Order Code IB10006
Issue Brief for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
Electricity: The Road
Toward Restructuring
Updated April 8, 2003
Amy Abel and Larry Parker
Resources, Science, and Industry Division
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

CONTENTS
SUMMARY
MOST RECENT DEVELOPMENTS
BACKGROUND AND ANALYSIS
Transmission Issues
Standard Market Design
Market Transparency
Environmental Questions and Proposed Responses
Calls for Additional Electric Regulatory Reform
PUHCA
PURPA
Retail Wheeling
Recent Developments in California
Price Caps
Legislative Activity
Senate Debate


IB10006
04-08-03
Electricity: The Road Toward Restructuring
SUMMARY
The Public Utility Holding Company Act
provide an orderly and fair transition to com-
of 1935 (PUHCA) and the Federal Power Act
petitive bulk power markets. Order 2000,
(FPA) were enacted to eliminate unfair prac-
issued December 20, 1999, established crite-
tices and other abuses by electricity and gas
ria for forming transmission organizations.
holding companies by requiring federal con-
trol and regulation of interstate public utility
Comprehensive electricity legislation
holding companies. Prior to PUHCA, elec-
involves three issues. The first is PUHCA
tricity holding companies were characterized
reform. Some electric utilities want PUHCA
as having excessive consumer rates, high
changed so they can more easily diversify
debt-to-equity ratios, and unreliable service.
their assets. State regulators have expressed
PUHCA remained virtually unchanged for 50
concerns that increased diversification could
years until enactment of the Public Utility
lead to abuses, including cross-subsidization.
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978 (PURPA,
Consumer groups have expressed concern that
P.L. 95-617). PURPA was, in part, intended
a repeal of PUHCA could exacerbate market
to augment electric utility generation with
power abuses in a monopolistic industry
more efficiently produced electricity and to
where true competition does not yet exist.
provide equitable rates to electric consumers.
Utilities are required to buy all power pro-
The second issue is PURPA’s mandatory
duced by qualifying facilities (QFs) at
purchase requirement provisions. Many
“avoided cost.” QFs are exempt from regula-
investor-owned utilities support repeal of
tion under PUHCA and the FPA.
these provisions. They argue that their state
regulators’ “misguided” implementation of
Electricity regulation was changed again
PURPA has forced them to pay contractually
in 1992 with the passage of the Energy Policy
high prices for power that they do not need.
Act (EPACT, P.L. 102-486). The intent of
Opponents of this legislation argue that it
Title 7 of EPACT is to increase competition in
would decrease competition and impede
the electric generating sector by creating new
development of renewable energy. The third
entities, called “exempt wholesale generators”
is retail wheeling. It involves allowing retail
(EWGs) that can generate and sell electricity
customers to choose their electric generation
at wholesale without being regulated as
supplier.
utilities under PUHCA. This title also
provides EWGs with a way to assure
On April 2, 2003, the House Energy and
transmission of their wholesale power to its
Commerce Committee reported unnumbered
purchaser. The effect of this Act on the
energy legislation by a vote of 36-17. This is
electric supply system is potentially more
now part of H.R. 6, introduced on April 7,
far-reaching than PURPA.
2003. H.R. 6 includes an electricity title that
would, in part, repeal the Public Utility Hold-
On April 24, 1996, the Federal Energy
ing Company Act, would prospectively repeal
Regulatory Commission (FERC) issued Or-
the mandatory purchase requirement under the
ders 888 and 889. FERC believed these rules
Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act, and
would remedy undue discrimination in trans-
would create an electric reliability
mission services in interstate commerce and
organization.
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

