Order Code RL31363
Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
China’s Banking Reforms: Background and
Issues for Congress
May 22, 2002
name redacted
Specialist in Industry and Trade
name redacted
Research Associate
Foreign Affairs, Defense, and Trade Division
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

China’s Banking Reforms: Background and Issues for
Congress
Summary
The Peoples Republic of China’s entry into the World Trade Organization
(WTO) will require that it open its financial services sector to foreign investment and
international competition. In preparation for a more market-based banking system,
China has announced reforms intended to strengthen its banks and American
investors have been buying portfolios of Chinese non-performing loans. The
international community has a stake in Chinese financial reform primarily for three
reasons. The first is to prevent contagion – to keep a failure of Chinese banks from
touching off global financial turmoil. The second surrounds the likely political
unrest in China that could ensue should the Chinese economy fail, and the third is to
ensure that foreign firms gain access to Chinese financial markets.
This report concludes that despite serious problems in China’s banking system,
the risk seems small that, in the near future, a financial crisis will occur that will pose
severe problems for the international financial system. An internal financial crisis,
however, could occur. Without government support, the economic viability of many
of China’s banks is questionable. The government and central bank authorities
acknowledge the situation and have taken some steps toward reform. The most
serious threat to the banking system lies in the accumulation of non-performing loans
(NPLs) – many of them policy-based loans extended by state-owned banks to
money-losing state-owned companies with little expectation that they would be
completely repaid. Between 28 and 40 percent of all bank loans in China are
estimated to be nonperforming. China has been taking measures to keep the problem
from worsening and has created four asset management companies to dispose of
NPLs that still have value.
Since the Chinese economic reforms began in 1978, Chinese authorities have
made significant progress in modernizing their banking system, although they still
have a long way to go and are faced with competing interests. While attempting to
introduce more market forces and efficiency into their economy, for political and
other reasons, the government continues to subsidize ailing state-owned enterprises.
They would like to clear the banks of excess NPLs, but fear the resultant rise in
unemployment and social distress that might occur.
China escaped the worst effects of the 1997-99 Asian financial crisis because
of factors that still keep its financial and foreign exchange system viable. China’s
continued high rate of growth and high savings rate have funneled deposits into the
banking system, while a $20 to $30 billion annual trade surplus together with an
inflow of foreign direct investment at about $40 billion per year have resulted in an
accumulation of foreign exchange reserves exceeding $200 billion. China does not
carry an unusually heavy debt burden, either domestic or international, although its
short-term borrowing in foreign currencies has been increasing. China, therefore,
does not currently face a serious risk of either a domestic or international liquidity
crisis – unless, of course, a severe and prolonged world recession occurs that
adversely affects Chinese exports as well as the inflow of foreign direct investment.

Contents
The Development of China’s Banks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
People’s Bank of China and Monetary Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
Weaknesses of the Chinese Banking System . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
Insolvency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
Profitability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
Non-Performing Loans . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
Attempts to Resolve the Banking Problems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Non-Performing Loans . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Asset Management Companies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
Consolidation, Mergers and Closures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
Foreign Banks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
Privatization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
How Vulnerable is China to an Asian-Type Financial Crisis? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26
List of Figures
Figure 1. China’s Banking Sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
Figure 2. Total Non-Performing Bank Loans as a Percent of Total Bank
Lending for Selected Asian Economies, 2001 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
List of Tables
Table 1. Asset Distribution in China’s Financial System, 1999 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
Table 2. Rate of Return on Assets of Selected Chinese Banks, 1999 . . . . . . . . . 14
Table 3. China’s Asset Management Companies (AMCs) and Matched
State-Owned Banks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
Table 4. Growth and Current Account Balances, 1996-97,
1999-2001 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
Table 5. Inflow of Foreign Direct Investment into Selected Asian Countries,
1985-2000 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
Table 6. International Banks’ Claims on Selected Asian Countries,
End-September 2001 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

China’s Banking Reforms: Background and
Issues for Congress
The Peoples Republic of China’s entry into the World Trade Organization
(WTO) will require that it open its financial services sector to foreign investment and
international competition. In preparation for a more market-based banking system,
China has announced reforms intended to strengthen its banks. American and
foreign investors have been buying portfolios of Chinese non-performing loans, and
the private investment arm of the World Bank has invested in the Bank of Shanghai.
For the U.S. Congress, China’s banking problems and reforms may be of
concern because: (1) China’s financial sector plays a key role in the development of
the Chinese economy; (2) the opening up of China’s banking sector could be an
indicator of the degree to which Beijing will be able to comply with its commitments
for entering the WTO; (3) China’s banks face a huge accumulation of nonperforming
loans which could threaten their solvency and, in turn, cause financial panic that
could spread to other countries; (4) U.S. banks are seeking access to the Chinese
market, and (5) China’s banking system plays a key role in the conduct of Beijing’s
monetary and fiscal policy.
Most analysts feel that despite serious problems in China’s banking system, the
risk seems small that, in the near future, a financial crisis will occur that will pose
severe problems for the international financial system.1 Recently, in a speech at the
China Economic Forum, People’s Bank of China Governor, Dai Xianglong gave the
assurance that in light of economic fundamentals and development of the financial
sector, financial risks in China are being contained, reduced and can be resolved.2
Nevertheless, China’s financial system has fundamental weaknesses and is in
immediate need of reform. Many state-owned banks are close to being technically
insolvent. In its 2001 consultation with China, the International Monetary Fund
concluded that progress has continued in addressing the problems in China’s
financial sector, but much remains to be done to complete the reform agenda.
Difficult reforms are yet to be accomplished, and China’s entry into the WTO has
increased the urgency of these reforms.3
1 Lau, Lawrence J, “The Macroeconomy and Reform of the Banking Sector in China,” in
Bank of International Settlements , Strengthening the Banking System in China: Issues and
Experience, BIS Policy Paper No.7, October 1999, p. 83. See also Fernald, John G., Babson,
Oliver D., “Why Has China Survived the Asian Crisis So Well? What Risks Remain”
(Unpublished), International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 633, February 1999, Board of
Governors the Federal Reserve System [http://www.bog.frb.fed.us].
2 People’s Daily, September 20, 2001 reported on [http://www.china.org.cn].
3 International Monetary Fund. IMF Concludes 2001 Article IV Consultation with the
(continued...)

CRS-2
Without government support, the economic viability of many of China’s banks
is questionable. The government and central bank authorities acknowledge the
situation and have taken some steps toward reform. They reorganized the People’s
Bank of China, the central bank, and have set in motion a supervisory and regulatory
structure with emphasis on upgrading the skills of those concerned. with
supervision. In 1998, they replenished the capital base of the state-owned banks in
order to help them meet the Basle Accord’s minimum capital adequacy requirements.
The most immediate threat to the banking system lies in the accumulation of
non-performing loans (NPLs) – many of them policy-based loans extended by state-
owned banks to money-losing state-owned enterprises with little expectation that
they would be completely repaid. In order to keep the problem from worsening,
China’s policy-banks have taken over policy-based lending, and even the state-
owned banks have been made responsible for their profits and losses. Ostensibly,
priority is now being given to commercial considerations over political and social
factors, and not all financial institutions in difficulty are being rescued. Some
international trusts, banks, and rural and urban cooperatives have been closed; others
have been consolidated.
Currently, the government guarantees bank deposits, but it is considering a
more conventional system of deposit insurance.4 Foreign banks are increasingly
being licensed to operate there, and under China’s WTO accession agreement they
will be allowed to undertake retail banking and local currency business. Commercial
banks – other than those owned by the state – can be owned by private individuals,
and even the state-owned banks may, in due course, sell shares on stock exchanges.
Many SOEs, which have been the main contributors to the problem of NPLs, are
being privatized, consolidated, or closed down. The pace of reform, however, has
been slow because reforming the SOEs increases unemployment and, consequently,
threatens to create social unrest. China also is strengthening its equity and bond
markets to provide alternative sources of finance for investment.
To reduce the accumulation of NPLs, the government has created four asset
management companies (AMCs) to help dispose of NPLs that are not completely
worthless being held by four state-owned banks. The AMCs have sold some
portfolios of NPLs to foreign investors at steep discounts.
The international community has a stake in Chinese financial reform for three
primary reasons. The first reason is to prevent contagion – to keep the failure of
Chinese banks from touching off global financial turmoil in the same manner that the
failure of several finance companies in Thailand ignited the 1997-99 Asian financial
crisis. The second reason is associated with the political turmoil that could ensue
should the Chinese economy fail. Indonesia and Argentina are two examples of what
can happen to society and political order when a country’s financial system
3 (...continued)
People’s Republic of China. Public Information Notice No. 01/91, August 24, 2001.
4 Wang Ying, ‘Banking on Insurance,’ Beijing China Daily(Business Weekly Supplement)
(Internet version) in English, May 22, 2001. (FBIS transcribed text)

