Order Code IB10068
CRS Issue Brief for Congress
Received through the CRS Web
Major Tax Issues in the 107th
Congress
Updated January 5, 2001
Edited by David L. Brumbaugh
Government and Finance Division
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

CONTENTS
SUMMARY
MOST RECENT DEVELOPMENTS
BACKGROUND AND ANALYSIS
The Economic Context
The State of the Economy
Taxes and the Budget
The Federal Tax Burden
Long-Run Economic Growth
Tax Proposals in the 106th Congress
The Bush Tax Proposals
A Closer Look at Selected Issues
Marriage Tax Penalties and Bonuses
The Estate Tax
The Alternative Minimum Tax for Individuals
Capital Gains
Tax Treatment of Saving
Fundamental Tax Reform Proposals


IB10068
01-05-01
Major Tax Issues in the 107th Congress
SUMMARY
Early indications are that the principal tax
alternative minimum tax, cuts in capital gains
issue in the first part of 2001 will be whether
taxes, more general rules for individual retire-
to cut taxes and, if so, by how much. In part,
ment accounts, and repeal of the estate and
this issue continues a debate that occurred
gift tax. The bill was estimated to reduce
through 1999 and 2000, as the federal budget
revenue by $792 billion over 10 years. Presi-
began to register surpluses for the first time in
dent Clinton argued that the tax cuts were too
nearly 30 years. Also, federal taxes as a per-
large and vetoed the bill.
cent of gross domestic product (GDP) reached
post World War II highs in fiscal years 1998-
In 2000, Congress revisited many of the
2000. These and other factors led some
proposed tax cuts that were in the TRRA, but
policymakers (especially Republicans) to
with a series of narrower, stand-alone bills
argue that the time was right for a tax cut.
rather than with one omnibus tax-cut package.
And, indeed, the congressional budget resolu-
Over the course of the year, Congress ap-
tions in 1999 and 2000 called for sizeable cuts.
proved a tax cut for married couples and
In general, supporters of tax cuts argued that
repeal of the estate tax. However, President
some or all of the non-Social Security “on
Clinton vetoed both measures. In addition, the
budget” surpluses should be returned to tax-
following tax cut proposals passed either the
payers as a tax cut. Critics maintained that the
House or Senate (or both, albeit in different
tax cuts were too large and those that were
forms): tax cuts for small business linked to a
actively considered favored upper income
minimum wage increase; tax benefits linked
individuals. Instead, they maintained that the
with retirement and pensions; repeal of taxes
surpluses should be used to pay down the
on Social Security benefits; repeal of the
national debt or increase spending.
telephone excise tax; and tax benefits linked
with education.
The precise outlines of the congressional
tax agenda for the first part of the 107th Con-
The new Congress may also consider the
gress have yet to take shape. But if tax cuts
tax proposals made by President-elect Bush
are considered in 2001, one place to look for
during the election campaign. Governor Bush
their possible shape is the tax measures that
proposed a $1.3 trillion tax cut over the period
were considered (and in some cases passed) by
2002-2010. Prominent specific tax cuts in his
Congress in 1999 and 2000, but that were not
proposal were a cut in statutory tax rates,
adopted due to opposition by the Clinton
doubling of the child tax credit, a tax cut for
Administration. In 1999, Congress passed the
married couples, and repeal of the estate and
Taxpayer Refund and Relief Act (TRRA).
gift tax.
The bill’s most prominent provisions included
an across-the-board cut in tax rates, a “mar-
riage penalty” tax cut for couples, repeal of the
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

IB10068
01-05-01

MOST RECENT DEVELOPMENTS
Early indications are that the question of whether to cut taxes will be perhaps the most
prominent tax issue that the 107th Congress will face in its early months. While the exact
nature of the tax agenda remains unclear, one possibility is that Congress will reconsider
many of the same tax cut proposals that it considered in 1999 and 2000, some of which
passed Congress but were vetoed by President Clinton. The latter included tax cuts for
married couples and repeal of the estate and gift tax, as well as numerous other tax
proposals. President-elect Bush has proposed a $1.3 trillion tax cut over the period 2002-
2010 and has argued that such a cut would be insurance against an economic slowdown.

