Order Code RL31720
Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
Energy Policy: Historical Overview, Conceptual
Framework, and Continuing Issues
January 30, 2003
Robert Bamberger
Specialist in Energy Policy
Resources, Science, and Industry Division
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

Energy Policy: Historical Overview, Conceptual
Framework, and Continuing Issues
Summary
The persistent attention being given to energy policy has its roots in an
unexpected jump in oil prices that began in the late spring of 1999, following a
production cut by the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC). This
supply change affecting fuel prices was the fourth significant episode since 1973 to
jog American awareness of the extent to which the U.S. economy and lifestyle
depends on inexpensive and plentiful energy. When the United States experiences a
period marked by sharp increases in the price for energy and concern about the
adequacy of essential supplies, there is widespread concern that the nation has no
energy policy. The nation has, in fact, adopted several distinct policy approaches
over the years, many of the debates turning around the question of the appropriate
extent of the federal government’s role in energy.
The fashioning of national energy policy is complicated by the fact that a review
of the years since the time of the Arab oil embargo and first oil price shock in 1973
reveals that it is more accurate to see this 30-year period as one of general price and
supply stability that is periodically broken by shorter episodes of supply disruption
and price volatility. It isn’t so much that energy policy has failed to be responsive to
crises; rather, during lengthy periods of stability and declining prices for conventional
fuels, it has proven difficult to sustain certain policy courses that might help shield
the nation from the occasional episodes of instability. Awareness has also grown
about the complexity of constructing a balanced energy policy that will not
undermine other competing and equally legitimate policy goals.
Traditionally, the energy debate has been the most vigorous over the balance to
be struck between increasing supply and encouraging conservation. However, when
markets are unstable, debate turns on another axis as well, that of short-term versus
long-term policies. There are other alternatives. For example, tax policy can affect
energy price directly to the extent that excise taxes on fuel products can be raised or
lowered. Programs such as the Low Income Home Energy Assistance Program
(LIHEAP) can provide direct assistance to families whose quality of life is especially
burdened by high energy prices. Lastly, Congress always has the option to require
study and analysis of a problem before settling on a policy course.
Energy policy issues of continuing interest include whether or not to open up the
Arctic National Wildlife Refuge (ANWR) for leasing; settlement upon a pipeline
route to allow production of Alaskan natural gas; access to public lands for energy
exploration and development; restructuring of the electric utility industry to
encourage competition and consumer choice; raising corporate average fuel economy
(CAFE) standards for motor vehicles; seeking effective means to promote energy
conservation using currently available technologies; and development of new
technologies and alternative fuels.
This report has been prepared at the outset of the 108th Congress to provide
background context, and will not be updated.

Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
Energy Policy Since the Arab Embargo . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
The Final Years of Price Controls . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
The Early Effects of a Market-Oriented Energy Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
Other Responses to the Disruptions of the 1970s and 1980s . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
The Challenge Faced by Policymakers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
An Energy Policy Schematic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
The Current Context: What’s Now Different? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
Major Unresolved Energy Issues
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
Petroleum and Natural Gas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
Clean Air Standards . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
Drilling in ANWR and on Other Federal Lands . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
Natural Gas Supply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
Electricity Regulation and Supply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
Conservation and Energy Efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
The Uncertain Future . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
List of Tables
Table 1. A Schematic of Energy Policies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5