IB10006
04-08-03
MOST RECENT DEVELOPMENTS
On April 2, 2003, the House Energy and Commerce Committee reported unnumbered
energy legislation by a vote of 36-17; it, unlike omnibus energy legislation debated in the
107th Congress, included provisions pertaining to restructuring of the electric utility industry.
This was merged into H.R. 6, introduced on April 7, 2003. On March 5, 2003, and March 13,
2003, the House Energy and Commerce Committee held hearings on draft comprehensive
energy legislation. S. 475 was introduced on February 27, 2003, by Senator Thomas. S. 475
in part, would repeal the Public Utility Holding Company Act, repeal the mandatory purchase
requirement under the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act, establish an Electric Reliability
Organization, and establish market transparency rules.
On July 31, 2002, the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) issued a Notice
of Proposed Rulemaking (NOPR) on standard market design (Docket No. RM01-12-000)
[http://www.ferc.gov/Electric/RTO/Mrkt-Strct-comments/nopr/Web-NOPR.pdf]. The
proposed rulemaking would create a new tariff under which transmission owners would be
required to turn over operation of their transmission systems to unaffiliated independent
transmission providers.(See also the CRS Electronic Briefing Book on electricity
restructuring at [http://www.congress.gov/brbk/html/ebele1.shtml].)
BACKGROUND AND ANALYSIS
Historically, electricity service has been defined as a natural monopoly, meaning that
the industry has (1) an inherent tendency toward declining long-term costs, (2) high threshold
investment, and (3) technological conditions that limit the number of potential entrants. In
addition, many regulators have considered unified control of generation, transmission, and
distribution as the most efficient means of providing service. As a result, most people (about
75%) are currently served by a vertically integrated, investor-owned utility.
As the electric utility industry has evolved, however, there has been a growing belief
that the historic classification of electric utilities as natural monopolies has been overtaken
by events and that market forces can and should replace some of the traditional economic
regulatory structure. For example, the existence of utilities that do not own all of their
generating facilities, primarily cooperatives and publicly owned utilities, has provided
evidence that vertical integration has not been necessary for providing efficient electric
service. (For additional information on Public Power, see also the CRS Electronic Briefing
Book on electricity restructuring at [http://www.congress.gov/brbk/html/ebele12.html].)
Moreover, recent changes in electric utility regulation and improved technologies have
allowed additional generating capacity to be provided by independent firms rather than
utilities.
The Public Utility Holding Company Act (PUHCA) and the Federal Power Act (FPA)
of 1935 (Title I and Title II of the Public Utility Act) established a regime of regulating
electric utilities that gave specific and separate powers to the states and the federal
government (see CRS Report RS20015). A regulatory bargain was made between the
government and utilities. In exchange for an exclusive franchise service territory, utilities
CRS-1

IB10006
04-08-03
must provide electricity to all users at reasonable, regulated rates. State regulatory
commissions address intrastate utility activities, including wholesale and retail rate-making.
State authority currently tends to be as broad and as varied as the states are diverse. At the
least, a state public utility commission will have authority over retail rates, and often over
investment and debt. At the other end of the spectrum, the state regulatory body will oversee
many facets of utility operation. Despite this diversity, the essential mission of the state
regulator in states that have not restructured is the establishment of retail electric prices. This
is accomplished through an adversarial hearing process. The central issues in such cases are
the total amount of money the utility will be permitted to collect and how the burden of the
revenue requirement will be distributed among the various customer classes (residential,
commercial, and industrial).
Under the FPA, federal economic regulation addresses wholesale transactions and rates
for electric power flowing in interstate commerce. Federal regulation followed state
regulation and is premised on the need to fill the regulatory vacuum resulting from the
constitutional inability of states to regulate interstate commerce. In this bifurcation of
regulatory jurisdiction, federal regulation is limited and conceived to supplement state
regulation. The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) has the principal functions
at the federal level for the economic regulation of the electricity utility industry, including
financial transactions, wholesale rate regulation, transactions involving transmission of
unbundled retail electricity, interconnection and wheeling of wholesale electricity, and
ensuring adequate and reliable service. In addition, to prevent a recurrence of the abusive
practices of the 1920s (e.g., cross-subsidization, self-dealing, pyramiding, etc.), the Securities
and Exchange Commission (SEC) regulates utilities’ corporate structure and business
ventures under PUHCA.
The electric utility industry has been in the process of transformation. During the past
two decades, there has been a major change in direction concerning generation. First,
improved technologies have reduced the cost of generating electricity as well as the size of
generating facilities. Prior preference for large-scale — often nuclear or coal-fired —
powerplants has been supplanted by a preference for small-scale production facilities that can
be brought online more quickly and cheaply, with fewer regulatory impediments. Second,
this has lowered the entry barrier to electricity generation and permitted non-utility entities
to build profitable facilities. Recent changes in electric utility regulation and improved
technologies have allowed additional generating capacity to be provided by independent
firms rather than utilities.

The oil embargoes of the 1970s created concerns about the security of the nation’s
electricity supply and led to enactment of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978
(PURPA, P.L. 95-617). For the first time, utilities were required to purchase power from
outside sources. The purchase price was set at the utilities’ “avoided cost,” the cost they
would have incurred to generate the additional power themselves, as determined by utility
regulators. PURPA was established in part to augment electric utility generation with more
efficiently produced electricity and to provide equitable rates to electric consumers.
In addition to PURPA, the Fuel Use Act of 1978 (FUA, P.L. 95-620) helped qualifying
facilities (QFs) become established. Under FUA, utilities were not permitted to use natural
gas to fuel new generating technology. QFs, which are by definition not utilities, were able
to take advantage of abundant natural gas as well as new generating technology, such as
CRS-2