BACKGROUND AND ANALYSIS
The Economic Context

The State of the Economy
At times in the past, tax cuts have been employed as a fiscal stimulus – that is, as a
means of boosting economic activity so as to revive a sluggish economy. For example, the
tax cut enacted by the Revenue Act of 1964 is thought by many to have boosted economic
growth and reduced unemployment. At the outset of 2001, however, the U.S. economy has
recorded over nine consecutive years of continuous expansion – the longest uninterrupted
expansion in U.S. history. Given this unprecedented prosperity, tax policy has not been called
upon in recent years as a tool to solve an economic crisis. Moreover, economists have
increasingly come to regard fiscal policy as a less effective tool than monetary policy for
addressing economic cycles because of time lags and adjustments in the international
economy.
But this may change in 2001 – indeed, the advisability of a tax cut as a fiscal stimulus
has emerged as one of the first tax policy debates in which the incoming Bush administration
has engaged. During the election campaign, President-elect Bush proposed a large tax cut,
including an across-the-board cut in marginal tax rates. And in December, both President-
elect Bush and Vice President-elect Richard Cheney have pointed to signs of weakness in the
economy and have argued that enactment of their tax-cut proposal would be insurance against
a recession.
There have, indeed, been indications of slowing economic growth: gross domestic
product grew at a substantially slower pace in the second quarter of 2000 than in the first; a
recent Federal Reserve survey found weakness in auto sales, manufacturing, and
construction. And Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan stated in early December that
U.S. economic growth had slowed “appreciably,” and early in January the Fed cut interest
rates by half a percentage point. At the same time, however, the outgoing Clinton
Administration has maintained that economic performance is still sound and a large tax cut
would not be prudent.
CRS-1

IB10068
01-05-01
For further information, see: CRS Report RL30329, Current Economic Conditions and
Selected Forecasts.

Taxes and the Budget
In fiscal year (FY) 1998, the federal budget registered a surplus for the first time in
nearly 30 years. The surplus is expected to grow steadily through FY2010, from 1.4% and
2.4% of GDP in FY1999 and FY2000 respectively to 4.2% by FY2005 and 5.5% by 2010.
While these surpluses have been expected, they occurred sooner than anticipated and are
larger than expected. According to the Congressional Budget Office (CBO), revenues are
the cause of the unexpected size of the surpluses. Rapid economic growth and changes in the
character of income have generated faster than expected growth in revenues. In particular,
the types of income that are taxable – corporate profits and wages and salaries – have grown
relatively rapidly, as has the share of income earned by upper income families who are subject
to high tax rates. In addition, growth in the volume and value of stock markets has increased
capital gains revenues.
The large number of individuals born during the surge in population growth following
World War II will begin to retire and start collecting Social Security and Medicare payments
within 20 years. This group of retirees is likely to experience an increase in life expectancy
and may face increased medical costs from improved technology. The combination of these
factors over time will rapidly increase the share of GDP devoted to health and retirement
programs and could produce – absent policy changes – a return to deficits in the long run.
The long-run budget outlook has been an important element in the current debate on
whether to cut taxes. For example, should near-term budget surpluses be returned to
taxpayers in the form of a tax cut? Recent congressional budget resolutions have stated that
“on budget” surpluses – that is, the surpluses excluding Social Security and Medicare
payments and revenues – should be returned to taxpayers as a tax cut. Opponents argue that
a larger share of near-term budget surpluses should be used to retire federal debt, which, they
contend, might promote economic growth that would delay the advent of future deficits,
thereby setting aside part of surpluses to finance the expected growth in health and retirement
costs.
For further information, see: CRS Issue Brief IB10052, The Budget for Fiscal Year 2001:
Issue Brief
; and CRS Report RL30583, The Economics of the Federal Budget Surplus.
The Federal Tax Burden1
During the 106th Congress, some pointed to the relatively high aggregate level of federal
taxes compared to the economy as evidence of the desirability of a tax cut. As a percentage
of gross domestic product (GDP), federal taxes were at their highest level since the end of
World War II in fiscal year 1999, at 20.0%. This level is not a dramatic departure from the
past; since the mid 1950s, federal taxes as a percentage of GDP have remained within a range
of between 17% and just below 20% of GDP. Growth in the economy combined with, to a
lesser extent, federal legislation to reduce the budget deficit (tax increases in 1990 and 1993)
1 Authored by Gregg A. Esenwein, Specialist in Public Finance, Government and Finance Division.
CRS-2

