Order Code RS20981
July 30, 2001
CRS Report for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
Energy Efficiency and the Rebound Effect:
Does Increasing Efficiency Decrease
Demand?
nae redacted
Science and Technology Analyst
Resources, Science, and Industry Division
Summary
Intuitively it seems obvious to most observers that increasing energy efficiency will
ultimately reduce demand for an energy resource such as electricity. Paradoxically,
economic theory suggests that this decrease in demand and subsequent decrease in cost
of using the resource could cause a rebound in demand. A commonly cited example is
an increase in the efficiency of home air conditioning which may reduce the resident’s
monetary incentive to conserve. The resident may opt to change the thermostat setting
to keep the amount he pays constant, but living at a more comfortable temperature.
When actually measured this “Rebound Effect” is generally acknowledged to lower
predicted reductions in electricity demand by 10%-40% depending on the device that is
made more efficient. This report will be updated as events warrant.
Introduction
Several bills introduced in the 107th Congress focus on increasing energy efficiency.
Three bills in particular have been reported in the House that aim to promote energy
efficiency through tax credits, grants, efficiency standard mandates or increased money for
energy efficiency research (H.R. 2587, H.R. 2511, and H.R. 2460, all of which have been
incorporated into H.R. 4). However some have suggested that government-supported
efforts to conserve energy by increasing efficiency will not produce the expected results
because of the “Rebound Effect”1. This brief paper describes the rebound effect and
outlines the current thinking of those studying this effect.
The rebound effect (also referred to as the “take-back” or “snap-back”) was first
described in 1865 when Stanley Jevons observed that the introduction of the new efficient
1 see K. Strassel, Conservation wastes money, Wall Street Journal, May 17, 2001, Eastern Edition,
p. A26; F. Pearce, Consuming myths, New Scientist, September 5, 1998, p. 18-19; and J.
Glassman, The conservation myth as the latest (sub)urban legend,
[http://www.TechCentralStation.com/NewsDesk.asp?FormMode=MainTerminalArticles&ID=68]
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

CRS-2
steam engine initially decreased coal consumption which led to a drop in the price of coal.
This meant not only that more people could afford coal, but also that coal was now
economically viable for new uses, which ultimately greatly increased coal consumption2.
More recently, analysts have focused on the rebound effect in the electricity and gasoline
markets. If a large rebound effect exists in these markets, it could weaken arguments for
increased efficiency requirements and strengthen arguments to scale back such efforts.
Definition of the Rebound Effect
The rebound effect is most simply measured by the difference between the projected
and actual savings due to increased efficiency. The rebound effect consists of direct,
indirect and macroeconomic effects that can happen following the installation of more
efficient equipment.
Direct Effects - The consumer chooses to use more of the resource instead of
realizing the energy cost savings. For example, a person with a more efficient home heater
may chose to raise the setting on the thermostat or a person driving a more efficient car
may drive more. This effect is limited since a person will only set the thermostat so high
or have so many hours to spend driving.
Indirect Effects - The consumer chooses to spend the money saved by buying other
goods which use the same resource. For example, a person whose electric bill decreases
due to a more efficient air conditioner may use the savings to buy more electronic goods.
Market or Dynamic Effects - Decreased demand for a resource leads to a lower
resource price, making new uses economically viable. For example, residential electricity
was initially used mainly for lighting, but as the price dropped many new electric devices
became common. This is the most difficult aspect of the rebound effect to predict and to
measure.
Theory Versus Practice
Under certain circumstances, the rebound effect could actually turn an increase in
efficiency into an increase in demand. However this has only happened in very special
cases such as in some developing countries or in new markets such as the coal market in
the mid 1800s or the electricity market in the early 1900s. For mature markets, it is
generally accepted that although real the rebound effect is limited3. The actual rebound
depends on many variables, including specific resource, the specific device and how
developed the resource market and overall economy are.
Actual measures of the rebound effect for electric end-use equipment have been
found to be between 0% and 40%4. That is, the actual decrease in demand realized can
range from 100% to about 60% of the projected amount. The result is very dependent on
2 W.S. Jevons The coal question: can Britain survive? First published 1865, Republished
Macmillan, London 1906.
3 Lee Schipper, On the rebound: the interaction of energy efficiency, energy use and economic
activity. An introduction.
Energy Policy 28 (2000): 351-353.
4 L. Schipper, p. 353