CRS-3
collapses. With a quarter of the world’s population living in China, economic and
political turmoil, such as occurred during the Great Leap Forward or Cultural
Revolution, would have a direct impact upon the rest of the world. The third reason
is to ensure that China opens its financial markets in accord with its WTO
obligations.
Since the initiation of the economic reforms in 1978, China has acted to
implement a number of changes to open the economy and move further away from
central planning, even though many have criticized the pace of change as being too
slow. Considering their starting point, the Chinese authorities have made significant
progress, although they still have a long way to go and are faced with competing
interests. While attempting to introduce more market forces and efficiency into their
economy, they continue to subsidize ailing state-owned enterprises for political and
other reasons. They would like to clear the banks of excess NPLs, but fear the
resultant rise in unemployment and social distress that might occur.
The need for China to change its financial system to make it more market and
profit-based has been made more urgent by China’s entry into the World Trade
Organization in December 2001. Under its accession agreement, China has
committed itself to the following actions related to banks and other financial
institutions:
! for foreign currency business, upon accession, no geographic or
client restrictions;
! for local currency business, upon accession, no geographic
restrictions in Shanghai, Shenzhen, Tianjin, and Dalian; within one
year after accession, no restrictions in Guangzhou, Zhuhai, Qingdao,
Nanjing, and Wuhan; within 2 years after accession, Jinan, Fuzhou,
Chengdu, and Chongqing; within 3 years after accession, Kumming,
Beijing, and Xiamen; within 4 years after accession, Shantou,
Ningbo, Shenyang, and Xi’an; and within 5 years after accession, all
geographic restrictions to be removed;
! for local currency business, within two years after accession, foreign
financial institutions are to be permitted to provide services to
Chinese enterprises; within 5 years after accession, foreign financial
institutions are to be permitted to provide services to all Chinese
clients; those institutions licensed in one region are to be able to
service clients in any other region that has been opened for such
business;
! within 5 years after accession, all existing non-prudential criteria
(economic needs tests, quantitative limits, etc.) for licenses to deal
in China’s financial services sector are to be eliminated;
! upon accession, motor vehicle financing by non-bank financial
institutions is to be unbound (except for some restrictions on the

CRS-4
provision and transfer of financial information, data processing, and
software).5
In essence, within five years, China is to grant foreign banks full market access
to conduct local currency business (including taking deposits), with no geographic
and customer restrictions. Upon accession, non-bank financial companies are to be
able to offer automobile financing.
The Development of China’s Banks
Serious problems remain if the Chinese banking system is to efficiently service
and help allocate scarce financial resources in the rapidly developing and
modernizing economy of China. Yet the country has made considerable progress
over the last quarter of the twentieth century in transforming its banks. Before the
economic reforms initiated in 1978, China had only one bank, the People’s Bank of
China (PBC), which had branches located throughout the country. The PBC
accepted deposits, offered loans, and handled monetary remittances. All public
institutions and state-owned enterprises (SOEs) had to deposit their cash with the
PBC. Cash and bank deposits were the only two financial assets available. In effect,
the PBC combined the functions of a central bank with those of commercial banks.
All lending by the PBC was policy-based – the availability, size, term, and interest
rates on loans were administratively determined.6
As part of the economic reforms, China changed its banking system from one
of strictly centralized control to a diversified and functionally more specialized
system. The first step towards specialization came in 1979 with the establishment
of three state-owned banks, the Agricultural Bank of China (ABC), the Bank of
China (BOC), and the People’s Construction Bank of China (PCBC). The ABC was
given the responsibility of providing banking services to rural areas and townships
and to supervise the activities of the Rural Credit Cooperatives. The ABC gives
priority to the development of rural infrastructure, particularly, key sectors such as
transportation, telecommunications, public utilities and power. The BOC is much
like an urbanized international bank providing a wide range of banking services.
When first formed, it primarily funded imports and exports. The China Construction
Bank (PCBC) gives priority to financing fixed capital investment projects,
construction of infrastructure, and the development of large enterprises.
Subsequently, in 1985, Beijing established the Industrial and Commercial Bank of
China (ICBC) as the fourth state-owned specialized bank to deal with commercial
enterprises and urban credit cooperatives. The ICBC also took over from the central
5 World Trade Organization. Report of the Working Party on the Accession of China, WTO
Document No. WT/MIN(01)/3, November 10, 2001.
6 Nasution, Anwar, Recent Issues in the Management of Macroeconomic Policies:
The People’s Republic of China,” in Asian Development Bank, Rising Challenges
in Asia: A study of Financial Markets
The People’s Republic of China (Manila:
Asian Development Bank, 1999), p. 11.

CRS-5
bank the normal commercial banking functions (such as taking deposits and
commercial lending).7
In 1984, the PRC named the People’s Bank of China as its central bank and, as
is the case with other central banks, gave it the responsibility for formulating and
implementing Chinese monetary policy. In this context, the Bank issues Renminbi,
(RMB, also referred to as yuan) the Chinese currency, and regulates its supply.8 It
also manages the country’s foreign exchange and gold reserves, regulates the
financial market, manages international financial operations, and safeguards the
workings of China’s payment and clearing system.
The PBC’s control over monetary policy, however, remains relatively weak.
In the past, under pressure from various public authorities – including the provincial
governments and SOEs engaged in aggressive development strategies, the PBC
often exceeded its credit targets.9 In order to reduce the undue influence on the bank
by provincial and local politicians, The PBC abolished its 31 provincial branches and
established nine regional branches in central cities (Tianjin, Shanghai, Shenyang,
Nanjing, Jinan, Wuhan, Guangzhou, Chengdu and Xi’an).10 This placed the head of
each regional bank in a position superior to that of the provincial governors.
In a further effort to streamline the Chinese banking system and to release the
four state-owned commercial banks from the responsibility of policy lending, in
1994 China created three ‘policy’ banks. These include the State Development
Bank, the China Export-Import Bank, and the China Agricultural Development
Bank. The State Development Bank provides finance for infrastructure projects,
with priority on transportation, telecommunications, electric power and power grids,
agriculture, forestry and water conservancy, urban development, and environmental
protection.11 The Export-import Bank finances foreign trade transactions, and the
Agricultural Development Bank provides capital or loans for projects related to
agricultural development projects. It also assists in the reform of the grain marketing
system and provides funds for purchasing grain, cotton and oilseeds.12
Under the Commercial Banking Law of 1995, the four specialized state-owned
banks, the Industrial and Commercial Bank of China (ICBC), the Agricultural Bank
of China (ABC), the Bank of China (BOC) and the People’s Construction Bank of
7 For a more information on bank development, see: Lardy, Nicholas R. China’s Unfinished
Economic Revolution (Washington: Brookings Institution Press, 1998), pp. 59-73.
8 The annual average exchange rate in terms of yuan (RMB) per dollar was: 2.5 in 1970, 1.9
in 1975, 1.5 in 1980, 2.9 in 1985, 4.8 in 1990, 8.6 after devaluation in 1994, and has
continued at about 8.3 since 1996. It was 8.2774 yuan per dollar on March 29, 2002.
9 Cho, Yoon Je, ‘The Banking System of the People’s Republic of China, in Asian
Development Bank, Rising Challenges in Asia: A Study of Financial Markets -The People’s
Republic of China (Manila: Asian Development Bank, 1999), p. 62.
10 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 1999, (Beijing: China’s financial Publishing
House, 1999), p. 31. This report states that 32 provincial branches were closed. (p. 57)
11 1999 Banking Almanac, p.73.
12 1999 Banking Almanac, pp. 81-2.

CRS-6
China (PCBC) began to operate as commercial banks responsible for their profits and
losses. Loans were to be made on a commercial, not policy, basis. From 1998, the
ICBC began extending consumer credit for purchases of automobiles and
telecommunications equipment in addition to its role of providing financial support
to enterprises of all sizes and to joint ventures.13
Figure 1. China’s Banking Sector
During the second half of the 1990s, China also saw the emergence of a new
genre of commercial banks with shares owned by public authorities at various levels
of government, including local governments and, in some cases, by private
13 1999 Banking Almanac, pp. 86-7.

CRS-7
individuals. This included the Shenzhen Development Bank, Guangdong
Development Bank, Everbright Bank, and the Fujian Industrial Bank.
In a further move toward greater specialization, the 9th National People’s
Congress in December 1998 adopted a Securities Law which transferred the
responsibility for examining securities houses from the People’s Bank of China to
the newly created China Securities Regulatory Commission.14 Similarly, the
supervision and regulation of the insurance industry was transferred from the PBC
to a newly created China Insurance Regulatory Commission.15
Currently, therefore, the Chinese financial system consists of policy banks,
state-owned commercial banks, several other nationwide and regional commercial
banks, and some foreign banks, nearly 60,000 rural credit cooperatives, and some
15,000 urban credit cooperatives, as well as trust and investment companies and
finance companies. The financial system also includes securities firms, insurance
companies, and leasing firms.16 As Table 1 indicates, somewhat more than three-
quarters of the assets of all the financial institutions are held by the PBC and the
state-owned commercial banks – the later owning slightly more than half the total
assets. Non-banking financial institutions17 in China are still in their infancy. They
own about 6% of the assets. Not counting the assets of the PBC, state-owned
commercial banks represent nearly 69% of the total assets of all China’s financial
institutions. Non-state-owned commercial banks account for only 7% of the total
assets.
People’s Bank of China and Monetary Policy
As China has transformed its economy from one under the direct control and
direction of the central government toward a type of market socialism, it has
introduced methods for conducting monetary policy similar to those in other
industrialized countries. Still, the bulk of China’s available financial resources are
allocated by the government through investment, credit, and the cash plans aimed at
meeting the investment targets and the credit needs of the state-owned enterprises.18
The credit and cash plans determine quantitative limits on lending by commercial
banks, although since 1995, the credit plans have applied only to four state-owned
14 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking 1999, op. cit., p. 194.
15 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking 1999, op. cit., p.157.
16 Cho (1999), op. cit., p. 62. The Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000 mentions
that in 1999, there were 39,516 rural credit cooperatives as independent accounting units,
and 61,885 rural credit cooperative branches and savings offices without accounting
independence.( P.144).
17 These include trust and investment companies, leasing companies, securities companies,
finance and insurance companies. At the end of 1997, China had 16 leasing companies, 13
insurance companies (not including 8 foreign insurance companies), 63 finance companies
(not including 5 foreign finance companies), 93 securities houses, and 244 trust insurance
companies. See Nasution (1999), op. cit., p. 32.
18 Ibid., p. 11,