IB10068
01-05-01
have produced a slight increase in federal revenues as a percentage of GDP over the last
several years. In FY1990, federal taxes accounted for only 18.0% of GDP. Over the same
period, however, the federal budget has improved from a deficit of 3.9% of GDP in FY1990
to a surplus of 1.4% of GDP in FY1999.
While there have been some fluctuations in the distribution of the federal tax burden over
the last 20 years, the fluctuations have been concentrated at the ends of the income spectrum.
During the 1980s the federal tax burden increased for lower-income families and decreased
for upper income families. This trend was reversed in the 1990s with tax reductions at the
lower end of the income spectrum and tax increases at the upper end of the income spectrum.
Families in the middle income brackets, however, experienced very little change in their
federal tax burdens over this period, despite legislated tax cuts. Some of the benefits of the
tax changes contained in the tax cut enacted with the 1997 Taxpayer Relief Act did not
necessarily accrue to middle-income families. The $500 child tax credit likely reduced federal
taxes for middle income families, but only those families with qualifying children. The
benefits of reductions in the tax on capital gains, expanded IRAs, and other savings and
investment incentives tended to accrue to families at the upper-end of the income spectrum.
For further information, see CRS Report RS20059, The Federal Tax Burden, and CRS
Report RS20087, The Level of Taxes in the United States, 1941-1999.

Long-Run Economic Growth
As noted above (see the section entitled “The State of the Economy”), President-elect
Bush has stated that a tax cut is desirable early in 2001 because the economy is beginning to
show signs of slowing down. This position suggests a view of tax cuts as a useful tool for
countering down-turns in the business cycle, as well as for other purposes. Many of the tax
cut proposals in the previous Congress, however, were intended to promote long-run
economic growth in an already-booming economy by increasing private saving and
investment. In that context, the impact of these previous congressional proposals on saving
is perhaps the most prominent economic performance issue they presented. First, can tax
incentives for saving or tax benefits for investment actually boost the nation’s rate of private
saving and investment? Second, total national saving consists of private saving minus
government borrowing. Thus, is any expansion the proposals may cause in private saving
larger than any increase they also cause in the federal budget deficit (or decrease in the federal
budget surplus)? If provisions actually cause an increase in total national saving, the nation’s
capital stock expands, resulting in higher economic growth. Yet economic analysis is not
clear on whether and by how much private savings responds to tax incentives.
A number of the tax provisions that were considered provided favorable tax treatment
to particular types of economic activity, extending special tax credits, deductions, or
exclusions to certain activities. In these cases, economic theory suggests that favorable
treatment for the specified activities can distort the economy’s ordinary decision making and
channel more resources into the favored activity than would otherwise occur. Since the
economy’s resources are limited, this effect also means that resources are simultaneously
drawn away from activities that are not tax-favored. The question that economic analysis
pursues is whether a specific intervention in resource allocation actually improves overall
economic performance.
CRS-3

IB10068
01-05-01
An important aspect of any tax proposal is its effect on federal revenues and the federal
budget deficit or surplus. Deficit reduction has been a primary focus of budget debates over
the past several years. The effects on federal revenue of several elements of the various tax
proposals have been questioned. For instance, as noted earlier, economic analysis does not
provide clear-cut answers about the extent to which economic activity might increase in
response to tax incentives. As a result, the ultimate revenue effects of broad-based tax cuts
or tax incentives for saving are unclear. In addition, several changes — notably, those
involving IRAs, depreciation, and capital gains — would likely register a much larger revenue
impact a number of years in the future rather than in the near term. Their supporters,
however, generally argue that the measures would stimulate economic growth that would
shrink any revenue loss.
Tax Proposals in the 106th Congress

If Congress actively considers a tax cut in 2001, its precise shape is as yet unclear.
However, one guide to possible congressional action may be proposals that were considered
in 1999 and 2000, but that were vetoed or not adopted.
! Tax cuts for married couples. This proposal is designed, in part, to offset
current law’s so-called “marriage penalty” that results in two persons paying
more as a married couple than they would if they were single. (Many
couples, however, receive a marriage bonus rather than penalty under current
law; the proposals passed by the 106th Congress would have given tax cuts
to these couples also.) A tax cut for couples was a prominent part of the
vetoed Taxpayer Refund and Relief Act of 1999 (TRRA) and was passed in
2000 as H.R. 4810, which was also vetoed by President Clinton.
! Repeal or reduction of the estate and gift tax. Because of its exemption
amount and other special provisions, only a small fraction of estates pay the
federal estate and gift tax. The tax has been criticized by some, however, as
discouraging saving and placing a burden on the cash-flow of small
businesses. The TRRA would have repealed the tax as would have H.R. 8,
which passed Congress in 2000. Both were vetoed by the President.
! Tax cuts for small business. The House passed several bills – H.R. 3081
and the Taxpayer Relief Act of 2000 (TRA2000; H.R. 2416) – increasing the
minimum wage. The bills included a number of tax cuts that were designed
to offset part of the burden of the minimum wage increase for small business.
Prominent among the cuts were an increase in the so-called “expensing”
allowance for small business investment, an increase in the allowable business
meals deduction, and more generous rules for accounting for installment
sales.
! Tax benefits for health insurance and long-term care. Both TRRA99 and
TRA2000 included deductions for health insurance costs and long-term care
insurance that would be available to non-itemizers and a deduction for
caretakers of family members. Both bills also included a number of other tax
cuts related to health insurance and long-term care.
CRS-4