Energy Policy: Historical Overview,
Conceptual Framework, and Continuing
Issues
Introduction
The persistent attention currently being given to energy policy has its roots in
an unexpected jump in oil prices that began in the late spring of 1999, following a
production cut by the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC).
Expecting that oil prices would soon drop again, refiners drew down existing, lower-
cost inventories of refined products and crude oil rather than purchase higher-priced
new supplies. But instead of declining, prices rose even higher as OPEC
demonstrated a sustained level of discipline that had not been seen since the 1970s.
With inventories down during the winter of 1999-2000, severe weather
disrupted waterborne transport of home heating oil to New England, leading to sharp
price increases that spread to diesel fuel as well. Then, in the summer of 2000,
inadequate supplies of blending components used in the manufacture of reformulated
gasoline to meet clean-air objectives, among other problems, led to shortages of
gasoline in the Midwest with some prices exceeding, for a time, $2.00/gallon. In the
winter of 2000-2001, natural gas prices spiked because of low inventories and strong
demand, which exacerbated a crisis in Western electricity supplies. In early 2003,
oil prices were reaching into the mid-$30's, and appeared poised to possibly go higher
as a result of events in Venezuela and possible disruptions in oil supply from the
Middle East.
This current period of prolonged volatility in fuel supplies and prices has been
the fourth significant episode since 1973 to jog American awareness of the extent to
which the U.S. economy and lifestyle depends on inexpensive and plentiful energy.
When the United States experiences a period marked by sharp increases in the price
for energy and concern about the adequacy of essential supplies, there is widespread
concern that the nation has no energy policy. However, not only does the nation have
an energy policy, it has adopted several distinct policy approaches over the years.
This report discusses those major policy approaches, provides a conceptual
framework for categorizing energy policy proposals, and briefly describes issues that
remain current in the debates over energy policy.
Energy Policy Since the Arab Embargo
In the nearly thirty years since the Arab oil embargo, the United States has
pursued a number of different energy policy courses. In the course of several episodes

CRS-2
during this period when oil price and supply became unstable, the U.S. moved from
a set of policies more reliant on the federal government, to policies more dependent
upon markets. This history is briefly summarized in the section to follow.

The Final Years of Price Controls
In the aftermath of the Arab oil embargo in 1973, many looked to government
to solve the problem, for both the short- and long-term. By 1975, refiner acquisition
costs for imported crude oil had roughly tripled, rising from an average cost of
$4/barrel (bbl) in 1973 to $12.50/barrel in 1974. However, refiner acquisition costs
for domestic crude did not even double – from $4/bbl to $7/bbl – owing to a system
of federal price controls that kept the price of domestic production below the market
price. This insulated consumers from some of the price increase, but had the
companion effect of discouraging domestic production and encouraging imports.
Automobile fuel economy standards were enacted to reduce gasoline consumption
in the transportation sector. At the same time, hopes were invested in government-
funded research and development of conservation technologies and alternative fuels.
A second oil interruption and shortage was triggered in1979 by the fall of the
Shah of Iran and the loss of Iranian oil to world markets for several months.
However, by this time, a phased deregulation of oil prices, enacted in 1975 (Energy
Policy and Conservation Act, P.L. 94-163), enabled prices to be more responsive to
market conditions. Letting the market set prices, supporters of deregulation had
argued in the 1975 debate, would encourage the development of additional domestic
supplies of oil as well as the development of alternative energy sources.
The Early Effects of a Market-Oriented Energy Policy
Shortly after assuming office in 1981, President Reagan accelerated the schedule
for price decontrol. Energy policy, in general, became more market-oriented, and the
government role was lessened.
Sustained high crude oil prices contributed to a reduction in U.S. petroleum
consumption from 18.8 to 15.2 million barrels per day (mbd) from 1978 to 1982;
there was more fuel substitution, more efficient consumption of oil, and price-
induced conservation. Higher prices drew new oil production from outside the OPEC
nations, allowing the United States and other consuming nations to diversify their
sources of supply. Faced with a loss of market share and revenue, OPEC sharply
increased its own production in the mid-1980s, thereby lowering the price for crude
oil. In the course of the year from 1985 to 1986, refiner acquisition cost for imported
oil fell from $27/barrel to $14/barrel.
Prices remained depressed until a fresh round of sharp spikes in oil prices
occurred in 1990-91 following Iraq’s invasion of Kuwait in early August 1990,
cutting off 4.3 million barrels per day (mbd) from world markets. The price of oil,
which had averaged $16/bbl at the end of July 1990, exceeded $28 by late August
and reached $36/bbl in September 1990.

