Order Code RL31511
Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
Federal Taxation of the Drug Industry:
1990 to 1999
July 22, 2002
Gary Guenther
Analyst in Business Taxation and Finance
Government and Finance Division
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

Federal Taxation of the Drug Industry: 1990 to 1999
Summary
A critical consideration in the current debate in Congress over expanding access
to prescription drugs is the key forces driving the discovery and development of new
medicines. Obviously, one such force is federal policy in areas related to
pharmaceutical innovation. This report examines a small slice of the assortment of
federal policies that affect the incentive to invest in pharmaceutical innovation: the
federal tax burden on the pharmaceutical industry from 1990 to 1999.
Most industries have distinctive traits, and the pharmaceutical industry clearly
is no exception. In the minds of most analysts, what distinguishes firms that develop,
produce, and sell patented or branded medicines is their singular combination of
heavy investment in research and development and advertising, concentration in
specific market segments, relatively high dependence on patents to generate revenue
and profit growth, and extensive web of foreign operations. Some of these traits have
important implications for the industry’s federal tax burden.
Public finance economists define a firm’s or an industry’s federal tax burden as
the share of its pre-tax economic income paid in federal income taxes. One
commonly used measure of an industry’s federal tax burden is its average effective
tax rate, which is the ratio of its federal tax liability after all credits (except the
foreign tax credit) to its pre-tax income expressed as a percentage. This measure is
not without shortcomings. A principal problem is that average effective rates do not
consider the influence of tax provisions that accelerate the timing of deductions or
delay the recognition of income. Moreover, the concept of income used in the
calculations here is taxable income, which may differ considerably from economic
income or pre-tax income defined according to financial accounting principles.
A comparison of the average effective federal tax rates for the drug industry and
major U.S. industries suggests that the drug industry had a relatively light federal tax
burden in much of the 1990s. This finding reflected the substantial tax savings that
drug firms derived from three tax credits: (1) the possessions tax credit; (2) the
research tax credit; and (3) the orphan drug tax credit. These credits were available
to all firms. On the whole, it appeared that pharmaceutical firms extracted greater
benefit from them – especially the possessions tax credit – than most other firms.
If it were possible to compute marginal effective tax rates for the same industries, it
is likely that the drug industry still would have the lowest rate. This is because
pharmaceutical firms are likely to benefit disproportionately from three tax
preferences: (1) the deferral of federal income tax on the retained earnings of foreign
subsidiaries of U.S.-chartered corporations, (2) the expensing of R&D outlays, and(3)
the expensing of advertising outlays.
Pharmaceutical firms have sought to maximize after-tax profits by taking
advantage of certain provisions in the tax code whose purpose is to promote specific
policy goals of the federal government. Most of these provisions have nothing to do
with the advancement of pharmaceutical innovation.
This report will be updated when more recent data become available.

Contents
Distinguishing Characteristics of the U.S. Pharmaceutical Industry . . . . . . . . . . . 2
Heavy Investment in R&D . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
Heavy Investment in Product Promotion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
Competitive Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
Dependence on Patent Protection . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
Extensive Foreign Operations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
Federal Income Taxes Paid by the Drug Industry Between 1990 and 1999 . . . . . 6
Foreign Tax Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
Orphan Drug Tax Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
Possessions and Puerto Rican Economic Activity Tax Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
Research and Experimentation Tax Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
Federal Tax Burden on the Drug Industry and Major U.S. Industries
from 1994 to 1999 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
Deferral of Federal Income Taxes on Foreign-Source Income . . . . . . . . . . 13
Expensing of R&D Spending . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
Expensing of Advertising Spending . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
List of Tables
Table 1. Federal Income Tax Liability for the Drug Industry, 1990 to 1999 . . . . 6
Table 2. Main Federal Tax Credits Claimed by the Drug Industry from
1990 to 1999 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
Table 3. Average Effective Tax Rates for the Drug Industry and
Major U.S. Industries from 1994 to 1999 (%) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

Federal Taxation of the Drug Industry:
1990 to 1999
The pharmaceutical industry is no stranger to controversy. On the one hand,
pharmaceutical firms are lauded for their huge and growing investments in the
development of safer or more effective medicines and new medicines that advance
the treatment of a variety of serious illnesses.1 On the other hand, the same firms are
castigated for their pricing of branded or patented drugs, their efforts to thwart
competition from cheaper generic drugs, their relatively strong profitability, and their
large and rising outlays for direct advertising to consumers and product promotion
among physicians, who serve as the central players in the decision to use prescription
drugs.2 Framing these contrary sentiments is a contentious debate in Congress over
how to improve access to prescription drugs among Americans of all ages –
especially Medicare beneficiaries – without incurring massive future federal budget
deficits or undermining incentives for pharmaceutical innovation.
A critical component of this debate is the chief forces driving the discovery and
development of new medicines, one of which is federal policies affecting new drug
development. The federal government plays a far-reaching role in pharmaceutical
innovation. This role encompasses a variety of discrete activities, including federal
funding of pharmaceutical research and development (R&D), federal approval of new
patented and generic drugs, federal patent policy toward prescription drugs, federal
support of biomedical research and education in universities, federal financing of
drug purchases through Medicaid and Medicare, and federal tax subsidies for R&D
and employer-provided health insurance. While it is difficult to estimate the
proportion of pharmaceutical R&D affected by these activities, one thing seems
certain: the domestic climate for pharmaceutical innovation would be radically
different in their absence.
1In 2001, companies that were members of the Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers
of America, the principal trade association for the U.S. pharmaceutical industry, spent an
estimated $23.9 billion on domestic pharmaceutical research and development (R&D), up
from $6.8 billion in 1990. At the same time, 98 new drugs were either awaiting regulatory
approval by the U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA) or undergoing human clinical
trials. See Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America, Pharmaceutical
Industry Profile
(Washington: 2002), pp. 12 and IX.
2Between 1998 and 2000, the Consumer Price Index (CPI) for brand-name prescription
drugs rose at an average annual rate of 10.5%, compared to a rate of 2.8% for the overall
CPI. According to recent data for Fortune 500 companies, the median ratio of after-tax
income to revenues for pharmaceutical manufacturers in 2000 was 18.6%, compared to a
median ratio for all Fortune 500 companies of 4.5%. And total promotional spending by the
pharmaceutical industry rose from $9.2 billion in 1996 to $15.7 billion in 2000. See The
Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation, Prescription Drug Trends: A Chartbook Update
(Washington: Nov. 2001), pp. 28, 46, and 31.