IB10068
01-05-01
! Tax cuts related to pensions and retirement. TRRA99 and TRA2000
also contained a set of tax reductions related to pensions and retirement
savings. Prominent among these was a proposal in TRA2000 to increase
contribution limits for Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs).
! Tax benefits for education. In 2000 the House Ways and Means
Committee approved H.R. 7, which contained a number of tax cuts related
to education. The bill expanded tax-favored savings accounts for education
and provided expanded tax benefits for bonds used to finance school
construction and rehabilitation. The bill was never considered by the full
House.
! Telecommunications excise tax. In 2000, Congress passed a repeal of the
federal excise tax on communications as part of H.R. 4516, which also
included appropriations for several federal agencies and the legislative
branch. President Clinton vetoed the bill for reasons not directly related to
the tax’s repeal.
! Tax on Social Security benefits. In 2000, the House passed H.R. 4865,
which repealed the tax on Social Security benefits that was enacted in 1993.
The Senate did not consider the measure.
! Alternative minimum tax. In recent years, concern has increased in some
quarters over the likelihood that an increasing number of taxpayers will
become subject to the alternative minimum tax (AMT) – a consequence of
new tax benefits that have been enacted in recent years and the erosion of the
real value of the AMT exemption by inflation. To address these concerns,
TRRA99 would have repealed the AMT altogether; Public Law 106-170
provided for the applicability of personal tax credits against the AMT, but
only through 2001.
! Tax cut for capital gains. Supporters of tax cuts for capital gains argue
that such reductions stimulate savings, investment, and economic growth;
opponents of capital gains cuts maintain they favor upper-income individuals.
One of the most prominent provisions of TRRA99 was a reduction in capital
gains tax rates. The proposal was not one of the issues addressed by “stand
alone” bills in 2000.
! Across-the-board tax rate reduction. TRRA99 included a reduction in the
statutory individual income tax rates. As with capital gains, the provision
was not included in a stand alone bill in 2000. A broad cut in tax rates,
however, is part of the tax plan set forth by President-elect Bush during the
presidential campaign.
CRS-5

IB10068
01-05-01
The Bush Tax Proposals

Another possible set of proposals Congress may consider are those set forth by
President-elect Bush during the 2000 election campaign. The Bush tax proposals call for a
tax cut what would total an estimated $1.3 trillion over the 2002-2010 period. His plan
includes the following proposals.
! Reduction in individual income tax rates. The plan would replace the
current rate structure with rates of 10%, 15%, 25%, and 33%.
! Increased child credit. The credit would be doubled to $1,000 from
current law’s $500.
! Tax cut for married couples. Married couples would be allowed a
deduction equal to 10% of a second-earners wages, up to $3,000.
! Elimination of estate and gift taxes.
! Permanent research and experimentation tax credit. Current law’s credit
is scheduled to expire June 30th, 2004.
! Charitable contribution deduction for non-itemizers.
! Education savings accounts. Current law’s annual contribution limit of
$500 would be increased to $5,000.
! Elimination of the Social Security earnings test.

