In March 2001, the Bush Administration announced that the Kyoto Protocol was “dead”
as far as it was concerned. In rejecting the Kyoto Protocol as unfair to the United States,
EPA Administrator Whitman emphasized the Administration’s desire to work constructively
with the EC to develop technologies, market-based incentives, and other innovative
approaches to global climate change. However, the Administration has yet to announce or
outline any policy alternatives as a basis for international discussions.
Administration Domestic Initiatives
In late September 2000, presidential candidate George W. Bush proposed a national
energy plan that would include requiring utilities to reduce their carbon dioxide emission
over a “reasonable” time frame in a manner similar to the current market-based acid rain
reduction program. Few specifics, such as reduction targets or schedule, were included in
CRS-14

IB97057
08-01-03
the plan. In March 2001, the Bush Administration reversed this position, stating that it
would not seek legislation to reduce CO2 emissions.
In making the reversal, the
Administration cited a DOE study indicating that energy costs would increase if controls
were put on CO2 emissions.
In February 2002, the Administration initiated a new voluntary greenhouse gas program,
similar to ones introduced by the earlier Bush and Clinton Administrations. Developed in
response to the U.S. ratification of the 1992 United Nations Framework Convention on
Climate Change (UNFCCC), these previous plans projected U.S. compliance, or near
compliance, with the UNFCCC goal of stabilizing greenhouse gas emissions at their 1990
levels by the year 2000 through voluntary measures. The new proposal introduced by the
Bush Administration did not make that claim, only projecting a 100 million metric ton
reduction in emissions from what would occur otherwise in the year 2012. The plan focuses
on improving the carbon efficiency of the economy, reducing current emissions of 183 metric
tons per million dollars of GDP to 151 metric tons per million dollars of GDP in 2010. It
proposes several voluntary initiatives, along with increased spending and tax incentives, to
achieve this goal. However, the Administration projects that three-quarters of this reduction
would be achieved through current efforts underway, not by the new initiatives.
Based on the Administration’s estimates, the initiative will result in U.S. greenhouse
gas emissions being 28% above 1990 levels in the year 2010, a 4.5% reduction over a
business-as-usual baseline.
CRS-15