IB10006
04-08-03
combined-cycle plants that use hot gases from combustion turbines to generate additional
power. These technologies lowered the financial threshold for entrance into the electricity
generation business as well as shortened the lead time for constructing new plants. FUA was
repealed in 1987, but by this time QFs and small power producers had gained a portion of
the total electricity supply.
This influx of QF power challenged the cost-based rates that previously guided
wholesale transactions. Before implementation of PURPA, FERC approved wholesale
interstate electricity transactions based on the seller’s costs to generate and transmit the
power. As more non-utility generators entered the market in the 1980s, these cost-based
rates were challenged. Since non-utility generators typically do not have enough market
power to influence the rates they charge, FERC began approving certain wholesale
transactions whose rates were a result of a competitive bidding process. These rates are
called market-based rates.
This first incremental change to traditional electricity regulation started a movement
towards a market-oriented approach to electricity supply. Following the enactment of
PURPA, two basic issues stimulated calls for further reform: whether to encourage nonutility
generation and whether to permit utilities to diversify into non-regulated activities.
The Energy Policy Act of 1992 (EPACT, P.L. 102-486) removed several regulatory
barriers to entry into electricity generation to increase competition of electricity supply.
Specifically, EPACT provides for the creation of entities, called “exempt wholesale
generators” (EWGs), that can generate and sell electricity at wholesale without being
regulated as utilities under PUHCA. Under EPACT, EWGs are also provided with a way to
assure transmission of their wholesale power to a wholesale purchaser. However, EPACT
does not permit FERC to mandate that utilities transmit EWG power to retail consumers
(commonly called “retail wheeling” or “retail competition”), an activity that remains under
the jurisdiction of state public utility commissions. PURPA began to shift more regulatory
responsibilities to the federal government, and EPACT continued that shift away from the
states by creating new options for utilities and regulators to meet electricity demand. (For
additional background on EPACT and PURPA, see CRS Report 98-419.)
The question now is whether further federal legislative action is desirable to encourage
competition in the electric utility sector and if so at what speed this change would occur.
Currently, 24 states and the District of Columbia have either enacted legislation or issued
regulatory orders to implement retail access. Six states, Arkansas, Montana, Nevada, New
Mexico, Oklahoma and West Virginia, have delayed implementation of retail access. The
map later in this issue brief shows the current status of each state’s restructuring efforts.
Issues discussed in this brief include repeal or alteration of both PUHCA and PURPA;
transmission access and FERC’s Orders 888, 889 and 2000; environmental impact; and
issues related to standard market design.
Transmission Issues
In addition to creating a new type of wholesale electricity generator, Exempt Wholesale
Generators (EWGs), the Energy Policy Act (EPACT) provides EWGs with a system to
assure transmission of their wholesale power to its purchaser. However, EPACT did not
CRS-3

IB10006
04-08-03
solve all of the issues relating to transmission access. As a result of EPACT, on April 24,
1996, FERC issued Orders 888 and 889. In issuing its final rules, FERC concluded that
these Orders will "remedy undue discrimination in transmission services in interstate
commerce and provide an orderly and fair transition to competitive bulk power markets."
Under Order 888, the Open Access Rule, transmission line owners are required to offer
both point-to-point and network transmission services under comparable terms and
conditions that they provide for themselves. The Rule provides a single tariff providing
minimum conditions for both network and point-to-point services and the non-price terms
and conditions for providing these services and ancillary services. This Rule also allows for
full recovery of so-called stranded costs with those costs being paid by wholesale customers
wishing to leave their current supply arrangements. The rule encourages but does not require
creation of Independent System Operators (ISOs) to coordinate intercompany transmission
of electricity.
Order 889, the Open Access Same-time Information System (OASIS) rule, establishes
standards of conduct to ensure a level playing field. The Rule requires utilities to separate
their wholesale power marketing and transmission operation functions, but does not require
corporate unbundling or divestiture of assets. Utilities are still allowed to own transmission,
distribution, and generation facilities but must maintain separate books and records.
On December 20, 1999, FERC issued Order 2000 that described the minimum
characteristics and functions of regional transmission organizations (RTOs)
[http://www.ferc.gov/news/rules/pages/RM99-2A.pdf]. The required characteristics of an
RTO are: the RTO must be independent from market participants; it must serve a region of
sufficient size to permit the RTO to perform effectively; an RTO will be responsible for
operational control; and it will be responsible for maintaining the short-term reliability of the
grid. The required functions of an RTO outlined in Order 2000 are: it must administer its
own transmission tariff; it must ensure the development and operation of market mechanisms
to manage congestion; it must address parallel flow issues both within and outside its region;
it will serve as supplier of last resort for all ancillary services; it must administer an Open
Access Same-time Information System; it must monitor markets to identify design flaws and
market power and propose appropriate remedial actions; it must provide for interregional
coordination; and an RTO must plan necessary transmission additions and upgrades.
Order 2000 does not require RTO participation, set out RTO boundaries, or mandate
the acceptable RTO structure. RTOs will be able to file with FERC as an independent
system operator (ISO), a for-profit transmission company (transco), or another type of entity
that has not yet been proposed. Although RTO participation is voluntary under Order 2000,
FERC built in guidelines and safeguards to ensure independent operation of the transmission
grid. RTOs are required to conduct independent audits to ensure that owners do not exert
undue influence over RTO operation.
FERC Order 2000 required the existing ISOs to submit to FERC by January 1, 2001,
a plan to describe whether their transmission organization meets the criteria established in
the RTO rulemaking. Electric utilities not currently members of an ISO had to file plans
with FERC by October 1, 2000. The Order does not mandate RTO formation, but if an
individual utility opts not to join an RTO, the utility is required to prove why it would be
harmed by joining such an entity.
CRS-4