CRS-3
Responding to the Iraqi threat, Western and Middle Eastern nations found
common ground that would have been unimaginable a decade earlier. By the late
1980s, recognition had grown of the interdependence of oil-producing and oil-
consuming nations; the OPEC nations had come to recognize that long-term demand
for their oil was jeopardized by any prolonged period of high oil prices. Most did not
wish to repeat the cycle of the early- to mid-1980s and boosted their production to
make up for some of the lost supply. Consuming nations also coordinated the release
of strategic stocks of crude and products. Prices began to fall in mid-October 1990
when the United Nations approved the use of force against Iraq. Prices fell more
sharply after the United States and a consortium of nations began conducting air
strikes on Iraq in mid-January 1991.
Other Responses to the Disruptions of the 1970s and 1980s
During all of these episodes, importance was placed on conservation, more
efficient use of energy, and development of alternative energy sources. The oil shocks
of the mid- and late-1970s spurred considerable spending on alternative fuels –
including solar, geothermal, wind, clean coal, synthetic fuels, alcohol-based fuels –
and technologies to improve the efficiency of energy use. Regulations were
developed to improve the efficiency of home appliances and to incorporate more
energy-efficient designs in buildings. In the early 1980s, states and utilities promoted
energy efficiency as one form of “demand-side management” to reduce the need for
construction of new power plants. Many industries re-engineered their processes to
save energy. Conservation and efficiency were championed by some as a lower-cost
and more environmentally appealing way to achieve greater energy security than
policies to boost supply. However, largely because of the generally lower prices over
time for fossil fuels – as is noted below – these energy programs have shown mixed
results.
The Challenge Faced by Policymakers
As suggested earlier, each episode of short supply and higher prices spurs
concern that the nation lacks an energy policy and has ignored past lessons.
However, it is apparent from a review of the years since the time of the Arab oil
embargo and first oil price shock in 1973 that it is more accurate to see this 30-year
period as one of general price and supply stability that is periodically broken by
shorter episodes of supply disruption and price volatility. It isn’t so much that energy
policy has failed to be responsive to crises; rather, during lengthy periods of stability
and declining prices for conventional fuels, it has proven difficult to sustain certain
policy courses that might help shield the nation from the occasional episodes of
instability.
An energy policy that would most effectively shield the nation and the economy
from the worst effects of supply shortages would be a policy that might well deny the
nation the full benefits of cheap and plentiful energy when markets are stable. The
periods of relative calm and stability result in a markedly uncertain environment for
investment in alternative fuels, energy efficiency technologies, and boosting the
production of conventional fuels in regions where production costs are significantly
higher than in the Middle East. State and local regulations and codes further cloud