CRS-8
commercial banks and four nationwide commercial banks.19 This limits the authority
of the People’s Bank of China to conduct its monetary policy independently of
direction by the government.
Table 1. Asset Distribution in China’s Financial System, 1999
Assets
Percent of
Institutions
(billion Renminbi)
Total
Total Assets
16,406.2
100.0
People’s Bank of China
3,534.9
21.5
Deposit Money Banks
11,982.6
73.0
State-owned commercial banks*
8,852.8
54.0
Other commercial banks**
1,123.5
6.8
Rural cooperative banks
1,239.2
7.6
Urban cooperative banks
630.0
3.8
Finance companies
137.0
0.8
Specific Deposit Institutions***
888.7
5.4
Source: Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000 (Beijing: China’s Financial
Publishing House, 2000), Tables 4-11, pp. 212-219.
*Includes the Industrial and Commercial Bank of China, Agricultural Bank of China, Bank
of China, Construction Bank of China, and the Agricultural Development Bank of
China.
**Includes the Bank of communications, the China ITIC Industrial Bank, the China
Everbright Bank, the Hua Xia Bank, the Guangdong Development Bank, the Shenzhen
Development Bank, the Pudong Development Bank, the Shenzhen Merchant Bank, the
Fujian Industrial Bank, the China Investment Bank, the Yentai Housing Savings Bank
, the Bengbu Housing Savings Bank, the Merchant Bank, and the Minsheng Bank.
***Includes financial trusts, investment corporations, and financial leasing companies, the
State Development Bank of China, and the Export-Import Bank.
Yet, within constraints, the PBC has introduced conventional monetary policy
instruments such as control over interest rates and the money supply through bank
reserve requirements and open market operations. The Bank establishes projected
targets for money growth and has been working with commercial banks to improve
the transmission of monetary policy.20
19 Ibid., p. 16.
20 Dai Xianglong, Continuing the Sound Monetary Policy and Consolidating the Rebound
(continued...)

CRS-9
For example, in response to the Asian financial crisis that began in 1997,
Beijing decided to pursue expansionary monetary and fiscal policies in order to
maintain the high growth rate of the economy. With this objective, in 1998, the PBC
reduced its discount rate and the interest rates on deposits and loans of financial
institutions three times (following three previous cuts in 1996-97). According to
Bank of China estimates, the three interest rate cuts in 1998 saved enterprises over
83 billion yuan ($10 billion) in interest charges during the following year.21 In 1999,
countering deflation remained the main focus of Chinese monetary policy, and the
Bank cut interest rates a seventh time in June1999. This reduced the PBC’s interest
rate on loans to financial institutions from the May 1996 level of 10.98% to 3.24%
in June 1999 where it remained through 2001. The lending rate for short- and
medium-term loans by banks consequently fell from 12% in April 1996 to 3.24% in
June 1999.22
Introduced first in 1984, the PBC has vigorously used changes in reserve
requirements of financial institutions as an instrument of monetary policy. In 1989
an additional ‘excess reserve requirement’ made it obligatory for financial
institutions to keep in reserve an amount equivalent to 5 to 7 percent of their
domestic currency deposits. Furthermore, each branch of a financial institution was
required to keep its reserves on deposit in a branch of the PBC at the same
administrative level. In order to meet this requirement, bank branches often resorted
to borrowing on the interbank loan market which was not always readily available
to them. As a result, the bank branches tended to keep high excess reserves.
Monitoring of the reserves under this fragmented system proved to be cumbersome
and somewhat wasteful. Hence, in 1998, the PBC decided to allow banks to meet
the reserve requirement on a consolidated basis.23
In 1998, the PBC reduced the required reserve ratio from 13 to 8 percent and
again to 6% in November 1999. The Bank required that the liquidity created by the
cuts in the reserve ratio in 1998 be used for buying special government bonds. In
1999, however, the Bank allowed the nearly 200 billion yuan ($24 billion) worth of
liquidity created by lowering the reserve ratio to be used at the discretion of the
financial institutions.24
As for open market operations (buying and selling government securities), from
1993, the PBC has used them to regulate the reserve base of the banking system.
20 (...continued)
of the Economy. Speech by the Governor of the People’s Bank of China, January 17, 2001.
21 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 1999, op. cit., p. 18.
22 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000, op. cit., Table 24, p. 239. Before 1998
discount rates were normally 5-10% lower than the rates charged by financial institutions on
loans of the same grade, and the rediscount rate was usually 5-10% lower than the rates on
relending rates of the same grade. In 1998, the rediscount rate was made an independent
basic rate which could, thenceforth, be determined according to the relending rate. The
discount rate was determined by adding points to the relending rate. See: Almanac of China’s
Finance and Banking, 1999, pp. 21-22.
23 Nasution (1999), op. cit., p. 17.
24 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000, op. cit., p. 19.

CRS-10
From 1995, however, it also began to use open market operations for debt
management and for government borrowing.
Initially, open market operations were kept to a relatively small scale. The PBC
bought and sold its own bank bills to reduce surplus liquidity in some areas and to
redistribute the funds to other areas. In 1995, the PBC, in addition to using its own
bills, began to use treasury bills with maturity of less than one year and policy-based
financial bonds as instruments for its open market operations.25 During 1998, the
PBC carried out 36 open market operations by which it injected 70.1 billion yuan
($8.4 billion) of base money into the system.26 In 1999, such operations increased
the monetary base by 192 billion yuan ($23.1 billion) which accounted for 52% of
the annual increase in the monetary base. The buying of foreign exchange by the
Bank added another 101.3 billion yuan ($12.2 billion) to the monetary base, thereby
creating a total of 293.3 billion yuan ($35.3 billion) – an amount equivalent to
nearly 80% of the annual growth of the monetary base.27
In addition to these three main instruments of monetary policy, the PBC uses
other requirements (such as the loan/deposit ratio and limits on legal lending) to
regulate the money supply. It also uses moral suasion (extra-legal pressures) quite
effectively to influence bank behavior because the main financial institutions are
owned by the state.
Weaknesses of the Chinese Banking System
When compared with banks in industrialized countries or to international
standards, Chinese banks have some major weaknesses. Most of the problems have
been caused by years of central planning in which banks were an intermediary
through which the central government carried out its national plans. As the economy
has become more open, market oriented, less dependent on direction from Beijing,
and more reliant on equity markets, China’s banks are being compelled to transform
themselves from conduits for government subsidies into financial institutions subject
to international standards and market pressures. This has exposed several weakness,
including: (1) relatively low capital-asset ratios, (2) declining net-worth28 of state-
owned banks, (3) insufficient provision of set-asides to cover losses on loan
accounts, (4) low (less than 1%) rate of profitability, and (5) a large proportion of
non-performing loans.29
25 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000, op. cit., p. 17.
26 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 1999, op. cit., p. 20.
27 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000, op. cit., p. 19.
28 Net worth = retained profits and other surpluses plus paid-up capital. This approximates
the sum of Tier 1 and Tier 2 capital under the Basle Accord.
29 The Standard & Poor’s Rating group estimated the share of non-performing loans in 1997
to be around 24%, some analysts suggest the ratio as high as 40%. See Cho (1999), op. cit.,
p. 42.

CRS-11
The Governor of the PBC, Dai Xianglong, in an address in 1999, candidly
pointed out that China’s financial industry is not free of problems and risks. He
listed the major problems as the excessively large proportion of savings in the money
supply (RMB 5.4 trillion out of RMB 10.5 trillion), the high leverage ratio of the
state-owned enterprises, the high ratio of non-performing loans of the state
commercial banks, and the insolvency of a handful of small- and medium-sized
financial institutions.30
As judged by Western financial rating institutions, Chinese banks have
problems, although when probable government support is considered, some are
considered to be strong. The Fitch ratings (which take into account probable
government support) for the Bank of China and Industrial Commercial Bank of
China, for example, are BBB+.31 Moody’s Bank Financial Strength ratings (which
assess intrinsic strength without outside support), place the Bank of China as D- and
the Industrial Commercial Bank of China as E+.32 These ratings are low and imply
that the banks are likely to require government assistance at some point.
There are two major approaches to assessing the problems with banks in China.
The first is to evaluate the probability of insolvency and assess the probability and
effectiveness of intervention by Beijing. The second is to evaluate the effects of the
banking problems in view of China’s obligations to the world community and the
operation and growth of the Chinese economy.
Insolvency
Those who frame China’s banking problems in terms of the probability of
bankruptcy of the system or widespread banking panic view the risks as relatively
low because of the Chinese government’s involvement in the economy. In essence,
this argument rests on the fact that a sizable proportion of the non-performing loans
never were intended to be repaid anyway. They were government subsidies funneled
through state-owned banks to state-owned enterprises intended to carry out the goals
of the planned economy or to accomplish other state priorities, such as maintaining
employment. The fact that the loans have become “non-performing” is not
surprising to either the lenders or the borrowers, since most of the lenders did not
expect the loans to be collectible even at the time they were first made. They were
policy loans.33
30 Dai Xianglong, Opening Address, in The Bank of International Settlements, Monetary and
Economics Department, Strengthening the Banking System in China: Issues and Experience,
BIS Policy Paper No.7, October 1999, p. 13.
31 Fitch, Inc. Fitch Ratings. The ratings are A (very strong), B (strong), C (adequate), D (has
weaknesses), and E (very serious problems).
32 Mergent Bond Record. June 2001, pp. 608-10. Banks rated D possess adequate financial
strength but may be limited by factors such as weak financial fundamentals or unstable
operating environment. Banks rated E possess very weak intrinsic financial strength
requiring periodic outside support or suggesting an eventual need for outside assistance.
33 Lau (1999), op. cit., pp. 73-74.