IB10006
04-08-03
On July 12, 2001, FERC issued several orders requiring utilities to enter into talks to
form four Regional Transmission Organizations. Even though FERC Order 2000 did not set
out RTO boundaries, in effect the July 12, 2001, order does. On September 17, 2001,
FERC’s Administrative Law Judge Mediator H. Peter Young filed his report (Docket No.
RT01-99-000) [http://www.ferc.gov/Electric/RTO/rto/issuance/RT01-991-9-17.pdf] that
presented a blueprint for creating a single RTO in the Northeast.
FERC has granted RTO status to three entities. On December 20, 2001, FERC granted
RTO status [Docket No. RTO1-87-000] to the Midwest Independent Transmission System
Operator (MISO). On September 18, 2002, FERC approved the RTO West proposal
[http://ferc.gov/Electric/rto/RT01-35-005-09-18-02.pdf]. RTO West includes all, or part of,
Washington, Idaho, Montana, Oregon, Nevada, Wyoming, Utah and a small part of northern
California near the Oregon border. FERC granted PJM RTO status on December 19, 2002
[http://ferc.gov/Electric/rto/pjm-12-19-02.pdf]. PJM manages the grid in parts of Ohio,
West Virginia, Pennsylvania, New Jersey, Delaware, Maryland, Virginia and the District of
Columbia. Other RTOs have received conditional approval from FERC. Most recently,
FERC conditionally approved SeTrans RTO and WestConnect RTO on October, 9, 2002
[Docket Nos. EL02,101-000, RTO2-1-000 and EL02-9-000]. SeTrans includes utilities in
Alabama, Arkansas, Florida, Georgia, Louisiana, Mississippi, South Carolina and Texas.
WestConnect RTO will operate in parts of Arizona, Colorado, New Mexico and Utah.
In the past, utilities and some state utility commissioners have argued against large
RTOs, stating that currently the expertise is not available to integrate a large geographic
region with multiple control centers and power pools. On February 26, 2002, FERC released
a report [http://www.ferc.gov/electric/rto/mrkt-strct-comments/rtostudy_final_0226.pdf] that
assessed the potential economic costs and benefits of RTOs. The study concluded the annual
savings from RTO formation could range from $1- $10 billion. However, the study did not
find significant differences in savings between larger and smaller RTOs. Those in favor of
large RTOs argue that the most efficient operations of the transmission system would take
place with large RTOs. On November 7, 2001, FERC issued an order (Docket No. RM01-
12-000) [http://www.ferc.gov/Electric/RTO/rto/issuance/RM01-12.pdf] that stated FERC’s
goals and process for creating Regional Transmission Organizations.
On May 14, 1999, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Eighth Circuit ruled in a case
between FERC and Northern States Power. The court held that the Commission overstepped
its authority when it ordered Northern States Power Company to treat wholesale customers
the same as it treats native load customers in making electricity curtailment decisions. This
decision raised federal-state jurisdictional questions, particularly a state's right to guarantee
system reliability.
On October 3, 2001, the U.S. Supreme Court heard arguments in a case (New York et
al. v. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission) that challenges FERC’s authority under
Order 888 to regulate transmission for retail sales if a utility unbundles transmission from
other retail charges. In states that have opened their generation market to competition,
unbundling occurs when customers are charged separately for generation, transmission, and
distribution. Nine states, led by New York, filed suit, arguing that the Federal Power Act
gives FERC jurisdiction over wholesale sales and interstate transmission and leaves all retail
issues up to the state utility commissions. Enron argued that FERC clearly has jurisdiction
over all transmission and FERC is obligated to prevent transmission owners from
CRS-5