CRS-4
the climate for investment. Local opposition to new power plants, electric
transmission lines, refineries, and pipelines is often most effective during periods of
price and supply stability, but sometimes eases only after shortages have actually
occurred.
An Energy Policy Schematic
Constructing a balanced energy policy that will not undermine other competing
and equally legitimate policy goals is a complex problem. How to boost energy
supply without exacting an unacceptable toll on the environment? How, then, to
reduce gasoline consumption, a commodity central to the nation’s economy and
lifestyle, when raising its price to achieve a meaningful reduction in demand could
be economically disruptive and politically unappealing? Should federal policy
encourage the use of more expensive alternative fuels and technologies that heighten
efficiency, when OPEC has the capacity to adjust the price of oil to keep it far
cheaper than its substitutes?
Debate over energy policy has produced an enormous range of proposals, many
of which have been adopted at one point or another over the years. In general,
however, it is helpful to recognize the broad categories into which most proposals
fall: Most energy policies are designed to affect either the supply of or the demand
for energy products, and they are, at the same time, designed to have an effect either
in the near term or the longer term.
Traditionally, the energy debate has been the most vigorous over the balance to
be struck between increasing supply and encouraging conservation. However, energy
policy turns on the additional axis of short- and long-term policies. In the midst of
high prices during the spring of 2001, policymakers were pressed to come up with
immediate policy responses that would afford consumers price relief. However,
President Bush was advising Congress and Americans that the Administration’s
energy policy plan (shortly to be released) would focus on long-term remedies for the
nation’s energy problems and that there would be no immediate relief for consumers
paying higher prices for gasoline, electricity, and other fuels. The President and his
supporters suggested that by setting out an action-oriented and actionable
comprehensive policy, markets and consumers should feel some short-term
reassurance. This did not quell all the demands for more immediate action to reduce
energy prices. The various reactions to the Bush energy proposals underscored the
difficulty of developing comprehensive energy policy during a period of tight supply
and high prices.1
It is useful to clarify the differences between short-term and long-term policy
initiatives. For example, a drawdown of oil from the Strategic Petroleum Reserve
(SPR) affects crude oil supply in the near term. However, enactment of tax
incentives for investment in new oil drilling technologies might add to domestic
crude supply further in the future. Proponents of drilling in the Arctic National
Wildlife Refuge (ANWR) argue it might add anywhere from 300,000 b/d (barrels per
1 For details of the Administration energy policy, see CRS Report RL31096, Bush Energy
Policy: Overview of Major Proposals and Legislative Action
, August 22, 2001.

CRS-5
day) to 1.4 mbd to U.S. domestic supply, but this, too, is a longer-term policy
initiative.
Turning to the consumption side of the ledger, boosting the federal gasoline tax
by $1.00/gallon might be expected to reduce gasoline consumption in the short term,
but increasing the corporate average fuel economy (CAFE) standards on new motor
vehicles would not take full effect until older vehicles were largely replaced, a
process that could take more than a decade.
The table below suggests a way in which many energy policies may be
visualized along these lines:
Table 1
A Schematic of Energy Policies
Affecting Supply
Affecting Demand
Short-term to Mid-
Strategic Petroleum
High energy prices due
term
Reserve (SPR)
to unfettered market
forces or taxation
Allowing high prices to
allocate and price scarce
Policies promoting
energy
conservation and more
energy-efficient choices
Mid- to Long-term
Tax incentives to
Corporate Average Fuel
promote production
Economy Standards
(CAFE)
Open new areas to
leasing and exploration
Tax incentives to
encourage less, or more-
Research and
efficient consumption
development
Efficiency standards
Market pricing of energy
Efficiency labeling
Research and
development in
efficiency technologies
The axis of long-term/short-term, supply/demand does not capture all policy
options. For example, one of the major issues in energy policy is the price for fuels.
Energy policy generally is designed to affect price indirectly – by having price
follow, or reflect, current demand or supply for energy. There are a few exceptions.
Tax policy may address energy price directly to the extent that excise taxes on fuel
products can be raised or lowered (recognizing that these tax boosts or cuts may not
be reflected penny-for-penny in the “pump” price for fuels).