CRS-2
This report examines a small slice of the assortment of federal policies
influencing pharmaceutical innovation: federal taxation of the pharmaceutical
industry. The federal tax code directly and indirectly affects private investment in
new drug discovery and development. The direct effect comes from tax subsidies for
R&D investment; federal tax policy indirectly affects industry spending on
pharmaceutical R&D through its impact on the cost of capital for this purpose. The
report looks at the industry’s federal tax burden from 1990 to 1999, highlighting the
provisions in the federal tax code that appear to generate significant tax benefits or
penalties for pharmaceutical firms. It begins with a description of the distinguishing
traits of the pharmaceutical industry, many of which play a prominent role in its tax
treatment.
Distinguishing Characteristics of the U.S.
Pharmaceutical Industry
Most industries have distinctive traits, and the pharmaceutical industry is no
exception. In the minds of many analysts, what distinguishes firms that develop,
produce, and sell patented or branded prescription drugs is their singular combination
of heavy investment in R&D and advertising, concentration in specific market
segments, relatively high dependence on patents to generate sustained revenue and
profit growth and to bolster competitiveness, and extensive network of foreign
operations.
Heavy Investment in R&D
The pharmaceutical industry is one of the most research-intensive U.S.
industries, even though pharmaceutical firms receive little in the way of direct
funding from federal government agencies for their innovative activities. According
to estimates by the National Science Board, U.S. makers of drugs and medicines
spent 10.5% of their net sales on R&D in 1997, compared to ratios of 2.9% for all
industries and 3.3% for manufacturing.3 In the same year, U.S. makers of drugs and
medicines spent $11.6 billion on R&D, while federal spending on pharmaceutical
R&D amounted to only $3 million.4 The principal trade association for the U.S.
pharmaceutical industry, the Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America
(or PhRMA), estimates that in 2001, domestic spending on pharmaceutical R&D by
member firms totaled $23.9 billion (or 17.7% of their domestic sales), compared with
$6.8 billion (or 16.2% of domestic sales) in 1990.5
Pharmaceutical firms pour substantial resources into R&D mainly because it is
a powerful engine of long-term survival and growth in the prescription drug business.
On the one hand, discovering and developing a new innovative drug is a lengthy,
3National Science Board, Science & Engineering Indicators – 2000 (Arlington, VA:
National Science Foundation, 2000), appendix table 2-57, p. A-102.
4Ibid., appendix tables 2-54 and 2-55, pp. A-97 and A-99.
5Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America, 2002 Industry Profile
(Washington: PhRMA, 2002), pp. 12-13.

CRS-3
risky, and costly process.6 On the other hand, firms launching new innovative drugs
that eventually gain wide acceptance in the marketplace can reap huge profits from
them until their patents expire or rival patented drugs gain regulatory approval.7
Significant advances in the technology for new drug development over the past 25
years have greatly increased the number of drug compounds with therapeutic
potential being discovered. Nonetheless, there is growing concern among analysts
that the flow of new breakthrough drugs through the developmental pipeline is
slowing to the point where some major firms might be forced to merge. A recent
study by the National Institute for Health Care Management Foundation found that
only 15% of the 1,035 new drug applications approved by the FDA from 1989 to
2000, contained new chemical ingredients that offered significant therapeutic
improvements over existing drugs.8 A spate of mergers could affect the future
amount and composition of domestic pharmaceutical R&D by lessening competition
in key segments of the market for prescription drugs.9
Heavy Investment in Product Promotion
In light of the enormous investments in R&D made by pharmaceutical firms and
small likelihood of delivering highly profitable drugs to the marketplace, it is no
surprise that these firms spend large sums annually on promoting their branded
products to physicians and consumers. In fact, one could argue that major
pharmaceutical firms deem advertising nearly as important as R&D in their
competitive strategies. According to one estimate, domestic promotional spending
by pharmaceutical firms totaled $15.7 billion in 2000, up from $9.1 billion in 1996.10
More than half of the 2000 expenditures went to the distribution of free drug samples
to physicians; another 30% covered the cost of making direct sales pitches to
physicians; and nearly 16% were funneled into direct advertising to consumers. The
strong focus on informing and encouraging brand loyalty among physicians reflects
a distinctive feature of the U.S. market for prescription drugs: consumers rely on the
judgment and consent of third parties – namely, doctors – in deciding which
prescription drugs to use in treating illness.
6According to research findings summarized by PhRMA, the average period from synthesis
of a new compound to approval by the U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA) was over
14 years in the 1990s; only one out of every 5,000 compounds synthesized in a laboratory
gains FDA approval; the cost of developing a new drug (including the cost of failures) rose
from $54 million in 1976 to $802 million in 2000; and as few as three out of ten newly
approved drugs earn enough revenues to cover their R&D cost. See Ibid., pp. 18-22.
7For example, U.S. retail sales of Lipitor, a patented cholesterol-lowering drug sold by
Pfizer, totaled $4.5 billion in 2001, up from $3.7 billion in 2000. See National Institute for
Health Care Management Foundation, Prescription Drug Expenditures in 2001: Another
Year of Escalating Costs
(Washington: April 2002), table 3, p. 13.
8National Institute for Health Care Management Foundation, Changing Patterns of
Pharmaceutical Innovation
(Washington: May 2002), p. 3.
9Andrew Pollack, “Despite Billions for Discoveries, Pipeline of Drugs is Far From Full,”
New York Times, Apr. 19, 2002, pp. C1 and C7.
10Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation, Prescription Drug Trends, p. 31.