CRS-12
Under this framework, it can be argued that banking concepts developed for
privately held commercial banks should not apply directly to China’s state-owned
banks. Even under the Basle Accord for estimating the capital adequacy for banks,
the degree of risk that can be assigned to loans to domestic public sector entities is
less that half the risk for loans to private sector borrowers.34
In China’s case, its “Big Four” state-owned commercial banks hold some 70%
of the country’s financial assets with their main debtors being large enterprises that
are also state-owned. The risk weights on their loans, therefore, would be expected
to be smaller than 100% – the exact number depending on the government’s
willingness to bail them out or to let them collapse. In cases where Beijing is likely
to rescue an unprofitable SOE, Chinese banks could require less capital to back loans
to that enterprise and still meet the capital-asset ratio stipulated in the Basle
Accord.35 In theory, one could assign a risk probability to each SOE depending on
the importance of the SOE to the government, the nature of the product produced,
and the amount of employment it provides. In the face of rising unemployment and
worker discontent in China, SOE employment has become an important
consideration in determining whether Beijing would allow an enterprise to go under.
For the government, too many unemployed workers could intensify social discontent
and threaten civil order. Civil unrest, in turn, could threaten Beijing’s rule, economic
growth, and undermine economic reform.
The Chinese government already has intervened to replenish the capital base of
the state-owned banks. In 1998, for example, Chinese authorities lowered bank
reserve requirements which freed funds that the banks then used to buy special
government bonds worth RMB 270 billion (U.S.$32.5 billion). With the proceeds
from the sale of the bonds, the government bought subordinated debt of the
commercial banks thereby providing them with more capital and enabling them to
meet the required capital-asset ratios.36 This infusion of capital amounted to some
3.5% of GDP.
The problem of policy loans in China is analogous to problems in other
countries of political interference in the lending process, loans extended on the basis
of relationships and connections (cronyism), and other non-financial determinants
of lending that have channeled scarce financial resources to favored borrowers. In
Japan, the problem with non-performing loans can be traced partly to excessively
close ties among industrial groups, in South Korea to political pressures and
similarly close business ties, and in Indonesia to family connections. Even though
governments may be willing to bail out banks that eventually run into trouble
because of such questionable lending, unless the underlying lending process is
34 Basle Committee on Bank Supervision, International Convergence of Capital
Measurements and Capital Standards, Basle, July 1988, Annex 2, p. 21.
35 Under the Basle criteria, an 8% capital adequacy ratio means that the ratio of capital to
assets must be 0.08 or higher. Loans are counted as assets, so that a loan with a risk weight
of less than 100% (1.0) implies that a bank would need less capital to back that loan.
36 Lau, Lawrence J, “The Macroeconomy and Reform of the Banking Sector in China” in
the Bank of International Settlements (BIS), Monetary and Economics Department,
Strengthening the Banking System in China: Issues and Experience, BIS Policy Paper No.7,
October 1999, p. 73.

CRS-13
rationalized, a higher than expected level of non-performing loans is likely to
emerge.
Profitability
Since asset quality may not reveal the true risks in Chinese banks, their rate of
profitability may be a better indicator. Profit rates at less than 1% are low and seem
to be falling.37 Even these low profitability rates are probably overstated. Under
Chinese accounting practices, even after debt service payments have stopped, banks
are required to record accrued interest as income for two years. When loans are
rolled over, the interest due is capitalized and reported as income. Pre-tax profits
also are inflated by inadequate provision for non-performing loans, lack of payments
for deposit insurance, and the lack of consolidated financial reports that would
include losses by subsidiaries. In addition, certain subsidies provided by the Finance
Ministry are customarily included as profits.38
In terms of profitability, the three policy banks and four state-owned banks
come out the worst. Other commercial banks seem to be doing better. Still, it is
doubtful that profitability should be the main criterion to assess the financial
condition and economic viability in the Chinese situation. The state-owned
enterprise exist to achieve other national objectives – such as sustaining employment.
Regardless of whether Chinese banks have an implicit government guarantee
against insolvency, if they want to compete in the global marketplace and issue their
shares on international equity markets, they eventually will have to clean up their
balance sheets and operate according to international standards and market principles
much like banks in other industrial nations. This will require that Chinese banks take
action to reduce their huge accumulation of nonperforming loans.
Non-Performing Loans
Despite efforts by the Bank for International Settlements and other international
financial organizations, countries do not all adhere to a uniform definition of non-
performing loans (NPLs) or non-performing assets. Different countries have
different ways of classifying NPLs and valuing foreclosed assets.39 China currently
37 For the four state-owned banks, Cho (1999) gives higher figures (Figure 5, p. 42) than
those mentioned in Table 2 in this paper. Both estimates relate to return on assets but Figure
5 does not clearly indicate that the earnings are represented by net profits after tax which is
the basis for the calculations in Table 2 in this report.
38 See: Lardy, Nicholas R., “The Challenge of Bank Restructuring in China’ in the Bank of
International Settlements (BIS), Monetary and Economics Department, Strengthening the
Banking System in China: Issues and Experience, BIS Policy Paper No.7, October 1999, pp.
21-30. Presented at a conference jointly organized by the Bank of International settlements
and the People’s Bank of China held in Beijing on March 1-2, 1999.
39 Cooke, David and Foley, Jason, The Role of the Asset Management Entity: An East Asian
(continued...)

CRS-14
classifies loans as normal, special mention, past due (substandard), doubtful, or bad
(loss). Past due loans are those for which repayment of principal is in arrears;
doubtful are those for which the arrearage has exceeded one year.40 Bad or “loss”
loans are those which are two years or more overdue. This is quite a liberal
definition of non-performing loans, since the United States and most industrialized
countries classify any loan for which interest payment is past due for at least 90 days
as non-performing.41
Table 2. Rate of Return on Assets of Selected Chinese Banks,
1999
Banks
Rate of Return (%)*
Policy Banks
China Development Bank
0.15
Export-Import Bank
0.24
Agricultural Development Bank
0.14
State-owned Commercial Banks
Industrial and Commercial Bank of China
0.11
Agricultural Bank of China
-0.01
Bank of China
0.17
China Construction Bank
0.05
Other Commercial Banks
Bank of Communications
0.50
CITIC Industrial Bank
0.72
China Everbright Bank
0.40
Hua Xia Bank
0.59
Minsheng Banking
0.99
39 (...continued)
Perspective, A Study of Financial Markets, Barent Group (USA), p.63, note 2.
40 Chan, Terry, Bank Industry Risk Analysis: China, Standard & Poor’s Ratings Direct
[http://www.standardpoor.com/Forum/RatingsAnalysis/FinancialInstitutions/Articles/092
000_ChinaBank.html]. The Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 1999 mentions a five-
category system of loan classification but does not describe the classification. (pp. 50-51)
However, Walker mentions the five categories as normal, special mention, substandard,
doubtful and loss. See Walker, John L., “Financial Reform in China’ ChinaOnline,
[http://www.chinaonline.com/commentary_analysis/instreform/cur].
41 Cooke, David and Foley, Jason, op. cit.

CRS-15
* Estimates based on the Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000, Tables 33 to 57,
pp. 252-283. The rate of return is profit before income taxes divided by total assets.
In China, the actual magnitude of the NPL problem is not known, but it is large
and growing. In 2001, the Chinese government and Bank of China reported that the
NPLs held by China’s banks total $218 billion or 27% of total lending. As shown
in Figure 2, this is considerably higher than even the 18.5% in Indonesia or 16.3%
in Japan. A 2001 study by Ernst & Young (an accounting and business services
firm), however, put the total for China’s NPLs at $480 billion or 44% of total bank
lending42 which is lower than the corresponding estimates for Indonesia or Thailand
but more than those for the Philippines, Japan, Malaysia, South Korea, or Taiwan.
Standard & Poor’s estimates that 50% of China’s bank loans are nonperforming.43
The 40 to 50% level puts China’s NPL problem in the same range as other East
Asian nations at the onset of the Asian financial crisis. In 1997, just before the
financial crisis, the share of NPLs to total loans was about 70% for Indonesia, 35%
for Korea, 30% for Malaysia, and 50% for Thailand.44 For China’s non-banking
financial institutions (trusts, investment companies, and rural cooperatives), the NPL
levels appear to be even higher.45
42 Chandler, Clay. Trying to Make Good on Bad-Debt Reform; China Selling Bank Assets
to Solve Problem. Washington Post, January 15, 2002. P. E01.
43 Mukherji, Joydeep. View From the Silk Road: Comparing Reform in China and India.
Standard and Poor’s Ratings Direct, January 24, 2002.
44 Ibid., Table 1, p. 4.
45 Lardy (1999), op. cit., pp. 28-9.