IB10006
04-08-03
discriminating against those wishing to use the transmission lines. On March 4, 2002, the
U.S. Supreme Court ruled in favor of FERC and held that FERC has jurisdiction over
transmission including unbundled retail transactions. The ruling is available at:
[http://a257.g.akamaitech.net/7/257/2422/04mar20021030/www.supremecourtus.gov/opi
nions/01pdf/00-568.pdf]. H.R. 6 would allow utilities that are not members of regional
transmission organizations to give preferential treatment to native load customers.
Many groups assert that difficulty siting transmission lines is one reason that in the past
decade, there has been less transmission capacity added than generation capacity. H.R. 6
would provide for incentive-based transmission rates. In addition, H.R. 6 and H.R. 1370
would allow transmission owners in certain instances to exercise the right of eminent domain
to site new transmission lines
S. 475, introduced February 27, 2003, H.R. 6, and H.R. 1370 would provide for an
Electric Reliability Organization to prescribe and enforce mandatory reliability standards.
Standard Market Design. On July 31, 2002, FERC issued a Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (NOPR) on standard market design (SMD) (Docket No. RM01-12-
000)[http://www.ferc.gov/Electric/RTO/Mrkt-Strct-comments/nopr/Web-NOPR.pdf].
FERC’s stated goal of SMD requirements in conjunction with a standardized transmission
service is to create “seamless” wholesale power markets that allow sellers to transact easily
across transmission grid boundaries. The proposed rulemaking would create a new tariff
under which each transmission owner would be required to turn over operation of its
transmission system to an unaffiliated independent transmission provider (ITP). The ITP,
which could be an RTO, would provide service to all customers and run energy markets.
Under the NOPR, congestion would be managed with locational marginal pricing. The
NOPR comment period originally was 75 days (November 15, 2002), but the comment
period was extended to January 10, 2003, for the following issues:1) market design for the
Western Interconnection; 2) transmission plan in pricing, including participant funding; 3)
Regional State Advisory Committees and state participation; 4) resource adequacy; and 5)
Congestion Revenue Rights and transition issues.
Under the NOPR, FERC asserts jurisdiction over all power transmission, including
service to bundled retail customers. Commissioners from 15 states (Alabama, Arkansas,
California, Georgia, Idaho, Kentucky, Louisiana, Mississippi, New Hampshire, North
Carolina, South Carolina, Oregon, South Dakota, Washington, and Wyoming) are planning
to fight FERC’s proposed changes on the grounds that FERC usurps state authority. On
August 15, 2002, state regulators from 22 states and the District of Columbia (Illinois,
Indiana, Iowa, Michigan, Minnesota, Missouri, Montana, North Dakota, Ohio, Oklahoma,
Texas, Wisconsin, Delaware, the District of Columbia, New Jersey, New York,
Pennsylvania, West Virginia, Connecticut, Maine, Massachusetts, New Hampshire, and
Rhode Island) released a statement that “voiced support for FERC’s ongoing effort to remedy
undue discrimination in the use of the nation’s interstate high voltage transmission system
in order to create a truly competitive bulk power market.” In general, the industry has been
in favor of FERC’s SMD proposal, but some industry groups have voiced concerns about the
implementation of SMD. For additional information on Standard Market Design, see CRS
Report RS21407.
CRS-6

IB10006
04-08-03
Market Transparency. Some have argued that the wholesale power markets cannot
be competitive without additional market transparency for both generation and transmission.
S. 475, H.R. 6 and H.R. 1254 would require FERC to issue rules to establish an electronic
information system to provide the public, FERC, state commissions, buyers and sellers of
wholesale electric energy, and users of transmission services, with information on the
availability and price of wholesale electric energy and transmission services. H.R. 1272
would require participants in the electric markets to provide FERC with records of all
transmission and sale transactions.
Environmental Questions and Proposed Responses
The electric industry is a major source of air pollution as well as of greenhouse gases.
Therefore, changes underway in the industry are being closely examined for their potential
environmental effects. At issue is whether proposed legislation to restructure the industry
should include environmental protections.
The Clean Air Act regulates emissions of conventional air pollutants from electric
utilities. While it has historically focused on new construction in applying its most stringent
standards, several current and prospective regulations would significantly increase controls
on existing coal-fired facilities. These controls may diminish the attractiveness of renovating
older, more polluting facilities, but the effectiveness of the regulations in coping with a
restructured industry remains to be seen. In addition, greenhouse gas emissions are not
regulated, so any increases in carbon dioxide would not be controlled under existing
authorities.
Thus the environmental effects of restructuring depend on whether, for conventional air
pollutants, the existing regulatory regimen will work effectively as the industry structure
changes. For some pollutants, such as sulfur oxides, a nationwide emissions "cap" seems
secure; but for others, particularly nitrogen oxides, the state-led implementation process may
have difficulty coping with regional disparities in emissions. For carbon dioxide, any controls
would be contingent on future ratification of the Kyoto Agreement to curtail emissions and
on domestic legislation.
Several bills that deal with these environmental issues have been introduced in the 108th
Congress. For a summary of these bills and legislative action, see CRS Report RL31779.
Calls for Additional Electric Regulatory Reform
PUHCA
One argument for additional PUHCA reform has been made by electric utilities that
want to further diversify their assets. Currently under PUHCA, a holding company can
acquire securities or utility assets only if the SEC finds that such a purchase will improve the
economic efficiency and service of an integrated public utility system. It has been argued
that reform to allow diversification would improve the risk profile of electric utilities in
much the same way as in other businesses: The risk of any one investment is diluted by the
CRS-7