CRS-4
Competitive Structure
Another distinguishing characteristic of the pharmaceutical industry is its
fragmented competitive structure. No single firm or small cluster of firms seems to
dominate the U.S. market for branded prescription drugs. The U.S. Census Bureau
has determined that in 1997, the four largest producers accounted for 32% of the
value of domestic shipments of medicines, the eight largest for 48%, and the 20
largest for 67%.11 Ten years earlier, the four largest accounted for 22% of shipments
and the 20 largest for 65%. Yet, owing in part to the competitive advantages arising
from being among the first to bring new innovative drugs to the marketplace, some
firms are able to establish at least a temporary supremacy in certain key segments of
the market. For example, in October 2001, five companies held 70% of the U.S.
market for anti-ulcer drugs; three companies accounted for 83% of U.S. prescriptions
for anti-psychotic drugs; and three companies laid claim to 81% of the U.S. market
for cholesterol-lowering drugs.12
Dependence on Patent Protection
In addition, U.S. pharmaceutical firms exhibit a heavy reliance on patents to
generate revenue and profit growth and augment their competitiveness. Patents give
holders a temporary legal monopoly over the commercial use of an invention. They
are widely viewed as an indispensable policy instrument for fostering innovation in
that in the absence of patent protection, the cost of imitating a new invention might
be so low as to discourage investment in innovation. In the United States and most
other advanced industrialized nations, the life of a patent is 20 years from the date of
application. A patent holder may license other firms to exploit the invention, but it
would assess them royalties as compensation for the waiver of its exclusive control.
Pharmaceutical firms claim patents for the design of drug compounds, their
formulation as drug therapies, their uses in treating illnesses, and their methods of
manufacture.13 Thus it comes as no surprise that pharmaceutical industry executives
regard patents as one of the most effective means of protecting the competitive
advantages that flow from investing in innovation.14
The industry’s reliance on patents partly explains why drug firms have long
been among the most profitable of all firms. From 1960 to 1991, the reported rate
of return on stockholders’ equity for pharmaceutical firms included in the annual
ranking of the top 500 industrial corporations by Fortune magazine averaged 18.4%,
11U.S. Census Bureau, 1997 Economic Census: Concentration Ratios in Manufacturing
(Washington: June 2001), table 2, p. 11.
12Standard & Poor’s, Industry Surveys, Healthcare: Pharmaceuticals (New York, Dec. 27,
2001), pp. 10-13.
13U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment, Pharmaceutical R&D: Costs, Risks, and
Rewards
(Washington: U.S. Govt. Print. Off., Feb. 1993), pp. 290-293.
14F. M. Scherer, Industry Structure, Strategy, and Public Policy (New York: Harper-Collins,
1996), pp. 360-362.

CRS-5
compared to 11.9% for all 500 firms.15 More recently, pharmaceuticals ranked first
in return on shareholders’ equity (33.2%) among the 48 industries represented in the
Fortune 500 in 2001.16 Proof that patents are critical to the profitability of
pharmaceutical firms can be found in the differences in selling prices between
branded drugs and their generic counterparts. Innovative medicines protected by
patents typically command far higher prices than competing generic drugs, which
lack patent protection.17
Extensive Foreign Operations
Finally, no account of the distinctive traits of U.S. pharmaceutical firms –
especially those having a bearing on their federal tax treatment – would be complete
without a brief description of their extensive foreign operations, including Puerto
Rico. Most major U.S. pharmaceutical firms own foreign subsidiaries that
manufacture and sell drugs and conduct R&D – especially in Europe and Japan, the
two largest regional markets (measured in U.S. dollars) for patented medicines after
North America.18 Like U.S. automobile producers, major pharmaceutical firms
recognized three or four decades ago that in order to become serious long-term
players in key foreign markets, they needed to establish a manufacturing presence
there.19
As the following figures testify, the industry has done so in a big way. In 2000,
U.S. exports by PhRMA member companies came to $399 million, whereas foreign
sales through their subsidiaries and branches totaled $39.5 billion, or 34% of
domestic sales by these companies.20 In the same year, foreign R&D spending for
drugs for human consumption by PhRMA member companies amounted to $6.3
billion, or 27% of their spending on domestic R&D.21 According to estimates by the
U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis, in 2000, assets held by foreign affiliates of U.S.
producers of drugs had a book value of $32.3 billion; foreign direct investment by
these producers amounted to $1.8 billion; and they received $4.1 billion in income
from foreign affiliates.22 Some of this foreign income represents a return on past U.S.
R&D investments because it is in the form of royalty payments. According to figures
15Ibid., p. 342.
1 6 2002 Fortune 500, “Top Performing Companies and Industries,”
[http://www.fortune.com/lists/F500/topperf_ind_mostproft_equit.html], visited Apr. 23,
2002.
17Once a prescription drug’s patent expires, generic drugs, which are chemical equivalents
of branded drugs, usually appear immediately, and prices begin to fall. The price of a new
generic drug is typically 25% to 50% lower than that of the branded version. See Standard
& Poor’s, Healthcare: Pharmaceuticals, p. 15.
18Ibid., p. 6.
19Scherer, Industry Structure, Strategy, and Public Policy, p. 342.
20Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America, 2002 Industry Profile, p. 85.
21Ibid., p. 77.
22U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Survey of Current Business,
Sept. 2001, table 17, p. 108.

CRS-6
collected by the U.S. Commerce Department, majority-owned foreign affiliates of
U.S.-based multinational pharmaceutical firms made $1.3 billion in royalty payments
to their U.S. parents in 1994, the most recent year for which data are available.
Federal Income Taxes Paid by the Drug Industry
Between 1990 and 1999
Federal income taxes paid by the drug industry from 1990 to 1999 – the most
recent year for which corporate tax return data are available – are shown in table 1.
The figures on tax liability include any alternative minimum taxes owed by drug
corporations.
Table 1. Federal Income Tax Liability for the Drug Industry,
1990 to 1999
(millions of dollars)
Year
Taxable Income
Federal Income
Tax Credits
Income Tax
Tax Before Credits
Claimed
After Credits
(Except the
(Except the
Foreign Tax
Foreign Tax
Credit)
Credit)
1990
15,934
5,482
1,825
3,657
1991
17,452
6,026
2,070
3,956
1992
19,920
6,920
2,238
4,682
1993
19,997
7,092
2,441
4,651
1994
24,837
8,752
2,479
6,273
1995
23,963
8,502
1,880
6,622
1996
24,810
8,816
1,948
6,868
1997
27,627
9,729
1,983
7,746
1998
29,218
10,240
2,204
8,216
1999
30,912
10,851
1,138
9,713
Source: Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income Division, Corporation Source Book
(Washington: U.S. Govt. Print. Off., 1990 to 1999).
The industry’s taxable income in Table 1 represents a blend of domestic income
earned by U.S.-based corporations and U.S. affiliates of foreign-based firms and
income earned abroad by foreign branches and subsidiaries of U.S.-based
corporations. Such a blend results from the fact that the United States taxes
corporate income on the basis of residence and not source. Consequently,
corporations chartered in the United States owe taxes to the federal government on
their worldwide income, whether it is earned inside or outside the country. U.S.-
based firms also owe foreign income taxes on much of the foreign-source income