CRS-16
Figure 2. Total Non-Performing Bank Loans as a Percent of Total
Bank Lending for Selected Asian Economies, 2001
Percent
70
60
Reported
60
Estimated
50
45
40
40
32
28
30
27
25
21
18.5
20
20
16.6
16.3
12.5
11.5
9.5
10
6.5
0
sia
ia
n
iland
pan
China
Ja
iwa
alays
Korea
Ta
Indone
Tha
M
Philippines
South
Source: Respective Central Banks for Reported. Estimates by Ernst & Young
As a percent of gross domestic product, China’s level of NPLs is fairly high –
between 28 and 50 percent. China’s total public debt, however, is relatively low at
14.6% of GDP, so adding total NPLs to total public debt gives a total of 64% or less
of GDP, a figure that does not push China’s total debt into atmospheric territory. In
Japan, Indonesia, Canada, and Italy, total public debt exceeds 100% of GDP.46
If the non-performing loans of the state-owned enterprises are considered to be
sovereign debt, therefore, the burden on the Chinese government would be large but
not excessive relative to sovereign debt in other nations. The Chinese government
also seems inclined to support its state-owned banks, should they require outside
help.
The excessive levels of NPLs in China’s banking system also can be viewed as
a manifestation of more fundamental problems dealing with governance in the
Chinese economy. That is, the bad loans have resulted primarily from the structure
of how lending decisions are made and how the Chinese economy operates. Most
of the nonperforming loans were made to uneconomic state-owned enterprises with
46 According to the Bank for International Settlements, public debt as a proportion of GDP
was 53% in India, 107% in Indonesia, 23% in South Korea, 65% in Malaysia, 84% in
Singapore, 30% in Taiwan, 64% in Thailand, 102% in Canada, 58% in France, 60% in
Germany, 110% in Italy, 131% in Japan, 41% in the UK, and 58% in the United States.

CRS-17
considerations of profitability and probability of repayment secondary to policy
considerations or personal/political connections. As long as loans are extended for
non-economic purposes, the proportion of them that eventually become
nonperforming will naturally remain high.
The Chinese government has recognized the problem with so-called policy
lending and has been attempting to rectify it. In 1994, Beijing created three policy
banks, and, from 1995, the four state-owned commercial banks were made
responsible for their profits and losses. Under the 1995 Commercial Banking Law,
the government attempted to separate policy lending from commercial lending. The
government ostensibly is not to intervene in the commercial banking business.
Banks are to make their own lending decisions, although they cooperate with the
state-owned banks in lending to certain priority sectors and enterprises. The question
remains, however, of how much influence the state-owned banks have in the lending
decisions of the other commercial banks.
As Chinese banks have had to cope with problems of NPLs caused partly by
policy lending, they have also been confronted with corruption and purely illegal
activities by banking officers. While these problems can occur in the banks of any
country, the potential for them in Chinese banks appears particularly great because
of the rapid transition to a market economy; relatively new oversight methods,
regulations, and institutions, and a culture of corruption that the Chinese government
is attempting to curb in all parts of the government. For example, in disposing of
nonperforming loans at one bank, Chinese authorities discovered a RMB70 million
($8.4 million) loan used to finance the constructions of a gold and jade replica of the
world’s first seismograph (invented in China around 220 AD). The replica included
50 kilograms of gold, 5,000 precious rubies, sapphires, and pearls, and 8 decorative
toads carved from emeralds inlaid with diamonds.47 Recent audits of Chinese banks
have uncovered so many problems with false reporting of profits and losses, irregular
operations, poor-quality credit assets, and outright fraud that a staff worker of the
National Auditing Office asserted that the office must ignore cases involving less
than 100 million yuan ($12 million) because they already are too busy dealing with
larger cases.48
In a case that involved the United States, in January 2002, Wang Xuebing, the
head of China’s Construction Bank and formerly head of the Bank of China was
arrested after the U.S. Office of the Comptroller of the Currency imposed a $20
million fine, its largest ever, on the Bank of China for irregularities during Wang’s
time in charge of the Bank’s New York office. The incident has reportedly revealed
systemic problems in China’s banking system in which it has no effective policing
mechanism, low pay, a lack of ethics in the business culture, and an abundance of
opportunities for corruption.49
47 McGregor, Richard. Asia-Pacific: Some Priceless Tales of What China’s Banks Lent
Money For. Financial Times, March 22, 2002. (Internet Edition)
48 China – An Audity: What Bank Auditors Face in China. ChinaOnline, February 15, 2002.
(Translated from the Feb. 5, 2002, Jingji Guancha Bao.)
49 Pomfret, John. In China’s Market Transition, Some Pay Price; Prominent Banker’s Fall
(continued...)

CRS-18
A related question centers on the overall efficiency of the Chinese economy.
When banks channel scarce resources into relatively inefficient enterprises or
projects with low or non-existent returns, overall economic efficiency and the ability
of Chinese businesses to compete in international markets are impaired. Currently,
China is able to compete primarily on the basis of its low-cost and plentiful labor.
Other Asian economies, such as South Korea and Thailand, however, have
discovered that low-cost labor does not stay low-cost for long, and uneconomic
investments in office-building construction, real estate ventures, and unprofitable
business ventures can drag down a whole economy. An indicator of this problem is
the fact that domestic credit has been growing faster than gross domestic product.
The domestic credit to GDP ratio rose from .87 in 1995 to 1.17 at the end of 1999.
This means that economic productivity has been lagging behind credit expansion
and opens the possibility that lending growth has been for unproductive or under-
productive purposes.50
China’s banks also must become more internationally competitive. Since the
country now is a member of the World Trade Organization, it has committed itself
to opening its banking market to foreign banks within five years (allowing them to
compete for domestic deposits). By then, if China’s banks still are carrying a large
burden of NPLs, they will have great difficulty competing, not only with foreign
banks, but with new private Chinese banks that are being incorporated.
Attempts to Resolve the Banking Problems
The Chinese government is tackling its banking problems through several
avenues. The first is by addressing the problem of non-performing loans. It also is
pursuing consolidation, mergers, and closures as well as allowing in foreign banks
and some privatization.
Non-Performing Loans
China is attempting to resolve the problem of nonperforming bank loans
through two avenues. The first, as mentioned above, has been to place lending on
a more commercial basis and to channel so-called policy loans through special policy
banks. This is an attempt to reduce the probability that future loans will go sour.
The second approach is to reduce the current accumulation of NPLs being carried by
banks. The target for Chinese banking policy is to bring the level of non-performing
loans in the state commercial banks to the level in developed countries within three
to five years after China’s entry into the World Trade Organization (December
2001).
Countries usually take either or a combination of three approaches to NPLs
depending on how serious the problem is: (1) provide assistance to banks; (2)
49 (...continued)
Illuminates Corrupt System. Washington Post, February 16, 2002. P. A1.
50 Chan Terry and Wayne K. Gee. Bank Industry risk Analysis: China. Standard & Poor’s
Ratings Direct, September 20, 2000.

CRS-19
provide assistance to debtors; or (3) intervene directly and take over and manage the
problem assets (bad loans) of banks.51
In the first approach, the government tries to relax various kinds of restrictions
on the banks with regard to reserve requirements, loan classification, and loan-loss
provisioning. For instance, during 1995 and 1996, the South Korean government
relaxed the provisioning requirements for non-performing assets and for losses on
securities portfolios. In 1998, the Malaysian government lowered reserve
requirements and relaxed restrictions on lending to the property and equity sectors.
In the Philippines, the government lowered the requirements regarding the reserves
against bad loans. Such regulatory forbearance often achieves only marginal results,
and in many cases, the problems worsen.
The policies of regulatory forbearance are often supplemented by financial
assistance, particularly in the form of short-term liquidity assistance through the
central bank, to the troubled banks. Some countries also provide long-term capital
assistance in form of debentures, with options of being converted into equity in the
bank. Sometimes financial assistance is geared to facilitating a merger with a
healthier bank. The provision of financial assistance is often criticized on grounds
of moral hazard, because such a policy ultimately protects bad bank managers
against their own imprudent management. Since the decision to assist a bank in
trouble is, by and large, a political decision, it is possible that the choice of a bank
to be assisted is made on the basis of the political influence of the owners of a bank.
This happened in Indonesia during the Asian financial crisis. Similarly, private
banks in Sweden complained that financial assistance primarily went to a state-
owned bank which used the resources to take market share away from private banks.
As an attempt to reduce the overhang of NPLs, the government may try to
facilitate or mediate debt restructuring negotiations. Some countries establish
corporate debt restructuring agencies in order to encourage voluntary meetings
between creditors and debtors and to obtain independent assessments of the viability
and the worth of the indebted company. Sometimes, debtors are given financial
assistance to meet their increased costs from rising interest rates or losses arising
from a devalued currency. Several East Asian countries, such as Indonesia, South
Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand have used the debt restructuring
agency approach.52
A much more interventionist approach requires the government to take over the
troubled bank and run it until a permanent solution is found. The failing bank may
be kept under conservatorship, with a new management running the operations.
Sometimes, a “bridge bank” is created to takeover the deposits and assets and for
running the operation of the failing bank for a short-period. In some cases the
government decides to intervene informally. In this case, the government does not
take control of the failing bank but only works with the bank management to find a
51 Cooke, David and Jason Foley, The Role of the Asset Management Entity: An East Asian
Perspective, p. 9-10.
52 Ibid., p. 11.