CRS-6
Short-term policies to affect supply, such as potential use of strategic reserves,
have been sometimes very controversial because, in the absence of a very clear-cut
and widely acknowledged physical shortage, such initiatives are perceived to be
thinly disguised efforts to grant price relief.2 Some suggest at times that high prices
– left uninterfered with – are the best policy of all, encouraging markets to provide
more supply in due course, and that federal policy should address only those most
adversely affected by sharply higher prices. The Low Income Home Energy
Assistance Program (LIHEAP) is one such effort to provide direct assistance to
families whose quality of life is especially burdened by high energy prices. LIHEAP
is a short-term policy for addressing the impact of high prices for energy.
Supply and demand may also be affected by external events, including political
and diplomatic dynamics between or among the producing nations. Weather,
seasonal or otherwise, will affect supply and demand; policy cannot affect the
weather, only its consequences. Lastly, Congress always has the option to require
study and analysis of a problem before settling on a policy course. Requirements for
such studies are regularly included in appropriations bills and other legislation.
The Current Context: What’s Now Different?
In every energy debate, one question is a constant: How extensive a federal role
is appropriate in energy policy? But even prior to the terrorist attacks upon the nation
on September 11, 2001, the context for the current energy debate was distinctly
different from previous episodes.
! U.S. energy policy has been primarily market-based for nearly 20 years, but
policy makers have been weighing whether problems in some sectors and with
some fuels are attributable to distribution or regulatory inefficiencies
interfering with markets, or whether government intervention may be
necessary to protect consumers and the economy from problems to which
markets cannot flexibly respond.
! Strong economic growth during the mid- and late 1990s at a time of declining
real energy prices resulted in growth in consumption even though efficiency
of energy use is dramatically better than during the 1970s and 1980s. Growth
in petroleum consumption in the United States as domestic production
declines has meant a commensurate increase in oil imports.
! There is recognition of the interdependence of producing and consuming
nations; however, the political balance among the OPEC nations is delicate
2 The Energy Policy and Conservation Act (P.L. 94-163, EPCA) authorizes drawdown of
the Strategic Petroleum Reserve upon a finding by the President that there is a “severe
energy supply interruption,” or in the event of a circumstance that “constitutes, or is likely
to become, a domestic or international energy supply shortage of significant scope or
duration” and where “action taken ... would assist directly and significantly in preventing
or reducing the adverse impact of such shortage.”

CRS-7
and can influence oil production decisions and whether OPEC is able to exert
market control at all.
! There is growing recognition that the recent shortages and price spikes in
some regions of the country have been largely caused or compounded by
insufficiencies in the nation’s energy infrastructure – refining capacity, gas
and oil pipelines, transmission lines, and electric generating facilities.
! Problems with gasoline supply and home heating oil stocks during 2000-2001
imply some need to develop additional refining capacity and transport systems
that will add both capacity and flexibility to distribution. However, national
and local environmental regulation and requirements, and local community
sentiment, affect the speed and ease of siting and building such facilities.
Concerns about greenhouse gas emissions add an additional measure of
uncertainty, as has the depth of the economic slowdown.
! The experience with deregulation of electricity in California has added
uncertainty to the policy debate over national restructuring of the industry.
Major Unresolved Energy Issues

The shift to a more market-oriented energy policy, additional lessons some have
taken from experiences during the 1980s and 1990s, geopolitical developments, and
developments such as those outlined above, are likely to play a part in any resolution
of energy issues still pending and of interest to many policymakers. Some of these
issues are broadly reviewed below.
Petroleum and Natural Gas
Demand for petroleum products in the United States ranges between 19-20 mbd.
Increases in demand, as well as declining domestic production, have been offset by
increased crude and product imports, which now approach an average of 10 mbd.
Cuts in world crude production in March 1999 by OPEC sent domestic refiner
acquisition costs for crude oil on a sharp ascent from less than $11/bbl in February
1999 to $24.50/bbl by December of the same year. These costs peaked at over
$31/bbl in the latter part of 2000.
Subsequently, after intense lobbying by the United States, the OPEC oil
ministers boosted crude production and settled upon $22-$28 per barrel (bbl) as a
desirable “price band.” In the wake of the terrorist attacks in September 2001, OPEC
chose not to defend crude prices too aggressively lest OPEC appear to be tipping the
global economy into recession. By late November 2001, prices had fallen below
$20/bbl, and OPEC was seeking production cuts from outside the cartel to bolster
price. Crude oil prices reached the mid-$30s/bbl in January 2003 as concern about
war with Iraq grew and as Venezuela, a major exporter, was paralyzed by a general
strike.