CRS-7
they report on their federal corporate income tax returns. To avoid double taxation
of this income, U.S. tax law grants U.S.-based multinational corporations a credit for
foreign income tax payments up to their U.S. tax liability on the income. In addition,
U.S. affiliates of corporations chartered in other countries are required to pay federal
income taxes on income earned in the United States.
It can be inferred from the nearly twofold increase in its tax liability before
credits between 1990 and 1999 that the 1990s was a period of vigorous growth for
the drug industry. It is also evident from the figures in the table that the industry
derives considerable benefit from available tax credits: from 1990 to 1999, its
average tax liability after credits (except the foreign tax credit) was 71% of its
average tax liability before credits.
The main tax credits claimed by the drug industry are shown in Table 2. Four
points regarding their implications for the industry’s federal tax burden are
noteworthy.
Foreign Tax Credit
First, unlike the other tax credits shown in the table, the foreign tax credit
should not be viewed as conferring a tax benefit on pharmaceutical firms. Under
section 901 of the Internal Revenue Code (IRC), a corporation chartered in the
United States and paying income and related taxes to foreign governments may claim
a limited tax credit for those tax payments. This provision is intended to avoid the
double taxation of income earned by foreign branches of U.S.-based corporations or
income earned by foreign subsidiaries of such corporations and repatriated to their
U.S. parents. The credit is limited to the tentative federal income tax owed on
foreign-source income and may not offset any federal tax owed on domestic-source
income. In addition, the U.S. Treasury does not give a refund when foreign income
taxes exceed the tentative federal tax. In this case, the excess results in an excess
foreign tax credit which may be carried back up to two years or carried forward up
to five years, subject to the same limitations.
Orphan Drug Tax Credit
Second, only one of the credits shown in Table 2 is targeted at drugs, the
primary product of the pharmaceutical industry, and that is the orphan drug tax credit.
The other credits are much more likely to be claimed by firms in other industries –
although this is not to suggest that they are claimed with equal frequency by
pharmaceutical firms and most other firms. Under IRC section 45C a firm may claim
a tax credit equal to 50% of the cost of human clinical trials for drugs intended to
treat rare diseases. The credit is commonly referred to as the orphan drug credit.
Such a credit has the potential to sharply reduce the after-tax cost of pharmaceutical
R&D because human clinical trials, which are conducted in three phases, are the most
time-consuming and costly step in the new drug development process.23 A rare
disease or condition is defined as one that is likely to affect fewer than 200,000
individuals residing in the United States, or one that may affect more than 200,000
23Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America, 2002 Industry Profile, pp. 19-22.

CRS-8
such individuals but for which there is little or no realistic hope of recouping R&D
costs from U.S. sales alone. The credit applies to the cost of supplies and the wages
and salaries of researchers used in clinical trials for orphan drugs only. Moreover,
it is a component of the general business credit and thus subject to its limitations.
Table 2. Main Federal Tax Credits Claimed by the Drug Industry
From 1990 to 1999
(millions of dollars, unless otherwise noted)
Year
Foreign Tax
Possessions Tax
General Business Tax
Orphan Drug
Credit
Credit
Credita
Tax Credit
1990
1,205
1,666
142
15
1991
1,367
1,883
150
18
1992
1,613
2,033
180
17
1993
1,886
2,150
208
19
1994
1,960
2,116
271
19
1995
2,633
1,611
214
NAb
1996
2,628
1,651
219
NA
1997
2,204
1,591
329
NA
1998
2,677
1,459
514
NA
1999
2,938
866
222
NA
Source: Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income Division, Corporation Source Book
(Washington, 1990 to 1998), and Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation, Prescription Drug Trends: A
Chartbook Update
(Washington: Nov. 2001).
Notes: a Under IRC section 38, the general business credit is a limited, non-refundable credit against
income tax that is claimed after all other non-refundable credits, except for the credit for the
alternative minimum tax. The general business credit is the sum of the rehabilitation credit, the
energy credit, the reforestation credit, the work opportunity credit, the welfare-to-work credit,
the alcohol fuels credit, the research credit, the low-income housing credit, the enhanced oil
recovery credit, the disabled access credit, the renewable resources electricity production credit,
the empowerment zone employment credit, the Indian employment credit, the employer social
security credit, the orphan drug credit, the new markets credit, small employer pension plan
start-up costs credit, and the employer-provided child care credit. There is a limit on the general
business credit that a corporate taxpayer may claim in a given tax year: it may not exceed its
tax liability less the greater of (a) the tentative alternative minimum tax or (b) 25% of regular
tax liability above $25,000. If the general business credit claimed in the current year exceeds
this limitation, the excess or unused credit may be carried back one year or forward 20 years.
b The orphan drug tax credit was suspended from January 1, 1995 to June 30, 1996. Under the Small
Business Job Protection Act of 1996 (P.L. 104-188), the credit was reinstated from July 1, 1996
to May 31, 1997 and made part of the general business credit. The credit has yet to be reinstated
retroactively for the period from January 1, 1995 to June 30, 1996. As a result, data on the
aggregate amount of the credit claimed since 1995 are not available.