A Closer Look at Selected Issues
Marriage Tax Penalties and Bonuses2
Defining the married couple as a single tax unit under the federal individual income tax
conflicts with the principle of marriage neutrality. Marriage neutrality means that the tax
system should not influence the choice of individuals with regard to their marital status.
However, under the current federal income tax system, some married couples pay more
income tax than they would as two unmarried singles (a marriage tax penalty) while other
married couples pay less income tax than they would as two unmarried singles (a marriage
tax bonus). A marriage-neutral income tax is an elusive goal. Marriage neutrality conflicts
with two other concepts of equity: progressivity and equal taxation of couples with equal
incomes. Regardless of how these three concepts of equity are juggled, an income tax can
achieve any two of these goals but cannot simultaneously achieve all three.
2 Authored by Gregg Esenwein, Specialist in Public Finance, Government and Finance Division.
CRS-6

IB10068
01-05-01
A number of bills were introduced in the 106th Congress that tried to mitigate marriage
tax penalties. For instance, H.R. 2488, the Taxpayer Refund and Relief Act of 1999,
contained a provision that would have increased the standard deduction for a married couple
filing a joint return to twice the amount of the standard deduction for a single return, doubled
the width of the lowest income tax bracket for married couples, and raised the phase-out
range of the Earned Income Tax Credit for married persons. H.R. 4810, which Congress
passed in 2000, adopted the same approach. Other bills in the 106th Congress took alternative
approaches, including a tax deduction for a couple’s second earner, and permitting married
persons the option of filing separately as singles.
For further information, see: CRS Report RL30420, Marriage Tax Penalties: Legislative
Proposals in the 106th Congress
; and CRS Report RL30419, The Marriage Tax Penalty: An
Overview of the Issues
.
The Estate Tax3
The estate tax was enacted in 1916 as a revenue source for World War I. As with
wealth taxes before it, and like most other taxes, revenue was the primary rationale for the
tax. Why the estate tax rather than other possible sources of revenue? There were essentially
two reasons: first, the estate tax is viewed as a type of fee for the services by the government
in protecting property during lifetime, as well as a fee to cover part of the cost of probating
the estate at death. More importantly, the estate tax was chosen over other taxes for reasons
of equity and to reduce the concentration of wealth. In 1998, only 4.2% of decedents left
estates large enough to file a tax return. Further, due primarily to the marital deduction, less
than half of those required to file a return (2.0% of all estates) owed tax.
The federal estate tax is a tax on wealth and as such, it raises some of the same economic
issues as annual wealth taxes, which are economically equivalent to annual capital income
taxes. The accumulation of wealth is, in large part, the result of an individual’s decision to
postpone consumption, to save and accumulate capital during one’s life of work and
investment, and to take risks. The estate tax is a tax on accumulated savings imposed at the
end of one’s life. And the tax is paid out of the economy’s total supply of private savings —
reducing private sector savings and increasing government savings (i.e, tax revenue). But an
important economic question is what is the effect, if any, on the lifetime savings behavior of
individuals? Does the estate tax reduce savings rates? Does the tax reduce the incentives to
accumulate capital? To what extent do individuals compensate for the tax by increasing their
accumulation of pre-tax wealth such that enough after-tax wealth is accumulated to bequeath
to their heirs?
The estate tax is part of the overall cost of bequeathing wealth to one’s heirs. The
existence of the estate tax is believed to reduce the level of planned bequests. If so, reducing
the estate tax is likely to increase planned bequests, but according to economic theory, the
effect on savings is uncertain. The estate tax does create incentives for lifetime gift giving,
for estate planning, for substantial charitable donations, and for the establishment of trusts.
With federal marginal estate tax rates reaching 55%, significant resources and time may be
expended at minimizing the estate tax burden. And a relatively large estate planning industry
3 Authored by Sal Lazzari, Specialist in Public Finance, Resources, Science, and Industry Division.
CRS-7