IB10006
04-08-03
risk associated with all investments. Utilities have also argued that diversification would
lead to better use of under-utilized resources (due to the seasonal nature of electric demand).
Utility holding companies that have been exempt from SEC regulation argue that PUHCA
discourages diversification because the SEC could repeal exempt status if exemption would
be “detrimental to the public interest.”
For a number of years there has been significant bipartisan congressional support for
repealing much of PUHCA. However, as a result of Enron’s recent collapse, Congress may
take a somewhat different view toward significantly amending or repealing PUHCA. Even
though FERC had claimed exemption from PUHCA, on February 6, 2003, Securities and
Exchange Commission Chief Administrative Law Judge Brenda P. Murray denied Enron’s
PUHCA exemption applications of February 28, 2002, amended on May 31, 2002, and April
12, 2000 (Initial Decision Release No. 222 (File No. 3-10909) can be found at:
[http://www.sec.gov/litigation/aljdec/id222bpm.htm]). It is now being argued by some that
without PUHCA, Enron’s collapse might have adversely affected many other power
companies. (For additional information on Enron, see also the CRS Electronic Briefing
Book on electricity restructuring at [http://www.congress.gov/brbk/html/ebele1.shtml].)
State regulators have expressed concerns that increased diversification could lead to
abuses, including cross-subsidization: a regulated company subsidizing an unregulated
affiliate. Cross-subsidization was a major argument against the creation of EWGs and has
reemerged as an argument against further PUHCA reform. In the case of electric and gas
companies, non-utility ventures that are undertaken as a result of diversification may benefit
from the regulated utilities’ allowed rate of return. Moneymaking non-utility enterprises
would contribute to the overall financial health of a holding company. However,
unsuccessful ventures could harm the entire holding company, including utility subsidiaries.
In this situation, utilities would not be penalized for failure in terms of reduced access to new
capital, because they could increase retail rates.
Several consumer and environmental public interest groups, as well as state legislators,
have expressed concerns about PUHCA repeal. PUHCA repeal, such groups argue, could
only exacerbate market power abuses in what they see as a monopolistic industry where true
competition does not yet exist. The National Rural Electric Cooperative Association also
opposes stand-alone changes to PUHCA. (For further information on PUHCA, see CRS
Report RS20015.)

S. 475 and H.R. 6 would repeal PUHCA and give FERC and state commissions access
to books and records.
CRS-8








































































































































































































































































































































































































































































































































































































































IB10006
04-08-03
Figure 1. Status of State Electric Utility Restructuring as of October 1, 2002
1. Arizona, Connecticut, Delaware, District of Columbia, Illinois, Maine, Maryland, Massachusetts,
Michigan, New Hampshire, New Jersey, New York, Ohio, Oregon, Pennsylvania, Rhode Island,
Texas, and Virginia.
2. Arkansas, Montana, Nevada, New Mexico, Oklahoma, and West Virginia.
3. California.
4. Alabama, Alaska, Colorado, Florida, Georgia, Hawaii, Idaho, Indiana, Iowa, Kansas, Kentucky,
Louisiana, Minnesota, Mississippi, Missouri, Nebraska, North Carolina, North Dakota, South
Carolina, South Dakota, Tennessee, Utah, Vermont, Washington, Wisconsin, and Wyoming.
Source: Energy Information Administration
[http://www.eia.doe.gov/cneaf/electricity/chg_str/regmap.html]
PURPA
H.R. 6, S. 475 and S. 688 would prospectively repeal §210 of PURPA, the mandatory
purchase requirement provisions. Proponents of PURPA repeal — primarily investor-owned
utilities (IOUs) located in the Northeast and in California — argue that their state regulators’
“misguided” implementation of PURPA in the early 1980s has forced them to pay
contractually high prices for power they do not need. They argue that, given the current
environment for cost-conscious competition, PURPA is outdated. The PURPA Reform
Group, which promotes IOU interests, strongly supports such bills by contending that the
current law’s mandatory purchase obligation was anti-competitive and anti-consumer.
CRS-9