CRS-9
Since the credit was enacted in 1983 as part of a package of measures aimed at
stimulating increased investment in the development of new orphan drugs, over 180
such drugs have gained regulatory approval in the United States. Ironically, some of
them went on to become major sources of revenue for their producers, including
Glaxo Wellcome’s anti-AIDS drug Retrovir AZT, Amgen’s anti-anemia drug
Epogen, and Genentech’s human growth hormone Protropin.24 In 1994, firms
classified in the drug industry accounted for 91% of the total value of claims for the
credit.
Possessions and Puerto Rican Economic Activity Tax Credit
Third, the pharmaceutical industry has been a major beneficiary of what was
known until 1996 as the possessions tax credit available under IRC section 936 and
is now labeled the Puerto Rican Economic Activity Credit (PREAC) available under
IRC section 30A. In 1999, the industry was able to reduce its federal income tax
liability by 8% by claiming the credit, and accounted for 58% of the total value of
claims for it. Corporations chartered in the United States may be able to exempt
from federal income tax as much as 40% of their income from business operations
they own in Puerto Rico, the U.S. Virgin Islands, and other U.S. territorial
possessions. To be eligible for such tax treatment, a firm must derive 80% of its
gross income from business operations in one or more of these possessions and 75%
of its overall gross income from the active conduct of a business.
The PREAC is equal to a firm’s tax liability on possession-source income,
subject to one of two alternative caps enacted in 1993. Under one cap – known as
the “economic-activity limitation”– the credit is restricted to specified portions of
wage and depreciation costs; and under the second cap – known as the “percentage
limitation”– the credit is limited to 40% of the unlimited credit a firm could claim
under rules in effect before 1993. As a result of the Small Business Job Protection
Act of 1996, the credit is scheduled to phase out by 2005 for firms already claiming
it and was repealed immediately for all other firms.25 In addition, the act contained
phase-out rules that differ between firms subject to the percentage limitation and
those subject to the economic-activity limitation. To take advantage of the credit, the
pharmaceutical industry has established a substantial manufacturing base in Puerto
Rico. According to a 1992 report by the General Accounting Office, as of 1990, 26
pharmaceutical firms had manufacturing operations there; they realized an estimated
tax savings of $10.1 billion from these operations; and the operations had the
approval of the FDA to produce 17 of the 21 most commonly prescribed drugs in the
United States.26
24Standard & Poor’s, Healthcare: Pharmaceuticals, p. 19.
25For further details on the design of the credit and congressional proposals to extend it, see
CRS Report RS20695, The Puerto Rican Economic Activity Tax Credit: Current Proposals
and Scheduled Phase Out
, by David L. Brumbaugh.
26U.S. General Accounting Office, Pharmaceutical Industry: Tax Benefits of operating in
Puerto Rico
, GAO report GGD-92-72BR (Washington: May 1992), pp. 4-7.

CRS-10
Research and Experimentation Tax Credit
Finally, while the general business credit is composed of 18 separate and distinct
tax credits, the vast share of the drug industry’s claims for the credit in the 1990s
probably related to a single credit: that for increasing research expenditures under
IRC section 41. From 1991 to 1998, the amount of the research tax credit claimed
by the industry exceeded its general business tax credit in every year except 1995.
And during that period, the cumulative value of claims for the research credit by the
industry exceeded the cumulative value of its claims for the general business credit
by $621 million, suggesting that many drug firms emerged from the 1990s with
excess general business credits. The research tax credit is equal to 20% of a firm’s
qualified spending on research in the United States above a base amount.27 Its rate
structure is incremental rather than flat in order to avoid rewarding firms for
undertaking R&D that they probably would have done in the absence of the credit.
Various rules governing the use of the credit make its marginal effective rate
much lower than its statutory rate for many firms. Firms have the option of claiming
an alternative incremental research credit with a maximum rate considerably below
the statutory rate of the regular credit. Besides the regular and alternative research
credits, firms may claim a basic research tax credit that is equal to 20% of payments
for contract basic research above a base amount. The following expenses are eligible
for the regular and alternative credits: wages and salaries of researchers, supplies and
materials used in qualified research, leased computer time for qualified research, and
either 65% or 75% of payments for contract research.
Although the drug industry benefits from the research tax credit, it does not
appear to be a major beneficiary among R&D-performing industries: in 1997, drug
industry claims for the credit totaled $630 million, or 14% of the total value of claims
for the credit. It also appears doubtful that the credit serves as a major incentive for
major pharmaceutical firms to raise their R&D spending from one year to the next.
In 1999, the total value of drug industry claims for the credit came to $714 million,
or about 4% of domestic R&D spending by PhRMA member companies. CRS
estimated in a recent report that under current law, the major U.S.-based
pharmaceutical company Merck was unable to claim the regular research tax credit
in 1998 despite spending $1.8 billion on R&D.28
27For more details on the design of the credit and initiatives in the 107th Congress to modify
it, see CRS Report RL31181, Research Tax Credit: Policy Issues for the 107th Congress, by
Gary Guenther.
28CRS Report RL30479, The Research and Experimentation Tax Credit: Current Law and
Selected Policy Issues for the 106th Congress
, by Gary Guenther, pp. 33-35.

CRS-11
Federal Tax Burden on the Drug Industry and Major
U.S. Industries from 1994 to 1999
The federal tax code affects an industry’s return on investment through the laws
and regulations defining taxable income, adjustments to taxable income (e.g.,
deductions and exemptions), tax rates, and adjustments to tax liability (e.g., tax
credits and minimum tax payments). These provisions serve the dual purpose of
raising the revenue needed to fund government operations and programs and giving
firms an incentive to engage in certain favored activities. The federal tax credit for
increasing research expenditures exemplifies this second purpose.
Public finance economists define a firm’s tax burden as its share of real pre-tax
economic income paid in taxes. In practice, however, it is difficult to determine a
firm’s economic income from tax return data because of allowable exclusions,
deductions, and deferrals of taxable income. So alternative approaches often must
be taken to measure tax burdens, such as substituting taxable income as determined
by the federal tax code for pre-tax economic income. Such an approach is taken here.
A common measure of an industry’s federal tax burden is its average effective tax
rate, which is the ratio of its federal income taxes paid to its income subject to tax,
expressed as a percentage. As such, the ratio combines most of the provisions in the
federal tax code affecting an industry’s returns on past investments. Some of these
provisions have the effect of imposing tax penalties, while others may confer tax
benefits.
There are some serious shortcomings with using average effective tax rates to
measure an industry’s federal tax burden, shortcomings that limit the rates’
usefulness in evaluating the impact of tax policy on business enterprises. Because
these rates are an average, they obscure differences in the marginal effective tax rates
that apply to the mix of assets held by an industry and to the different firms in that
industry. Furthermore, average effective tax rates do not accurately measure the
federal tax burden for an industry because the rates exclude the influence of
provisions that accelerate the timing of tax deductions or delay the recognition of
income for tax purposes. A better measure is the marginal effective tax rate for an
industry, which captures the net effect of such provisions on the return on new
investment by an industry. Unfortunately, it is impossible to compute such a rate for
most industries because the value of some important tax benefits (e.g., expensing of
R&D costs) cannot be calculated using available corporate financial or tax return
data. Nonetheless, if average effective tax rates are applied consistently across
industries, they can shed some light on how their federal tax burdens differ.
Table 3 shows the average effective federal tax rates for the drug industry and
major U.S. industries from 1994 to 1999. The rates are based on a comparison of the
industries’ federal income tax liability after all credits (except for the foreign tax
credit) with their worldwide taxable income. As such, they indicate neither the
domestic tax burden on domestic income nor the worldwide tax burden on worldwide
income for the industries. Instead, the rates represent something of a hybrid of the
two measures, showing the federal tax burden on domestic income plus foreign
income that has been recognized for federal tax purposes. To the extent that the rates
in the table exclude foreign-source income retained by foreign subsidiaries of U.S.-