IB10068
01-05-01
— accountants, lawyers, and financial advisors — is available to wealth holders to minimize
any potential estate tax burden.
One economic effect — the effect on farms and small businesses — has dominated the
recent debate over the estate tax and played a key role in the estate tax cuts enacted as part
of the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997. The estate tax is imposed on business capital and wealth
— land, equipment, stock, buildings, etc. — in addition to personal wealth. It is argued that
this takes capital out of farms and small businesses, inhibiting their transfer to heirs and
retention in the family; that the tax can cause the break-up or dissolution of family farms and
small business. A sale of the assets to or merger of the enterprise with a large competitor
could reduce market competition and inhibit economic efficiency. These effects were a
principal reason for the 1981 estate tax reductions, and have been a key impetus for most of
the recent proposals to reduce the estate tax. However, the estate tax is only one of many
possible causes for the sale of farm or business assets outside the family at death, and not
always the principal cause – especially since only a small fraction of family businesses pay the
tax.
For further information, see: CRS Report RL30600, Estate and Gift Taxes: Economic
Issues
; and CRS Report RS20593, Asset Distribution of Taxable Estates: An Analysis.
The Alternative Minimum Tax for Individuals4
To make sure that everyone pays at least a minimum of taxes while still preserving the
economic and social incentives in the tax code, Congress created, in 1969, what is now
known as the individual alternative minimum tax (AMT). In essence, the AMT is a tax on the
use of tax incentives and preferences and was primarily targeted at upper-income taxpayers
who were thought to overuse these preferences to reduce or eliminate their regular income
tax liabilities. However, since its inception, the value and effectiveness of the minimum tax
has routinely been the subject of congressional debate. Recently, many analysts have voiced
concern over the expected increase in the number of upper-middle income taxpayers who may
be subject to AMT coverage in the near future. This increase will occur because of the
combined effects of inflation and recent legislative changes to the regular income tax.
The structural components of the regular income tax are indexed for inflation while the
structural components of the AMT are not. Consequently, the gap between tax liabilities
under the regular income tax and the AMT will shrink over time and many taxpayers could
end up subject to the unindexed AMT or experience reductions in their nonrefundable tax
credits under the regular income tax solely as the result of inflation. The potential problems
of an indexed regular tax and an unindexed AMT have long been recognized by tax analysts.
The Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT) released estimates showing that in 1997,
approximately 605,000 taxpayers were subject to the AMT but that the number of taxpayers
subject to the AMT will increase to around 9.2 million by tax year 2007. These estimates,
however, were made prior to the passage of the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997. When the
effects of both inflation and the 1997 legislative changes are taken into account, preliminary
estimates indicate that by 2007, the number of taxpayers falling under either the AMT or
AMT limits on their tax credits under the regular income tax will grow to almost 12 million.
4 Authored by Gregg Esenwein, Specialist in Public Finance, Government and Finance Division.
CRS-8

IB10068
01-05-01
In general, nonrefundable personal tax credits under the regular income tax are limited to the
amount by which a taxpayer’s regular income tax liability exceeds his tentative minimum tax.
Hence, even if a taxpayer owes no AMT, the AMT could reduce the value of his
nonrefundable personal tax credits under the regular income tax.
The child tax credit and the HOPE tax credit are the two changes contained in the 1997
act that would have the largest impact in increasing the number of taxpayers subject to the
AMT, either directly or indirectly. Many taxpayers in the upper-middle income ranges likely
will see the value of these two credits reduced or eliminated because of the AMT. The fact
that the AMT is now going to affect many upper-middle income taxpayers who were not
subject to the tax in the past has prompted some calls in Congress for action to remedy the
situation. Congress did take limited action in 1998 by including a provision in the Omnibus
Consolidated and Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act (PL. 105-277) that will
mitigate part of the problems with the AMT for tax year 1998. Under this provision,
nonrefundable personal tax credits are fully allowed against a taxpayer’s regular income tax
liability for 1998 even if the credits are in excess of the amount by which the taxpayer’s
regular income tax exceeds the amount of his tentative minimum tax.
For further information, see CRS Report RL30149, The Alternative Minimum Tax for
Individuals
and CRS Report RL30485, The Individual Alternative Minimum Tax: Interaction
with Marriage Penalty Relief and Other Tax Cuts
.
Capital Gains5
Since the enactment of the individual income tax in 1913, the appropriate taxation of
capital gains income has been a perennial topic of debate in Congress. Capital gains income
is often discussed as if it were somehow different from other forms of income. Yet, for
purposes of income taxation, capital gains income is essentially no different from any other
form of income from capital, such as interest or dividend income. A capital gain or loss is the
result of a sale or exchange of a capital asset. If the asset is sold for a higher price than its
acquisition price, then the transaction produces a capital gain. If an asset is sold for a lower
price than its acquisition price, then the transaction produces a capital loss.
Current law’s treatment of capital gains differs from what would occur under a
theoretically pure income tax. Ideally, a tax consistent with a theoretically correct measure
of income would be assessed on real (inflation-adjusted) income when that income accrues
to the taxpayer. Conversely, real losses should be deducted as they accrue to the taxpayer.
In addition, economic theory indicates that any untaxed real appreciation in the value of
capital assets given as gifts or bequests should be subject to tax at the time of transfer. Under
the current income tax, however, nominal (non-inflation adjusted) capital gains income is
taxed when it is realized (sold or exchanged) by the taxpayer. Capital losses (within certain
limits) are also deducted on a nominal basis when they are realized by the taxpayer.
Currently, the untaxed appreciation in the value of capital assets transferred at death is not
subject to tax.
5 Authored by Gregg Esenwein, Specialist in Public Finance, Government and Finance Division.
CRS-9