IB10006
04-08-03
Opponents of these types of bills (IPPs, industrial power customers, most segments of
the natural gas industry, the renewable energy industry, and environmental groups) have
many reasons to support PURPA as it stands. Mainly, their argument is that PURPA
introduced competition in the electric generating sector and, at the same time, helped
promote wider use of cleaner, alternative fuels to generate electricity. Since the electric
generating sector is not yet fully competitive, they argue, repeal of PURPA would decrease
competition and impede the development of the renewable energy industry. Additionally,
opponents of PURPA repeal argue that it would result in less competition and greater utility
monopoly control over the electric industry. The Electric Power Supply Association (EPSA)
also wants comprehensive legislation to look at all aspects of electricity regulation. State
regulators are concerned that this legislation would prevent them from deciding matters
currently under their jurisdiction. The National Association of Regulatory Utility
Commissioners has opposed legislation that would allow FERC to protect utilities from costs
associated with PURPA contracts.
Retail Wheeling
Some analysts believe the next logical step in restructuring is retail competition.
Encouraging competition in the electric supply system is already occurring as some states
allow generating utilities to arrange for transmission of electricity from its sources to a retail
consumer whether or not this transaction occurs within their service territory. EPACT
expressly prevents FERC from ordering retail competition (retail wheeling). Such
transactions remain under state regulatory control; FERC’s open access Orders address
wheeling at the wholesale level only. However, it is clear that FERC hopes that its Orders
will pave the way for states to permit retail customers to shop for their electricity needs
anywhere they want, rather than being limited to buying electricity from their local utility.
Indeed, who should determine the pace and boundaries of retail wheeling efforts is a
fundamental issue. Electric service is a vital component of a modern economy; thus, national
interests are at stake in what direction the restructuring debate takes. Concerns about
economic efficiency and the treatment of various participants (such as electric utilities) may
suggest to some that the federal government provide direction to current state initiatives. In
contrast, others argue that the states, which have traditionally had responsibility over retail
electricity issues, have the expertise and experience necessary to handle the situation (more
so than the federal government) and that the national interest in electricity supply is neither
threatened by state initiatives nor a justification for federal preemption of states’ rights.
Currently, retail choice is under state jurisdiction, and 24 states and the District of Columbia
have moved toward retail competition. Congress may consider whether expanding federal
jurisdiction is warranted in the continuing evolution of the electric utility industry or whether
a “wait and see” attitude toward state proceedings is more appropriate at this point. No bills
addressing retail wheeling have been introduced in the 108th Congress.
Recent Developments in California
California’s experience in 2001 with a marked decrease in reliability of electricity
supply as well as retail price spikes in the San Diego region has now been replaced with
excess generating supply. The original situation was partly due to California’s restructured
CRS-10

IB10006
04-08-03
electric markets and possible market manipulation, increased demand, generating plant
outages and lack of new transmission and generating capacity. Currently, California has
more long-term contracts than it needs to meet demand, and the contracts are locked-in at
prices higher than the current market price of electricity. On March 26, 2003, FERC ordered
an estimated $3.3 billion in refunds to California for unjust and unreasonable rates that were
charged between October 2000 and June 2001. (See also the CRS Electronic Briefing Book
on electricity restructuring at [http://www.congress.gov/brbk/html/ebele1.shtml].)

Price Caps
Several bills were introduced in the 107th Congress that would have imposed wholesale
price caps in California, a return to cost-of-service wholesale rate regulation or demand-
based time-of-use rates. Cost-of-service rate regulation allows for recovery of generating
costs plus a reasonable rate of return. Those in favor of price caps argue that competition
does not yet exist in California’s wholesale generating sector and wholesale prices do not
reflect what would be expected in a functional market. In addition, it is argued that
generators in California were exerting market power by intentionally withholding generating
capacity to increase wholesale prices. Those opposed to price caps, including President
Bush, argue that price caps discourage investment in new generating facilities and would
further distort the wholesale electricity market. For further discussion on price controls, see
[http://www.congress.gov/brbk/html/ebele23.html].
On June 18, 2001, FERC extended its price mitigation Order of April 26, 2001, to
include the 11 states in the Western System Coordinating Council (WSCC). FERC's Order
[http://www.ferc.gov/electric/bulkpower/el00-95-031-6-19.PDF] provided for a two-tiered
rate structure for the day-ahead and hour-ahead spot market. If California entered a Stage 1
electricity emergency (reserves fall below 7%), the spot market clearing price for California
was based on the bid from the least efficient gas-fired plant located in California that was
needed by the Independent System Operator (ISO). All sellers into the California ISO spot
market received the spot market clearing price. For sellers outside of California, California's
spot market clearing price was the maximum price, but sellers could bid and receive less than
the spot market clearing price. Generators, but not power marketers, had the ability to justify
their cost if it exceeded the established spot market clearing price. When operating reserves
were above 7% in California, the maximum price that could be charged was 85% of the spot
market clearing price set during the most recent Stage 1 emergency. These price caps were
expired in September 2002. For a chronological listing of important events in the California
electricity situation, see the Chronology in the CRS Electronic Briefing Book at
[http://www.congress.gov/brbk/html/ebele18.html].
On July 17, 2002, FERC issued a new price mitigation order for the Western markets
(Docket Number ER02-1656-000 et al.). Unlike the order described above, the new price
mitigation plan has no end date, and went into effect October 1, 2002. Unlike the soft cap
of $91.87 per megawatt hour that has been in effect since June 2001, the plan establishes a
hard price cap of $250 per megawatt hour for spot market sales. In addition, the plan creates
an automated mitigation procedure (AMP) that will screen all bids that exceed $91.87 per
megawatt hour for possible market abuses.
CRS-11