CRS-3
the type of device. For example, increasing the efficiency of home appliances (so called
“white goods”) showed no measurable rebound effect, while the rebound for space heating
or cooling units ranged from 0% to 50% (see Table 1). The rebound effect for increasing
automobile fuel economy has also been much studied. This rebound is generally reported
to range between 10% and 30%5.
Table 1. Measured Rebound Effects on Various Devices.
DEVICE
SIZE OF REBOUND
NUMBER OF STUDIES
Space Heating
10-30%
26
Space Cooling
0-50%
9
Water Heating
10-40%
5
Residential Lighting
5-12%
4
Home Appliances
0%
2
Automobiles
10-30%
23
Adapted from L.A. Greening Energy Policy (2000) 28:398
Effects on Policy
Energy Efficiency.
There has been much debate on the role government-supported increases in energy
efficiency should play in the development of national energy policy. At one end of the
spectrum, some have even suggested increases in efficiency are counterproductive because
the rebound effect will lead to increased demand. Although most experts agree that this
is theoretically possible, in the U.S. domestic electricity and gasoline markets the rebound
effect will likely not exceed 10% to 40%, depending on which device is improved6.
Policy makers may be able to more accurately gauge the true benefits of proposed
efficiency programs by accounting for the rebound effect. For instance, some may
consider it desirable to increase appliance efficiency or fuel economy standards even
further than previously suggested to compensate for the predicted rebound effect. On the
other hand, some policy makers may feel that the proposed energy savings have been
reduced to the point to make the program no longer cost effective. Another choice could
be to keep the same program but slightly lower expectations of the benefits. In any event,
it should help policy makers objectively evaluate programs to know if the proponents of
a plan have accounted for the possible rebound effect in their projections of energy
savings.
It is important to remember that losses in energy savings due to the rebound effect
would generally be associated with gains in quality of life of the consumer. That is the
5 L.A. Greening, Energy efficiency and consumption - the rebound effect - a survey,
Energy Policy (2000) 28: 389-401
6 L. Schipper, p. 351

CRS-4
recipient of a more efficient heater can choose to live in a warmer house or spend the
energy cost savings on some other consumer good.
Greenhouse Gas Emissions.
The rebound effect can increase the difficulty of projecting the reduction in
greenhouse emissions from an improvement in energy efficiency. For example, a consumer
who saves money on his heating bill may spend it on a more carbon intensive activity.
Alternatively, the money could be spent on a less carbon intensive activity. Currently, the
only general agreement among specialists in this field, is that it is likely that increases in
energy efficiency will reduce carbon emissions per unit of Gross Domestic Product7. Some
argue that this suggests that increasing efficiency through government efforts is the best
route to reduce emissions while others argue that the market would produce the same or
better results without government intervention8.
For Additional Reading
On the rebound: the interaction of energy efficiency, energy use and economic activity
Energy Policy, v.28 (6-7), June 2000 p.351-500, L. Schipper ed.
U. S. Dept. of Energy, An econometric analysis of the elasticity of vehicle travel with
respect to fuel cost per mile using RTEC survey data.
ORNL-6950.
CRS Report RL30414. Global Climate Change: The Role for Energy Efficiency, by (nam
e redacted).
CRS Report IB10020. Energy Efficiency: Budget, Oil Conservation, and Electricity
Conservation Issues
, by (name redacted).
7 L. Schipper, p. 351
8 J. Glassman, p. 2

EveryCRSReport.com
The Congressional Research Service (CRS) is a federal legislative branch agency, housed inside the
Library of Congress, charged with providing the United States Congress non-partisan advice on
issues that may come before Congress.
EveryCRSReport.com republishes CRS reports that are available to al Congressional staff. The
reports are not classified, and Members of Congress routinely make individual reports available to
the public.
Prior to our republication, we redacted names, phone numbers and email addresses of analysts
who produced the reports. We also added this page to the report. We have not intentional y made
any other changes to any report published on EveryCRSReport.com.
CRS reports, as a work of the United States government, are not subject to copyright protection in
the United States. Any CRS report may be reproduced and distributed in its entirety without
permission from CRS. However, as a CRS report may include copyrighted images or material from a
third party, you may need to obtain permission of the copyright holder if you wish to copy or
otherwise use copyrighted material.
Information in a CRS report should not be relied upon for purposes other than public
understanding of information that has been provided by CRS to members of Congress in
connection with CRS' institutional role.
EveryCRSReport.com is not a government website and is not affiliated with CRS. We do not claim
copyright on any CRS report we have republished.