IB10068
01-05-01
Under current law, capital assets are separated into four categories. Assets that have
been held for 12 months or less are considered short-term assets. Assets that have been held
longer than 12 months are considered long-term assets. Collectibles (art work, antiques,
coins, stamps, etc.) are the third category of assets and the fourth category of capital gains
assets includes the portion of gain attributable to previously taken depreciation deductions
on section 1250 property (depreciable real estate). Short-term capital gains are taxed at
regular income tax rates. Long-term capital gains are taxed at a maximum tax rate of 20%.
The tax rate is 10% for long-term gains that would have been taxed at a 15% regular tax rate.
Collectibles held longer than 12 months are taxed at 28%. The un-recaptured section 1250
gain attributable to depreciation deductions is taxed at a maximum tax rate of 25%.
Effective for taxable years beginning in 2001, assets that have been held for at least five
years and would have been taxed at a 10% tax rate will be taxed at an 8% tax rate. For assets
which are held more than five years and whose holding period begins after December 31,
2000, the maximum tax rate will be 18% rather than 20%. Net capital losses are deductible
against up to $3,000 of ordinary income, that is, non-capital gain income. Any portion of the
net loss in excess of the $3,000 limit can be carried forward and used to offset gains in
succeeding tax years. Excess net losses can be carried forward indefinitely and without limit
on the amount of losses that can be carried forward.
Under current law, taxpayers are allowed to exclude from taxable income up to
$500,000 ($250,000 in the case of single returns) of the gain from the sale of their principal
residences. To qualify the taxpayer must have owned and occupied the residence for at least
two of the previous five years prior to the date of sale. Under current law, capital gains
transferred at time of death are not subject to tax. On transfer at death, the basis of the asset
(original cost plus changes in the value due to improvements or depreciation) is stepped up
to the market value of the asset on the date of death.
For further information, see CRS Report 98-473, Individual Capital Gains Income:
Legislative History
; CRS Report 96-769, Capital Gains Taxes: An Overview; and CRS
Report RL30040, Capital Gains Taxes, Innovation and Growth.
Tax Treatment of Saving
The appropriate tax treatment of saving has been one of the most prominent tax policy
debates in recent decades and will likely be so again in the 107th Congress. It incorporates
such topics as individual retirement accounts (IRAs), capital gains taxes, investment
incentives, and corporate income taxes, to name a few. The issue of savings has links to both
economic performance and equity, which has helped make it controversial. An increased
saving rate generally increases the country’s capital stock, which in turn makes possible higher
economic growth and a higher standard of living in the future. If tax incentives can boost
saving, targeted tax cuts may thus be able to boost economic growth. On the other hand,
income from investments is a higher proportion of income at higher income levels; tax benefits
for saving thus reduce the progressivity of the tax system.
Economics suggests that the efficacy of tax incentives for saving depends heavily on how
responsive individuals’ savings rates are to changes in the rate of return to saving, after taxes.
If individuals respond to tax incentives by increasing their saving, tax benefits may be an
effective tool for increasing economic growth. On the other hand, if saving is unresponsive
CRS-10

IB10068
01-05-01
to targeted tax cuts, their efficacy for that purpose is questionable. Economic theory provides
no clear answer on this issue and instead identifies two countervailing effects of tax incentives
for saving. One effect (known as the substitution effect) leads individuals to save more
because the aftertax rate of return has increased; a second effect (the income effect) works
in the opposite direction, because a tax cut enables an individual to reach a given savings
target with a lower savings rate.
The ambiguity of economic theory in this case passes the burden of proof to empirical
evidence, and there have indeed been a plentitude of statistical studies. But taken as a group,
these studies too produce no clear answer; some find a positive and significant relationship
between tax incentives and saving — that is, they find that targeted tax cuts increase saving.
Other studies find no relationship, and still others find a negative relationship. Thus, the
impact of taxes on saving is unproved. However, even if individuals were to respond
positively to savings incentives, that does not necessarily mean incentives are good economic
policy. First, what matters for economic growth is not simply private saving but national
saving — that is, the private saving rate minus any government dissaving by means of a
budget deficit. Thus, the effect of tax cuts for saving in reducing government tax revenue
may at least partly offset any positive effect they may have on private saving. Second, even
though increased saving produces higher standards of living in the future, a tax-induced
distortion that increases saving may not actually increase economic welfare. Absent market
failures, economic theory suggests a tax is more efficient the less it changes behavior. And
if saving is unresponsive to tax changes, it may be less damaging to economic welfare than
alternative sources of tax revenue. Again, however, evidence on the responsiveness of saving
is conflicting. Indeed, this statement summarizes what economics has to say about tax
incentives for saving: theory and evidence on the efficacy of savings incentives is ambiguous
and conflicting.
Tax benefits for saving in the current tax code are numerous. Among the most
prominent are Individual Retirement Account (IRAs), 401(k) retirement savings plans and
other qualified employer-sponsored retirement plans, life insurance policies and annuities,
qualified state tuition programs, and medical savings accounts (MSAs). In addition, the
favorable tax treatment of owner-occupied housing can be thought of as a saving incentive,
as can the reduced tax rates for capital gains under the individual income tax.
For further information, see CRS Report RL30255. Individual Retirement Accounts
(IRAs): Issues, Proposed Expansion and Universal Savings Accounts (USAs)