IB10006
04-08-03
Rate Refunds
Under current law, FERC may order refunds for rates found to be unjust, unreasonable,
unduly discriminatory or preferential. However, the effective date of such refunds begins a
minimum of 60 days after the original complaint is filed with FERC (16 U.S.C.8 2 4e(b)).
H.R. 964 and H.R. 1272 would allow refunds to be retroactive to the date a rate complaint
is filed with FERC. S. 723 would require FERC to order refunds of at least $8.9 billion for
unjust and unreasonable rates charged between June 1, 2000 and June 19, 2001.
LEGISLATION
H.R. 6 (Tauzin)
Title VI would, in part, provide for incentive-based transmission rates, allow
transmission owners in certain instances to exercise the right of eminent domain to site new
transmission lines, allow transmission owners that do not belong to a regional transmission
organization to preferentially serve native load customers, create an Electric Reliability
Organization, and give new, but limited, authority to the Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission (FERC) over municipal and cooperative transmission systems. It would repeal
PUHCA and give FERC and state public utility commissions access to books and records,
prospectively repeal the mandatory purchase requirement of the Public Utility Regulatory
Policies Act of 1978, and require utilities to provide real-time rates and time-of-use metering.
It would establish market transparency rules, explicitly prohibit round-trip trading, and
significantly increase criminal penalties under the Federal Power Act. Introduced April 7,
2003; referred to multiple committees.
H.R. 964 (Ose)
Would make electric rate refunds retroactive to the date a complaint is filed with FERC.
Introduced February 27, 2003; referred to Committee on Energy and Commerce .
H.R. 1254 (Walden)
Would require FERC to issue rules to establish an electronic information system to
provide the public, FERC, state commissions, buyers and sellers of wholesale electric
energy, and users of transmission services, with information on the availability and price of
wholesale electric energy and transmission services. Would prohibit round-trip electricity
trading. Would increases criminal penalties under the Federal Power Act. Introduced March
12, 2003; referred to Committee on Energy Commerce.
H.R. 1272 (Dingell)
Would prohibit fraudulent, manipulative, or deceptive acts in electric and natural gas
markets. Provides for audit trails. Increases criminal and civil penalties under the Federal
Power Act. Would make electric rate refunds retroactive to the date a complaint is filed with
FERC. Would require FERC to review all market-based rates on annual basis. Introduced
March 13, 2003; referred to Committee on Energy and Commerce.
CRS-12

IB10006
04-08-03
H.R. 1338 (Shadegg)
Would amend the Federal Power Act to provide for federal and state coordination of
permitting for electric transmission facilities. Introduced March 18, 2003; referred to
Committee on Energy and Commerce.
H.R. 1370 (Wynn)
Would establish an Electric Reliability Organization. In some instances, would allow
transmission companies to exercise the right of eminent domain to acquire transmission
rights-of-way. Would exempt regional transmission organizations from PUHCA.
Introduced March 19, 2003; referred to Committees on Energy, and Commerce and Ways
and Means.
S. 475 (Thomas)
Would establish an Electric Reliability Organization. Would repeal PUHCA and
would give FERC and state utility commissions access to books and records. Would
prospectively repeal §210 of PURPA. Would require FERC to issue rules to establish an
electronic information system to provide the public, FERC, state commissions, buyers and
sellers of wholesale electric energy, and users of transmission services, with information on
the availability and price of wholesale electric energy and transmission services. Would
prohibit round-trip trading. Would make electric rate refunds retroactive to the date a
complaint is filed with FERC. Introduced February 27, 2003; referred to Committee on
Energy and Natural Resources.
S. 681 (Cantwell)
Would require FERC to revoke market-based rates upon determination that effective
competition does not exist. Introduced March 21, 2003; referred to Committee on Energy
and Natural Resources.
S. 688 (Graham)
Prospective repeal of §210 to of PURPA. Introduced March 21, 2003; referred to
Committee on Energy and Natural Resources.
S. 716 (Landrieu)
Would establish participant funding for transmission facilities. Would require FERC
to establish technical standards and procedures for transmission interconnection. Would
require cooperative and municipal utilities to provide transmission services with rates and
conditions that are comparable to what the cooperative or municipality charges itself.
Introduced March 26, 2003; referred to Committee on Energy and Natural Resources.
S. 723 (Boxer)
Would require FERC to order refunds of at least $8.9 billion for unjust and
unreasonable rates charged between June 1, 2000 and June 19, 2001. Introduced March 26,
2003; referred to Committee on Energy and Natural Resources.
Note: For a complete description of H.R. 4 (107th Congress), see CRS Report RL31427,
Omnibus Energy Legislation: H.R. 4 Side-by-side Comparison. For a listing of electric utility
restructuring legislation in the 107th Congress, see CRS Report RL31210, Electric Utility
Restructuring Legislation in the 107th Congress.

CRS-13