CRS-12
based corporations and thus exempt from federal taxation, they understate the federal
tax burden on the industries. As noted earlier, the foreign tax credit is excluded from
the determination of net tax liability because it serves as a mechanism for precluding
the double taxation of foreign-source income. Including it would further understate
the federal tax burden on the industries.
Table 3. Average Effective Tax Rates for the Drug Industry and
Major U.S. Industries from 1994 to 1999 (%)
Industry
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
Average
Average
for
for
1994-
1990-
1999
1999
All Industries
33
33
33
33
33
33
33
33
Agriculture,
28.5
27
28
26
28
28
28
27
Forestry &
Fishing
Mining
36
35
33
34
33
35
34
35
Construction
29
29.5
30
29.5
30
30
30
29
Manufacturing
32
33
33
33
32.5
33
33
32
Drugs
25
28
28
28
28
31
28
26
Transportation
34
33
33
32
32
33
33
33
& Public
Utilities
Wholesale &
33
32
33
33
33
33
33
33
Retail Trade
Finance,
33
34
34
34
34
34
34
33
Insurance &
Real Estate
Services
32
32
32
28
33
33
32
32
Source: Calculated by CRS from figures taken from Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income
Division, Corporation Source Book (Washington: U.S. Govt. Print. Off., 1993 to 1998).
Note: As calculated here, the average effective tax rate for an industry is the ratio of its federal
income tax liability after all credits except the foreign tax credit to its worldwide taxable income,
expressed as a percentage.
With these caveats in mind, one can see from the table that in the second half
of the 1990s, the average effective federal income tax rate for the drug industry was
lower – much lower in some cases – than that of every major industry except
agriculture, forestry & fishing. Further analysis reveals that most of this difference
in federal tax burdens can be ascribed to drug industry claims for the possessions tax
credit. If the credit had been unavailable in 1998 and 1999, the drug industry’s
average effective tax rate would have been almost identical to that of all industries:
33.6% compared to 33.5%.

CRS-13
Enough is known about the structural features of the pharmaceutical industry
and their interaction with the federal tax code to carry this comparative analysis a
step or two further. If marginal effective federal tax rates could be computed for the
industries shown in table 3, it is likely that the drug industry would still have the
lowest rate. The reason lies in certain tax preferences not reflected in the average
effective tax rates that tend to disproportionately benefit pharmaceutical firms. These
preferences encompass deferred income taxes and accelerated tax deductions. Three
tax preferences in particular seem to yield significant tax savings for U.S.-based
pharmaceutical firms and thus deserve further exploration: (1) the deferral of federal
income taxes on net income retained by foreign subsidiaries of U.S.-based
corporations; (2) the expensing (or immediate deduction) of most R&D costs; and
(3) the expensing of promotional costs.
Deferral of Federal Income Taxes on Foreign-Source Income
As was discussed earlier, the federal government taxes corporations based or
chartered in the United States on their worldwide income and grants them tax credits
for foreign income tax payments up to their federal tax liability on foreign-source
income. However, not all foreign-source income is treated equally for tax purposes.
Foreign-source income earned by foreign branches of U.S.-based corporations is
taxed at the applicable federal rates in the year when it is earned, regardless of
whether the income is repatriated. But foreign-source income earned by foreign
subsidiaries of these corporations is taxed only when it is repatriated to parent firms
as dividends, royalty payments, or other income. Any income retained by these
subsidiaries is exempt from federal income taxation.
This exemption constitutes a significant tax benefit because it defers the
payment of federal income taxes. The value of tax deferral to a taxpayer stems from
the timing of tax payments: because a dollar received today is worth more than one
dollar received in the future, the longer a taxpayer can defer a tax payment, the better
off it is.29 The deferral of federal taxes on income retained by foreign subsidiaries
provides an incentive for U.S.-based firms to establish active business operations in
countries with lower corporate income tax rates than the United States.30 There is
some evidence that U.S.-based pharmaceutical firms are major beneficiaries of this
tax treatment. At the end of 2001, five major U.S.-based pharmaceutical firms that
are among the leading sellers of prescription drugs in the United States reported a
total of $36.6 billion in retained earnings held by their foreign subsidiaries for future
investment.31 Considering that each firm is subject to the maximum federal corporate
29To some analysts, the deferral of tax payments is analogous to receiving an interest-free
loan from the federal government. For more details on the benefits of tax deferral, see Emil
M. Sunley, “Deferral of Tax,”in The Encyclopedia of Taxation and Tax Policy, Joseph J.
Cordes, Robert D. Ebel, and Jane G. Gravelle, eds. (Washington: Urban Institute Press,
1999), pp. 70-73.
30U.S. Congress, Senate Committee on the Budget, Tax Expenditures: A Compendium of
Background Material on Individual Provisions
, committee print, 106th Cong., 2d sess.
(Washington: GPO, Dec. 2000), p. 32.
31The five companies are Pfizer, Merck, Bristol-Myers Squibb, Pharmacia, and Wyeth
(continued...)