CRS-8
The ability of the OPEC cartel to exert influence upon oil prices at critical times
underscores that – with respect to petroleum – the problem is less that the world
supply of oil is tight than that so much of it is concentrated in other parts of the
globe, principally the Middle East. U.S. dependence upon imported oil exceeds 50%
of total consumption. Absent some elusive technical “fix,” there are limited
prospects for significantly reducing that figure without incurring economic hardship
and lifestyle compromises. However, relatively modest increases in worldwide
production or reductions in demand by consuming nations can substantially reduce
the magnitude of oil price spikes.
Clean Air Standards. Attention has focused on the Clean Air Act standards
that regulate the oxygen content, volatility, benzene and the sulfur content of
gasoline. Refineries face state and local standards on how to achieve compliance
with federal requirements. The result is a multiplicity of gasoline formulations, some
using methyl tertiary butyl ether (MTBE) as an oxygenate and octane booster, while
other regions require ethanol.
One consequence of these regional variations is that gasoline supply has lost
some of its fungibility; one region experiencing a shortage may no longer be able to
secure additional supply from a refiner servicing a nearby locality with a different
blend of gasoline. Distribution becomes more complicated because different blends
sharing the same pipeline must be carefully batched to avoid contamination.
Additionally, most foreign refineries have not made the investment to supply any but
the most general U.S. gasoline market.
Some have urged a relaxation of Clean Air Act standards that would permit a
“harmonization” of U.S. gasoline standards. This would introduce flexibility into the
gasoline manufacture and distribution system that might bring prices down. It would
mean, however, temporarily compromising clean air objectives and, depending upon
where the harmonized standard was set, might actually raise prices for fuel in regions
that did not require the more exacting formulations.
Drilling in ANWR and on Other Federal Lands. The greater the nation’s
ability to produce its own fuels, the less vulnerable it is to unanticipated international
developments that can reduce or threaten supply. But the policy options on the
supply side, such as opening up the Arctic National Wildlife Refuge (ANWR) for
exploration, are mostly long-term. Alaskan oil production, which once touched 2
mbd, has now fallen below 1 mbd and, without new production, will continue to
decline until production levels can no longer support the costs of transporting it
through the Trans-Alaska Pipeline.
Proponents of exploring ANWR point to advances in exploration and drilling
technology and methods that have significantly reduced the extent of surface
disturbance. While opponents concede this may be so, they argue that these advances
are limited to exploration and extraction, and that considerable risk to the
environment remains during the production and transportation phases. Opponents
also suggest that the risks are not worth bearing, especially if the resources in ANWR
turn out to be at the lower range of estimates, providing only an additional 300,000
b/d of supply. Some respond to this argument by noting that the nation has
experienced periods of tight supply when even an additional few hundred thousand