CRS-20
solution to the problems facing the bank. The interventionist approach may
sometimes involve liquidation of an insolvent bank.
Asset Management Companies
The interventionist approach often involves the creation of Asset Management
Companies (AMCs) to acquire, manage, and recover illiquid or non-performing
assets of a financial institution. The AMCs can be either bank-based or government-
based. The latter is used when the problem is serious and the bank management is
not able to run properly a bank-based AMC. In a government-based AMC, the
government takes over the non-performing assets from a bank and replaces them
with government bonds. The non-performing assets belong to the government, but
they are managed by the AMCs. The AMCs strategy is generally linked to bank
restructuring and recapitalization. In Asia, Japan, South Korea, Malaysia, Thailand,
and Indonesia have established AMCs in some form.
China established four asset management companies in 1999, beginning with
China Xinda Assets Management Company on April 20. It was established with
registered capital of RMB 10 billion ($1.2 billion) wholly provided by China’s
Ministry of Finance. Three other AMCs, China Oriental Assets Management
Company, China Greatwall Assets Management Company, and China Huarong
Assets Management Company, also each began with registered capital of RMB 10
billion injected by the Ministry of Finance.53
According to the Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, the main functions
of the AMCs include the following: (1) issuance of bonds, (2) borrowing from
financial institutions and from the People’s Bank of China, (3) purchase and
management of non-performing loans of commercial banks, (4) recovery of overdue
debts and replacement, (5) transfer and sale of assets, (6) restructuring of debts and
reorganization of enterprises, (7) conversion of debt into equity and temporarily
holding of shares, (8) underwriting bonds and shares, (9) direct investment, (10)
securitization of assets, and (11) auditing and liquidation of enterprises.
Table 3. China’s Asset Management Companies (AMCs) and
Matched State-Owned Banks
Asset Management
Registered
State-owned Banks
Companies
Capital
China Great Wall AMC
RMB 10 billion
Agricultural Bank of China
China Huarong AMC
RMB 10 billion
Industrial and Commercial Bank
of China
China Xinda AMC
RMB 10 billion
China Construction Bank and
China Development Bank
China Oriental AMC
RMB 10 billion
Bank of China
Source: Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000.
53 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000, op. cit., pp. 33-36.

CRS-21
The AMCs are to take over the following categories of NPLs from the state-
owned banks: (1) loans made before 1995 and overdue for more than one year by the
end of 1998, (2) bad loans of state-owned banks at the end of September 1999, (3)
loans extended after 1995 which are to be converted into equity, and (4) part of the
NPLs advanced by the China Development Bank.54
The way the AMCs operate is that bank assets (loans) classified as “normal”
and “special mention” are to remain with the bank. The “substandard” (past due) and
“doubtful” loans are to be transferred to the AMC, and the assets classified as “bad”
(loss) are to be written off by the bank. The AMCs issue bonds to their counterpart
state banks in exchange for their NPLs at face value.
As of December 2001, there were approximately $170 billion (face value) in
NPLs between the banks and the AMCs. This amounted to about 15% of GDP. One
of the major ways of disposing off the NPAs has been debt-equity swaps. The
AMCs approach a state-owned enterprise to provide equity to the AMC in exchange
for the debt the state-owned enterprise owed to the state-owned commercial bank.
Once having received the equity, the AMC could retain the equity for a time or sell
it.55 By the end of 1999 the State Economic and Trade Commission (SETC) had
recommended 600 enterprises as potential for the debt-equity swaps, out of which
framework agreements were reached with 73 enterprises for RMB 95.2 billion
yuan.56 For example, by August 2000, China Huarong AMC had acquired NPLs
totaling RMB 407.7 billion related to 72,000 borrowers nationwide in China.
According to the accounting firm, Ernst & Young, the AMCs have gotten off
to a good start in collecting and resolving their NPLs. Early results indicate that
Chinese borrowers prefer to negotiate discounted payoffs in favor of protracted
litigation. The AMCs recovered as much as 50% of outstanding principal during the
first 18 months of operations.57
The AMCs have been seeking foreign investors to purchase portfolios of NPLs.
Xinda AMC has reached agreements with two foreign companies in setting up joint-
ventures for handling NPLs. China Huarong AMC has announced two portfolio sales
of NPLs to foreign investors. In the first, announced on November 29, 2001, China
Huarong Asset Management Corporation agreed to sell a portfolio of NPLs totaling
RMB10.8 billion (about $1.3 billion) to an international consortium led by Morgan
Stanley including Lehman Brothers, Salomon Smith Barney, Zhongjin Fengde, and
KTH Capital Management, Ltd. The portfolio contained loans by 254 borrowers in
18 cities and provinces throughout China.58 In the second, announced on December
54 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000, op. cit., pp. 36.
55 Walker, John L., “Financial Reform in China.” ChinaOnline,
[http://www.chinaonline.com/]
56 Ibid., pp.37-8.
57 Ernst & Young. Non-Performing Loan Report: Asia 2002, Executive Summary.
November 2001. P. 5.
58 Ernst & Young. China Announces Winning Bid for First Ever Nonperforming Loan Sale,
(continued...)

CRS-22
20, 2001, China Huarong AMC stated that it had sold a portfolio of NPLs with a face
value of approximately RMB 2 billion (US$240 million) to a Goldman Sachs
sponsored investment fund. This structured transaction was priced at 10% of the
outstanding principal balance plus a 50% participation to Huarong after the investor
receives a preferred return.59
The sales to foreign investors carry some uncertainties. What will local
authorities do if a foreign investor insists on laying off surplus labor, an act that may
be unacceptable to authorities concerned about rising unemployment and whose
consent is needed in such lay offs. The other uncertainty concerns the
implementation of court verdicts. It is common experience in China that if a foreign
company is involved in a dispute with a local company and the court verdict goes in
favor of the foreign company, the local enforcement officials delay acting on the
judgement. Reportedly, the Great Wall AMC had $3.6 billion indictment-related
assets, a little more than half of which were in doubt as a result of failure to
implement a court verdict.60
While the AMCs appear to be off to a reasonable start, they also appear to be
underfunded – initial capital of only RMB 40 billion ($4.8 billion) for all four AMCs
to handle NPLs totaling as much as $480 billion.
Consolidation, Mergers and Closures
In the aftermath of the 1997-99 Asian financial crisis, Asian governments have
been encouraging bank mergers to strengthen their capital adequacy and financial
viability. In China’s case, it dodged the worst effects the financial crisis, and the
scale of bank failures and consolidations there have remained at a relatively low
level. The People’s Bank of China, however, has consolidated some small- and
medium-sized trusts and investment companies exposed to high risks. It also closed
down 1,600 insolvent urban and rural cooperatives.61 The PBC also encouraged the
state-owned commercial banks to reduce the numbers of their branches, particularly
by merging municipal and provincial branches. The government has also attempted
several times to consolidate International Trust and Investment Companies (ITIC)
that had proliferated in the 1980s to meet the growing demand for foreign funds and
to act as intermediaries between foreign creditors and domestic enterprises in need
of funds. Even though licensed to conduct foreign business, including raising
foreign capital, some of these companies also conducted banking business in
58 (...continued)
Financial Advisor Ernst & Young Sees Transaction Opening Door to Greater Global Investor
Interest in NPLs. News Release. Beijing, China, November 29, 2001.
59 Ernst & Young. As Winter Sets In, NPL Sales Start to Snowball; Huarong Completes
Second Sale of Non-performing Loans to Goldman Sachs Investment Fund. News Release.
Beijing, December 20, 2001.
60 Wang Huidong, ‘Debt-to-Equity Swaps Trade SOEs Out of Plight,’ Beijing China Daily
(Business Week Supplement) (Internet version) in English (FBIS transcribed)
61 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000, op. cit., p. 32.

CRS-23
disguise.62 Their numbers were brought down from 620 in 1982 to only 239 by the
end of 1998. From 1993 the ITICs were asked to sever their connections with the
banks.63

Since 1997 four medium-sized financial institutions, Hunan Development Bank,
China Agribusiness International Trust and Investment Company (AITIC), China
Venture Technology Investment and Trust Company (VITIC) and Guangdong
International Trust and Investment Company (GITIC), have been closed.64 The
GITIC was a high profile operation with over 200 subsidiaries. It was China’s best
known raiser of funds on foreign markets. However, as a result of imprudent
investment policies, inadequate supervision, and various alleged illegalities, it had
amassed a liability of RMB 36.2 billion, while its assets did not total more than RMB
21.5 billion.
When GITIC went insolvent, almost half the claims were by foreign creditors.
Since the foreign debts were not approved by the State Administration of Foreign
exchange, they were technically illegal, and the central government refused to accept
any liability. Even in the case of registered debts which were legal, the state decided
to treat them like domestic debts to be paid back out of realized resources after
liquidation. In the absence of the government decision to honor the registered
foreign debts in their entirety, foreign creditors had to bear considerable losses.65
The Chinese government’s refusal to bail out GITIC and to fully reimburse foreign
creditors had mixed consequences; in the short-run, it generated a lack of confidence
among foreign creditors. However, it also confirmed the government’s
determination to reform the Chinese financial system, thus having a positive long-
term consequence.
The only major acquisition and merger of a banking institution was that of
China Investment Bank with the Everbright Bank of China.66
Foreign Banks
Gradually, China is allowing foreign banks to operate domestically in order to
increase competition in the financial sector and to improve efficiency by introducing
modern banking practices. It is also hoped that they might (by providing financial
services to foreign businesses) serve as an additional inducement for foreign
investment.67 In Beijing, however, there has been a lurking fear that nascent
62 Jun, Zhu, ‘Closure of Financial Institution in China,’ the Bank of International
Settlements (BIS), Monetary and Economics Department, Strengthening the Banking System
in China
: Issues and Experience, BIS Policy Paper No.7, October 1999, p. 309.
63 Ibid., pp.311-2.
64 Ibid., pp. 311-2.
65 Ibid., pp. 313-4.
66 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000, op. cit., pp. 31-32., 114.
67 Chen, Ji and Thomas, Stephen C., “Banking on China,” The China Business Review, U.S.-
China Business Council, November 3, 1999.
(continued...)