CRS-14
income tax rate of 35%, these earnings might yield as much as $13 billion in federal
tax revenue before credits (including the foreign tax credit) if they were to be
repatriated immediately. In addition, the controlled foreign subsidiaries of U.S.-
based pharmaceutical firms exhibit a relatively strong propensity to retain earnings.
At the end of 1996, the most recent year for which data are available, drug industry
subsidiaries had retained earnings equal in value to 40.3% of their assets; by contrast,
the ratio for controlled foreign subsidiaries in all industries was 11.4%, and the two
highest industry ratios after drugs were 23.2% for manufacturing and 16.0% for
finance, insurance and real estate.32
Expensing of R&D Spending
Another federal tax provision that appears to confer disproportionate benefits
on pharmaceutical firms is the expensing of qualified research expenditures under
IRC section 174. Under this provision, firms are permitted to deduct a substantial
proportion of their R&D costs in the year in which they are incurred. Such treatment
is a significant tax subsidy for investment in R&D relative to assets whose costs are
recovered more slowly under current depreciation rules.
For most firms, spending on industrial R&D eventually creates intangible assets
such as patents that generate revenues over a number of years, implying that the
economic life of these assets exceeds one year. In principle, under the federal income
tax, a firm’s stock of R&D capital should be depreciated rather than expensed in
determining its taxable income, in an effort to match income with the expenses
incurred in generating it. There are varying estimates of the economic life of this
capital.33 The expensing of R&D costs has the effect of imposing a marginal
effective tax rate of zero on the returns to R&D investment; by contrast, the returns
to investment in plant and equipment are taxed at much higher marginal effective
rates.34 This means that the user cost of capital for R&D investment is lower than for
many alternative investments a firm could make.
To be eligible for expensing, R&D expenditures must be related to a firm’s trade
or business, cannot be considered capital costs, and must relate to “the development
of an experimental or pilot model, a plant process, a product, a formula, an invention,
31(...continued)
(formerly known as American Home Products). The data on retained earnings by foreign
subsidiaries come from the companies’ annual reports to shareholders for 2001.
32The calculations are based on data received via e-mail from John Miller of the Statistics
of Income Division of IRS on May 15, 2002.
33Estimates of the rate of depreciation for R&D capital range from 15% to 30% per year.
See James R. Hines, Jr., “No Place Like Home: Tax Incentives and the Location of R&D
by American Multinationals,” Working Paper 4574 (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research, Dec. 1993), p. 7; and Bronwyn H. Hall and John van Reenen, “How
Effective Are Fiscal Incentives for R&D? A Review of the Evidence,” Working Paper 7098
(Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, April 1999), p. 6.
34Because of the availability of a research tax credit, the marginal effective rate on a portion
of business R&D investment is actually negative.

CRS-15
or similar property and the improvement of an already existing property.” In
practice, only the wages and salaries of research personnel and cost of supplies and
materials used in qualified research and related overhead costs may be expensed. The
cost of structures and equipment used in this research must be recovered over 15
years and three years, respectively, using allowable depreciation methods.
Pharmaceutical firms are likely to benefit more from the tax preference for R&D
expenditures than most other firms because of their relatively strong propensity to
invest in R&D. In 1999, according to estimates by the National Science Foundation,
pharmaceutical firms spent 10.5% of their domestic sales on domestic R&D,
compared to R&D-to-sales ratios of 2.7% for all firms, 3.2% for manufacturing
firms, and 2.2% for non-manufacturing firms.35
Expensing of Advertising Spending
The tax treatment of business advertising is another likely source of comparative
advantage for pharmaceutical firms. Under current law, advertising expenses are
deductible if they are reasonable in amount and related to a firm’s lines of business.
These expenses can be for the purpose of developing goodwill among customers or
soliciting immediate sales. Outlays for advertising, like those for R&D, are
expensed, imposing a marginal effective tax rate of zero on any income generated
through advertising.
Yet there is reason to think that investment in advertising can be equivalent to
purchasing a durable asset that yields a stream of income in some future period. In
certain markets, advertising generates intangible assets such as brand recognition and
consumer loyalty which help boost a firm’s sales to levels they otherwise would be
unlikely to attain. For instance, Ernst R. Berndt and three colleagues found in a 1994
study of the U.S. market for anti-ulcer drugs that the efforts by leading sellers to
market H -antagonists prescription drugs to physicians through detailing and medical
2
journal advertising had “substantial effects” on the growth of domestic demand for
the drugs and the sellers’ market shares from 1977 to 1993.36 In coming to this
conclusion, they divided these marketing efforts into those aimed at expanding
overall demand for H antagonist drugs and those aimed at expanding the market
2
shares of the leading sellers. They then estimated that the cumulative value of the
marketing intended to expand overall demand depreciated at a rate of zero, but that
the cumulative value of the marketing intended to expand market shares depreciated
35National Science Foundation, Division of Science Resources Statistics, Research and
Development in Industry: 1999
, NSF 02-312 (Arlington, VA: March 2002), table A-18. The
NSF definition of R&D covers compensation for researchers and the cost of materials,
supplies, and overhead.
36Ernst R. Berndt, Linda Bui, David Reiley, and Glen Urban, “The Roles of Marketing,
Product Quality and Price Competition in the Growth and Composition of the U.S. Anti-
Ulcer Drug Industry,” Working Paper 4904 (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research, Oct. 1994), pp. 35. Detailing is the widespread industry practice of promoting
drugs directly to physicians by sending marketing representatives to doctor offices and
hospitals.