Fundamental Tax Reform Proposals6
(Including Flat Tax Plans)
The idea of replacing our current income tax system with a “flat-rate tax” is receiving
renewed congressional interest. Although often referred to as “flat-rate taxes,” many of the
recent proposals (introduced in the 104th, 105th, or 106th Congresses) go much further than
merely adopting a flat-rate tax structure. Some involve significant income tax base-
broadening while others entail changing the tax base from income to consumption. Most of
the recent tax reform proposals (the Armey, Shelby, Domenici/Nunn, English, Specter,
6 Authored by James M. Bickley, Specialist in Public Finance, Government and Finance Division.
CRS-11

IB10068
01-05-01
Lugar, Tauzin, Linder, Souder, Gramm, Faircloth, and Largent/Hutchinson plans) would
change the tax base from income to consumption. Others are not consumption tax proposals.
Representative Gephardt would keep income as the tax base but broaden the base and lower
the tax rates. Representative Crane’s proposal would levy a tax on the earned income of each
individual as a replacement for the current individual income tax, corporate income tax, and
estate and gift taxes. Representative Snowbarger’s proposal would permit each taxpayer to
choose between the current individual income tax return and an alternative individual tax
return with a flat rate. Senator Dorgan’s proposal would allow most taxpayers to choose
between the current individual tax system and his “shortcut” tax plan under which taxes
withheld would equal the employee’s tax liability.
The flat tax controversy has focused on shifting from the present system, which is
predominantly an income tax system, to a consumption tax system as a way to raise the
savings rate, improve economic efficiency, and simplify the tax system. There is, however,
no conclusive empirical evidence that a consumption tax will or will not increase the personal
savings rate and consequently the level of national savings. Highly stylized life-cycle models
show that a consumption tax would cause a substantial increase in the savings rate, but these
models are controversial because of their idealized assumptions. To raise the same amount
of tax revenue, a consumption-based tax would require higher marginal tax rates than would
an income tax (since consumption is smaller than income). Distortions caused by these higher
marginal rates could offset (or even exceed) other advantages of the consumption tax. Hence,
whether an income tax system or a consumption tax system is more efficient is unknown.
Proponents of some flat tax proposals argue that integration of the current corporate and
individual income taxes as well as simple returns would result from a consumption tax. The
current income tax system is complex. The federal tax code and the federal tax regulations
are lengthy and continue to expand. However, in tax year 1999, approximately 70% of
individual taxpayers took the standard deduction, which made complexity less relevant. In
comparison to the current income tax, a flat rate would do little to reduce complexity for
most taxpayers who currently just look up their tax liability in a table, although it might
reduce complexity for a significant minority. Finally, some argue that it is “unfair” to
compare the current income tax system with an uncomplicated, “pure” consumption tax that
could become complicated by the time it is enacted.
It has been argued that some flat tax proposals would reduce the balance-of-trade deficit
since imports would be taxed but the tax would be rebatable on exports. Economic theory,
however, suggests that border tax adjustments have no effect on the balance-of-trade because
the balance-of-trade is a function of international capital flows; border tax adjustments would
be offset by exchange rate adjustments.
The United States is the only developed country without a broad-based consumption tax
at the national level. Other developed nations have adopted broad-based consumption taxes,
but as adjuncts rather than as replacements for their income based taxes.
For further information, see CRS Issue Brief IB95060, Flat Tax Proposals: An Overview.
CRS-12