CRS-24
domestic banks would not be able to compete with well-capitalized foreign banks
with their access to world-wide financial markets and that foreign banks might take
disproportionate control over the domestic economy. Such fears have not been
uncommon in other countries – many of whom impose restrictions on foreign
ownership of banks.68
In 1979, after much internal debate, foreign banks were allowed to begin to
operate again in China. The first was the Export-Import Bank of Japan which was
allowed to open a representative office. In 1982, Hong Kong’s Nanyang
Commercial Bank also opened a branch. From 1994 foreign banks were allowed to
conduct foreign currency business for foreign and overseas Chinese enterprises,
individuals, and for Chinese SOEs needing foreign currency. Foreign banks were
not allowed to deal in renminbi except on an experimental basis in the Pudong
district of Shanghai and in Shenzhen (the city adjoining Hong Kong).
By the end of 1999, the number of financial institutions established in China by
foreign-funded banks and enterprise groups totaled 176, including 20 locally
registered entities (7 joint-venture banks, 6 wholly foreign funded banks and 7
foreign finance corporations) and 156 branches of foreign-funded banks. By the end
of 1999, 25 foreign-funded banks were allowed to conduct renminbi business, 19 in
Shanghai and 6 in Shenzhen.69 From 1999, foreign banks are permitted to operate
in any Chinese city, and geographic restrictions on doing RMB business were
relaxed. The six foreign banks authorized to conduct local-currency business in
Shenzhen can now have clients from Guangdong and Hunan provinces and the
Guangxi Zhuang Autonomous Region. The nineteen foreign banks in Shanghai can,
within certain limitations, undertake local-currency business with clients in Jiangsu
and Zhejiang provinces.70
Some Chinese banks also are allowing foreign investors to secure a stake in
their operations by acquiring their shares. London’s HSBC Holdings became the
first commercial bank to secure a stake in a mainland Chinese bank when it acquired
an 8% share of the Bank of Shanghai in December 2001. The investment arm of the
World Bank, the International Finance Corporation, also raised its stake in the Bank
from 5 to 7%. Previously, the governor of the PBC stated that foreign investment in
the country’s shareholding banks would be welcomed up to a 25% level. Other
Chinese banks are preparing to list their shares on stock exchanges with the
expectation that foreigners will invest in their operations.71
67 (...continued)
[http://www.chinabusinessreview.com/9911/chen.html]
68 For instance, no one foreign bank can have more than 10% of ownership in a Canadian or
Australian bank. Denmark limits the ownership at 30 % and south Africa at 50%.
69 Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, 2000, op. cit., pp. 134-5.
70 Chen and Thomas (1999), op. cit.
71 China: Banks Open Up to Foreign Investment. Janet Matthews Information Services.
Quest Economics Database. February 15, 2002. P. 12.

CRS-25
As part of its accession agreement to the World Trade Organization, China
agreed to open the local currency business to foreign banks within five years of
accession (by December 2006) and to allow foreign banks to conduct consumer
banking business. These actions certainly will intensify competition with domestic
banks. Chinese authorities are proceeding with financial reforms partly to meet this
challenge.
What seems apparent is that Chinese banks are ill prepared to compete with
foreign financial institutions in head-to-head competition without government help
and some protection. Still, even though some analysts argue that opening the
banking sector will cause many of them to fail, Nicolas Lardy, a leading expert on
the Chinese economy, thinks that by 2007, the market share of foreign banks is
unlikely to rise above 2 or 3 percent.72 Standard & Poor’s, a financial rating agency,
also has stated that the heightened competitive pressures on Chinese banks after
WTO accession may be mitigated by their established corporate and government ties,
the underdeveloped domestic market, and other structural barriers.73 Existing
Chinese banks already have an extensive network of branches, and Beijing seems to
be able to find ways to protect its favored industries.
Privatization
The role of the state-owned commercial banks (SOCBs) has been on the decline
in most emerging economies. During the 1990s, the share of the SOCBs in total
bank assets in Central Europe declined from nearly half to about 20% and in Latin
America to only 15%. In Indonesia, South Korea and Thailand, their share has
increased because of temporary nationalizations resulting from the Asian financial
crisis.74
In China, the share of SOCBs, so far, remains undiminished. Beijing apparently
has no immediate plans for privatization of the state-owned banks. However, the
governor of the People’s Bank of China indicated that the reform of these banks will
proceed in three stages: first, operation and management systems are to be ungraded;
second, ownership of the banks is to be opened to domestic enterprises and
individuals as well as foreigners, but the state will keep a controlling share, and third,
the banks are to be listed on the stock exchange. According to the Governor the
whole process may take five or more years.75
72 Lardy, Nicolas R. Integrating China into the Global Economy (Washington, Brookings
Institution, 2002).
73 Impact of WTO Pact on Chinese Banks May be Muted. Standard & Poor’s CreditWire,
March 16, 2000.
74 Hawkins and Mihaljek (2001), op. cit, pp. 7-16.
75 Xu, Han, ‘The PBOC Governor Dai Xianglong Says State Commercial Banks Will be
reformed in Three Phases; Foreign Investors Encouraged to Buy shares of Commercial
Banks,’ in Beijing Jingji Ribao October 2, 2001. (Internet Version) Translated by FBIS CPP
2001/1003000042.1

CRS-26
China, however, already has many private lending institutions. These, along
with foreign financial institutions, are likely to continue to increase their presence
in the Chinese economy.
How Vulnerable is China to an Asian-Type Financial
Crisis?
If China’s banking problems could all be contained within the country, they
would not be a major concern to the Western world. Financial turmoil in China,
however, could spill over into the world financial system through two major
channels. The first is through contagion in the same manner that the failure of
several finance companies in Thailand ignited the 1997-99 Asian financial crisis.
The second is through the political turmoil that could ensue should the Chinese
economy fail. Indonesia and Argentina are two obvious examples of what can
happen to society and political order when a country’s financial system collapses.
With a quarter of the world’s population living in China, economic and political
turmoil, such as occurred during China’s Great Leap Forward or Cultural Revolution,
has a direct impact on the rest of the world. In this section, we attempt to evaluate
how vulnerable China is to an Asian-type financial crisis.
Broadly, two sets of explanations are put forward for the Asian financial crisis.76
The first emphasizes weaknesses in the financial systems based on imprudent short-
term international borrowing to fund long-term lending to fund investments of
questionable value. The second attributes the crisis to the “contagion effect and
financial panic” that was exacerbated by the herding behavior of market participants.
Creditors and investors with short-term claims withdrew suddenly from markets or
refused to roll over outstanding payment obligations in several countries
simultaneously. Massive capital outflows undermined the Asian currencies which
had been on fixed pegs causing drastic currency depreciation, soaring interest rates,
and shortages of foreign exchange.
The Chinese financial system has some of the same systemic weaknesses of its
Asian counterparts. Bank supervision, though gradually being tightened by the
People’s Bank of China, is lax by modern banking standards. Particularly, in the
case of the state-owned commercial banks, political rather than economic and
commercial considerations play an important role in decision making with regard to
loans. Risk analysis is in its infancy, and bank supervisors rarely possess adequate
training for the duties they are required to perform. The banks have a high
proportion of non-performing loans, and for state-owned banks, a low rate of return
on assets and net worth that is virtually negative.
On the other hand, China has some distinct advantages over its neighbors. Even
during the Asian financial crisis, China achieved relatively high rates of growth
which have continued into 2002. As indicated in Table 4, however, other Asian
76 Asian Development Bank, “The Asian Crisis and Lessons for Macroeconomic and
Financial Management” (Manila: Asian Development Bank, 2001).
[http://www.adb.org/Documents/Speeches/1999/ms1999033.asp]

CRS-27
nations also had high growth rates in 1996-97 leading into the financial crisis. High
growth, in itself, is not a sufficient condition to keep a nation from facing financial
crisis. In 2001, moreover, many of the Asian nations registered recessionary growth
rates and recovery from the global economic slowdown is occurring only haltingly.
While China’s continued economic growth bodes well for its ability to avoid an
immediate financial crisis, the experience with other Asian nations shows that high
growth rates can drop precipitously, particularly if they are based on uneconomic
investments and government deficit spending.
The macroeconomic weakness that precipitated the Asian financial crisis was
the rising current account deficit in the troubled economies of Thailand, South
Korea, and Indonesia. If a nation’s deficit on current account reaches 4% of GDP,
that is a warning signal that financial danger lies ahead. As shown in Table 4, in
China’s case, its current account balance at $20 to $30 billion remains positive at 2
to 3 percent of GDP. As long as this account remains in surplus, it is unlikely that
China will experience a foreign exchange shortage such as occurred in Thailand,
Indonesia, and South Korea. China’s current account surplus, however, is shrinking,
and may turn into a small deficit by 2004. This deficit may continue through the
decade.77
Even if a nation runs a current account deficit, it can finance it through foreign
capital flows into the country. This foreign investment can take the form of foreign
direct investment which goes into purchasing controlling shares of companies or
establishing subsidiaries or joint ventures. It also can take the form of portfolio
investment which goes primarily into non-controlling equity shares or securities. In
the case of China, foreign direct investment (FDI) has remained high at about $40
billion per year – even during the Asian financial crisis. Since this source of foreign
exchange is for direct investments – much of it going for actual plant and equipment,
it is much less volatile than portfolio investment which can flee a country as quickly
as it entered.
Table 4. Growth and Current Account Balances, 1996-97,
1999-2001
Real GDP
Current Account Balance
1996-
1996-
1999
2000
2001
1999
2000
2001
Country or
97
97
region
Annual Percentage Change
As a Percentage of GDP
China
9.2
7.1
8.1
7.3
2.2
1.7
3.1
2.7
Hong Kong
4.8
3.0
10.5
-0.3
-2.1
5.6
5.0
3.0
S. Korea
5.8
10.9
8.6
2.5
-3.1
6.0
2.5
2.1
Taiwan
6.4
5.4
5.9
-2.0
3.2
2.9
2.9
5.6
77 DRI-WEFA forecast.