CRS-16
at an annual rate of close to 40%.37 Other analysts have estimated the depreciation
rate for the intangible assets created by commercial advertising in general to fall in
the range of 20% to 30%.38
To the extent that advertising creates a durable asset, the immediate deduction
permitted by current tax law favors such investments over investments in many other
durable assets. What is uncertain, however, is the actual rate at which advertising
depreciates. There is conflicting evidence about the economic life of advertising, and
the same evidence suggests that the depreciation rate may differ considerably by type
of advertising (e.g., television advertising, magazine advertising, radio advertising).39
Nonetheless, it appears reasonable to view the expensing of advertising outlays as a
tax preference of uncertain magnitude. Pharmaceutical firms are likely to benefit
more from this tax treatment than most other firms because of their relatively strong
propensity to invest in advertising. In 1999, the pharmaceutical industry had a ratio
of deductions for advertising to business receipts of 5.3%, compared to 1.3% for all
industries.40
Conclusions
Tax policy is one of numerous channels through which the federal government
influences the domestic climate for pharmaceutical innovation. The analysis
presented here suggests that its impact is significant. In essence, the federal tax code
affects a pharmaceutical firm’s user cost of capital and supply of internal funds, two
important factors in how much it invests in R&D.
The user cost of capital is the cost a firm incurs as a result of owning a tangible
or intangible asset. As such, it embraces both the opportunity cost of forgoing other
investments and the direct costs of ownership such as depreciation. In general, the
user cost of capital indicates the rate of return an investment project must earn in
order to be profitable. As a firm’s user cost of capital declines, the number of
investment projects it can profitably undertake increases, all other things being equal.
There is evidence to support the view that business investment responds to changes
in the user cost of capital, although the magnitude and variability of the response are
subjects of ongoing debate and research.41 One factor shaping the user cost of capital
is the tax burden on the returns to the investments a firm makes. Generally, the lower
37Ibid., p. 36.
38See Mark Hirschey, “Intangible Capital Aspects of Advertising and R&D Expenditures,”
Journal of Industrial Economics, vol. 30, no. 4, June 1982, pp. 375-389.
39U.S. Congressional Budget Office, Reducing the Deficit: Spending and Revenue Options
(Washington: GPO, 1997), p. 377.
40Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income Division, 1999 Corporation Source Book,
Publication 1053 (Washington).
41Harvey S. Rosen, Public Finance, 6th edition (New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2002), p.
409.

CRS-17
this burden, the lower the cost of capital, all other things being equal.42 A measure
of this burden is the marginal effective tax rate on the income earned by an
investment. This rate, which is calculated by subtracting the expected after-tax rate
of return on a new investment from the expected pre-tax rate of return and dividing
by the pretax rate of return, reflects the statutory corporate income tax rate faced by
a firm and all the tax provisions that reward or penalize the firm for making a
particular investment.
Under current law, the federal tax burden on R&D investment is relatively low.
This is mainly because of two tax subsidies for such investment. One is a tax credit
for increases in research spending above a base amount under IRC section 41, and
the other the option to expense research spending under IRC section 174. In
combination, they reduce the after-tax cost of performing R&D and raise the after-tax
rate of return on R&D investment relative to other investments a firm could make,
such as purchases of plant or equipment. Owing to their heavy investment in R&D
relative to revenue, pharmaceutical firms probably benefit more from these tax
incentives than many other firms – although it is difficult to estimate to what extent.
In addition, the tax code can affect a firm’s cash flow or supply of internal
funds, which in turn affects how much that firm can spend on R&D. Some firms
base their annual investment budgets on the amount of money they expect to have on
hand after paying all expenses in a given year. For them, the cost of internal funds
may be lower than the cost of external funds, such as money raised through
borrowing or issuing new stock. Small start-up firms caught in the throes of a sharp
downturn in economic activity are especially likely to find themselves in this position
because potential investors or lenders may lack critical information needed to
evaluate their prospects for commercial success. A firm’s supply of internal funds
hinges in part on its tax burden as measured by the percentage of taxable income paid
as income tax: the lower the tax burden, the greater its cash flow. Firms that rely
heavily on retained earnings to finance new investment would have an increasing
capacity to invest in R&D as their tax burdens fall, all other things being equal. Of
course, there is no certainty that a reduction in tax burden would lead to an increase
in R&D investment by firms that perform R&D, such as pharmaceutical firms. The
increased cash flow could be used for many other purposes, including paying higher
dividends to shareholders in the case of publicly held companies. Nonetheless, to the
extent that cash flow or retained earnings play a significant role in domestic spending
on pharmaceutical R&D, the tax burden of pharmaceutical firms could affect the
domestic climate for the development of new medicines.43
42For a discussion of the impact of taxes on the user cost of capital, see Jane G. Gravelle,
“Cost of Capital,” in The Encyclopedia of Taxation and Tax Policy, Joseph J. Cordes,
Robert D. Ebel, and Jane G. Gravelle, eds. (Washington: Urban Institute Press, 1999), pp.
68-70.
43How influential cash flow is in patterns of pharmaceutical R&D investment over time is
a matter of continuing research and debate among experts. See F. M. Scherer, “The Link
Between Gross Profitability and Pharmaceutical R&D Spending,” Health Affairs, vol. 20,
no. 5, Sept./Oct. 2001, pp. 216-220; and Frank R. Lichtenberg, “Probing the Link Between
Gross Profitability and R&D Spending,” Health Affairs, vol. 20, no. 5, Sept./Oct. 2001, pp.
(continued...)

CRS-18
Based on the estimate of its average effective tax rate presented here, it appears
that the drug industry had a relatively light federal tax burden in the 1990s. From
1990 to 1999, its ratio of federal income tax liability after all credits (except the
foreign tax credit) to worldwide income was 0.26; by contrast, the ratio for all
industries was 0.33; only two major industries had ratios below 0.30: construction
at 0.29 and agriculture, forestry & fishing at 0.27 (see table 3). The relatively light
tax burden of the drug industry reflected the substantial tax savings pharmaceutical
firms derived from three tax credits that are available to all firms: the possessions
tax credit, the research tax credit, and the orphan drug tax credit – in descending
order of importance. If it were possible to calculate marginal effective tax rates for
a typical firm in the drug industry and in the major industries shown in table 3, the
results might suggest that the gap in tax burden between the pharmaceutical industry
and other industries was even greater. This is because pharmaceutical firms benefit
disproportionately from the expensing of R&D and advertising spending and the
opportunities for tax deferral created by the rules governing federal taxation of the
foreign-source income of U.S. multinational corporations.
In assessing the federal tax burden of the pharmaceutical industry, it should also
be kept in mind that pharmaceutical firms have sought to maximize after-tax profits
by taking advantage of certain provisions in the tax code whose purpose is to
promote specific policy goals of the federal government. Most of these provisions
serve goals unrelated to the encouragement or advancement of pharmaceutical
innovation. The expensing of research and advertising outlays is largely intended to
simplify tax accounting for firms of all sizes; the research tax credit is intended to
stimulate increased domestic R&D; and the possessions tax credit is intended to
promote investment in U.S. territories. Only the orphan drug tax credit arguably is
targeted at pharmaceutical innovation in that it is intended to spur increased domestic
investment in the development of new and more effective medicines to treat rare
diseases.
43(...continued)
221-222.