CRS-9
barrels of crude oil per day would have significantly reduced gasoline and heating oil
prices. For some opponents, any weighing of risks and benefits are pointless because,
citing the area’s pristine character, they argue that its ecology and habitat should not
be disturbed under any circumstances. (For additional information and background,
see CRS Report RL31278, Arctic National Wildlife Refuge: Background and Issues.)
The broader issue raised by ANWR – that of access to public lands for energy
exploration and development – is a significant component of the national energy
debate. There is considerable disagreement about the potential resources on federal
lands – particularly the amount of oil and gas that may be “locked up” by land-use
restrictions and other regulatory factors. The Bush Administration’s energy policy
report recommended an examination of “land status and lease stipulation
impediments” and that policymakers “consider modifications where appropriate.”
(For additional information and background, see CRS Report RS20902, National
Monument Issues
.) A report by the Department of Interior, on the other hand,
indicates this may not be the problem some have alleged.3
Natural Gas Supply. For the past decade in the United States, natural gas
consumption was encouraged, particularly for gas-fired combined-cycle power plants
that could provide incremental electric supply to the nation’s power grid at highly
competitive prices and with few environmental constraints. Plentiful supplies, and
relatively low prices for several years, discouraged additions to natural gas reserves
during the 1990s.4 With surges in demand for electricity and a colder winter in 2000-
2001, residential and other consumers of natural gas suddenly faced sharply higher
prices as competition grew for gas supplies. At the wellhead, gas prices rose from
$2.60 per thousand cubic feet (mcf) in January 2000 to $8.06 per mcf in January
2001, after which prices declined steadily.5
After that winter, prices declined, as did reserve additions, which fell from
152% of production in 2000 to 131% during 2001.6 Drilling activity also declined
through 2002, falling from a high of 1,058 active rigs in mid-2001 to an average of
690 during 2002.7 This suggests that 2002 reserve additions – when tabulated – are
likely to be less than those of 2001. Supporting this assessment is the fact that natural
gas prices declined sharply during the fall of 2001 to the range of $2.00. However,
during the winter of 2002-2003, prices rose sharply once more – to roughly the
$5.50/mcf range – underscoring the difficulty of crafting policy when sharp
fluctuations in demand, price, and supply can occur suddenly between, or even
during, seasons.
3 Scientific Inventory of Onshore Federal Lands’ Oil and Gas Resources and Reserves and
the Extent and Nature of Restrictions or Impediments to the Development. January 2003.
http://momentum.doi.gov/epca/ExecSum.pdf
4See http://www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/aer/txt/ptb0410.html.
5 EIA, Monthly Energy Review, Table 9.11.
6 EIA, U.S. Crude Oil, Natural Gas and Natural Gas liquids Reserves 2001 Annual Report.
Page 29.
7 EIA, Monthly Energy Review, Table 5.1.

CRS-10
A major potential source of additional gas is tanker-borne imports in the form
of liquefied natural gas (LNG). Expansion and refurbishment of facilities to
accommodate LNG imports continues. Additionally, there are a number of proposals
for new facilities – some, offshore in Mexico and the Bahamas – that would receive
LNG produced abroad for consumption in the United States. The Alaska North Slope
holds large proven reserves of natural gas, but supporters of constructing a pipeline
have argued that it may require loan guarantees and price supports.
Electricity Regulation and Supply
The Enron debacle raised new questions about restructuring of the electricity
industry and has slowed the momentum of federal restructuring legislation. However,
it was the electric utility crisis in California in early 2001 that shifted the focus of
electricity restructuring legislation away from comprehensive bills that previously
dominated the electric utility restructuring debate toward issues related to electric
system reliability. Regulatory functions are currently divided between the states and
the federal government, and there has been considerable argument not only about
which controls need to be retained, but how to redraw the respective roles of the
federal government and the states to assure reliability.
A reliable electric system depends on adequate transmission capacity. The
regulatory regime has shifted in the electricity industry to encourage competition in
the generation sector, but investment in transmission infrastructure has not kept up
with increases in bulk power transfers and electricity demand. Additionally,
transmission lines are congested in several regions of the United States. Difficulty in
siting the lines and regulatory uncertainty have dampened interest in investing in the
transmission system. FERC has approved three Regional Transmission Organizations
(RTOs) and is in the process of evaluating others.8
Some have argued that transmission and wholesale power markets cannot be
competitive without additional market transparency, or access to market information.
Proposals have been made to require FERC to issue rules establishing an electronic
information system to provide information about the availability and price of
wholesale electric energy and transmission services to FERC, state commissions,
buyers and sellers of wholesale electric energy, users of transmission services, and
the public. However, concerns have been raised that such a system would take away
too much authority from the states.
Comprehensive energy legislation debated in the Senate, but not enacted during
the 107th Congress, included language to establish a renewable portfolio standard
requiring that 10% of electricity generation come from non-hydro renewable energy
resources by 2020. Proposals such as this one introduce dimensions that were not
part of restructuring when it was first raised, but may be a part of any continuing
debate.
Concern over electricity supply has also led to some reassessment of the relative
roles that natural gas, coal, renewables, and nuclear energy may have in future
8For details, see: http://www.ferc.gov/Electric/RTO/post_rto.htm.