CRS-28
Real GDP
Current Account Balance
1996-
1996-
1999
2000
2001
1999
2000
2001
Country or
97
97
region
Indonesia
6.3
0.8
4.8
3.3
-2.9
4.1
5.2
3.0
Malaysia
8.7
6.1
8.3
-0.4
-5.0
16.8
13.3
6.1
Philippines
5.5
3.4
4.0
2.3
-5.1
9.5
12.1
5.1
Thailand
5.1
4.2
4.4
1.0
-5.1
10.2
7.5
4.2
Source: DRI-WEFA, Inc.
This high level of FDI into China has been a clear endorsement of foreign
investors regarding the health of the Chinese economy. China has been the largest
recipient of FDI in East Asia – 50% more than the FDI received by all the East Asian
countries included in Table 5 (except for Hong Kong which is now part of China).
The primary method by which a country defends against a run on its currency
is by selling foreign exchange from its reserves and buying the domestic currency
that is being dumped on international markets. For China, its foreign exchange
reserves (minus gold) have risen from $75 billion in 1995, to $158 billion in 1999,
and further to $212 billion in 2001. This is a huge war chest that can be used to
counter sudden downward pressures on the renminbi exchange rate. In the Asian
financial crisis, countries with large foreign exchange reserves, as was the case with
China and Hong Kong, were able to keep their exchange rates stable, or in
Singapore’s case, suffered only modest depreciation. Countries with insufficient
reserves experienced severe depreciation of their currencies because they did not
have the financial resources to defend them.78 For China, the current $200 billion
plus in foreign exchange reserves is large compared with the reserves of other
countries. In 2001, Indonesia had reserves of $25 billion, Malaysia $33 billion, the
Philippines $13 billion, Singapore $74 billion, and South Korea $97 billion.
Table 5. Inflow of Foreign Direct Investment into Selected Asian
Countries, 1985-2000
($billion)
Country
1985-95*
1997
1998
1999
2000
China
11.7
44.2
43.8
40.3
40.8
Hong Kong
4.0
11.4
14.8
24.6
64.4
Indonesia
1.4
4.7
-0.4
-2.7
-4.6
78 Hawkins, John and Turner, Phillip, Managing Foreign debt and Liquidity risks In
Emerging Economies: An Overview (Basle: BIS, 1999), p. 29.

CRS-29
Country
1985-95*
1997
1998
1999
2000
Korea
0.8
2.8
5.4
10.6
10.2
Malaysia
2.9
6.5
2.7
3.5
5.5
Philippines
0.7
1.2
1.8
0.7
1.5
Singapore
4.3
13.0
6.3
7.2
6.4
Taiwan
1.0
2.2
0.2
2.9
4.9
Thailand
1.4
3.6
5.1
3.6
2.4
* Average annual inflow.
Source: UNCTAD, World Investment Report, 2001: Promoting Linkages. (Geneva: UNCTAD,
2001.) Relevant country fact sheets.
In addition to the use of foreign exchange reserves to counter speculators and
investors who are fleeing a currency in trouble, exchange reserves also may become
necessary to repay loans denominated in dollars or other international currency. In
the years leading up to the Asian financial crisis, borrowers were obtaining short-
term international loans to fund long-term domestic lending. As long as international
banks were willing to roll over the loans as they came due, the borrowers had no
problem managing them. Many of the borrowers were quasi-national banks whose
debt was considered semi-sovereign and, hence, low risk. As financial institutions
in the borrowing nations began to face insolvency and their short-term debts fell due,
however, skittish lenders refused to roll over their loans. This precipitated a crisis
as investors and lenders stampeded out of Thailand, Malaysia, Indonesia, the
Philippines, and South Korea. One indicator of risk for a nation, therefore, is the
extent of its borrowing in foreign currencies that is short-term (less than one year).
In this respect, the Chinese situation has been significantly different from its
neighbors. As indicated in Table 6, at the end of September 2001, $21.8 billion out
of total foreign currency debt to international banks of $54.4 billion (40.1%) was
short-term. This amounts to about 10% of China’s foreign exchange reserves and
about the level of annual current account surplus – which is declining. In South
Korea’s case, in 1997, at the onset of the Asian financial crisis, as much as 60% of
its borrowing was short-term. For China, moreover, reliance on short-term debt has
been rising.

CRS-30
Table 6. International Banks’ Claims on Selected Asian
Countries, End-September 2001
(Billion U.S. Dollars)
Distribution by Maturity
Total Foreign
Claims in Non-
Up to and
Over One
Local Currencies
Including
Year
Unallocated
One Year
China
54.4
21.8
19.1
13.5
Indonesia
36.5
18.2
16.7
1.6
Malaysia
20.3
6.9
11.9
2.4
Philippines
15.7
5.8
8.7
1.2
Korea, Republic
54.1
32.0
13.4
8.6
Taiwan
15.4
10.4
3.2
1.8
Thailand
23.9
9.5
9.9
4.5
Source: BIS, BIS International Consolidated Banking Statistics for the Second Quarter of 2001, Press
Release, 29 October, 2001, Table 4, p. 7.
A factor in lessening the likelihood that China will suffer from an international
liquidity crisis is that its RMB is non-convertible on capital account. That implies
that RMB cannot be converted into foreign exchange for capital account transactions.
In other words, RMB cannot be converted into foreign exchange without government
permission for use in international transactions related to foreign direct and portfolio
investments, bank loans, and deposits. (The RMB is convertible for current account
or trade transactions.)79
Another factor for stability in the Chinese banking system is that it allows
citizens to hold foreign currency accounts. The banking system, therefore, is able
to keep foreign exchange within the system and thereby, “domesticate” capital
flight.80 Citizens with dollars, for example, can simply deposit them in their Chinese
banking accounts rather than use a Swiss or other international account. According
to the People’s Bank of China, the foreign exchange deposits in the Chinese banking
system amounted to $113.7 billion at the end of June 2000.81 This sum alone was
almost twice as much as the claims of international banks on China.
79 Of course, investors or businesses in need of foreign exchange for capital account
transactions can circumvent restrictions by disguising foreign exchange for capital account
transactions as a current account transaction.
80 McCauley, Robert N., and Y.K. Mo. “Foreign Currency Deposits of Firms and Individuals
with Banks in China,” International Banking and Financial Market Developments, BIS
Quarterly Review, August 2000, 35.
81 Ibid., p. 37.

CRS-31
The risk of an external liquidity crisis for China, therefore, currently seems low
but might arise if the world-wide recession and import liberalization required by
entry into the World Trade Organization pushes the country’s current account
substantially into deficit. A prolonged recession also could reduce the inflow of
foreign capital. China, therefore, would have to depend on its foreign exchange
reserves which now are ample but cannot last forever.
For China, a domestic liquidity crisis or credit crunch is less likely because the
government is continuing to guarantee the bank deposits, particularly, in the state-
owned banks. As long as the economy is growing at a reasonable rate, Chinese
depositors have no reason to loose confidence in the banking system. Equity and
bond markets are still relatively underdeveloped and not providing alternatives to
bank deposits for the bulk of the population. China, moreover, has a high rate of
savings – roughly 35% of GDP. The prospect that households will be required to
pay for education and health further increase the incentive for households to save
more. The prospect of buying one’s own house – which the government is
promoting – may provide further incentives to save more. In fact, the regular flow
of deposits into China’s financial institutions is rising at rates higher than the rate of
growth of GDP. Despite the various problems of Chinese banks, their deposits
continue to grow. The Chinese banking system is, by no means, illiquid.

EveryCRSReport.com
The Congressional Research Service (CRS) is a federal legislative branch agency, housed inside the
Library of Congress, charged with providing the United States Congress non-partisan advice on
issues that may come before Congress.
EveryCRSReport.com republishes CRS reports that are available to al Congressional staff. The
reports are not classified, and Members of Congress routinely make individual reports available to
the public.
Prior to our republication, we redacted names, phone numbers and email addresses of analysts
who produced the reports. We also added this page to the report. We have not intentional y made
any other changes to any report published on EveryCRSReport.com.
CRS reports, as a work of the United States government, are not subject to copyright protection in
the United States. Any CRS report may be reproduced and distributed in its entirety without
permission from CRS. However, as a CRS report may include copyrighted images or material from a
third party, you may need to obtain permission of the copyright holder if you wish to copy or
otherwise use copyrighted material.
Information in a CRS report should not be relied upon for purposes other than public
understanding of information that has been provided by CRS to members of Congress in
connection with CRS' institutional role.
EveryCRSReport.com is not a government website and is not affiliated with CRS. We do not claim
copyright on any CRS report we have republished.