CRS-11
electricity generation. In its energy policy report, the Bush Administration indicated
its objectives to remove barriers to the use of coal in electric power generation, with
a renewed emphasis on cleaner-burning coal technologies.
Supporters of renewable energy have urged the establishment of a national
“renewable portfolio standard,” which would require that a certain percentage of
electricity generation come from non-hydro renewable energy sources. Nuclear
energy supporters have long proposed that new nuclear generating capacity receive
incentives for helping to reduce air emissions.
(For additional information, see CRS Electronic Briefing Book: Electric Utility
Restructuring [http://www.congress.gov/brbk/html/ebele1.shtml].

Conservation and Energy Efficiency
As has been noted, the energy policy debate has turned partly on perceptions of
the balance between supply-oriented and conservation-oriented policies that make up
an appropriate energy policy to address the current matrix of energy problems. For
example, environmental groups often ask why ANWR should be opened to leasing
if a comparable amount of oil could be saved by raising motor vehicle fuel economy.
The Energy Policy and Conservation Act (P.L. 94-163) established new car
corporate average fuel economy (CAFE) standards, beginning with model year 1978.
Currently, the standards are 27.5 miles per gallon (mpg) for cars and 20.7 mpg for
light-duty trucks, including sport utility vehicles (SUVs). Proposals to raise the
CAFE standards have been controversial. Beginning with enactment of the FY1996
Department of Transportation Appropriations Act, Congress forbade the expenditure
of appropriated funds to make any change in the current CAFE requirements.
However, a study by the National Academy of Sciences (NAS), requested by
the 106th Congress, to recommend “appropriate” CAFE standards, was released at the
end of July 2001.9 While the report did not recommend a specific level for CAFE,
it did conclude that “significant” reductions in fuel consumption could be achieved
within 15 years utilizing existing technologies. Were increases in new car fuel
economy achieved by reducing vehicle weight or disproportionately encouraging the
sale of small vehicles, the study allowed that additional fatalities could result.
However, some members of the NAS panel dissented, suggesting that the analysis
of the relationship between fuel economy and vehicle safety is extremely complex.
Before the 107th Congress ended without enactment of comprehensive energy
legislation, the conferees had agreed to language in the House version of the bill that
would have required a savings of 5 billion gallons in gasoline consumption by SUVs
between model years 2006 and 2012.
On December 16, 2002, the National Highway Traffic Safety Administration
(NHTSA) issued a notice of proposed rulemaking to boost the CAFE of light-duty
9 http://www.nap.edu/books/0309076013/html/.

CRS-12
trucks by 1.5 mpg by 2007. This may not satisfy some policymakers who may seek
more aggressive CAFE improvements in future energy legislation.
There is little question that the price hikes during past episodes of tight energy
supply spurred many improvements in energy efficiency. Some argue, however, that
the easiest and lowest-cost efficiency gains have been achieved, and that expectations
should be lowered about the additional efficiency gains that can be captured in the
present price framework for energy. When the Reagan Administration redirected
energy policy to a more market-oriented framework, it was argued that R&D needed
to be carefully focused on areas that were promising, but unlikely to be explored by
the private sector.
The current Bush Administration energy policy recommended a review of the
funding and performance of energy efficiency research and development for the
purpose of determining appropriate funding for performance-based research in
public-private partnerships.
The Uncertain Future
As apparent as it seems to many that the nation should do “something” about
energy, the preceding pages have outlined the layers of complexity that augur against
easy agreement to many of the policy options that have been proposed and debated
since the mid-1970s. A review of the history shows that every episode of instability
has had its own set of contributing factors – and that these may be geopolitical, based
in energy infrastructure, or triggered by extremes of heat or cold beyond anyone’s
control. Making policy decisions that will anticipate unpredictable future
developments, or settling on policies to mitigate the consequences when these events
are before us, will remain a challenge for policymakers as the energy debate
continues.